Spatial Inequalities and Regional Development
Spatial Inequalities and Regional Development
development
SPRINGER-SCIENCE+BUSINESS MEDIA, B. V.
Library of Congress Cataloging in PubHcadon Data
Regional Science Symposium, University of Groningen, 1977.
Spatial inequalities and regional development.
"Held at the Faculty of Economics of the University of
Groningen."
Includes index.
1. Regional planning-Congresses. 2. Regional economics-
Congresses. I. Folmer, Hendrik. II. Oosterhaven,
Jan. III. Groningen. Rijksuniversiteit. Faculteit der
Economische Wettenschappen. IV. Title.
HT391.R3S4 1977 309.2'S 79-13176
ISBN 978-90-481-5806-5 ISBN 978-94-017-3046-4 (eBook)
DOI 10.1007/978-94-017-3046-4
Hans Heijke is Head of the Department of Labour Market Research of the Netherlands
Economic Institute at Rotterdam.
Leo Klaassen is President Director of the Netherlands Economic Institute and Professor
of Regional and Social-Economic Research at the University of Rotterdam.
Walter Stohr is Director of the Interdisciplinary Institute for Urban and Regional
Studies and Professor of Regional Policy at the University of Economics of Vienna.
Franz TOdtling is Lecturer of Regional Economics and Regional Policy at the Univer-
sity of Economics of Vienna.
Preface
LIST OF CONTRIBUTORS v
PREFACE VII
INTRODUCTION XIII
8.1 The fallacy of self-balance theory and current regional policy 186
8.2 EXisting power structure and regional policy 201
8.3 Socialisation and change 210
When a state vector for every regional system in the set of regions under
consideration has been established, the state matrix W of the multi-
regional system (see Section 3.1) has been determined and the framework
for determining spatial inequalities has originated. Analysis of spatial
inequalities now amounts in essence to comparing the state vectors of
the various regions under study. By comparing the state vectors of the
various regions with an 'ideal' state vector the spatial inequity pattern of
the various regions under study comes into existence, which is of crucial
importance from a policy point of view.
In regional science as well as in other social sciences serious problems
have prevailed with respect to the measurableness of theoretical concepts,
like 'the state of the economic or sociocultural subsystem of a region',
because of their non-observable and multi-dimensional character. Mostly
a single measurable indicator was selected (e.g. income per capita for the
socioeconomic situation of a region, see Reiner 1973), or an index was
constructed (income, investments in schools, hospitals, etc., see Richardson,
Section 7.1) to represent the theoretical construct. More adequate models
have been developed, especially in psychometrics, which also present
interesting possibilities for regional science.
Briefly summarized, these models go as follows. Let a hypothesis
between two sets of variables be derived from theory. None, one, or both
subsets of variables are theoretical constructs or, as they are called in psycho-
logical literature, latent variables. If the vector of endogenous latent
variables is denoted by 11 and the vector of exogenous latent variables by
~, then, under certain restrictions, which often can be weakened, (Le.
linearity, measurableness at interval or ratio level, etc.), the hypothesis
can be formulated as:
where:
!J : matrix of relationships between the endogenous latent variables;
r : matrix of relationships between the latent exogenous and endo-
genous variables;
r: vector of random disturbances.
4 A FRAMEWORK
f = ~y'!l+!l (1.3)
4 = Ax~+§ (1.4)
where:
A: matrix of relationships between the latent variables and their
indicators;
§ and § : vectors of random measurement errors.
For more information about these models, and especially about the
estimating and testing procedures, see Goldberger and Duncan (1974) and
Joreskog (1976).
The measurement problem with these kinds of linear structural equa-
tion models is no longer how to reduce a theoretical construct to a single
indicator or a single index but, instead, how to fmd as complete a set as
possible of valid observable indicators - which certainly does better
justice to the complexity of the theoretical construct than the use of a
single indicator or index.
p!'f:t+1)
where:
pi(t) the age-specific population vector of region i;
(i(t,t+T) li(t,t+T) +Si(t,t+T) ;
Mii(t,t+T) matrix of gross immigration rates for region i;
with:
~
o. b~ (t,t+1) , b~+l (t,t+1) ...... b~(t,t+1). ...... o~
1/(t,t+1) 0... 0
0... ... 0
o o 0 ... o
S~I(t,t+1) 0 0 o
o sh(t,t+1) 0 o
o 0... 0 ... o
mYt (t,t+T) 0... 0 o
o m#k(t,t+T) 0 o , with:
o 0 ...
(2.2)
where:
M/i gross migration from region i to region j of age group r;
o .r /
= /I
1"""/
.r pi.
r '
where:
/1/ = g,/ ~{ + €i
O.r total emigration from age group r in region i;
/1/
/
propensity of age group r to emigrate from region i;
p.r
/
population in region i in age group r;
f!:r vector of regression coefficients;
~./ vector of variables relevant for age group r which characterize
region i (push factors);
ti disturbance term;
TiI.1" = _r ".r + [).I '.
b TLI
FOUR SUBSYSTEMS 7
where:
12r vector of regression coefficients;
v~
-I
vector of variables relevant for age group r which characterize
region j (pull factor);
disturbance term;
A( = [~ T{ ['(dij)r 1 ,
I
where:
[T(dij ) : distance function between region i and j relevant for age group r.
Even the lower needs of health and shelter are threatened. All three
authors refer to the same causes: fun·ctional specialisation and integration.
In Stohr and Todtling's view, this means a one-sided attention in
regional development for economic efficiency. As a remedy for this
problem they suggest, inter alia, that economic objectives have to be
integrated in a broader set of policy goals which do justice to the total
complexity of human well-being. To Friedmann, functional integration
means that man and his primary social structures based on territorial
integration have come under the domination of growing anonymous
corporate and bureaucratic power. In Friedmann's definitions functional
integration implies territorial integration and the converse, so that the
total destruction of neither is possible. Nevertheless there exists at the
moment a serious lack of balance. In order to restore the natural situation
of equilibrium a recovery and strengthening of territorial values and
organisations seems necessary.
Of the many relations of the sociocultural subsystem to the other sub-
systems, we additionally want to mention the changing attitudes towards
modern production and consumption methods, which may induce changes
in production technology and environmental protection. Of the influences
the sociocultural subsystem exerts on the demographic subsystems most
known are the attitudes towards birth rate and family structure, but
migration also is influenced, as noted by Heijke and Klaassen.
large that they can internalise most classical economies of localisation and
agglomeration at almost any place, thereby marginalising the smaller
enterprises in the less-developed regions of more developed countries.
On the other hand these same factors contribute to the expansion of
industrial growth poles in some tax and labour union havens in Third
World countries. However, this expansion is reached at the costs of
growing intra- and interregional inequalities (see Sections 6.3 and 7.5),
particularly with regard to non-income components of welfare as Richard-
son argues in Chapter 7.
The fifth important primary income-generating factor is denoted by
the general tenn 'service sector'. It covers a conglomerate of economic
activities like banking, insurance, medical and social care, education,
etc. The location of these activities is in general dependent on the loca-
tion of the activities it provides services for. Lots of models have been
developed to describe and predict the size and location of these activities,
of which the economic base and Lowry models probably are most well-
known.
So far this section has been devoted to the traditional income-generat-
ing factors. These factors, however, are not sufficient to explain the
concentration of decision-making functions in, e.g., industry, banking,
government, and the concentration there of such activities as research
and development in major urban regions. The location of these kinds of
activities is mainly detennined by the opportunity they provide for
immediate, regular and frequent face-to-face contacts between the holders
of the associated functions (see Section 4.1). This aspect of spatial in-
equality at the Western European level is the main theme of Erlandsson's
contribution. He derives the total number of contact possibilities for
inhabitants of the major European urban regions as a function of their
numbers and the existing high-speed transportation network, which
provides the face-to-face communication facilities between these regions.
Decision-making and research functions in tum attract a great number
of other functions which supply them with infonnation processing,
accounting and other kinds of services. Therefore their concentration also
explains the concentration of other kinds of administrative functions. In a
way this process is comparable to the same kind of processes described
by the Lowry model for basic industrial activities and dependent service
sectors.
As decision-making and most administrative functions generally are
better paid than, inter alia, manufacturing and primary functions, this
FOUR SUBSYSTEMS 13
~
Economic Sociocultural Demographic Environmental
From subsystem subsystem SUbsystem subsystem
Economic A +
subsystem
Sociocul tural A +
subsystem (2.4.)
Demographic A +
subsystem
Environmental X X X A
subsystem
REFERENCES
Andersson, A., 'Economic analysis of demographic problems', in Andersson and Holmberg (1977).
Andersson, A., and P. Holmberg (eds.), Demt>graphic, economic and social interaction. Ballinger,
Cambridge, Mass., 1977.
Andersson, A., and Th. Plant, 'Economic analysis of the supply and demand for labour in Regions',
in Andersson and Holmberg (1977).
Boguslav, R., The new Utopians: a study of systems design and social change. Prentice Hall, Engle-
wood Cliffs, 1965.
Churchman, C. and W. Kant, 'A decision theorist', Theory and Decision 1,1970,107-116.
Daly, H.E., 'On economics as a life science',Journal of Political Economy, vol. 76,1968,392-406.
Dror, Y., Public policy making reexamined. Chandler, San Francisco, 1968.
Goldberger, A.S. and O.D. Duncan (eds.) ,Structural equation mt>dels in the social sciences. Seminar
Press, New York, 1974.
Gustavsson, J .R., B. Harsman and F. Snickars, 'Intraregional migration and the housing market', in
Andersson and Holmberg (1977).
Harris, C.C. and F.E. Hopkins, Locational analysis. Lexington Books, London, 1972.
Isard, W., 'Some notes on the linkage of the ecological and economic systems', Papers of the
Regional Association , vol. 22, 1969, 107-118.
Joreskog, K.G., 'Structural equation models in the social sciences: specification, estimation and
testing', Invited paper for the symposium on Applications of Statistics, Dayton, Ohio, 1976.
Karlq uist, A. and F. Snickars, 'Regional migration and labor markets', in Andersson and Holmberg
(1977).
Kassouf, S.,Normative decision making. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, 1970.
Krech, D. and R.S. Crutchfield,Elementsofpsychology. Knopf, New York, 1965.
McLoughlin, B., Urban and region planning: a systems approach. Faber and Faber, London, 1969.
Norlen, U., 'Development of a statistical model for social indicators', in Andersson and Holmberg
(1977).
Nijkamp, P., Theory and application of environmental economics. North Holland, Amsterdam,
1977.
Ozbekhan, H., 'Toward a general theory of planning', in Jautsch (ed.), Perspectives of planning.
OECD,Paris, 1969.
Paelinck, JR. and P. Nijkamp, Operational theory and methods in regional economics. Saxon
House, Farnborough, 1975.
Reiner, T.A. 'Welfare differences within a nation' ,Papers of the Regional Science Association, vol.
32,1973.
Rogers, A. and S. McDougall, 'An analysis of population growth and change in Slovenia and the
rest of Yugoslavia', Working Paper 81, Center for Planning and Development Research, Univers-
ity of California, Berkeley, 1968.
Salih, K., 'Goal conflicts in pluralistic multi-level planning for development' ,International Regional
Science Review, vol. 1, no. 1,1975,49-72.
Smith, D.M., Industrial location: an economic geographical analysis. Wiley, London/New York,
1971.
Victor, P A., Input-output analysis and the study of economic and environmental interaction.
Ph.D. thesis, University of Columbia, 1971.
Wadensjo, E., 'Some factors determining international migration', in Andersson and Holmberg
(1977).
Wilson, A.G., Entropy in urban and regional mt>delling. Pion, London, 1970.
Wilson, A.G., Urban and regional mt>dels in geography and planning. Wlley, London, 1974.
Part I: Analytical studies in spatial
inequalities and regional development
2. On the contradictions between city
and countryside
JOHN FRIEDMANN*
The existence of the town implies, at the same time, the necessity of administration,
police, taxes, etc.; in short, of the municipality, and thus of politics in general. Here
first became manifest the division of the population into two great classes, which is
directly based on the division of labour and on the instruments of production. The
town already is in actual fact the conception of the population, of the instruments of
production, of capital, of pleasures, of needs, while the country demonstrates just the
opposite fact, isolation and separation. The antagonism between town and country
can only exist within the framework of private property. It is the most crass expres-
sion of the subjection of the individual under the division of labour, under a definite
activity forced upon him - a subjection which makes one man into a restricted town-
animal, the other into a restricted country-animal, and daily creates anew the conflict
between their interests. Labour is here again the chief thing, power over individuals,
and as long as the latter exists, private property must exist. The abolition of the antag-
onism between town and country is one of the first conditions of communal life, a
* University of California, Los Angeles. The research for this essay was done while
the author was on a Guggenheim Foundation fellowship at the Centre for Environ-
mental Studies in London, England. Earlier drafts received very helpful comments
from Peter Marris, Edward Soja, Clyde Weaver, and the editors ofthe present volume.
24 CITY AND COUNTRYSIDE: CONTRADICTIONS
condition which again depends on a mass of material premises and which cannot be
fulfilled by the mere will, as anyone can see at first glance ... The separation of town
and country can also be understood as the separation of capital and landed property,
as the beginning of the existence and development of capital independent of landed
property - the beginning of property having its basis only in labour and exchange
(Marx and Engels 1970, p. 69).
In this famous passage, Marx and Engels refer to the 'antagonism' between
town and countryside, tracing the conflict to the spatial division of labor.
But only a year or two later, in the Communist Manifesto, they wrote
about the 'gradual abolition of the distinction between town and country'.
And to confuse matters still further, a footnote in the English translation
of this work reminds us that 'in the German edition of 1848, the word
"distinction" reads "antithesis" '(Marx and Engels 1975, p. 60).
Now antagonism, distinction, antithesis, and contradiction - this last
term being currently in vogue - are clearly not synonymous; each conveys
a different theoretical meaning. Because clarification of this central
concept is essential to my task, 'contradiction' is made the subject of an
extended theoretical inquiry in Section 2.1. This is followed, in Section
2.2, by an examination of the nature of the contradiction between the
functional and territorial bases of social integration. A final component
of the theoretical framework is added in Section 2.3, where the related
concepts of city and countryside are discussed in terms that will be useful
to the further development of my topic. The remaining two sections are
devoted to an extended analysis of the clash between rural and urban-
centered interests. Section 2.4 concerns the pseudo-resolution of this
clash within the core countries of western capitalism, while section 2.5
projects the argument into a global context. The question is: if rural-
urban contradictions were 'successfully' resolved within the advanced
capitalist nations, could not this process be replicated with a view to the
ultimate integration of the world economy into a single, homogeneous
system of functional relationships?
2.1 CONTRADICTIONS: COSMIC AND HISTORICAL
B' in the sense that A and B cannot be logically maintained at the same
time), it came to be applied, in the hands of German idealist philosophers
(Kant, Hegel), to relations in reality (Williams 1976,91-93). Subsequently,
it played a key role in the formalization of dialectical materialism. 1 In
Marxist thought, contradiction acquired specific, if sometimes elusive,
historical and existential meanings; it became simultaneously a condition
and principal method of revolutionary practice.
In this paper, I shall use contradiction to refer to a standing in mutual
opposition of two social forces which, though interpenetrating and
clashing, are complementary to one another, comprising a unity, a
whole. 2 The broad scope of this definition can be rendered more precise
by distinguishing its several moments. Contradictions that are constitutive
of the human condition, I propose to call cosmic contradictions. An
example would be the contradictions that exist between the individual
self and the matrix of social relations that sustains us and through which
we become human. A cosmic contradiction also exists between the two
opposing bases of social integration: functional and territorial. I shall
return to this contradiction in the next section. For the present, let it
suffice to note that cosmic contradictions can change in only two
1. It was Engels, rather than Marx, who formalized the dialectic as a way of viewing
the world and so transformed the loose notion of contradictions-in-reality into a
more rigorous concept (Engels 1976; OHman 1971, Chapter 5).
2. The unity (the whole, the entity) arises from the contradictory relation; it is not
pre-existing to it. Thus there are no ultimate entities in the universe, only forces-
in-relation. According to Colletti (1975), this is the only true dialectical form of
opposition, but it exists exclusively in logic. Relations of opposition in reality, on
the other hand, are instances of contrariety (Realrepugnanz), and are without
logical contradiction.
This distinction is made in order to save Marxism for science, or possibly the
other way round. The argument is that, in a unity of opposites, neither of the two
component forces has ontological reality by itself; it is a mere shadow, whose
existence requires the constant presence of the other. Adopting Colletti's position,
both proletarians and bourgeois would, in themselves alone, be merely fictions
( epiphenomena).
Colletti's argument is not convincing. To reach it, he has to dip into idealist
philosophy. From an historical materialist point of view, the proletariat exists not
for itself alone, but only as the dialectical opposite of capitalist social forces.
Eliminate capitalism, and the proletariat, in its specific historical appearance and
mission, is eliminated as well. Within capitalism, however, the proletariat is 'real'
enough and not, as Colletti seems to think, an instance of the metaphysical imagina-
tion. For a non-dialectical 'systems' view of this same problem, see Edgar S. Dunn,
J r. (1971, Chapter VI).
26 CITY AND COUNTRYSIDE: CONTRADICTIONS
them, leading to a new and higher unity, a movement which suggests the
image of a forward-surging spiral. 4 In the process, although the formerly
opposing forces are destroyed and vanish from earth, some of the 'positive'
and usually secondary elements are rescued into the next ('higher') stage
of the historical process, where they are retained. 5 But every new unity,
in turn, will generate new forces in opposition to itself, and so the process
continues without let-up, destroying, surpassing, retaining, in a continuing
upward spiral of historical progress. 6
In this ontology, there are no 'cosmic' contradictions. Instead, the
outward appearance of historical phenomena in Hegel veils the unity of
spirit that pervades all things. All contradictions strain towards an expres-
sion of this unity. And only when the 'final' contradiction has been
overcome will humankind embark upon the true course of its history.
