Oxford University Press
Oxford University Press
Oxford University Press
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly
Journal of Economics.
http://www.jstor.org
THE OPTIMAL DEGREE OF COMMITMENT TO AN
INTERMEDIATE MONETARY TARGET*
KENNETH ROGOFF
Society can sometimes make itself better off by appointing a central banker
who does not share the social objective function, but instead places "too large" a
weight on inflation-rate stabilization relative to employment stabilization. Al-
though having such an agent head the central bank reduces the time-consistent
rate of inflation, it suboptimally raises the variance of employment when supply
shocks are large. Using an envelope theorem, we show that the ideal agent places
a large, but finite, weight on inflation. The analysis also provides a new framework
for choosing among alternative intermediate monetary targets.
I. INTRODUCTION
It is now widely recognized that even if a country has a per-
fectly benevolent central bank (one that attempts to maximize
the social welfare function), it may suffer from having an inflation
rate which is systematically too high.' Suppose, for example, that
a distortion (such as income taxation) causes the market rate of
employment to be suboptimal. Then inflation can arise because
wage setters rationally fear that the central bank will try to take
advantage of short-term nominal rigidities to raise employment
systematically. Only by setting high rates of wage inflation can
wage setters discourage the central bank from trying to reduce
the real wage below their target level.
This paper considers some institutional responses to the time-
consistency problem described above. In particular, we examine
the practice of appointing "conservatives" to head the central
bank, or of giving the central bank concrete incentives to achieve
an intermediate monetary target. Our analysis of intermediate
monetary targeting is quite different from conventional analyses
in which the central bank is rigidly constrained to follow a par-
ticular feedback rule. Indeed, an important conclusion is that it
is not generally optimal to legally constrain the central bank to
hit its intermediate target (or follow its rule) exactly, or to choose
t? 1985 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. Published by John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1985 CCC 0033-5533/85/041169-21$04.00
1170 QUARTERLYJOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
2. This follows from the assumption that there are nominal wage contracts.
See, for example, Fischer [19771.
THE OPTIMALDEGREE OF COMMITMENT 1171
2. Aggregate Demand
Demand for the good that firms produce is a decreasing func-
tion of the real interest rate:
(8) d= - {r - [Et(pt+1) - Pt]} + Ut,
4. This is the first of many times throughout the paper where use is made of
the fact that certainty equivalence holds when the loss function is quadratic; see
Sargent [1979].
THE OPTIMAL DEGREE OF COMMITMENT 1173
6. Unanticipated inflation enters indirectly into the social loss function (10)
through its effect on employment. Fischer and Modigliani [1978] catalog the eco-
nomic costs of both anticipated and unanticipated inflation.
THE OPTIMALDEGREE OF COMMITMENT 1175
tion, the contract at their firm has only a small impact on the
aggregate inflation rate.
By substituting equation (6) into equation (10), and recalling
that h' - n' = h - n, the central bank's objective function under
fully discretionary monetary policy may be written as
(11) Dt = At = [zWbq+ (Pt - )/o- (nf - n
+ X[Pt - Pt 1 -*],
Recall that (the logarithm of) wage setters' target real wage is
zero. Thus, wage setters select u' by taking expectations across
(12) and setting e =-Et -ID):8
I
(13) O = Et-1(pD) = Pt-i + * + (h - n)/Xot = Pt-i + ir1D.
By choosing t according to (13), wage setters assure themselves
that the monetary authorities will not systematically drive down
the real wage. Thus, as Kydland and Prescott [1977] point out,
the time-consistent rate of inflation is too high when h > n.