This mystical vision animates such fundamentally divergent thinkers as
Karl Marx (the 'higher phase of communist society') and Pierre Teilhard
de Chard in ('Omega').7 Hegel 'stood on his head', one must conclude, is
still indubitably Hegel (Althusser 1969).
Just as Hegel's philosophy, together with its materialist inversion, is,
in the final analysis, monistic (Le. reducible to a single, indivisible unity),
so traditional Chinese, including present-day Maoist, thought is funda-
mentally dualistic (Le. ultimate reality is two, not one). The idea of an
4. According to Friedrich Engels, the most important dialectical laws are the
'transformation of quantity to quality - mutual penetration of polar opposites and
the transfonnation of each other when carried to extremes - development through
contradiction or negation - spiral form of development' (cited in Ollman 1971,
p.55).
5. The German equivalent of 'surpassing' - au/heben - means both a 'raising up' and
a 'preserving' and thus contains the notions of progressive change as well as
continuity.
6. Hegelian dialectics, with its dual moment of destruction and preservation in histori-
cal processes, appeals to a romantic streak in the German imagination. The Valhallian
rhetoric of destruction (which also appears in Joseph Schumpeter's celebrated
phrase, 'gales of creative destruction', referring to economic innovations under
capitalism) accounts for much of the romantic appeal of Marxist writings.
7. With the achievement of a classless society from which all coercive (political) power
is absent, antagonistic contradictions will also have been overcome. At this point,
pre-history comes to an end, and humankind's true history begins to unfold.
Marx's profound intuition of this history is perhaps best expressed in a short
paragraph of the Critique of the Gotha Program (Marx 1972, p. 17). In all fairness,
it should be noted that what is historical transformation in Marx becomes trans-
figuration with Teilhard de Chardin. All the same, de Chardin's 'hyper-personal'
at the Omega-point of History is still this side of Heaven (de Chardin 1965, Book
IV, Chapter 2).
28 CITY AND COUNTRYSIDE: CONTRADICTIONS
8. This description of the two bases of social integration bears a certain family resem-
blance to such well-worn sociological distinctions as organic and mechanical
solidarity (Durkheim) and society and community (Tonnies). These earlier
concepts, however, were modelled, not as a 'unity of opposites' but as 'ideal types'
of two contrasting (and mutually exclusive) forms of social organization which
might subsequently be applied to the study of social history (from the primary
relations of Gemeinschaft to the secondary, associative relations of Gesellschaft,
from 'traditional' society to 'modern'). By contrast, functional and territorial bases
of social integration are complementary forces that stand in contradiction to each
other; they are complex social forms which arise from this double interaction.
9. All social integration above the level of the small, face-to-face group occurs on the
basis of either territory or function. This is true of even nomadic tribes whose
migrations are fixed within a given territorial range or of Jews in the diaspora whose
common history is comprehensible only with reference to their expUlsion from
their ancestral home in Judea. (Cf. Porteous 1976).
In territorially integrated societies, history and place are one. This is beautifully
illustrated in the following description, based on the Chinese Book of Rites (she-
king), on the founding of a new city:
'There is a settled order in which one must proceed. The ramparts are first raised:
they are the most sacred part of the town. Afterwards the temple of the ancestors
[Miao 1 is built. Care is taken to plant trees meanwhile (hazels and chestnuts) whose
fruits and berries will be offered to the ancestors, and those trees which are used
30 CITY AND COUNTRYSIDE: CONTRADICTIONS
to make coffins and sonorous drums. "In ancient times when the plan of the capital
was traced, they did not fail to choose the most important rising ground in the
kingdom and constitute the ancestral temple, nor to select trees of the finest
growth to make the sacred forest." When the walls, the altars and the plantations
which are to give sanctity to the town are finished, the palace and houses are built'
(Granet 1958).
The symbolic quality of this historical action reveals the reverence with which
human beings approach the task of staking out a territorial core for their lives.
Yet territory is merely the ground for human history. It is collective experience
which creates the essential bond between human beings. Thus Duchacek (1970,
p. 20): 'It should be recognized that men identify not only with a territory as such
but also (if not primarily) with its political and economic system, its methods and
goals, and with its history and its destiny' (emphasis added).
10. This distinction is also recognized by Miguel Morales (1976, p. 83):
'A third tendency, finally, has been shown to exist in the formal and a-historical use
of the term region. This has contributed to an asymmetrical relation: on one hand,
the evident descriptive power of the term, and on the other, its inability to explain.
In these cases, two aspects have dominated the scene: in the first, space is con-
ceived mathematically, in abstract form, which allows one to know areas based on
topological considerations; in the second, which is identified with empirical systems
analysis, the historical meaning of the process ofregionalization as a specific social
process has been practically dissolved in its phenomenological appearance. Regions,
in that case, are converted into mere study areas or areas for action without signifi-
cant historical contents; eventually, they become formalized planning areas which
in their practical aspects are manifestly efficient' (translated from the Spanish;
emphasis added).
CONCEPTS OF CITY AND COUNTRYSIDE 31
... large cities are formed by national and international connections and movements;
their future is bound up in a network of vaster activities; and their destiny crosses
administrative and even territorial borders to follow the general trade routes (in
Marilitegui 1971,p. 174).
32 CITY AND COUNTRYSIDE: CONTRADICTIONS
11. Such a map is produced by Edward W. Soja (1968b, fig. 47) for post-independence
Kenya. This map (together with the accompanying text) distinguishes between the
political (national) boundaries of Kenya and the 'effective national territory' which
occupied no more than a fifth of the former. The only data shown for the 'empty'
four-fifths are 'Shifta attacks and ethnic conflicts'.
12. Political autonomy was virtually absent in the Islamic city of the Middle ages
(Lapid~s 1967). The Greek polis, on the other hand, enjoyed complete autonomy
in principle (Finley 1973). In practice, of course, 'many poleis were joined in
"leagues" with their neighbors; others were in a permanent condition of subjection
to the more powerful' (Pounds 1969, p. 136).
CONCEPTS OF CITY AND COUNTRYSIDE 33
Two elements in the structure of headquarters towns impeded regional and market
integration. First, within the headquarters town, the military ruler and the professional
and business classes - particularly those with wide-ranging contacts - often battled
with one another. The goal of the ruler, which was usually to maximize political
control over his subjects, conflicted with the goals of the merchants and professionals,
which were to make profits and to exercise skills and talents. The ruler usually did not
want the town market and court to be independent entities. He wanted them subject
to his will ...
Towns in India impeded political and economic integration in a second way. The
towns, which may have served as hinges vertically linking higher and lower levels of the
polity, nevertheless served as military headquarters 'for ·antagonistic relations with
To describe the territorial city, Spodek had to set it off against the func-
tional city. And, indeed, both fonns of description are jointly necessary
for a complete account: the city is a node in a global network of economic
relations; it is also a place, possessing a political life of its own, a history,
a unique appearance, a mode of life, a sense of being. 15 After four
centuries of steady attrition, this second, psycho-historical dimension is
only vestigially present. 16 Both corporate and bureaucratic power have
become consolidated at the national level, extending cities into an
intricate network of functional relations. Symbolized in the literature as
'megalopolis' (e.g. Gottman 1961; Soja 1968a), this network is more
15. Historically, there has been a gradual evolution of the city from place to node. This
evolution is beautifully traced and recorded in Mumford (1938). A more dialectical
urban history in which the fate of the city as a place becomes intertwined with the
fate of the national economy is found in Conot (1974). The 'great city' of Conot's
saga is Detroit.
16. According to Charles Tilly (1976, p. 374), ' ... the two centuries after 1700 pro-
duced an enormous concentration of resources and means of coercion under the
control of national states, to the virtual exclusion of other levels of government .
. . . A whole series of organizational changes closely linked to urbanization, indus-
trialization and the expansion of capitalism greatly reduced the role of the communal
group as a setting for mobilization and as a repository for power; the association
of one kind or another came to be the characteristic vehicle for collective action.
The rise of the joint-stock company, the political party, the labor union, the club
all belong to the same general trend.'
THE PSEUDO-RESOLUTION OF CONTRADICTIONS 35
This article suggests a method for describing the magnitude of a city's influence on
its surrounding hinterland. And a method is proposed for partitioning an entire terrain
into metropolitan regions or even urban trade areas (Carroll 1955, p. 0-2).
The modern city is losing its external and formal structure. Internally it is in a state of
decay while the new community represented by the nation everywhere grows at its
expense. The age of the city seems to be at an end (Weber 1958, p. 62).
The new urban scale, coincident with the appearance of a national hier-
archy of cities and a nationally integrated economy, was ultimately
justified by referring to the immense gains in economic efficiency that
were supposed to be realized (Borts and Stein 1964; Mera 1975). The
immediate evidence for this was the seemingly irresistible growth of
national production and the resulting affluence of the population at large.
These gains were dearly bought, however. Bourgeois complacency was
profoundly shaken by the accumulation of misery and squalor in cities,
by cyclical instability, by massive structural unemployment, by life-
destroying pollution, by the rapid exhaustion of natural resources, by
increasingly devastating and senseless wars, by widespread social aliena-
tion. All the same, many 'costs' were thought to be the unavoidable
byproducts of a modern industrial economy:
system of nodal areas through which economic space is organized. But the
pattern of spatial efficiencies which in the course of two centuries had
expanded to the size of national boundaries, drastically changed as
economic growth came to be based on science, and as transport and
communication technologies improved, shrinking first national and then
global distances to the size of a village.
This change, manifested in a radical reduction of transport and com-
munication costs, was reinforced by an equally dramatic shift in relative
emphasis from fixed plant and equipment to finance capital. This de-
materialization of the forces of production facilitated the merging of
financial resources from different points of origin ('money doesn't smell')
and, in a quick progression, led to the de-nationalization of corporate
power.
The real power of finance capital resides in its global mobility. When
profits on investment are as high as 40 percent a year, as in many Third
World countries, investments can be written off in less than half a decade
without loss, and the recovered capital transferred to any part of the globe
that happens to be temporarily more attractive. 21 Cheap, almost instan-
taneous communication, and now even supersonic jet travel, has made
finance capital virtually independent of location. As a result, very large
cities - Tokyo, Los Angeles, Mexico City, Sao Paulo, New York, London
- have become primary centers within a global interlocking system of
banking and communication. But as financial centers, their world-wide
dominance has been 'etheralized'; it is no longer territorial.
The occasional alliance between finance capital and territorial power is
not a necessary but an historical relation. To a very large extent, finance
capital has become independent of territorial power. 22 This is true for
even leading capitalist countries, a development which is only now begin-
21. In a recent year, for example, employment in Mexico's border industries (i.e.
American firms operating in Mexico under a special arrangement which permits
them to take advantage of low-cost labor), fell from 80,000 to 30,000. The wages
of Mexican workers had risen, and Haiti had once more become politically attrac-
tive. Thus, in the early 1970s, Haiti, where women work for 40 cents a day, experi-
enced an enormous industrial boom whose counterpart was economic depression
in northern Mexico! (See Dillman 1976; Biderman 1974.)
22.According to Holland (1975, p. 368): 'The new imperialism is different. The parent
country has given way to the parent company, which rarely has any interest in
developing the infrastructure or strengthening the administration of the country
in which its subsidiaries operate. It leaves the social costs of running some of the
poorest countries in the world to local governments while maximizing the private
henefits of the multi-national corporation which it heads.'
GLOBALIZATION OF THE CONFLICT 41
International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development. Major world capitals play a
coordinative role, but their choice as a location for corporate staff is largely
a matter of historical accident and convenience (Heenan 1977). London is
a major financial market; it also happens to have the cheapest secretarial
labor force in Western Europe. A step or two further down the financial
hierarchy, is Beirut. But when Beirut was engulfed in civil war, much of
the financial capital moved to Amman. And if Amman should capsize,
then there is Kuwait or some other principality along the Arab Gulf. Let
it be noted: the first route of British supersonic jets was to Bahrain!
What is happening today is clearly the attempt by corporations to
replicate their earlier national phase on the scale of the whole globe. As a
consequence, national territories in the world periphery are penetrated at
suitable points, and these points are gradually incorporated and absorbed
into the whole global network of economic relations (Michalet 1975). The
earlier effort had successfully wiped out most local territorial entities as
effective political actors. It had reconcentrated power at the national
level, and it had realigned people's lives according to functional principles.
Today, the denationalized corporation seeks to achieve the same purpose
by weakening the integrity of nation states, undermining their power and
authority to act. Its long-term project is to totalize the principle of
functional integration and to resolve all social questions by the calculus
of profit. As Citicorp's Walter B. Wriston said: 'Far too many of the world's
people have now seen what the global shopping center holds in store for
them. They will not easily accept having the doors slammed shut by
nationalism. 25
Or will they? That is indeed the fateful question of our time. Will
territorial power, after all, succumb to corporate and bureaucratic power,
history to economic growth? Should we imagine the globalization of the
economy to the exclusion of the territorial principle? Or, more precisely,
25, See Note 23. Methods of conducting business such as those revealed by the Lock-
heed scandals of recent memory and involving pay-offs to heads of state and other
top-ranking government officials are only a tiny glimmering of what must be
extremely widespread practices. The Vice-President of the United States had to
resign for accepting bribes, and former Prime Minister Tanaka is standing trial in
Japan on similar charges. As Quisling of Norway sold out to Nazi Germany, so
Agnew and Tanaka have sold out to corporate interests. Is there a difference?
(Quisling was shot after the war as a collaborator. Agnew has become a successful
author-businessman. Tanaka went to jail.)
GLOBALIZATION OF THE CONFLICT 43
REFERENCES
Althusser, L.,For Marx. Pantheon, New York, 1969.
Amin, S., Accumulation on a world scale: a critique of the theory of underdevelopment. 2 vols.
Monthly Review Press, New York, 1974.
Arrow, K.,Social choice and individual values. 2nd ed. Wiley, New York, 1963.
Asalto al centralismo: la reivindicacion de la autonomw en las nacionalidades y regiones del estado
Espaiiol. Avabce/Intervenci6n, Madrid, 1976.
Berry, B.J.L., Metropolitan area definition; a re-evaluation of concept and statistical practice.
Rev. ed. Bureau of the Census Working Paper no. 28, Washington, D.C., 1969.
Berry, B.J.L., 'The geography of the United States in the year 2000', in J. Friedmann and W.
Alonso (eds.), Regional policy: readings in theory and applications. MIT Press, Cambridge,
Mass., 1975.
Biderman, J., Enclave development: the case of multinational assembly industries on Mexico's
northern border. Master's thesis, Department of City and Regional Planning, University of
California, Berkeley, 1974.
Borts, GR. and J.1. Stein, Economic growth in a free market. Columbia University Press, New
York,1964.
Carroll, J.D., Jr., 'Spatial interaction and the urban-metropolitan regional description'. Papers
and Proceedings, Regional Science Association, vol. 1, DI-14, 1955.
Colletti, 1., 'Marxism and the dialectic', New Left Review, no. 93,3-30,1975.
Conot, R., American odyssey: a unique history of America told through the life of a great city.
William Morrow, New York, 1974.
de Chardin, P.T., The phenomenon of man. Harper and Row, New York, 1965.
Dillman, C.D., 'Maquiladoras in Mexico's northern border communities and the border industrali-
zation program', Tijdschrift voor Econ. en Soc. Geografie, vol. 67,138-50,1976.
Duchacek, I.D., Comparative federalism: the territorial dimension of politics. Holt, Rinehart and
Winston, New York, 1970.
Dulong, R., La question Bretonne. Presses de la Fondation Nationale des Sciences Politiques, Paris,
1975.
Dulong, R., La question regionale en France. 1 Monographies, Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences
Sociales, Centre d'Etudes des Mouvement Sociaux, Paris, n.d.
Dunn, E.S., Jr., Economic and social development: a process of social learning. The Johns Hop-
kins Press, Baltimore, 1971.
Engels, F., Anti-Diihring. Foreign Languages Press, Peking, 1976.
Finley, M.I.,Democracy ancient and modern. Rutgers University Press, New Brunswick, N.J., 1973.
Frank, A.G., Capitalism and underdevelopment in Latin America: historical studies of Chile and
Brazil. Monthly Review Press, New York, 1967.
Friedmann, J. and J. Miller, 'The urban fields', Journal of the American Institute of Planners, vol.
31,312-320,1965.
Friedmann, J. and C. Weaver, Temtory and function: the evolution of regional planning doctrine.
Edward Arnold, London, 1978.
Gottman, J., Megapolis: the urbanized northeastern seaboard of the United States. Twentieth
Century Fund, New York, 1961.
Gaviria, M.,Ecologismo y Ordenacwn del Temtorio en Espana. Cuadernos para el Diagolo, Madrid,
1976.
Granet, M., Chinese civilization. Meridian Books, New York, 1958.
Hechter, M., Internal colonialism: the Celtic fringe in British national development, 1536-1966.
Routledge and Kegan Paul, London, 1975.
Heenan, D.A., 'Global cities of tomorrow', Harvard Business Review, vol. 5, 79-92, 1977.
Holborn, H., The political collapse of Europe. Knopf, New York, 1954.
Holland, S., The socialist challenge. Quartet Books, London, 1975.
Isard, W., Location and space economy: a general theory relating to industrial areas, land use,
trade, and urban structure. Wiley, New York, 1956.
Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, The United States response to the new
REFERENCES 45
international order: the economic implications for Latin America and the United States. U.S.
Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C., 1977.
Klaassen, 1.H., Social amenities in aret1 economic growth: an analysis of methods for defining
needs. OECD,Paris, 1968.
Kollek, T. and M. Pearlman, Jerusalem: sacred city of mankind: a history of forty centuries.
Weidenfeld and Nicholson, London, 1968.
Lapidus, I.M., Muslim cities in the later middle ages. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass.,
1967.