We are now prepared to evaluate social welfare under fully
discretionary monetary policy. But to facilitate exposition in later
sections, we shall first develop a notation for evaluating the ex-
pected value of the social welfare function under any arbitrary
monetary policy regime "A", AA:
(14) It =( - n)2+xHA+FA
Note that u and v do not enter the expression for the price pre-
diction error that the central bank allows to occur. The central
bank offsets the price level effects of aggregate demand shocks to
the best of its ability (here perfect, because of the complete in-
formation assumption), because offsetting these shocks is con-
sistent with both employment stabilization and inflation-rate sta-
bilization. By substituting (15) into (14), and simplifying, one can
obtain
(22a) cA X= (H) +
(22b) -= 2 (w-2 + X + ]
(3)
11. For an illustration of some issues that arise when the monetary author-
ities' preferences are unknown, see Backus and Driffill's
[i1985 interpretation of
Kreps and Wilson's [1982] analysis.
1180 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
V. INTERMEDIATEMONETARY TARGETING
In the previous section we demonstrated conditions under
which society can make itself better off by appointing an indi-
vidual to head the central bank who is (somewhat) more inflation-
conscious than average. The same model can be employed to ex-
plain many of the measures that countries take to insulate their
central banks from inflationary pressures. For example, central
banks are often endowed with a significant measure of political
and fiscal independence. The analysis also suggests why it would
be desirable to have a central bank's operations financed in such
a way that its expenditures are independent of the government's
seignorage revenues. (It is interesting to observe that during the
high inflation years of the late sixties and the seventies, archi-
tecturally stunning new Federal Reserve buildings sprouted up
all over the United States.)
In some sense, the widespread adoption of intermediate mone-
tary targeting during the seventies may be viewed as an insti-
tutional response to the time-consistency problem. Suppose, for
example, that through a system of rewards and punishments the
central bank's incentives are altered so that it places some direct
weight on achieving a low rate of growth for a nominal variable
such as the price level, nominal GNP, or the money supply. Al-
though these alternative targets have different stabilization prop-
erties, credibly increasing the central bank's commitment to
achieving any of them would reduce the time-consistent rate of
inflation (as can be demonstrated along the lines of the Theorem
in Section IV). A very direct way of making the commitment
credible would be to tie the annual remuneration or budget of the
monetary authorities to their success in hitting their intermediate
monetary targets. This could perhaps be accomplished through a
system of bonuses or by fixing their income in nominal terms.
Other explicit penalties might include requiring the central bank
to devote substantial resources to publicly justifying a deviation
from its targets. An implicit penalty would be if the central bank's
powers and independence are affected by how well it succeeds in
hitting its stated targets. (Of course, if the central bank is already
THE OPTIMAL DEGREE OF COMMITMENT 1181
+T[+(1 () (hPt +) t- Pt 1 - j *]
(25)
13. The fact that 0 < rmin < cc may be demonstrated analogously to the Theo-
rem in Section IV. A simpler proof makes use of the fact that NA is minimized at
p =D, and that FA is strictly increasing in JpA
THE OPTIMAL DEGREE OF COMMITMENT 1183
14. Tmin = w if (1
- p)2 + aL2X= (1 -
p)(1 + 43 - p)/(otw+ 1). Note that if
L = 0, then rigid nominal GNP targeting is equivalent to employment tar-
geting.
1184 QUARTERLYJOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
+ (; - 1)(1 t ) + Vt - Pt-1 -
2
(33) 1+o[7i+i + (1 ) Pt ( Zt)
where rt+ 1 has been substituted in for It+ 1. (Given the assump-
tions we have made about the parameters of the macro model,
the mean real interest rate under any monetary regime is zero.)
A comparison of equations (13) and (33) reveals that rR
S D as r + 1. In other words, suppose that an intermediate
targeting regime is put in place for one period, and the central
bank is given incentives to bring interest rates below their trend
rate, so that ? < rt+ 1. Then, instead of falling, the expected infla-
tion rate and expected nominal interest rate rise. They rise be-
cause wage setters recognize that once wages are set, the central
bank can lower interest rates through money growth. While it is
true that the central bank could try to bring down inflation by
setting ? greater than rt+ 1, the fact that this would indeed cause
the market-determined interest rate rt to be less than itA+1 sug-
gests a serious credibility problem. The central bank has to target
high interest rates if it wants low interest rates.