Lenin, V.I.,Imperialism: the highest stage of capitalism. Foreign Languages Press, Peking, 1970.
Lynch, K.,Managing the sense of a region. MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1976.
Mao Tse-tung, Four essays on philosophy. Foreign Languages Press, Peking, 1968.
Mariategui, J.C., Seven interpretive essays on Peruvian Reality. University of Texas Press, Austin,
1971.
Marx, K., Critique of the Gotha Program. Foreign Languages Press, Peking, 1972.
Marx, K. and F. Engels, Manifesto of the communist parry. Foreign Languages Press, Peking, 1975.
Marx, K. and F. Engels, The German IdeokJgy. Part One.C.J. Arthur (ed.},International Publishers,
New York, 1970.
Mera, K., Income distribution and regional development. University of Tokyo Press, Tokyo, 1975.
Michalet, CA., Les firmes multinationales et la nouvelle division internationale du travail. Inter-
national Labour Office, Geneva, 1975.
Morales,AM., 'Consideracionesgenerales sobre la planificaci6n urbano-regional en America Latina',
Revista Interamericana de Planificaci6n, vol. 10,78-91,1976.
Mumford, L., The city in history: its origins, its transformations, and its prospects. Harcourt, Brace
and World, New York, 1961.
Mumford, 1., The culture of cities. Harcourt, Brance, New York, 1938.
OIlman, B., Alienation: Marx's concept of man in capitalist society. University Press, Cambridge,
1971.
Peccei, A., The chasm ahead. Collier-Macmillan, London, 1969.
Porteous, J.D., 'Home: the territorial core', The Geographical Review, vol. 66, 383-390, 1976.
Pounds, N.J.G., 'The urbanization of the classical world', Annals of the Association of American
Geographers, vol. 59, no. 1,1969.
Schramm (ed.},Mao Tse·tung unrehet1rsed: talks and letters, 1956-71. Penguin, London, 1974.
Schumpeter, J.A., Capitalism, socialism and democracy. 2nd ed. Harper and Bros., New York,
1947.
Seymour, J.D., China: the politics of revolutionary reintegration. Crowell, New York, 1976.
Soja, E.W., 'Communication and territorial integration in East Africa: an introduction to transac-
tion flow analysis', East Lake Geographer, vol. 4, 39-57, 1968a.
Soja, E.W., The geography of modernization in Kenya. Syracuse University Press, Syracuse, N.Y.,
1968b.
Spodek, H., 'Urban politics in the local kingdoms of India: a view from the princely capitals of
Saurashtra under British rule', Modem Asian Studies, vol. 7, 253-275, 1973.
Tilly, C., 'Major forms of collective action in Western Europe, 1500-1975', Theory and Society,
vol. 3, 365-376, 1976.
United Nations, Measures for the economic devekJpment of underdevekJped countries. Report by
a group of experts. Department of Economic Affairs, New York, 1951.
Weber, M., The city. Free Press, Glencoe, 111.,1958.
Webber, MM., 'The urban place and the nonplace urban realm', in M.M. Webber et al.,Explorations
into urban structure. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia, 1964.
Wilhelm, R. (ed.), The I Ching, or book of changes. 3rd ed. Routledge and Kegan Paul, London,
1968.
Williams, R.,Keywords: a vocabulary of culture and society. Fontana, London, 1976.
Wriston, W.B., People, politics and productivity: the world corporation in the 1980s. Citicorp,
London, 1976.
3. Environmental protection and spatial
welfare patterns
WIM HAFKAMP and PETER NIJKAMP*
1 .................. . R
!Ys
( 1.1)
W=
I
I
I
I
,, .-L-
!Yp , .... "
.... "
!!1M -,-,,'
1 ...... r .. .... . R
Figure 1. A spatiotemporal welfare proflle.
Matrix (1.1) and Figure 1 constitute the foundation stones for measuring
discrepancies in welfare profiles between regions as well as the inter-
temporal evolution in these discrepancies. Two aspects of measuring
SPATIAL WELFARE PROFILES 53
0.2)
( 1.3)
or:
(1.4)
(1.5)
C=
, if i is a benefit criterion,
0.6)
W ir
1-- , if i is a cost criterion,
w:t'
1
w:t'
1
= max
r
W
ir
(1.7)
It is clear that this Euclidean distance and the rectangular distance are
special cases of (1.8), viz. if p = 2 and p = 1, respectively. Further details
on the use of the Minkowski p-metric are contained, among other sources,
in Bartels and Nijkamp (1976), Beckenbach and Bellman (1961), Green
and Cannone (1970), Nijkamp and Rietveld (1977) and Shephard (1966).
For a discussion on a weighted welfare metric, see Nijkamp and Rietveld
(1977).
ENVIRONMENTAL EXTERNALITIES FRAMEWORK 55
Clearly, the latter index can again by subdivided into the four above-
mentioned welfare profIles, so that the economic welfare index of region
r can be denoted by vEr' the environmental welfare index by vMr ' etc. In
the following sections the use of these welfare indices in an interregional
equilibrium system will be exposed in more detail.
etc.) is at first glance somewhat easier, but such a system suffers basically
from the same problem, because here also the welfare-theoretic implica-
tions of fixing a set of standards are to be assessed (Nijkamp 1977).
There is a wide variety of instruments to control environmental extern-
alities and environmental damage. Examples are changes in moral attitudes
(e.g. a call for a responsible stewardship (Nijkamp 1976) or moral coer-
cion), standards (e.g. maximum emission norms, prohibitions, rationing of
pollutants, constructioI). of public or private abatement installations),
charges (per unit of pollutant, per unit of input or per unit of output),
and subsidies (e.g. compensation for decline in welfare, production or
property values, stimulation of clean activities, stimulation of adjusted
environmental research, creation of equivalent environmental facilities).
The problem of spatial discrepancies in welfare profiles of diverse
regions will now be discussed from the point of view of environmental
externalities. Special attention will be devoted to the construction of an
interregional equilibrium model based on earlier studies of d'Aspremont
and Gerard-Varet (1976), Dr'eze and de la Vallee Poussin (1971), Malin-
vaud (1972) and Tulkens and Schoumaker (1975). For the sake of
presentation a set of simple hypothesis for the analysis of environmental
externalities in a spatial setting will be made (see also Tulkens and Schou-
maker 1975):
- the spatial system is composed of a set R =1rl r = I, ... ,R } of regions.
- R is subdiyided into a set U =1u I u = I, .. ( , U } of po1!utir:.g repons
and a set N = 1n I n = I, ... ,N } of poilu ted regions (U u N =R ,or
U+N=R).
- each region u has a production consumption set Gt = 1(xu. Pu)1 Xu > 0,
Pu > o} ,where Xu and Pu represent, respectively, the private production
and the emission of pollution of region u. This production set is a
feasible set which may be restricted by various side-conditions arising
from the economic system itself (e.g. capacity constraints, input-output
linkages, etc.).
- each region u has a (strictly quasi-concave, continuous and differen-
tiable) welfare function Wu (xu' pu) with the following properties:
w'Xu = awu(xu ,pu)/axu > ° (2.1)
1. Clearly, the specification of a poilu tion emission model is a special case of such a
multi-function.
58 ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AND SPATIAL WELFARE
w'
xn
= aWn (xn • zn)/axn >0 (2.3)
and
(2.8)
The latter assumption can easily be relaxed on the basis of more informa-
tion about spatial diffusion patterns and environmental damages (see
Section 3.4).
ENVIRONMENTAL EXTERNALITIES FRAMEWORK 59
Vu (2.9)
and
Vn (2.10)
and
(2.l4)
A U A
Z = -1: P
u= 1 u
(2.15)
and
(2.16)
subject to: 7rXn + Yn = 7rXn
2. The income transfers have a positive sign in case of payments by region u and n,
and a negative sign in case of receipts by region u and n. The sign of these transfers
depends on the type of taxation and redistribution (e.g. charges or compensations).
64 ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AND SPATIAL WELFARE
(2.17)
and
u P'"
1: = -z'" (2.18)
u=1 u
Evidently, the set of PBEs may also include Pareto and disagreement
equilibria.
It is clear that (2.15) through (2.18) constitute an optimization
program for U+N regions subject to constraints on regional budgets and
environmental quality. The introduction of a tax may lead to a decline in
Pu and hence to a rise in z. The redistribution of the tax proceeds will
affect the regional production distribution. However, the precise direction
of the income transfers Yu and Yn and its consequences for the commodity
sector are unknown so far. This is co-determined by the tax regime at
hand.
The way in which the redistribution takes place will be discussed later.
Suffice it to say for the moment that Yu and Yn lead to a spatial redis-
tribution of the tax proceeds, as is easily seen by adding up and combin-
ing (2.15) and (2.16):
or by using (2.17)
u '" U N
71:
u=1 u
P + 1: ~ + 1: Y
u=1 u n=1 n
=0 (2.20)
The latter result indicates that the total tax proceeds are redistributed
among all regions. Thus the charge-subsidy schemes presuppose a (hypo-
thetical) central agency.
The next section will be devoted to an analysis of the redistribution
effects on regional welfare profIles as a consequence of a policy of
environmental protection by means of a tax-subsidy scheme.
REDISTRIBUTION EFFECTS OF TAX-SUBSIDY 65
au = Tlrr (3.1)
or when rr is taken as a numeraire (Le. rr = I):
(3.2)
1r = 0 (3.5)
66 ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AND SPATIAL WELFARE
(3.7)
(3.8)
and
• U
Y n + f3n ~ fJu
u=1
=0 (3.9)
It is clear from (2.20) that a necessary condition for a PBE solution is:
N
a+ ~
n=1
f3n = 1, 0~.Bn~1 (3.10)
(3.12)
The dynamic process described by (3.4), (3.5), (3.6), (3.8) and (3.9) (or
(3.11) and (3.12) ) implies a continuous adjustment from a disagreement
z
equilibrium to a new equilibrium, where again T = Pu = =Yu =Yn = O.
The reason for a continuous shift is the fact that the 'budget' constraint
passing through point B in Figure 4 will rotate to the left in the case of
effluent charges (see Figure 5). In this case a shift from B to C has taken
place, which implies a transition from a disagreement equilibrium B to a
Pareto equilibrium C (at the line AA') via a series of PBEs. The location of
the Pareto optimum that is the outcome of this process depends on the
redistribution parameters Q, f3n and 'Y. Figure 5 also illustrates that Pu
declines as T increases.
Figure 5.
An Edgeworth box with a disagreement
equilibrium B and a Pareto optimum C.
68 ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AND SPATIAL WELFARE
It can easily be proved that the transition phase proceeds along a series
of continuous PBEs. The initial point B itself already reflects a PBE, since
it satisfies conditions (2.15) to (2.20). It is clear that the transition
process is continuous, because the utility functions are continuous
differentiable with respect to their (time-varying) arguments. Next, the
maximization of (2.15) and (2.16) subject to (2.17) and (2.18) also
guarantees that (2.15) and (2.16) are fulfIlled during the whole process, so
that the process satisfies this PBE-condition.
In addition, on the basis of (2.15), (2.16), (3.5), (3.7), (3.8) and (3.9)
one may derive:
(3.13)
and
• U
xn = f3.n ~
u= 1
()
u
(3.14)
N
a ~ (3 'Y Wu Xu Pu wn xn z
n =1 n
wu(x~,p~)
wu(AU ,pu)
*
u 0
wn(xn ,z) wn(x,:, - ~ p )u wn(~'zo)
u=1
with corresponding argument values X~, p~, x~ and!o. The right upper
element of Table 2 is empty, because regional system N does not influence
system 6. Inversely, the left lower element represents welfare of regions
n E iii, when polluting regions act as dominating decision-makers. Conse-
quently, the welfare loss Lu of a region n ENdue to environmental
externalities is:
(3.16)
max Xu
maxpu' ~fpu < ~} (3.17)
max -Pu' lfpu > Pu or: min I Pu - Pu I
Similarly, the objective functions of regions n EN become:
maxxn l (3.18)
maxz ~
xO pO xO zO
u u n
xO xu(p~) * *
u
pO *
pu(x~) u *
* * *
where 1'i (i = 1, 2) is a (2 xl) vector with value added coefficients for sector
A and B, ~i a (2 x 1) vector with sectoral production volumes (measured
in Df!.), 1i a (5 x 1) vector with cost coefficients for 5 pollutants and ~i a
(5 xl) vector with concentration levels of 5 pollutants (measured in Jlg/m 3 ).
The constraints of the model are input-ouput constraints, employment
constraints and pollution constraints.
The input-output constraints are:
(I-A.)x·;;;;'f·*
- - I -I _I
(4.2)
(4.3)
(4.4)
(4.5)
(4.6)
(4.7)
1'1 if
.73 .75 .10 .20 .09 .12 .07xl0-3 .06xl0- 3 700xl0 6 468xl0 6
.51 .60 .17 .29 .15 .28 .04xl0~ .03xl0- 3 1080xl0E7198xl0 6
!b !l11 !l12
.00 1.44 .39 .21 17,500
.00 8.80 .45 .18 97,500
.00 5.05 .30 .00 14,000
.00 5.28 .27 .11 13,500
.00 .01 .45 .18 200
~2 !!.21 !!.Z2
L 1=163xl0 3
.00 1.79 .21 .39 L z =941xl0 3
.00 9.91 .18 .45
.00 8.13 .00 .30
.00 4.90 .11 .27
.00 .02 .18 .45
Experiment A:
This experiment was simply based on a maximization of value added
without any additional pollution constraints or pollution costs (i.e. ~1 =
~z :;:: Q). The results ofthis 'free pollution' model are presented in Table 5
as a set ofregional welfare proflles.
76 ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AND SPATIAL WELFARE
Table Sa. The optimal regional Table Sb. The standardized regional
welfare profiles of experiment A. * welfare profiles of experiment A. **
Region 2 Region 2
Variable Variable
Income per capita 12,600 16,400 Income per capita .77 1.00
Pollution concentration 59,100 154,800 Environmental quality .38 1.00
Percentage employment 100 100 Percentage employment 1.00 1.00
* The pollution concentrations of the S pollutants are added here for the sake of
simplicity. All figures are rounded off on 10 2 units.
** Environmental quality (standardized) is defined here as 1 minus the (standardized)
pollution concentration.
Experiment B:
This experiment is based on a maximization of value added taking into
account the pollution constraints (4.7). The pollution costs and pollution
taxes are here again neglected (i.e. ~1 ::;:: ~2 ::;:: Q).The results are contained
in Table 6.
MODEL FOR ENVIRONMENTAL QUALITY 77
Table 6a. The optimal regional Table 6b. The standardized regional
welfare profiles of experiment B. welfare profiles of experiment B.
Region 1 2 Region 1 2
Variable Variable
Income per capita 12,400 13,800 Income per capita .76 .84
Pollution concentration 45,000 61,800 Environmental quality .29 .40
Percentage employment 100 100 Percentage employment 1.00 1.00
Experiment C:
In experiment C the assumption of a maximum value added is replaced by
a minimization of environmental damage costs (Le. PI = P2 = Q). The
pollution constraints are then abandoned. The results, based on the rigid
assumption that the unit environmental damage costs ~ (i = 1, 2) are
equal for all 5 types of pollutants, are contained in Table 7.
Table 7a. The optimal regional Table 7b. The standardized regional
welfare proflles of experiment C. welfare profJ.1es of experiment C.
Region 1 2 Region 1 2
Variable Variable
Income per capita 10,000 5,750 Income per capita .61 .35
Pollution concentration 17,600 23,000 Envirpnmental quality .11 .15
Percentage employment 82 42 Percentage employment .82 .42
Experiment D:
Experiment D is a combination of experiments A and C, except that the
unit environmental damage cost of region 1 and 2 are assumed to differ.
~1 and ~2 are calculated as follows. In a situation of free pollution (exper-
iment A) the pollution concentrations of region 1 and 2 are equal to
60,000 Ilg/m 3 and 160,000 Ilg/m3, respectively. The resulting regional
incomes for the same situation are approximately 1.6 X 109 Dfl. and
15.6 X 109 Dfl., respectively. Now the assumption is made that region 2
is prepared to pay 25 percent of its income in exchange for a clean
environment, while the less polluted region 1 is prepared to pay 12.5
percent of its income. Given this assumption, the marginal cost ('shadow-
price') per unit concentration in region 1 and 2 is approximately equal to
3,300 Dfl. and 24,000 Dfl., respectively. Hence, the vectors ~1 and ~2 are
equal to (3300, 3300, 3300, 3300, 3300)T and (24000, 24000, 24000,
24000,24000)T respectively.
The resulting welfare profiles can be found in Table 8. The income and
employment results of experiment D bear a close resemblance to those
from experiment B, but the environmental quality results show a rather
significant difference. The interregional inequality index S12 is equal to
.13, which falls also in the vicinity of the results of experiment B.
Table 8a. The optimal regional Table 8b. The standardized regional
welfare profiles of experiment D. welfare profiles of experiment D.
Region 1 2 Region 1 2
Variable Variable
Income per capita 12,000 13,500 Income per capita .73 .82
Pollution concentration 22,600 38,800 Environmental quality .15 .25
Percentage employment 100 100 Percentage employment 1.00 1.00
MODEL FOR ENVIRONMENTAL QUALITY 79
Experiment E:
Experiment E is the most integrated approach, since here pollution taxes
and subsidies are also taken into account. The pollution taxes ()i (i = 1, 2)
are levied upon the emitted pollutants, so that:
().1 = -r.Tp.
,_,
(4.8)
(4.9)
(4.10)
(4.11)
(4.12)
Next, Sl and S2 can be calculated, given (4.10), (4.11) and (4.12). Then
a can be derived ex post from (4.9).