The underlying problem is that given Et- (pt+l - Pt), an-
nouncing a target for rt is, in fact, tantamount to targeting the
real interest rate. For the regimes analyzed earlier, targeting
succeeds in at least temporarily lowering the inflation rate re-
gardless of how long the targeting regime is expected to last. This
is no longer true when the nominal interest rate is used as a
1186 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
VI. ON COMPARINGALTERNATIVETARGETINGREGIMES
In more traditional analyses of intermediate monetary tar-
geting, a conventional result is that the optimal target choice
depends on all the parameters of the model as well as on the
relative sizes of the disturbances. 19 While one must also consider
strategic factors in the more general model developed here, the
standard stabilization considerations are still relevant. For ex-
ample, money-supply targeting makes less sense when the mone-
tary authorities have information about how aggregate demand
shocks are affecting the price level. Inflation-rate targeting works
poorly when supply shocks are significant, etc. Indeed, if we were
to restrict our attention to "rigid" targeting regimes (that is, if
the monetary authorities are required to hit their target exactly),
then (of course) the ranking of regimes depends only on these
conventional stabilization considerations (see the Appendix).
Ranking the optimally flexible regimes of Section V is some-
what more difficult because they do not have tractable closed-
form solutions. (For specific parameter values, numerical com-
parisons are easily obtained.) It is worth noting, however, that
the ranking of optimally flexible regimes is not necessarily the
same as the ranking of "rigid" regimes presented in the Appen-
dix.20 This is not surprising in view of the "second-best" nature
of the rigid targeting regimes; it is almost never optimal to con-
strain the monetary authorities to hit their target exactly.
18. It can be shown that low nominal interest rate targeting is counterproduc-
tive when the regime is expected to last for any finite number of periods, as long
as the expected inflation rate in the final period is consistent with a return to
fully discretionary monetary policy. The regime fails because the central bank
cannot systematically achieve a below-market real interest rate for any future
period.
19. See Poole [1975], Friedman [1975], or Parkin [1978] for analyses of the
stabilization properties of alternative intermediate monetary targets.
20. Numerical examples of rank reversal are presented in an earlier version
of this paper, available on request. Numerical solutions for Tmin are easier to obtain
when AAi/aTiS strictly concave in T. Using Descartes' Law of Signs, one can derive
the sufficient condition 1I(a - (X2) > X. Similarly, dAM/dI is definitely concave in
p. if [4~+ (XIS)]/(ct - at2) > X.
THE OPTIMAL DEGREE OF COMMITMENT 1187
VII. CONCLUSIONS
It can be entirely rational for society to structure its central
bank in such a way that the monetary authorities have an ob-
jective function very different from the social welfare function.
Whenever a distortion causes the time-consistent rate of inflation
to be too high, then society can be made better off by having the
central bank place "too large" a weight on inflation rate stabili-
zation. The model presented here may help explain why many
countries set up an independent central bank and choose its gov-
ernors from conservative elements of the financial community.
Although society does want the central bank to place a large
weight on inflation rate stabilization relative to employment sta-
bilization, society will not (in general) want the weight to be infi-
nite. By having the central bank place an infinite weight on infla-
tion stabilization, society could succeed in bringing inflation down
to its socially optimal level. But the central bank would also end
up responding very inappropriately to supply shocks, allowing them
to pass entirely through to employment. By lowering the weight
which the central bank places on inflation, society could achieve a
first-order stabilization gain at a second-order inflation cost.
However, the inflation weight should not be so low that the cen-
tral bank is placing the same weight on inflation-stabilization as
society does. For then the central bank would be stabilizing opti-
mally and by raising the central bank's weight on inflation, it would
be possible to achieve a first-order inflation gain at a second-order
stabilization cost (by the envelope theorem).