The vectors of environmental cost coefficients ~i are calculated in
experiment D. The vectors of marginal pollution taxes '!i are now calcu-
lated accordingly. Given the assumed propensity of region 1 and 2 to pay
12.5 percent and 25 percent of its regional income, the total emission
80 ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AND SPATIAL WELFARE
in these regions in the case of a free pollution can be related to this total
pecuniary propensity for a cleaner environment in order to calculate the
corresponding pollution tax. Hence, the pollution tax rates are: II =
(5000, 5000, 5000, 5000, 5000)T and I2 = (9000, 9000, 9000, 9000,
9000).T
The results are presented in Table 9 (a appeared to be equal to .52).
These results show a high degree of correspondence with those from
e~eriment D. The interregional inequality index Sl2 is now approximately
equal to .10.
Table 9a. The optimal regional Table 9b. The standardized regional
welfare profIles of experiment E. welfare profIles of experiment E.
Region 1 2 Region 1 2
Variable Variable
Income per capita 12,900 13,400 Income per capita .79 .82
Pollution concentration 22,600 38,800 Environmental quality .15 .25
Percentage employment 100 100 Percentage employment 1.00 1.00
3.5 CONCLUSION
W~A
u
> 0, W~B
u
> 0, w~ .~
u
°
'V x~ > 0, 3 P~ , such that
(A.l)
> 0, ifp~ < Pu
-A
= °
, ifpA
u = P~
< 0, ifp~ > Pu
-A
(idem for B)
A. EXTENSIONS OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL MODEL 83
u
- Each region has a choice set Su = {x: ' x: 'p: 'p: }.
x:
- Each region n has a production-consumption set en = {(x:' P:, zn ll
> O,p: > O,zn .;;;; Of.
- Each region n has a well-behaved welfare function wn (x:' zn) P: '
with the following properties (see (2.3) and (2.4) ):
(A.3)
(A.4)
P: P:
- The environmental quality Zu in regions u is a weighted average of
pollution type and with weights 711 and 712 (711 + 712 = 1):
(A.S)
Given these hypotheses, the concepts described in Section 3.2 can again
be applied.
such that:
and
(A.8)
(A.9)
(A.IO)
and
(A.II)
zu =
and
In the case of free pollution, regions with production processes A will fix
their pollution levels independently, so that regions n E N suffer from uni-
directional environmental externalities from regions u E ii, while all
regions u E ii have reciprocal externalities. In this respect, only a partial
Pareto optimum may be possible, viz. with respect to production process
B which does not pollute other regions. Then only (A.9) and (A.10) are
fulfilled and not (A.1l).
Finally, aPBE is a feasible state dermed by the quadruple
sub;ect
J
to: xA
u + 1TxB
u + -rA
uu pA + rBpB + yA + yB =
uu u u xA
u + 1TxB
u
and
(A.lS)
while also the side-conditions from (A.12) and (A.13) are to be satisfied.
By adding up the side-conditions from (A.14) and (A.IS) and by combin-
ing them with those from (A.l2) and (A.13), it can easily be proved that:
= 0 (A.16)
which states that all effluent charges are redistributed over all regions.
The redistribution effects of a tax policy can be analysed in a way
analogous to the method in Section 3.3. Assuming again that the tax rate
is set equal to the marginal rate of substitution between pollution and
production, one finds:
.;.B
'n
= € 2 aB
nz - -.-B
'n (A.21)
'u = .....
.;.B a B rB
,,2 uz - U (A.22)
Z
. = -f/luu L
~ u·P A -f/2Pu
·B
(A.23)
u
u u=l
and
Z
. =- €1
u·
5nu=l A
L P - € PnB (A.24)
n u 2
The change in the pollution taxes ()u and ()n to be paid by region u and n
is by definition:
(A.2S)
and
()B
n
= i:BpB
n n
+ rBp·
n n
B (A.26)
Y• A
u
+ afJuA =0
'
0 ..;; a ..;; I (A.28)
yB
u + aOuB = 0 (A.29)
yB
n
+ aOnB = 0 (A.30)
and
U
Y• A + R L ()A = 0, 0..;; ~n ..;; I (A.31)
u "'n u = 1 u
88 ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AND SPATIAL WELFARE
Here the assumption is made that all pollution taxes associated with
process B are redistributed within the pollution-generating region itself,
so that the following conditions should be fulfilled:
N
ex + ~ {3, = 1 (A.32)
n=l n
(A.33)
(A.34)
which proves the fulfilment of the budget constraints from (A.l2) and
(A.l3). The same holds true for the pollution conditions from (A.l2)
and (A.l3). Consequently, the transition process can be characterized as a
set of continuous PBEs.
The fmal question is whether again a Pareto solution will be attained.
It can be derived by means of the proofs provided by Malinvaud (1972)
and Tulkens and Schoumaker (1975) that this indeed is the case. The
various redistribution options (depending on ex, i3n , etc.) can again be
represented by means of a table analogous to Table 1 including the
regional welfare profiles.
B. CONDITIONS FOR A GENERALIZED PARETO OPTIMUM 89
0uA -- WpA
, / WxA
' (B.la)
u u
, /w'xB
0uB -- WpB (B.lb)
u u
A -w' /W' A
°uz - zu xu (B.lc)
B -- W , /w'x B
0uz zu (B.ld)
u
OnB -w'
- p'B /w'xB (B.le)
n n
B -W' /W' B
°nz - zn xn (B.IO
L = WI - ¥ ) (wu -
u=2"u
WO) -
u
~
n=1 ''11
) (w -
n
WO) -
n
III (¥ xA
u=1 u
- 0 *)
U U A B
- ~ "u(zu + 111 ~u ~ Pu + 112Pu )
u=1 u=1
N U A B
- ~ I.In (zn +€l~n ~ Pu +€2P n ) (B.2)
n=1 u=1
The first-order conditions for a maximum are:
aL
-A =- \ W~A , Al =1 , V u (B.2a)
axu u
90 ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AND SPATIAL WELFARE
aL
- = - A w' B - J.l.2 \;fu (Bo2b)
axB u Xu
u
aL U N
ap;;
= - A w' A - 111 ~ V 8u - €1 ~ vn 8n = 0, \;f u (Bo2c)
u Pu u=1 u n=1
0, \;fu (Bo2d)
\;fu (Bo2e)
aL
- = - A w' B - J.l.2 = 0, \;f u (Bo2t)
axB n xn
n
aL
. - - - A w' B - V = 0 \;fn (Bo2g)
ap: n Pn n
€2
'
aL
- A w' - v = 0 \;f n (Bo2h)
n zn n '
oB
u = 112 V)J.l.2 (B.3b)
A
°uz = Vu /J.l.1 (B.3c)
°uz
B
= Vu /J.l.2 (B.3d)
iJB
n = €2 Vn /J.l.2 (B.3e)
°nz
B
= Vn /J.l.2 (Bo3f)
Combination of (B.3e) and (Bo3t) gives the first condition for a Pareto
optimum:
B. CONDITIONS FOR A GENERALIZED PARETO OPTIMUM 91
(BA)
which states that the marginal rate of substitution between pollution and
production is equal to the weighted marginal rate of substitution between
environmental quality and production.
Combination of(B.3b) and (B.3d) gives the second Pareto condition:
(B.S)
(B.6)
Substitution of (B.3c) and (B.6) into (B.3a) gives the last Pareto condition:
u u
auA = 1/1 L 0 aA
u = 1 u uz
+ t1 nL= 1 0n auz
A aB / aB
nz uz
(B.7)
The complexity of the latter condition arises from the diffusion mechan-
ism for environmental externalities assumed with regard to pollutants
from production process A.
REFERENCES
d'Aspremont, C. and L.A. Gerard-Varet, 'Un modele de negociation internationale pour certains
problemes de pollution'. Revue d'Economie Politique, 597-620, August, 1976.
Bartels, C.P.A. and P. Nijkamp, 'An empirical welfare approach to regional income distributions'.
Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, vol. 10,117-128,1976.
Bauer, R.A. (ed.), Social Indicators. MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1966.
Baumol, WJ., 'On taxation and the control of externalities'. American Economic Review, vol. 62,
307-322,1972.
Baumol, W.J. and W.E. Oates, The theory of environmental policy. Prentice-Hall, Englewood
Cliffs, 1975.
Beckenbach, E. and R. Bellman, An introduction to inequalities. Random House, New York,
1961.
Coupe, B.E.M .G., Regional economic structure and environmental pollution. Martinus Nijhoff, The
Hague, 1976.
Davis, O.A. and A. Whinston, 'Externalities, welfare and the theory of games' ,Journal of Political
Economy, vol. 70, 240-262,1962.
Dear, M., 'Spatial externalities and locational conflict', in D.B. Massey and P.W.J. Batey (eds.),
Alternative frameworks of analy sis. Pion, London, 152-167, 1977.
Delft, A. van and P. Nijkamp, Multi-criteria analysis and regional decision-making. Martinus
Nijhoff, The Hague, 1977.
92 REFERENCES
Dreze, J 11. and D. de la Vallee Poussin, 'A tatonnement process for public goods'. Review of
Economic Studies, vol. 38,133-150,1971.
Enzensberger, H.M., 'Zur Kritik der politischen Okologie'. Kursbuch 33, Rotbuch Verlag, Berlin,
142,1973.
Green, P.E. and F.J. Carmone, MultidimensioTUlI scaling and related techniques in marketing
aTUllysis. Allyn and Bacon, Boston, 1970.
Harvey, D., Social Justice and the city. Arnold, London, 1970.
Hordijk, 1. and P. Nijkamp, 'Dynamic models of spatial autocorrelation'. Environment and
Planning, vol. 9, 505 -519, 1977 .
Hueting, R.,Nieuwe Schaarste en Economische Groei. Agon Elsevier, Amsterdam, 1974.
Klaassen, 1.H. and T.H. Botterweg, 'Project evaluation and intangible effects: a shadow project
approach', in P. Nijkamp (ed.), Environmental economics, vol. 1. Martinus Nijhoff, The Hague,
3349,1976.
Mliler, K.G.,Environmental economics. The Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore,1974.
Malinvaud, E., Lectures on microeconomic theory. North-Holland Publishing Co., Amsterdam,
1972.
Milleron, J.C., 'Recherche des extremums de fonctions de plusieurs variables avec ou sans con-
trainte sur les variables', in E. Malinvaud (ed.) , Lec;ons de theorie microeconomique. Dunod,
Paris, 257-271, 1971.
Milleron, J .C., 'Theory of value with public goods'. JOurTUllofEconomic Theory, vol. 5,419472,
1972.
Nijkamp, P., 'Toward a society without a perspective?', Institute for Christian Studies, Toronto,
1976 (mimeographed).
Nijkamp, P., Theory and application of environmental economics. North-Holland Publishing Co.,
Amsterdam,1977.
Nijkamp, P. and R. Rietveld, 'Multi-objective programming models'. Regional Science and Urban
Economics, vol. 6,253-274,1976.
Nijkamp, P. and P. Rietveld, 'Impact analyses, spatial externalities and policy choices'. Paper for
First Canadian Regional Science Association Meeting, Halifax, 1977 (to appear in Northeast
Regional Science Review).
Paelinck, J.H.P. and P. Nijkamp, Operational theory and method in regional economics. Saxon
House, Farnborough (jointly with D.C. Heath, Lexington), 1976.
Pahl, R., 'Poverty and the urban system', in M. Chisholm and G. Manners (eds.) , Spatial policy of
the British economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 126-146, 1971.
Perloff, M.S. (ed.), The quality of the urban environment. Resources for the Future, Washington
D.C., 1969.
Pigou, A.C., The economics of welfare. MacMillan, London, 1930.
Richardson, H.W., RegioTUllgrowth theory. MacMillan, London, 1973.
Samuelson, PA., 'The pure theory of public expenditure'. Review of Economics and Statistics,
vol. 36, 387-389, 1954.
Shephard, R.N:, 'Matrix structures in ordinal data'. JourTUll of Mathematical Psychology, vol. 3,
125-139,1966.
Smith, D.M., The geography of social well·being. McGraw-Hill, New York, 1973.
Tulkens, H. and F. Schoumaker, 'Stability analysis of an effluent charge and the "polluter pays"
principle'. JourTUll ofPublic Economics, vol. 4, 245-269, 1975.
Vipond, J., 'City size and unemployment'. Urban Studies, vol. 11,39-47,1974.
4. Contact potentials in the European
system of cities
ULF ERLANDSSON*
ties of applying exactly the same approach as in the Swedish case. Finally,
in Section 4.4, some questions are raised concerning the prospects and
limitations of this approach and its possible implications for a regional
policy at a European scale.
i
ADMINISTRATIVE FUNCTIONS
Decision -making, planning, Direct personal contacts
negotiations. search. product
~ :"o~cow,
development etc.
Control. direction of
production. information-
processing. services to I ,"ro••
Al etc.
Accounting. routine
office work. services to
Al and A2 etc. Contacts via telephone
and correspondence
SERVICE FUNCTIONS
e=:U->
Business services Buying and service trips
Household services
MANUFACTURING FUNCTIONS
Processing of mot.rials. MATERIAL FLOWS
handling of goods. con- D
~---'>
struction. etc.
PRIMARY FUNCTIONS
Agriculture. mining,
energy production, etc. Goods tranportation
1970
Figure 2. The Swedish contact landscape 1970. Numbers indicate contact potentials
for urban regions. Stockholm = 100. (Adapted from Tornqvist 1973.)
CONTACT SYSTEMS IN SWEDISH REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT 99
4.2.4 Conclusions
The investigations previously mentioned show that contact activities occur
in a national system of cities. The embryo of the Swedish national system
of cities evolved long ago. Since this early development, a growing con-
centration of decision-making and administrative functions within the
largest cities has occurred. At the same time the accessibility of these large
cities has increased simultaneously with the extension of the transport
system and higher transport technology. On the national level, this has
resulted in the growth of a few urban centers at the expense of the
remaining national territory.
Additionally, the investigations showed that direct personal contacts
were not just maintained within a national system of cities, as foreign
contacts average about 10 percent of the number of contacts originating
in Sweden (Hedberg 1970; Sah1berg 1970). In the contact pattern formed
by decision-makers and other administrative personnel, it is thus possible
to see the outlines of an international 'business world'. This consists of a
set of large urban places which are connected with one another by rapid
100 CONT ACT POTENTIALS IN EUROPEAN CITIES
Given the conditions within a single country (e.g. Sweden) the Tornqvist
approach concerning contact potentials seems to work. It is evident,
however, that the change from a national to an international context gives
rise to additional methodological problems. For instance, in applying the
Tornqvist model on a wider spatial scale it could in principle be ques-
tioned if the measure of accessibility of various places should be expressed
by a length of stay time as short as a single-day visit at each locality.
Moreover, should the contact requirements on an international level be
measured on the basis of the actual number of contact-intensive em-
ployees within each of these places, when a great part of the contact
requirement of a certain urban place is likely to be intra-national rather
than international? There may also be additional constraints on the
travel behaviour of administrative employees when international bounda-
ries have to be crossed. However, th~ investigations below have not really
taken these problems into consideration and they will thus have to be left
aside for further research.
The foregoing discussion of contact patterns in Sweden has emphasized
the role of the principal urban nodes in the national information web. An
extension of the study to the international level also poses the immediate
problem of identifying the appropriate European system of cities for the
analysis of international information webs. It is, of course, impossible to
regard any such system as closed for there will be many flows across its
boundaries. Most large European cities, for instance, are in frequent direct
contact with American cities. Beyond the immediate periphery of Europe,
e.g. in North Africa, are cities where daily contact is as much with the
urban nodes of Europe as with themselves.
1. The investigations reported in this paper are derived from a study of the possible
consequences of a proposed bridge across the Oresund, part of which is concerned
with the general question of accessibility in Europe.
ACCESSIBILITY IN EUROPEAN CITIES 101
2. The urban centers are Bilbao, Nice, Nantes, Toulouse, Geneva, Erfurt and Aarhus.
102 CONTACT POTENTIALS IN EUROPEAN CITIES
from these two questions are used as measures of the outbound and
inbound potential contacts for each urban center.
Outbound maximum stay time. Figure 3 shows that the most favourable
zone for outbound maximum stay time occurs within an area delimited
by lines drawn between Paris-London-Hamburg-Munich-Milan-Lyon
-Paris. The only urban centers that show corresponding high values
outside this delineated area are West Berlin, Vienna, Rome and Man-
chester. This high accessibility area is called the Primary European Center.
The values for the urban centers within this area show variations but, as
seen from Figure 3, they constitute a reasonably homogeneous block.
Outside the Primary European Center, cities in Scandinavia, the British
Isles (excluding London and Manchester) and the south and west of
France form three relatively homogeneous accessibility blocks. The urban
centers within these three zones hold an intermediate position in terms of
ACCESSIBILITY IN EUROPEAN CITIES 103
~----------------~------------------------~-----------~
Figure 3. The European stay time map: outbound accessibility. The values are
expressed relative to the most accessible urban center (Paris = 100).
their outbound maximum stay time and are referred to as the Inter-
mediate European Centers.
The only urban area having a corresponding value to the Intermediate
European Centers and falling outside these three blocks is Madrid. Seen
from Figure 3, the variability in outbound maximum stay time in the rest
of Europe is large. The values vary between 0 and 30. Therefore, within
this low accessibility area there are different degrees of secondary posi-
tions. The urban centers within this zone are referred to as the Secondary
European Centers.
Another striking feature emerging from Figure 3 is the major difference
in values between East and West European centers, well illustrated in the
East and West German case.
104 CONTACT POTENTIALS IN EUROPEAN CITIES
Figure 4. The European stay time map: inbound accessibility. The values are
expressed relative to the most accessible urban center (Frankfurt = 100).
Inbound maximum stay time. The inbound maximum stay time map
(Figure 4) shows that most urban centers belonging to the Primary Euro-
pean Center have equally favourable positions regarding their inbound
travel. A striking change in ranking occurs for Copenhagen. It now belongs
to this group. Thus, Copenhagen has considerably better inbound than
outbound maximum stay time within Europe.
The urban centers belonging to the three blocks called the Intermediate
European Centers still keep their positions in relation to the 'secondary'
cities. But as their values overall are lower when compared to the Primary
European Center, the inbound maximum stay time of these blocks is
lower than their outbound maximum stay time. The opposite is true for
some places in the Secondary European Centers category (e.g. Barcelona,
Genoa, Zagreb and Warsaw). The outbound maximum stay time values
ACCESSIBILITY IN EUROPEAN CITIES 105
3. The populations of Bonn and The Hague are added to those of Cologne and Am-
sterdam.
106 CONTACT POTENTIALS IN EUROPEAN CITIES
Figure 5. The relationship between the maximum stay time and the potential
number of individuals who can be reached from Paris, Copenhagen and Malmo
during a day visit.
PoP. (millions)
80
70
60
50
40
20
10
L_...-~::=:==;:=:::~s::::::::;:::::::::;:::;;;=:;=?-
10 12 14 16 18
... Max. stay tIme
(hours)
Figure 6. The relationship between the maximum stay time and the potential
number of individuals who can travel to Paris, Copenhagen and Malmo
during a day visit.
108 CONT ACT POTENTIALS IN EUROPEAN CITIES
Pop. (millions)
Figure 7. The contact potential calculated as the area (a) below the whole location
profile (b) between four and eight hours of length of stay.
ACCESSIBILITY IN EUROPEAN CITIES 109
'--_--"590 km
The two investigations discussed in the second part of this paper have
dealt with regional balance between European travel facility demand and
supply in 1976. It was found that different nodes in different parts of
Europe differ greatly with regard to the possibility of maintaining direct
personal contacts.
To judge from a previous study dealing with the development of the
European air transport network during 1965-76, these regional differences
PERSONAL CONTACT NETWORKS 113
REFERENCES
Engstrom, M.-G., Regional arbetsfordelning. Nya drag i forviirsarbetets geografiska organisation i
Sverige. C.W.K. Gleerup, Lund, 1970.
Engstrom, M.-G., and B. Sahlberg, Travel demand, transport systems and regional development.
Modes in co·ordinated planning. Lund Studies in Geography, Ser. B., no. 39, Lund, 1973.
Engstrom, M.-G., and B. Sahlberg, Kommunikationer och regional utveckling. Nuvarande och
framtida utvecklingslinjer. SOU 1974: 3, bilaga 7. Stockholm, 1974.
Erlandsson, U., Kontakt och resemojligheter i Europa. Department of Social and Economic Geo-
graphy, University of Lund, 1977 (mimeographed).
Hall, P., The world cities. Weidenfeld and Nicholson, London, 1966.
Hedberg, B., Kontaktsystem inom svenskt niiringsliv. En studie av organisationers extema person·
kontaker. C.W.K. Gleerup, Lund, 1970.
Kristensson, F., People, firms and regions. The Economic Research Institute at the Stockholm
School of Economics, Stockholm, 1967.
Sahlberg, B., Interregionala kontaktmonster. Personkontakter inom svenskt niiringsliv - en flyg·
passagerarstudie. C.W.K. Gleerup, Lund, 1970.
Tornqvist, G., Flows of information and the location of economic activities. Lund Studies in
Geography, Ser. B., no. 30, Lund, 1968.
Tornqvist, G., Contact systems and regional development. Lund Studies in Geography, Ser. B., no.
35, Lund, 1970.
Tornqvist, G., Contact requirements and travel facilities - contact models of Sweden and regional
development alternatives in the future. Systems of Cities and Information Flows. Two Essays.
Lund Studies in Geography, Ser. B., no. 38, Lund, 1973.
5. Human reactions to spatial
diversity: Mobility in regional
labour markets
J.A.M. HEIJKE and L.H. KLAASSEN*
m = p.i (1)
where:
m : the size of the migration flow
p. : mobility
i : the size of the impulse.
Recalling the title of this contribution with these definitions in mind,
we may say that spatial diversity is to be considered as the main factor
behind the impulses, and mobility as the propensity to react to this spatial
diversity.
Spatial diversity concerns such factors as population, employment
positions, housing and living environment; in general, it refers to the
differences between regions in social and physical structure. Mobility is
associated with the preference structure of the population as far as a
change in residence is concerned. The preferences are related among other
things to the social group to which people belong, their training level, and
the experience gained with previous migration. In economic models the
preferences are generally found back as parameters, with the above-
mentioned impulses figuring as variables. That is understandable; a popula-
tion's preference structure is pretty constant. From a policy point of view
it is a one-sided approach, however, for it is possible for a government to
affect the population's mobility as well as the above impulses by policy
measures. In that case, one needs to understand both the migration model
and the mobility model superposed on it.
The effectiveness of a combined impulse and mobility policy can be
defined as:
The impulse policy (di) causes the migration to grow by p.di. The effec-
tiveness of the total impulse action is increased by idp., however, if
mobility is increased by dp.. So, improving educational facilities could (in
the long run) improve mobility and thus stimulate migration to regions
where a policy of stimulation is conducted.
About the factors behind mobility, little is known as yet. In this con-
tribution we shall confine ourselves for the moment to a discussion of
the structure of mobility as it emerges from two studies, each dealing with
a specific kind of migration flow. The first (Section 5.1) is concerned with
flows on the intra-national level (interregional migration) within Great
Britain, France, the Netherlands, and Sweden; the second (Section 5.2)
analyses flows on the international level, in particular from Mediterranean
countries to Western Europe. We shall compare the results of the two
studies, and analyse the structure of mobility in each case. The factors
that determine mobility will not be gone into here, though in the discus-
sion of the results of the enquiry into international migration an attempt
will be made to introduce into the analysis the concept of psychological
distance. Special attention will be paid to the influence of kinship
between the languages spoken in the countries of origin and destination
(Section 5.3). Finally, some conclusions will be drawn in Section 5.4.
MIGRATION/MOBILITY IN EUROPE 119
(3)
where:
Mij total number of migrants from region i to regionj; (during a given
period - for the countries involved between 1960 through 1968);
total number of jobs in industries and services in region j in the
base year of the period;
total number of people between 15 and 65 years of age in region i,
also in the base year;
D.. : distance between the centres of regions i and j in car kilometres.
If 0 is the factor most frequently cited on the household and individual
level as an impulse to undertake long-distance interregional migration.
This factor represents an indicator of the prospects on the labour market
of the region of destination. These prospects are a function of the number
of job opportunities coming available through the creation of new positions
and the vacancy of old ones. We will assume that these two components of
change are more or less proportional with 0' Naturally we should have
preferred to differentiate between skill groups for this variable as well as
for Li' but lack of data prevented such detail.
Li represents the number of people in the active age groups in the
region of origin. It is the least ambiguous definition that could be given,
ensuring a high degree of comparability between countries. Li then serves
as an indicator of the group of potential migrants. We assume that this
group is approximately proportional to Li . Differentiation between the
sexes would seem advisable, particularly because their participation rates
differ greatly in the various countries, e.g. between Sweden and the
Netherlands. However, such refinement would severely complicate the
analysis, for it is households rather than individuals that account for the
120 HUMAN REACTIONS TO SPATIAL DIVERSITY
bulk of the migration flows, and households tend to consist of both men
and women. In fact, a different kind of analysis altogether would be
required if sex differentiation were to be introduced. The variable chosen,
then, was simply the number of people in the active age groups.
Dij represen ts the distance between the regions i and j. It stands as a
proxy for psychological distance rather than for the costs of bridging the
physical distance. Assumedly, the financial costs of moving a household
from one region to another are, for one thing, virtually insensitive to
distance, and for another, are negligible compared to the net monetary
advantages of the move, though it must be admitted that at short term the
fmancing of a move may constitute a barrier. What really counts is the
pain of leaving one's friends and relations for a completely different
environment with a different social, sometimes also religious and cultural
structure. That is the 'cost' that, as we assume, increases with physical
distance.
But there are other migration impulses beside the factors mentioned.
Important impUlses may come from the housing facilities and the living
environment; the income advantages to be expected may also playa role.
Lack of data made it impossible to assess the impact of such impulses; the
migration enquiries to be discussed here were, indeed, purely labour
market-orien ted.
Furthermore, we want to draw attention to the fact that the variables
in the migration equation are expressed in absolute levels; in that way it is
relatively easy to determine how a changed impulse, e.g. the creation of
job opportunities, affects the number of migrants.
The results of the analysis are presented in Table 1. Looking at mobility
in its relation to each regression coefficient, we think a distinction should
be made between general mobility as represented by the value of the inter-
'cept, and specific mobility related to a specific impulse variable.
General mobility is highest in the Netherlands (- 3.36) and lowest in
France and Great Britain (- 11.37 and - 10.43, respectively). Sweden
occupies an intermediate position (- 6.81). The influence of distance is
obviously highest in the Netherlands (- 0.009) and lowest in Sweden
(- 0.0014), both France and Great Britain taking an intermediary position.
The coefficients of E. Gob opportunities in the immigration region)
J
suggest a certain relation with the coefficients of Li (potentially active
persons in the emigration region). In both cases the Netherlands show a
low mobility, France and Great Britain a high one, while Sweden takes an
intermediary position.
MIGRATION/MOBILITY IN EUROPE 121
Table 1. Regression statistics for France (F), Great Britain (GB), the Netherlands (NL)
and Sweden (S). * Observations between 1960 and 1968. * *
* The number of regions in France is 21, in Great Britain 8, in the Netherlands 11, in Sweden 23;
the numbers are dictated by the structure of available data.
** Numbers in brackets represent t-values.
The results of the analysis are summarized in Table 2 in qualitative terms.
The outcome for general mobility appears to mirror that of the push-and-
pull factors.
In France and Great Britain, while general mobility is low, push factors
(the number of people present in a region) as well as pull factors (job op-
Table 2. Mobility structure in France, Great Britain, the Netherlands and Sweden.
depends on that country's size: the smaller the country, the more distance
seems to be a barrier to migration.
The most important feature emerging for the Netherlands is the high
sensitivity of the working population to distances. Job creation, not a very
powerful migration stimulus at all times, is made even more ineffective by
the people's resistance to moving over any sizeable distance. Klaassen
and Drewe (1973) examined the effectiveness of job creation in regions
of destination at various distances. They found that the creation of jobs at
a short distance (say 100 kilometers) was most successful in inducing
migration in the Netherlands, with Sweden coming second. In France and
Great Britain such job creation was a great deal less effective. The impact
of job creation rapidly diminishes in the Netherlands as distances increase;
at 300 kilometers it is very nearly as low as in France and Great Britain.
The effectiveness of job creation at long distances turns out to be
considerably higher in Sweden than in the other countries studied.
On the grounds of the foregoing it may be assumed that attempts under-
taken in the Netherlands to stimulate migration over a large distance (e.g.
from the west to the north), by creating job opportunities in the area of
destination, will not be successful unless mobility is stimulated as well by
suitable policy measures. By the same token, the planned removal of
government agencies from the western to the northern part of the country
may be strongly opposed because of the relatively large distance involved.
(4)
and
124 HUMAN REACTIONS TO SPATIAL DIVERSITY
.6 = Ln(M ij )"
.5 = Ln(M ij )
.4
.3
.2
.1
-1
-2
-3
.7 0,72 Ln(aWji)
.6
Ej=working population in
,00""', QOO ~,,;'" ;0 j 1j
-2,69Ln(Dij} Dij= distance (as the crow flies
between i and j
-21
-22
.2
-1
Switzer-
-3 Austria France Germany land Belgium lands Sweden country
4 .
- 124561234567B91234567B91234561234567B9123456B91 234567B9 )
country i
Figure 1. Migrants from Mediterranean countries.
* The countries 'i' are numbered according to the appendix.
126 HUMAN REACTIONS TO SPATIAL DIVERSITY
Origin DZ E GR Total
MA I TR
Destination TV P YV
The first conclusion that may be drawn from the table is that the sum of
the residuals for each group of emigration countries is relatively small
compared to the residuals for each group of immigration countries
FINAL REMARKS 127
separately. That means that there are hardly any significant differences
between groups of Mediterranean countries as far as their total emigration
is concerned.
A second conclusion is that there seems to be a strong preference for
France and Belgium as immigration countries aad a negative preference
for the Germanic countries, with Switzerland taking an intermediary
position. An explanation for this preference could be the distribution of
language-groups among immigration and emigration countries. The coun-
tries with French as important second language (DZ, MA and TU) show
considerable positive preference for migration to France and Belgium and
a strong negative preference for the Germanic countries. The same, but to
a lesser extent, holds for the other Romance-languages-speaking countries
(E, I and P), where we find positive preference for France, Belgium and
Switzerland (possibly also due to the fact that in Switzerland Italian is
also spoken) and a negative preference for the Germanic countries. The
remaining group of countries, whose languages have no direct kinship with
either Romance or Germanic tongues and who therefore can be con-
sidered to have a free choice, show a slight preference for the Germanic
countries.
The results confirm the expectation that language barriers are an
important element of psychological distance, and affect migration
behaviour significantly. Indeed, further analysis in that direction might
well prove fruitful. On the whole it seems that in migration analyses, more
attention should be given to social and cultural factors, and'in particular
to language differences, than has been given so far.
Subtotal
Mediterranean area 57,470 2,483,250 1,699,800 644,465 282,670 67,000 31,690
Other countries of
origin 10,310 516,750 e 681,300 288,675 172,935 f 137 ,OO~ 107,000h
Population countries
of destination
(in millions) 7.4 50.3 60.8 6.2 9.6 12.7 8.0
Immigrants from
Mediterranean area
as a percentage of
the popUlation 0.8 4.9 2.8 10.5 2.9 0.5 0.4
Total number of
immigrants as a
percentage of
the population 0.9 6.0 3.9 15.2 4.7 1.6k 1.7
Exclusive of 129,858 seasonal workers (including 119,301 Spaniards, 3,110 Portuguese, 2,408
Italians and 2,079 Moroccans).
Exclusive of seasonal workers (114,081 in August 1968 and 14,233 in December 1968) and
frontier workers (63,062).
k Inclusive of Surinamese, Antillians, and Moluccans this percentage becomes 2.1.
REFERENCES
Heijke, J.A.M., L.H. Klaassen, and C.J. Offereins, Towards a labour market model. H.D. Tjeenk
Willink bv, Groningen, 1975 (published in Dutch).
Heijke, J .AM., Socio-economic aspects of foreign labour. (Forthcoming, to be published in Dutch.)
Klaassen, LB. and P. Drewe, Migration policy in Europe: a comparative study. Saxon House,
Lexington Books, Famborough and Lexington, 1973 (and literature quoted therein).
Part II: Policy-oriented studies in spatial
inequalities and regional development
6. Spatial equity: Some anti-theses to
current regional development doctrine
WALTER STOHR and FRANZ TODTLING*
few functional and geographical centres, on the impulses of which the rest
of the system has increasingly become dependent. It is maintained that
satisfactory solutions of existing problems at intermediate and small social
scales will only be possible if, along with the presently dominating
strategies for system-wide spatial integration (and regional openness),
explicit instruments for selective spatial closure at various levels are
applied. Essentially this would imply devolving some of the decision-
making powers which have become vested in functionally-organized
(vertical) units back to territorially-organized (horizontal) units at
different spatial scales.
Taking into account the impact which changes in large-scale functional
relations exert upon territorial structures, there are theoretically three
possible strategies for resolving emerging conflicts:
1. Complex systems management. This requires full knowledge of the
systematic interrelations between functional and territorial changes and
viCe versa. In view of the complexity of these interrelations this should
remain a long-term research item but it is doubtful whether - except
for selected problem areas - applicable research results may be avail-
able in the near future. Also, such results may render technocratic, but
not necessarily socially feasible solutions.
2. Priority given to functional change. This strategy has been implicitly
applied during the past half century or more. Large-systems oriented
criteria (technological change, efficiency, etc.) prevailed and the result-
ing territorial changes were either neglected or left to the individual
household, firm or local and regional community to cope with;1 at
best, extreme consequences of the disruption of territorial relations
were looked after by large-scale functional (public or private) institu-
tions, including central government.
3. Priority given to territorial integrity. This would mean that functional
changes are allowed to take place only to the extent that no major
disruption of territorial living conditions is caused, or that substantial
aids are given to territorial communities to adapt their structures to the
functional changes they consider desirable.
The choice between these three theoretical alternatives depends on
whether importance for human and social well-being is attributed to large-
scale functional (mainly market- and institution-based) relations as against
2. Kamal Salih in his concluding remarks to the Nagoya seminar said he was not sure
whether he had come 'to a burial of the growth pole idea or to a celebration of the
new agropolitan approach' . . . and . . . 'whether this symposium will mark the
demise of central planning of growth-oriented approaches and ·of accelerated
industrialization as the prime mover of development, or the birth of a self-reliant
planning, of the goal of distribution and of accelerated rural development' (Nagoya
Centre, 1975, p. 416).
140 SPATIAL EQUITY: SOME ANTI-THESES
In summary one can say that, since most problems to which national
policies for spatial development address themselves were caused by large-
scale influences transmitted through vertical functional channels, the use
of large-scale, vertically-integrated institutions turned out to be a rather
evasive instrument for controlling these problems and in the long-run must
be expected to operate in the interest of these large-scale organizations
rather than in the interest of the respective regions for which the policies
were designed.
We have seen that such (outright) global communication is not possible. Each
organization exceeding the 'critical group' size corresponding to its structure will
necessarily falter due to a collapse in internal communications. The unfeasibility of
communication beyond a certain scale favours the system of small organizations and
small groups. These small groups (or at least a large part of them) can survive in a
'poor' world if it foregoes specialization, individual storage and transport.
(author's translation)
4. Lasuen (1974) states further that 'until the early 1960s both rural-urban and inter-
regional income differentials were widening. It seems that only from the early
1960s onwards have the interurban and interregional income differentials been
ameliorated, in spite of the continuous worsening of rural-urban differentials due to
the growing weight of urban income in the underdeveloped areas'.