When supply shocks are important, society may prefer to give
the central bank incentives to focus on a monetary target other than
the inflation rate (though again, it is not optimal to have the weight
on the target be infinite). It might be expected that the best mone-
tary target would be the one most highly correlated with the so-
ciety's ultimate objective function. But while this is a useful rule
of thumb, the situation is actually somewhat more complicated. If
one compares how each of the targets would work if used rigidly,
one does not necessarily get the same ranking as when the cen-
tral bank gives its target an optimal weight relative to direct so-
cial objectives. Thus, it can be misleading to analyze separately the
stabilization and credibility problems of the central bank. The
model also highlights strategic problems that can arise in setting
targets at a non-inflationary level. If the central bank sets its
nominal GNP target consistent with the socially optimal rate of
1188 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
APPENDIX
(Al) AD ()L1 + X l +
(A2) A
21 See Barro and Gordon [1983b], Backus and Driffill [1985], or Canzoneri
[1985].
THE OPTIMAL DEGREE OF COMMITMENT 1189
2i
(A4) AMI =
CC L(-[1) + (X + X)J2
+ [- + x1[oT + ()1 2,
whereJ-(t - 1)/(1 -
UNIVERSITYOF WISCONSIN-MADISON
REFERENCES
Backus, David, and John Driffill, "Inflation and Reputation," American Economic
Review, LXXV (1985), 530-38.
Barro, Robert J., and David B. Gordon, "A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in
a Natural-Rate Model," Journal of Political Economy, XCI (Aug. 1983a),
589-610.
,and , "Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy,"
Journal of Monetary Economics, XII (July 1983b), 101-21.
Canzoneri, Matthew B., Dale W. Henderson, and Kenneth Rogoff, "The Infor-
mation Content of the Interest Rate and Optimal Monetary Policy," this
Journal, XCVIII (Nov. 1983), 545-66.
Canzoneri, Matthew B., "Monetary Policy Games and the Role of Private Infor-
mation," American Economic Review, LXXV (1985), forthcoming.
Fischer, Stanley, "Long-Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal
Money Supply Rule," Journal of Political Economy, LXXXV (Feb. 1977),
191-206.
,and Franco Modigliani, "Towards an Understanding of the Real Effects and
Costs of Inflation," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, CXIV (1978), 810-33.
Friedman, Benjamin M., "Targets, Instruments, and Indicators of Monetary Pol-
icy," Journal of Monetary Economics, I (Oct. 1975), 443-73.
Gray, Jo Anna, "Wage Indexation: A Macroeconomic Approach," Journal of Mone-
tary Economics, II (April 1976), 221-35.
Kreps, David, and Robert Wilson, "Reputation and Imperfect Information," Jour-
nal of Economic Theory, XXVII (Aug. 1982), 253-79.
Kydland, Finn E., and Edward C. Prescott, "Rules Rather than Indiscretion: The
Inconsistency of Optimal Plans," Journal of Political Economy, LXXXV (June
1977), 473-92.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, "Speculative Hyperinflations in Maxi-
mizing Models: Can We Rule Them Out?" Journal of Political Economy, XCI
(Aug. 1983), 675-87.
Parkin, Michael,. "A Comparison of Alternative Techniques of Monetary Control
under Rational Expectations," The Manchester School, XI (Sept. 1978), 252-87.
Phelps, Edmund S., "Phillips Curves, Expectations of Inflation and Optimal Em-
ployment Over Time," Economica, XXXIV (Aug. 1967), 254-81.
, "Inflation in the Theory of Public Finance," Swedish Journal of Economics,
LXXV (March 1973), 68-82.
Poole, William, "Optimal Choice of Monetary Instruments in a Simple Stochastic
Macro Model," this Journal, LXXXIV (May 1970), 197-216.
Sargent, Thomas J., Macroeconomic Theory (New York: Academic Press, 1979).