148 SPATIAL EQUITY: SOME ANTI-THESES
with the national growth rate but the gap towards the rest of Italy was
not noticeably diminished (similarly Rodgers 1970; Cao-Pinna 1974).
In France regional economic policy at first sight seems to have been
quite successful: the regional distribution of population and economic
activities (particularly industrial employment) was modified in the desired
direction, the century-old flow of people from the provinces to Paris had
been halted and possibly reversed (Prud'homme, in Hansen 1974, pp.
56 ff). A closer look however, shows that industrial employment increased
in the Western regions mainly around Paris, but not at the greater distance
from it where the most backward areas of France are. Similar findings
relate to the distribution of industrial employment (Sundqvist 1975,
pp. 119 ff). 5 Concerning income disparities between regions both Prud'
homme (1974), pp. 59 ff) and the OECD (1976, p. 26) indicate that these
disparities have not been significantly reduced.
Lack of success of regional policy measures is also indicated for
Belgium (Ruehmann 1968; Davin 1969).
There seem to exist also some examples of at least partial goal fulfilment
of regional policies with regard to reducing spatial disparities of living
levels.
For the United States, Cumberland and Thoman evaluate the Appala-
chian programme as successful in at least some respects. The large gap
between Appalachia and the rest of the nation in terms of employment
rates, migration balance and per capita income narrowed slightly in the
period 1965 to 1973 (Thoman 1976, pp. 20 ff; Cumberland 1973, pp.
101 ff). There is no clear answer to the questions of how much of this
trend is due to regional policy or how intra-regional disparities developed.
For the United Kingdom, Cameron (1974, p. 24) states that regional
policy has contributed to an improvement in the relative unemployment
level and per capita income growth. Moore and Rhodes (1974, p. 49) state
in this connection, however, that although disparities would have been
worse without regional policy they have remained at unacceptably high
levels.
In the Federal Republic of Germany about 550,000 jobs have been
subsidized by regional policy measures from 1969-74 (Hotger 1974, pp.
187 ff). Other investigations indicate, however, that the causal relation-
5. Sundqvist, however, states also a slight improvement of the more distant provinces
with regard to industrial employment in the late 1960s (1975, p. 120).
RECENT SPATIAL DEVELOPMENT TRENDS 149
ship between subsidies and job creation is rather weak and that the
diversity and qualification of jobs created is small (Wolf 1975, pp. 431 ff).
Von Boventer (1969) indicates that regional trends in Western Germany
are very much due to market forces rather than to regional policy measures.
In Austria, inter- and intra-regional material disparities seem to have
been decreasing during the 1950s and 1960s. Berentsen (1976) found that
regional inequalities of per capita product during the period 1961-71/2
have considerably declined both at the Bundesliinder (province) level
and at the Bezirk (county) level. Similarly a broader analysis of nine
indicators of regional levels of living by factor analysis for 1957-71 shows
that a considerable decline in the factor score inequalities was observed
(pp. 99 ff). Berentsen hypothesizes that Austrian regional policy
(although little coordinated) has certainly positively influenced the partial
goal fulfilment of reducing interregional and intra-regional disparities.
But it is difficult to say to what extent the little-coordinated regional
development policy or other specific Austrian conditions have contributed
to this phenomenon. 6
For Japan, Mera (Nagoya Centre 1975) also shows evidence of decreas-
ing income disparities for the forty-six prefectures of Japan during the
period 1961-72. He further analyzes how much regional policy, particularly
the growth pole strategy in existence since 1962, has contributed to the
reduction of income disparities. He concludes, from a comparison of the
spatial distribution of reductions in income disparities and the govern-
ment's industrial decentralization policy at selected growth poles, that this
policy seems to neither have contributed to a reduction in income dis-
6. Such specific conditions might be (some of these points were indicated by Berent-
sen, others by the present authors):
- the small geographical size of Austria;
the expansion of commuting radii from the main employment centres to cover
the majority of populated areas (Berentsen 1976, p. 11);
the long-standing traditions of tourist activities in many rural areas;
the stagnation and peripheral Eastern location of the richest province (Vienna);
the fact that the second richest province lies at the other extreme periphery
(Vorarlberg) ;
certain factor scarcities (land, labour) within the major cities, particularly in
Vienna, reinforced still by rigid land-use regulations and a fragmented land-
market;
the entrenched federalist character of the country;
a very rigid and all-embracing legal and administrative system acting as a forceful
brake for the rapid adoption of innovations.
150 SPATIAL EQUITY: SOME ANTI-THESES
on France; Hansen 1975a, on the USA; Allen and McLennan 1970 and
Sundqvist 1975, on Italy; Appa1raju and Safier 1975, on 'Third-world coun-
tries'). Others relate to 'spontaneous' growth centres (Moseley 1973,
on Rennes, France and East Anglia, United Kingdom; Gilbert 1975, on
Medellin, Collunibia; Waller 1974, on Peru).
The major findings of the abovementioned and other studies and
investigations can be summarized as follows:
1. Spread-effects from growth centres were usually smaller than expected,
or less than backwash-effects and therefore had a negative net result
on the hinterland. They were narrowly limited in geographical extent,
usually restricted to the commuting area, often as a function of the size
of the centre (Morrill 1974).
2. Increases in income of lower order centres or rural areas create strong
income multipliers in higher order centres but not the other way round
(Nichols 1969; Moseley 1973 and 1974). They seem to move upward
rather than downward within the urban hierarchy.
3. In the context of policies for broad spatial development it is difficult
to justify growth-centre policies for lagging areas due to their lack of
spread-effects in the urban hierarchy downward or from the growth
centre to a broader hinterland (Hansen 1975, Nichols 1969; Moseley
1973 and 1974).
economic tenns, but it will at the same time tend to increase disparities
in other respects such as in access to decision-making powers, social
amenities, etc. One reason is that economic interaction and redistribution
in general can take place at much larger scales than sociopolitical inter-
action and redistribution.
In view of the problems which policies of outright functional and
spatial integration have created - both at the international and at the
interregional level - we should like to discuss an alternative strategy of
regional development by selective spatial closure. The following ideas
by no means are to suggest a policy of regional autarchy. Both from an
efficiency and an equity standpoint this would be unthinkable today.
Suggested, however, are policies which pennit the channeling of today's
widely uncontrolled economic, social and political 'backwash' effects and
thereby facilitate greater spatial equity of living conditions in all the
respects discussed above. This requires a number of preconditions:
1. The broadening of explicit spatial development policy beyond presently
mainly economic (materially-oriented) consideration to a more explicit
inclusion of social and political processes.
2. The refonnulation of distance friction from a negative concept (to be
diminished as an obstacle to large-scale integration and spatial equili-
brium) to a positive one for the structuring of a spatially-dis aggregate
interaction and decision system (Isard 1976).
3. Greater attention to be paid to non-market- and non-institution-based
activities and to the requirements of small-scale human and man-
environment relations.
4. A shift of decision-making powers from today's mainly functional or
vertical (sectoral) units to horizontal (territorial) units at various levels.
The scale of the territorial decision-making level should ideally be the
one within which a maximum of the repercussions or external effects of
the respective decisions can be internalized. This means a closer
approximation of decision-making scales with corresponding spatial
impact scales. In case of doubt the lower decision-making levels should
be given preference.
We shall not propose specific instruments for such policies here,
particularly because they have to be carefully adapted to the specific
historical, institutional and political conditions in each country or region.
We shall only give examples of policy instruments already in use which
operate (often intuitively) in such directions.
Strategies of selective spatial closure can, in current economic tennin-
154 SPATIAL EQUITY: SOME ANTI-THESES
ology, be applied from the supply side (regional resources, Section 6.4.1),
the demand side (guidance of regional preference patterns, Section 6.4.2)
and through policy instruments modifying distance friction and thereby
changing accessibility to inputs, to markets, to social contacts and to
decision-making power as well as by redistributing the effects of external
and scale economies (Section 6.4.3). If integration between highly- and
little-developed areas takes place in an uncontrolled way, the absence of
these strategies would tend to increase existing spatial inequalities.
its copper, etc.); usually the regional bargaining position will be greater
the higher the demand for its natural resources.
3. Employment of human resources. Regional co-determination will vary
widely according to the respective sociopolitical system: from com-
munal decision-making on migration (e.g. in China) on one extreme,
to more liberal policies of regionally differentiated labour exchange
systems and regionally differentiated school and training facilities
geared to specific regional development potentials and needs rather
than to criteria of a uniform national education system.
tions within and between less developed areas (rather than between these
and highly developed core regions). Such a policy would unilaterally
improve the possibilities of less-developed areas to improve their internal
factor market, to increase internal demand, to make use of scale
economies and thereby improve their competitive position also vis-a-vis
the outside. In Sweden extensive proposals for an interperipheral trans-
port network have been made (Tornqvist 1973). In Britain proposals have
been made for intra-regional commuting subsidies for less-developed
sparsely populated areas in order to increase access to labour at individual
peripheral locations (Moseley 1974, p. 146). In France explicit priority
has been given to strengthening the transport connections between
regional equilibrium metropolises (Rapport 1971, pp. 46 ff; Friedly 1974,
pp. 158 fO.
Compensation for spatially-differentiated external and potential scale
economies. Within specific sectors, scale economies are to a great extent
a function of market accessibility. Accessibility again is - apart from
geographic location - considerably determined by public transport invest-
ment, an economy external to the firm. In peripheral areas in which
sufficient transport improvement is either not feasible or not possible
(not all locations can nor should be touched by freeways, etc.), compensa-
tion at a freeway exit, and thereby able to reap scale economies. It is the
maintain basic needs services. In areas with too low population and/or
income density, measures such as subsidies, negative income tax, etc.
might be justified in order to compensate for the lack of scale economies
and thereby facilitate the required private (or public) basic services. It will
depend on the specific economic and political system whether this com-
pensation has to be derived from general taxation or whether it can be
drawn from enterprises gaining high external economies, e.g. due to loca-
tion at a freeway exit, and thereby able to reap scale economies. It is the
typical question of how to compensate for differential locational
advantages between, for instance, a (freeway-oriented) supermarket and a
neighbourhood grocer, if the latter is needed for the supply of less mobile
population strata (children, aged, poor, etc.) in a local or regional context.
These were examples of policy instruments often intuitively developed
to control spatial 'backwash' effects. If strategies of selective spatial
closure were adopted as explicit components of regional development
policy, coherent sets of such policy instruments adapted to the specific
conditions of the respective country or region would have to be elaborated
and subjected to empirical testing. The fact that such instruments might
158 SPATIAL EQUITY: SOME ANTI-THESES
REFERENCES
Allardt, E., About dimensions of welfare. Research Group for Comparative Sociology, Research
Report no. 1, University of Helsinki, 1973.
Allen, K. and M.C. McLennan, Regional problems and policies in Italy and France. George Allen
and Unwin, London, 1970.
Alonso, W. and E. Medrich, 'Spontaneous growth centres in twentieth-century American urbaniza-
tion', in N.M. Hansen (ed.), Growth centres in regional economic development. The Free Press,
New York, 1972.
Appalraju, 1. and M. Safier, 'Growth centre strategies in less developed countries', in A. Gilbert
(1976).
Berentsen, B., 'Regional policy and regional inequalities in Austria: the impact of policy upon the
achievement of planning goals'. Unpublished PhD dissertation, Ohio State University, 1976.
Bourne, L.S., Urban systems: strategies for regulation. A comparison of policies in Britain, Sweden,
Australia and Canada. Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1975.
Boventer, E. von, 'Regional economic problems in West Germany', in Robinson (1969).
Bundesraumordnunsgesetz 1965 (GFR), Bad Godesberg.
Bundesminister fiir Raumordnung, Bauwesen und Stadtebau: Raumordnungsberichte 1968, 1970,
1972: and 1974 (GFR), Bonn-Bad Godesberg.
Buttler, F., Entwicklungspole und riiumliches Wirtschaftswachstum. J.C.B. Mohr, Tiibingen, 1973.
Cameron, G.C., 'Regional economic policy in the United Kingdom', in Sant (1974).
Cao-Pinna, V., 'Regional policy in Italy', in Hansen (1974).
Coates, B.E., R.J. Johnston and P.L. Knox, Geography and inequality. Oxford University Press,
1977.
Conroy, M.E., 'Rejection of growth center strategy in Latin American regional development
planning', Land Economics, Nov. 1973, 371-380.
Cumberland, J.H., Regional development experiences and prospects in the United States of
America. Mouton, Paris/The Hague, 1973.
Davin, L.E., 'The structural crisis of a regional economy. A case study: the Walloon Area', in
Robinson (1969).
Fox, K.A., Social indicators and social theory: elements of an operational system. John Wiley and
Sons, New York/London, 1974.
Friedly, Ph., National policy responses to urban growth. Lexington, Westmead, 1974.
Friedmann, J., 'The evolution of doctrine in regional development and planning. An American
view'. Series of seminars at the Interdisciplinary Institute of Urban and Regional Studies (UR),
Wirtschaftsuniversitat, Vienna, 1976.
Friedmann, J., 'Territory and function', Comparative Urbanization Studies, School of Architecture
and Urban Planning, University of California, Los Angeles, 1977.
REFERENCES 159
Since much of the argument of this paper implies that there may be no
universally acceptable definition of either aggregate efficiency or inter-
regional equity, it is proposed to elaborate these concepts as the analysis
proceeds rather than to start with strict definitions and to stand by them.
Hudson (1974) argues that there are three faces of equity: equality
of incomes, equal reward for effort, and the distributional impact of the
supply of public services. The first is the aim of an egalitarian society, the
second,. in its emphasis on equality of opportunity rather than on equality
of incomes, provides a rationale for the market economy (with all imper-
fections such as discrimination eliminated), while the third is an important
but disguised influence on equity in mixed economies. With regard to
public service supply, first impressions may be incorrect. For instance, it
may be wrong to designate the supply of a public service as progressive
merely because it is targeted towards the poor. It is also necessary to
examine who pays for it (possibly the taxpaying poor) and who obtains
the maximum benefit (probably the suppliers themselves rather than the
recipients). The suppliers may be a strong and effective interest group
(e.g. defence contractors) with a very clear knowledge about the value of
their own activities to them, while consumers may have no idea about
how they should value public goods.
A major problem with any discussion of interregional equity is the
extreme vagueness of the concept. First, most of the analyses use average
per capita incomes within a prescribed geographical area as the basic
indicator, then typically use measures of dispersion among regions or
ratios to present the state of interregional equity. 1
Suspicion about using income or gross product per capita data as an
index of welfare has always been strong, and is increasing. 2 Since the
interest in interregional equity is motivated by distributional concerns,
the analyst will not be indifferent to the intraregional distribution about
1. The problems arising from how to measure interregional equity can be illustrated
by a debate about the trade-off between national growth and interregional equity
in Japan. Fukuchi and Nobukini (1970), using a balanced growth model in which
all regions had the same linear homogeneous production function, argued that the
growth rate in the 1950s and early 1960s was much too high to allow progress in
interregional equity. However, Sakashita and Kamoike (1973) showed that the
Fukuchi-Nobukini model did not predict a trade-off if a relative variance of per
capita output was substituted for an absolute variance index. (This modification
is sensible, of course, since if per capita income doubled in every region, the
absolute variance index would become four times larger.) Instead, they suggested
that the lack of movement towards interregional income equalization in Japan was
due to regional differences in production functions.
2. See, for example, the concept of MEW (measure of economic welfare) per capita
developed by Nordhaus and Tobin (1972).
DEFINITIONAL PROBLEMS AND RELATED ISSUES 163
which the average income level says nothing. 3 Using Gini coefficients
sheds no light on the impact of policies on the 'target' lower income
groups. Reliance upon income criteria requires acceptance of the mone-
tary standard as an accurate reflector of relative social value. This is not
always acceptable, especially where there is a mix of public and private
goods. In other words, different components of regional income may have
implicit weights that do not match their relative monetary values. As an
example, $ 10 million spent on a.regional hospital may increase societal
welfare much more than the same dollar increase in industrial output.
Moreover, many variables influencing welfare are not reflected in
money incomes at all. For example, many social indicators such as educa-
tional achievement, health indices, welfare facility scores (e.g. patients
per doctor) and amenities fall into this category. There is no reason why
the distribution of these welfare measures among regions should be con-
sistent with the interregional distribution of income. In Canada, welfare
measures appear to converge more among regions than income measures
(Firestone 1974). This may be true of many developed countries, whereas
the converse may hold in developing countries. The advantage of welfare
disparities over income measures is that they often correct for income
distribution bias since they force a mass penetration approach (Le. a hori-
zontal rather than a vertical aid strategy). In other words, social indicator
scores can be high only by catering to the whole population, whereas
average incomes per capita may be boosted even via the most regressive
policies. Some analysts go further than the social indicators approach and
attempt to develop an aggregate quality of life (QOL) index for a region
(Liu 1975a; 1975b). In a study of United States regions, the two lowest
income regions (East and West South Central) also had the lowest QOL
scores. 4
3. Another weakness of the average per capita income measure was pointed out by
Alonso (1968, p. 10): 'It is perfectly possible for the per capita income of a
depressed region to drop, but for all individuals in it to be better off. The condi-
tions are that the depressed region be subject to diminishing returns and that the
higher-income members leave for other regions where their skills are better re-
warded. Since the region is, in a sense, overpopulated (diminishing returns), the
leaving of some raises the income of those who remain.'
4. The aggregate QOL index approach is questionable. There is a subjective element in
the perception of quality of life (e.g. an individual's attachment to an area) which
is difficult to measure. Also the analyst's value judgments are likely to distort the
index. For example, out of 100 variables Liu chose only two leisure indicators, one
of which was symphony orchestras (rather than, say, a team in a major sports
league).
164 AGGREGATE EFFICIENCY AND INTERREGIONAL EQUITY
5. This assumes that the region is larger than a city. Obviously, this statement is false
if a region is defined as a central city and then compared with a metropolitan area.
DEFINITIONAL PROBLEMS AND RELATED ISSUES 165
gressively (cf. the experience in some areas of the United States with
general revenue sharing).
Although efficiency is usually regarded as a much simpler concept,
there is a parallel argument for a broader view of 'efficiency' than output
maximization subject to given resource constraints that, if accepted, may
affect the efficiency-equity analysis. The rumblings about the inadequacy
of maximizing GNP (and GRP) as an efficiency criterion have been loud
in recent years. Consider for instance the problem of environmental
quality. The relocation of polluting industries from a densely populated
core region to an underdeveloped periphery may lower the rate of return
to capital if the new location is a high-cost site, but it may promote inter-
regional income convergence and it may be 'efficient' in a broader sense
in that the relocation may create substantial net social benefits. The
implication is that cost-benefit analysis is superior to output maximiza-
tion as an efficiency criterion. 6
In the developing world in general, and Asia in particular, another
paradigm of regional development is evolving which treats efficiency and
equity in quite a different way. Efficiency is defined in terms of satisfying
human needs rather than via the optimal allocation of a scarce resource
such as capital. The focus is not on generating new resources by capital
accumulation but on making the best use of existing resources, pre-
6. Unfortunately, this conclusion raises new problems. These are connected with the
well-known fact that cost-benefit analysis ignores the income distribution question.
Thus, in a traditional treatment the income equalization effects of a strategy would
have to be evaluated ex post rather than included as an intrinsic element in the cost-
benefit analysis. In fact, this issue has been the subject of a minor controversy.
Goldfarb and Woglom (1974) draw a distinction between the 'efficiency rule' and
a 'welfare rule'. The efficiency rule states that investment (and policy) decisions
should be based on pure efficiency grounds, leaving the question of income re-
distribution to fiscal transfers, assumed costless and instantaneous (Musgrave 1969).
Weisbrod (1968) and Sosnow (1974), on the other hand, argue that income
distribution gains are a benefit and should be explicitly included in the cost-benefit
analysis. Thus a welfare rule is needed to help select projects and strategies. The
justification for this position is that the political system and the institutional frame-
work impose severe constraints on the scope for and speed of direct income
redistribution. McGuire and Garn (1969) suggested a decision rule in which all
projects are evaluated by weighting benefit-cost ratios by a welfare index. Projects
are then selected by maximizing the sum of scores subject to a budget constraint.
A compromise between these conflicting standpoints might be to take account of
the redistributional context of each programme, policy and strategy in the alloca-
tion of the overall budget for spatial policies, but then to apply the efficiency rule
within each programme.
166 AGGREGATE EFFICIENCY AND INTERREGIONAL EQUITY
eminenjly human resources, at the local level. Equity becomes the domi-
nant element in regional planning by promoting a 'bottom-up' approach
in which the target group itself is mobilized to participate in the planning
process at all phases (identification of the problems and their priorities,
finding solutions and execution of projects). Equity criteria are satisfied
since the people themselves are not only involved in planning but are the
main recipients of its benefits, while efficiency is redefined so that it
almost coincides with equity. Thus, the trade-off problem is avoided.
This interesting idea, as yet imperfectly developed, raises certain
difficulties. It is easy to demonstrate its effectiveness in simple cases such
as when a health expert works out with local villagers the solution to a
polluted water supply. However, if the dominant objective is to make the
best use of existing resources, the implication is that material living
standards in rural areas will remain low, absolutely and relatively to urban
dwellers. Also, village participatory democracy may be tolerated so long
as its scope is confined to designing small-scale projects, but beyond a
certain level there is a contradiction between this idea and non-democratic
political structures that so often prevail at the national level. The assump-
tion that the existing elites will give up power rather than face the alterna-
tives of unrest and revolution may be unfounded. Furthermore, it is
insufficient to expound this approach without designing policy instruments
that can implement it. Finally, the revulsion against the dogma of maxi-
mum capital accumulation and discrimination in favour of highly capital-
intensive projects should not be allowed to lead to the equally false dogma
that capital has no role in economic, social and human development. Since
capital remains in short supply, its allocative efficiency remains important
if new allocation criteria are substituted for the old.
7. This statement refers to interregional equity. However, if low income migrants in-
crease their productivity by moving, spatial concentration is quite consistent with
an improvement in interpersonal equity. It is only fair to mention the alternative
view. Lasuen (1974) argues that the income convergence is only an apparition due
to arithmetic (additions to population here, reductions there), not economics.
More important, the critical impact of interregional migration is the dynamic
effects of selective migration on the economies of lagging regions.
168 AGGREGATE EFFICIENCY AND INTERREGIONAL EQUITY
8. In the first five years of the Appalachian Regional Commission, more than 60
percent of the programme's expenditures were for highways (Cumberland 1971,
96-97).
THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 169
9. A related argument is that governmental income transfers from rich to poor regions
may produce direct benefits for tax-donors in the wealthy areas through inter-
dependent utility functions. In other words, tax donors derive utility from the fact
that their revenues become public transfers equivalent to charitable donations
(Hochman and Rodgers 1973).
1O.The effects of outmigration on the region of origin may include: (1) the impact of
its selectivity in terms of age, education and skills on the composition of the popu-
lation (e.g. a higher dependency ratio); (2) a reduction in employment; (3) an
increase in wage levels; (4) the possibility of skill shortages in specific sectors; and
(5) the impact of population decline on the tax base, real estate values and the size
of local markets (Kabaya 1971).
11. These are the critical assumptions. Secondary assumptions include full employ-
ment, a single commodity, a fixed labour supply, no technical progress and zero
transport costs.
170 AGGREGATE EFFICIENCY AND INTERREGIONAL EQUITY
12.It should be obvious from the earlier discussion that these definitions are much too
simplistic. However, it is pedagogically convenient to use them here to illustrate the
concept of the trade-off function.
THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 171
least two reasons for this: many of the 'backward' regions of developed
countries have some growth potential because of their established infra-
structure, skilled labour pools and urban agglomeration economies; and in
such countries many industries are 'footloose' due to an extensive trans-
portation and communications network and relatively insignificant
locational cost differentials. Steering industries to the lagging regions may,
therefore, tend to be equity-promoting but efficiency-neutral. Situations
of this kind will be defined in this paper as effiency-equity compatible.
g
The above argument implies that the trade-off curve tells us nothing
about the policymaker's own trade-off. This requires specification of the
policymaker's preference function. The preference functions are a kind of
indifference curve with each point on anyone 'curve' representing iso-
utility combinations of growth rates and equity indices. The simplest
approach is to assume that policymakers correctly identify and intend to
implement society's preferences, and that society's preference substitu-
tions between growth and equity are linear. In this case, the preference
functions become a set of straight lines sloping downwards to the right.
The linearity assumption means that society prefers a constant improve-
ment in equity -fwm each one percent decline in the growth rate (needless
to say, this assumption is not critical to the analysis). The optimal choice
for society is to select the point on the 'objective' trade-off curve tt'
which is tangential to the highest preference function PF 1 • This implies
that the combination of gl and ZI is optimal for society. The steeper the
set of preference functions the more society is inclined to favour inter-
regional redistribution. A flat preference function, on the other hand,
implies a growth-oriented society unwilling to consider sacrifices in
national efficiency even for major interregional equity gains. In an equity-
oriented society, i.e. one with steep preference functions (e.g. PF2 ), it is
possible that the tangency point may be located on the section of the
trade-off curve corresponding to a negative growth rate.
The most systematic analysis of the relationship between aggregate
efficiency and interregional equity has been a theoretical and empirical
study of Japan by Mera (1975). The transition of an economy from an
underdeveloped to a developed state is accompanied by spatial polariza-
tion because, although there are diminishing returns to density in the
primary sector, there are increasing returns to density in secondary and
tertiary industries. Thus, the conflict between macro-efficiency and spatial
equity springs from the fact that income maximization requires a higher
degree of spatial concentration of economic sectors in space while income
equalization demands an even distribution of urban-oriented industries.
If direct income transfers are politically feasible (and if taxing the resi-
dents of the rich regions to finance such transfers does not damage their
productivity), the conflict can be avoided. If not, the spatial reallocation
of physical social capital (e.g. via a growth centre strategy) may be the
most appropriate instrument for promoting income equity in space.
As an exercise shedding light on the potential trade-off, Mera calculates
the efficiency loss of the reallocation of social capital to achieve income
THE WILLIAMSON CURVE 173
equalization among Japan's nine regions. In the short run income equaliza-
tion would involve sacrificing 30 percent of national output; in the longer
run when capital and labour can be treated as mobile between regions,13
the loss runs to 12 percent of output. Finally, Mera demonstrates
theoretically that in a two-region system without mobility of labour the
transfer of investment resources in the form of a lump-sum subsidy from
the rich to the poor region may not be harmful to efficiency within a
certain range, i.e. the transfer should not be so large as to throw the
subsidized region off its optimal path of capital accumulation.
13.In particular, the migration of popUlation will tend both to improve the distribu-
tion of income (by narrowing wage differentials) and raise aggregate efficiency in
production (if factor mobility is interpreted as a search for higher returns).
174 AGGREGATE EFFICIENCY AND INTERREGIONAL EQUITY
14.Spontaneous diffusion (and equalizing) forces in the United States have two
dimensions: shifts in locational advantages attracting industries out of the North-
east to the South and the Southwest; changes in household preferences and life-
styles resulting in a decentralization of popUlation out of the large cities into
smaller towns and rural areas in the intermetropolitan periphery (counterurbaniza-
tion; see Berry 1976).
THE WILLIAMSON CURVE 175
mobile external economies, lower wages, and the pull of amenities (e.g.
climate, recreational resources), may favour the less developed regions in
the location decisions of new and the relocation decisions of existing
firms. If export markets are volatile and very competitive, the exploitation
of the resources and demand potential of the lagging regions may offer a
more stable means of maintaining, or raising, the national growth rate.
Finally, the agglomeration economies that were responsible for the earlier
development of the core regions may begin to dissipate because of 'con-
gestion' costs such as rising land values, soaring labour costs and environ-
mental deterioration and symptoms of senescence such as obsolete
plants, a decline in entrepreneurial and managerial talent and debilitation
of the profit motive.
Since many of these arguments are speCUlative and the related hypo-
theses are untested, while the empirical base remains weak, the Williamson
curve remains a tantalizing question mark. For example, there has been no
discussion of how much inequality can be expected in the divergence
phase. In other words, is the curve very steep or almost flat?15 The pre-
diction that developing countries will eventually enter the convergence
phase implicitly assumes that they will become developed to levels com-
parable with those of the advanced industrial countries. This is by no
means self-evident. Also, the regional disparities exhibited by the develop-
ing countries are far wider than those of the developed countries at the
time of their maximum divergence. Of the many possible reasons for this
fact, the restriction of externally-induced growth (e.g. by multinationals
and earlier by colonialist powers) to the core regions is among the most
compelling. Finally, to use the Williamson curve to shed light on the
efficiency-equity trade-off and its possible non-existence, it would be
necessary to be able to separate out the regional policy effect from the
'spontaneous dispersion' effect. The difficulties in isolating regional policy
impacts by comparing 'actual' and 'expected' performance are notorious
(Moore and Rhodes 1973, 1976).
IS. Parr (1976) raised the question of whether there was any systematic variation
among countries in the height and base length of the curve. Noone has attempted
to answer it.
176 AGGREGATE EFFICIENCY AND INTERREGIONAL EQUITY
There are a few other cases, apart from those illustrating the Williamson
hypothesis, that may be efficiency-equity compatible, thus avoiding the
trade-off. One was mentioned earlier (Section 7.2.2); the possibility that
in certain developed countries the combination of footloose industries
and an almost ubiquitous infrastructure and adaptable labour force may
allow policymakers to promote the poorer regions without any loss in
efficiency. A more subtle example, advanced by Higgins (1973, 1975), is
that narrow regional disparities are a precondition for avoiding rampant
inflation. He argues that Phillips' curves in countries with small regional
gaps are lower and to the left of the curves in countries where regional
disparities are wide. The explanation is in terms of differential labour
market pressure and the 'price-setting' characteristics of firms in the
developed regions. The point is that labour markets are regional rather
than national, especially in the high disparity countries, whereas price
increases diffuse very quickly throughout the national economy. This
argument is suggestive rather than convincing. A contrary view is that
because of massive interregional leakages, strong action to develop the
backward regions might even accelerate inflation by stimulating demand
for the capital goods of the core regions. Even before there are direct
empirical tests of these hypotheses, however, price stability should
be considered as an element in efficiency in addition to more obvious
criteria such as maximizing GNP.
The existence of space implies frictions on mobility. If resources are
underutilized in less developed regions (e.g. the evidence of low labour
participation rates) but are immobile, it may be more efficient to invest in
such areas to boost growth, and incidentally to raise incomes, than to
leave the outcome to the imperfections of the market. This important
point was made by Borts and Stein (1964) when they argued that the
appropriate rate of return in such a case is the gross, not the net, marginal
product of capital, since the value of immobile and unemployed labour
would otherwise be close to zero.
Yet another instance of efficiency-equity compatibility may arise
under certain assumptions about the existence of externalities. This
implies yet again that efficiency should be measured in terms of the social
rather than private rates of return. It is not difficult to outline a scenario
with externalities of the kind fitting the efficiency-equity compatibility
case. For instance, if the relocation of industry from advanced to lagging
EQUITY IMPACTS OF REGIONAL POLICIES 177
regions dampens rising congestion costs at the core and builds up the
industrial base of the periphery enough to ensure its future growth poten-
tial, these dynamic social efficiency gains might easily outweigh any loss
in profitability measured by market criteria.
Furthermore, examples of efficiency-equity compatibility might be
based on the hypotheses that the marginal capital-output ratio is lower
in poor regions (implying a higher marginal productivity of investment)
and/or the exhaustion of agglomeration economies of the core region
(with the probable implication of an optimal urban size). In fact, neither
argument is convincing. The marginal capital-output ratio is higher in
lagging regions because of their poverty of infrastructure, absence of
external economies and location disadvantages. The concept of an optimal
city size is based on assertion and value judgment and is virtually untest-
able (Richardson 1973b).
REFERENCES
Alcaide Inchausti, J., La Distribucfon de la Riqueza y de la Renta en la Sociedad Espanola: Balance
de Tres Planes de Des/mollo. Madrid, 1974 (mimeographed).
Alonso, W., Equity and its relation to efficiency in urbanization. Center for Planning and Develop-
ment Research, University of California, WP 78, Berkeley, 1968.
Berry, B.J.L., The counter-urbanization process; how general? International Institute for Applied
Systems Analysis Conference, Schloss Laxenburg, Austria, 1976.
Borts, G.H. and J.L. Stein, Economic growth in a/ree market. Columbia University Press, New
York,1964.
Boventer, E.G. von, 'Regional growth theory', Urban Studies, vol. 12,1-29,1975.
Cumberland, J .H., Regional development: experiences and prospects in the United States of
America. Mouton, The Hague,1971.
Firestone, O.J., 'Regional economic and social disparity', 205-267, in O.J. Firestone (ed.), Regional
economic development. University of Ottawa Press, 1974.
Fukuchi, T. and M. Nobukini, 'An econometric analysis of national growth and regional income
inequality ',In ternational Economic Review, vol. 11,84-100,1970.
Gilbert, A.G. and D.E. Goodman, 'Regional income disparities and economic development: a cri-
tique', 113-141, in A.G. Gilbert (ed.), Development planning and spatiJZI structure. Wiley, New
York,1976.
Goldfarb, R.S. and G. Woglom, 'Government investment decisions and institutional constraints on
income redistribution',Journal of Public Economics, vol. 3, 171-180, 1974.
Hansen, N.M., Locational preferences, migration and regional growth. Praeger, New York, 1973.
Haworth, C.T., D.W. Rasmussen and J.E. Long, 'Income redistnoution effects of urban population
growth', Department of Economics, Florida State University, Tallahassee, 1975 (mimeo-
graphed).
Higgins, B., 'Trade-off curves and regional gaps', 152-177, in J. Bhagwati and R.S. Eckaus (eds.),
Development and planning: essays in honor of Paul Rosenstein Roden. Allen and Unwin, 1973.
Higgins, B., 'Trade-off curves, trends and regional disparities: the case of Quebec', Economie
Appliquee, vol. 28, 331-360,1975.
REFERENCES 183
Hochman, H.M. and J.D. Rodgers, 'Utility interdependence and income transfers through charity',
63-77, in K.E. Boulding, M. Pfaff and A. Pfaff (eds.), Transfers in an urbanized economy. Wads-
worth, Belmont, 1973.
Hudson, B.M., 'The three faces of equity', School of Architecture and Urban Planning, University
of California at Los Angeles, DP 47,1974.
Kabaya, R., 'Development of poor regions: general considerations and the case of Japan', Institute
of Urban and Regional Development, University of California, WP 159, Berkeley, 1971.
Kolm, S.C., Justice et Equiti. Edition du Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique, Paris,
1972.
Lasuen, J.R., 'Spain's regional growth', in N.M. Hansen (ed.), Public policy and regional develop-
ment. Ballinger, Cambridge, Mass., 1974.
Leira, J., 'Growth poles in Spain: a legitimizing instrument for an efficiency-oriented policy',
University of California at Berkeley, 1973 (mimeographed).
Liu, B.C., 'Differential net migration and the quality of life', Review of Economics and Statistics,
vol. 57, 329-337, 1975a.
Liu, B.C., 'Quality of life: concept, measure and results', American Journal of Economics and
Sociology, vol. 34, 1-13, 197 5b.
McGuire, M.C. and H.A. Gam, 'The integration of equity and efficiency criteria in public project
selection', Economic Journal, vol. 79, 883-893, 1969.
Mera, K.,!ncome distribution and regional development. University of Tokyo Press, 1975.
Metwally, M.M. and RC:Jensen, 'A note on the measurement of regional income dispersion',
Economic development and cultural change, vol. 22, 135-136, 1973.
Moore, B.C. and J. Rhodes, 'Evaluating the effects of Britain's regional economic policy', Econo-
mic Journal, vol. 83, 87-100,1973.
Musgrave, R., 'Cost-benefit analysis and the theory of public finance', Journal of Economic Litera·
ture, vol. 7,443-444, 1969.
Nordhaus, W.D. and J. Tobin, 'Is growth obsolete?', 4-17 in National Bureau of Economic Re-
search,Economic growth, 50th Anniversary Colloquium, vol. 5, New York, 1972.
Parr, J.B., 'Welfare differences within a nation: a comment ,Papers, Regional Science Association,
vol. 32, 83-91, 1976.
Rhodes, J. and B.C. Moore, 'Regional economic policy and the movement of manufacturing firms
to development areas', Economica, vol. 43,17-31,1976.
Richardson, H.W., Regional growth theory. Macmillan, London, 1973a.
Richardson, H.W., The economics of urban size. Saxon House, Farnborough, Harts, 1973b.
Richardson, H.W., 'Growth pole spillovers: the dynamics of backwash and spread', Regional
Studies, vol. 10,1-9,1976.
Sakashita, N. and O. Kamoike, 'National growth and regional income inequities: a consistent
model',!nternational Economic Review, vol. 14,372-382,1973.
Sosnow, N.D., 'Optimal policies for income redistribution', Journal of Public Economics, vol. 3,
156-169,1974.
United Nations, 'Population and equality',Development Forum, vol. 5, no. 1, p. 5,1977.
Weisbrod, 'Income distribution effects and benefit cost analysis', 177-222 in S.B. Chase (ed.),
Problems in public expenditure analysis. Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., 1968.
Whitman, M. von N., 'Place prosperity and people prosperity: the delineation of optimum policy
areas', 359-393, in M. Perlman, C.L. Leven and B Chinitz (eds.), Spatial, regional and popula·
tion economics; essays in honor of Edgar M. Hoover. Gordon and Breach, New York, 1972.
Williamson, J.G., 'Regional inequalities and the process of national development', Economic
Development and Cultural Change, vol. 13,3-45,1965.
Winnick, L., 'Place prosperity vs people prosperity: welfare considerations in the geographic re-
distribution of economic activity', 273-283, in Real Estate Research Program, Essays in urban
land economics in honor of Leo Grebler. University of California, Los Angeles, 1966.
8. Capital, labour and the regions: Aspects
of economic, social and political inequality
in regional theory and policy
STUART HOLLAND*
Labour Capital
(Investment)
Labour Capital
(Savings)
the LDRs). This was the case for both relatively capitai intensive invest-
ment, and for the lower paid and relatively insecure (seasonal) jobs in con-
struction .and services. This pattern could be seen in immigration to
countries such as France of workers from Spain, Portugal and Algeria,
and in the case of Germany of workers from Greece, Yugoslavia and
Turkey (cf. Castels and Kosack 1973, part II; see also Section 5.3).
\
\
\
J
I Capital
I (Savings)
J
/
""
Capital
(Investment)
In such cases, regions such as western and southern France were relatively
neglected both by French domestic capital, and by foreign multinationals
locating in France (D.A.T. 1974, Table 6). In the Italian case, domestic
capital such as Fiat, with minor exceptions, located increasingly in Latin
America rather than the Mezzogiorno, while most foreign multinational
capital locating in what is nominally southern Italy did so in the northern-
most belt close to either Rome or Napels (Benetti et al. 1975, Table 1).
In the West German case, relatively full employment levels and the relative
190 CAPITAL, LABOUR AND THE REGIONS
There are exceptions to these patterns, such as the recent highly publi-
cised decision by Ford (UK) to locate a new engine plant in South Wales.
But such ventures tend to be either in operations which employ relatively
capital widening and deepening investment, or to represent incidents in
the frontier relations between big business and the state. In other words,
where there is a danger that the state under public pressure might inter-
vene against other aspects of a multinational's activity, such as the
increased intra-company imports of components and finished vehicles
from abroad by Ford to the UK, big business will tend to be sensitive to
the public relations advantage of visible gestures by which they appear to
be cooperating significantly with the public interest in regional develop-
ment.
Certainly, the broad evidence from the post-war period in economies
such as those of Britain, France and Italy shows that big business is hardly
influenced in its routine location decisions in more developed countries by
the incentives on either the capital or labour account offered by govern-
ments (cf. H.C.E.H. 1972 and 1974). Nor are they significantly influenced
by the assumed advantages of the spatial clustering of interrelated activity,
as will be shown below. Both factors are critically important granted the
extent to which (1) state intervention and regional policy is based on such
instruments, complemented by infrastructure provision, in countries
such as Britain, France and Italy; (2) big business and the multinational
sector now dominates half or more of manufacturing output and employ-
ment in such countries (cf. EEC commission 1976c).
costs per
unit
24 r-------~~~I---------------------
_________ I LAC 1
20
12r-------------r-~~----~~----~---
_________ .1 ___ _
10 I MDC cost
I
6 ---------1------------ LDC cost
I
I
&.-._ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _........._ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _..1.-_ _ _ _ _ production
x y volume
the transport cost from more dispersed location. Granted relative limits to
production economies of scale, it appears from a wide range of evidence
that such economies from scale have widely outstripped shrinking trans-
port costs anyway.
But, in addition, and especially since the early 1960s, big business has
increasingly gone multinational on the lines previously described. This has
introduced an entirely new dimension to the issue of proximate versus dis-
tant location. For instance, in a case where labour costs equal half the total
production costs in manufacturing (which is not untypical), the use of
labour in a Third World labour haven where its cost is a fifth of that in a
more developed country would mean a reduction of labour cost (in terms
of Figure 4) from 5 to 1. Assuming unchanged capital costs, this would
reduce the overall cost of production at y from 10 to 6. In other words,
it would mean a cost reduction of 40 percent, and a total unit cost of
only 6.
Such a reduction of costs will massively outstrip normal transport costs
arising from a more distant location, even when the distance concerned
involves circumnavigation of the globe. It is illustrated in the case of a
high value-low weight product such as watches by the fact that the Bulova
company produces components in Switzerland, flies them to the Philip-
pines for assembly by low-cost labour, and then flies them back to the
United States for final sale (Barnett and Muller 1975, Chapter 11). It is
illustrated in general by the phenomenon of the 'run-away' labour
intensive industries of footwear, clothing, electrical goods, electronics and
now increasingly mechanical engineering to the South East Asian and
Latin America countries already cited.
If such factors completely outdate the proximity case of growth centre
or growth pole policy for the leading enterprises in developed economies,
they also undermine the basis of conventional incentives policies, at least
for the relatively labour intensive firms which governments want to attract
to less developed regions (H.C.E.C. 1974).
a
24 ~--------~~--------------~-----
I
20 -------------------i
I
I
meso I
I
______ J_
10
production
~------------------------------L---~-----volume
24 ~----------~~----~------~-%~----Pl
20
LDC
10
production
~----------------------------~--~-------vo1ume
need to represent more than fifteen times the cost of the capital
concerned, rather than the fifth at present offered.
Of course this is only a comparative cost illustration. Other factors
enter into the. calculus of multinational companies in their location deci-
sions, including not only public relations with governments, but also the
need to locate some plant in MDCs if governments are to award them
contracts from public expenditure, plus the not negligible tendency to
greater 'political stability' in MDCs and the lower threat - at least until
recently - from nationalisation of relatively capital intensive plants.
Nonetheless, allowing for even a wide margin of error in individual cases,
the argument illustrates some of the reasons why firms in the meso-
economic multinational sector can gain more from either raising prices or
going multinational - or both - rather than going multi-regional within
one country in response to regional incentives.
time. This is basically because technology does not stand still. Investment
today in a major plant using today's techniques of production could leave
a company five years' behind technologically if competitors only choose
to invest in new capacity half a decade from now with the production
techniques of the early 1980s.
Apart from this, the current crisis of capital accumulation is not simply
post-OPEC. Its specific form clearly is due substantially to the defla-
tionary policies imposed by the oil- and commodity-consuming developed
countries following the rise in commodity and oil prices in the 1970s. But
the underlying symptoms of crisis, at least in Western Europe, as already
indicated, were evident earlier. In West Germany, to take the example of
the key fast accumulator of capital in the 1950s, gross domestic fixed
capital formation fell from a high of 9 percent a year from 1950-54 to
6 percent in 1960-64 and less than 1 percent (in fact 0.2 percent) in
1970-74 (Zinn, forthcoming). In a stop-go economy such as Britain's,
capital accumulation in industry had lagged behind the Continent for
twenty years after 1950, but its level today, in 1977, is actually lower
than in 1970. In Italy the crisis of capital accumulation was first registered
in 1963-64, and then intensified from 1968. France alone managed a
sustained rate of growth of output into the 1970s but with increasing
investment crisis.
In these circumstances, governments increasingly tried to sustain
investment by offering capital incentives, irrespective of the location
concerned. The efforts were relatively futile. This stemmed partly from
the Keynesian pall in macro-economic policy-making, whereby govern-
ments tended to treat investment decline as a short term rather than
longer term structural problem. They were neglecting Marxist analysis
of trends to rising organic composition of capital, disproportion between
productive and unproductive sectors and under-consumption, partly
because they thought that Keynes had made Marx redundant. It is
perhaps more surprising that they did not even take account of Schum-
peter on the bunching of innovations and their spread effects, with the
implicit lesson that consumer booms of the postwar kind tend to be
followed by relative consumer saturation. Most surprisingly, they tended
to neglect Keynes' own crucial argument that investment performance
depends on profit expectations which themselves depend on expectations
of future demand rather than costs.
The result was a continual upgrading of incentives in the form of tax
rebates and write-offs - depreciation allowances, investment grants, Rand
200 CAPIT AL, LABOUR AND THE REGIONS
D write-offs against tax and later tax relief measures to offset rising
commodity costs. Figures on the total effect of such subsidies are difficult
to come by. In Britain in February 1974 the incoming Industry Minister
found that it took nearly a year for his officials to calculate just how
much public money had been rebated to the top twenty-five companies
from various sources in recent years. However, if the one measure of tax
relief on stock appreciation alone (totalling nearly £4 billion since its
introduction in 1975) is added to previous estimates of the difference
between effective and nominal corporation tax, it emerges that British big
business in the sector of £50 million turnover or more per year is probably
paying no net tax overall. 1
In such circumstances, it is hardly surprising that there is some force to
the previous claim that even major incentives will not promote new
regional initiatives. In Britain, in the meso-economic sector, even 100
percent tax write-offs are not exerting an effect in promoting net invest-
ment. However, what does emerge from the British case is the extent to
which the primary concern of the state with capital accumulation and the
measures which it has vainly taken to try to promote it to higher levels,
have been undertaken at the cost of the regional incentives programme
and in substantial contradiction to it.
This is quite apart from the tendency for big business during recession
to compensate for fallen sales by raising prices, thereby maintaining cash
flow. Such compensatory upward pressure on prices reinforces the price-
making mechanism outlined in Figure 6 and further decreases any pull
effect from regional incentives.
In these senses, the current regional crisis, and the crisis in regional
policy, is part of a wider economic and ideological crisis in the mature
capitalist economies.
Essentially, regional policies based on incentives assume relatively
normal profits between enterprise and within industries, via the com-
petitive process. Without competitive pricing, monopoly prices and
1. Before 1974, Mervyn King (1973) calculated that the cumulative effect of capital
grants, investment allowances and employment premia had amounted to the
equivalent of half the total company taxation. Add to this (1) the fact that by 1977
the British government had rebated nearly £4 billion in additional tax concession
through relief on stock appreciation; (2) also taking account of the analysis of
Geoffrey Wood (1973) that big business gains a disproportionate share of tax relief
through greater efficiency in internal adjustment and claims; plus (3) the fact that
the big league can understate taxable inco:me through under-stating real profits via
transfer pricing (Holland 1975, Chapter 2).
POWER STRUCTURE AND REGIONAL POLICY 201
Neither political life nor the state are quite like that. For one thing, the
pluralist model assumes a degree of rationality in decision-making and the
exercise of power which is notably lacking in too much policy-making
(or the response to events which frequently passes for policy). In other
words, it assumes not only competition for power between parties
representing individual interests (paralleling economic competition
between individual units), but also a responsiveness of the system to
individual ideas or sets of ideas in the form of policies proposed either by
pressure groups or parties, especially when the ideas are those of the
party forming the government. In short, the system is supposed to be
rational.
However, in reality, the political process in the sense of what happens
at the level of the ballot and political institutions does not dominate the
apparatus of the state and the exercise of state power. Nor are capital
and labour relatively balanced pressure groups within society in the
manner hypothesised in the pluralist model and represented in Figure 7.
In practice, the situation is much closer to that represented in Figure 8.
POWER STRUCTURE AND REGIONAL POLICY 205
8 I
I
State
Ideology
Capital
all these decisions to capital, despite the fact that they affect the nature
of production, investment, counter-cyclical policies, export and import
trade, innovation, prices and employment, as well as location. This is not
to say that the state does not try to influence the behaviour of firms, and
thus these macro-economic aggregates. Such attempts at influence are the
substance of economic policy. But the policy framework is almost
exclusively by indirect rather than direct measures, and intended to
influence rather than control - tax changes on consumption, investment
incentives, interest rate changes, and changes in the money supply,
exchange rate changes, Rand D under-writing, price ceiling targets and
employment subsidies.
related industry, it would arise from the case for a balanced and related
job structure in an area of high unemployment rather than from a need
for the proximate location of interrelated firms to gain from assumed
locational economies.
The political pluralism of such planning could actually be ensured in
part through the regionalisation of both planning itself and the new public
enterprise in manufacturing which would be necessary to ensure that the
public authorities disposed of direct means to fulfill national or regional
planning targets. The case for such an extension of public enterprise has
been argued elsewhere (Holland 1972 and 1975). Its rationale as a direct
instrument for intervention, as opposed to indirect measures such as
incentives and designated growth poles dependent on the free working of
the market, will be evident from the previous argument.
If such an extension of the public sector to ensure means for direct
intervention amounted to a re-mix in the present distribution of public
and private ownership in the developed economies, account should be
taken of the fact that at present public enterprise not only contributes on
average less than 15 percent of GDP, but also is mainly concentrated in
regionally immobile basic industry and services. In other words, the activi-
ties which have been nationalised to date, at least in Western Europe,
concern mainly mining and oil (which are geologically tied) or power
generation and distribution, transport and communications (which are
geographically tied). Despite nationalisation in some countries of all
or part of the steel and motor industries, the bulk of manufacturing
remains in private hands.
For such reasons, both in quantitative and qualitative terms, a re-
mix of the economy involving a significant extension of public enterprise
into the regionally mobile sector of manufacturing would not mean an
end to the mixed economy of the conventional wisdom, but a closer
approach to a more evenly mixed system rather than the unequal mix
represented by the contrast between public expenditure and the contribu-
tion to GDP of public enterprise.
In some cases, if an effective integration of the national and regional
economy is to be assured through planning, particular public enterprise
agencies would need to be primarily national in character. This is the
general case for state holding companies, even though these could and
probably should have related regionally-based subsidiaries. In other
cases, there is a strong argument to be made for regional public enter-
prise, and also municipal or borough enterprise, responsible to regional
SOCIALISATION AND CHANGE 213
the professional classes may not need a third automobile and television
or a second refrigerator and deep freeze, many working-class people would
be glad to gain their first of at least some such items. (Not that this would
benefit national employment while the goods at present are produced in
Third World labour and tax havens.)
This chapter is about the Integrated Structure Plan for the Northern
Netherlands (hereafter called ISP) as an example of integrated regional
planning.
In order to prepare the ground for a critical examination, we need:
a. some background information on ISP (provided in Section 2),
b. a framework for judging its creation and its products (outlined in
Section 3).
As a framework we have chosen the strategic choice approach, a particular
design of a planning cycle and pursuit of its stages (based on both
theoretical reasoning and practical experience).
In Section 4, we then confront ISP with strategic choice stepwise: from
problem formulation to monitoring and review, including information on,
recent ISP developments. At the end of this section an attempt is made to
summarize 'why integrated planning has failed (so far)'.
Finally, by way of evaluation, we try to link the analysis of ISP and its
results with the general theme of spatial inequalities, regional development
and regional science (Section 5).
Note that this chapter is not written by a participant observer of ISP,
but rather by an interested, though not 'innocent', bystander who had to
rely for data mainly on published sources, e.g. progress reports presented by
the Minister of Economic Affairs to the Dutch parliament and published
reports through which an interested public has been informed about
research results and policy conclusions.
The idea of preparing ISP was launced in a report dealing with the devel-
opment of the northern part of the Netherlands back in 1972. While the
northern part usually covers the provinces of Groningen, Friesland and
Drenthe, it was extended in this report to include similar problem areas in
northeastern and northwestern Overijssel, the latter being classified as an
eastern province. The total plan area corresponds to the shaded map area
of Figure 1.
LEGEND: PROVINCES
GR = Groningen
FR = Friesland
DR = Drenthe
o = Overijssel
G cc Gelderland
U = Utrecht
NH = Noord·Holland
ZH = Zuid-Holland
Z = Zeeland
NB = Noord-Brabant
L = Limburg
WEST
..
NB ..
:_. . ;<>. . /t·<
: .. ) ............... ....
...........
/ (:~.'
~.... : ..••.:
SOUTH WEST
.-'
MAASTRICHTC¥ /
f...············:-
-- I I I ------,-------.~I -- ~ -
1/5 3115 31/8
t 30/4
~
------~
Report on the Progress reporr---
----------~ Progress
------------------ Progress -- Progress Progress Report on
northern part number 1 report report report report socio-economic
of the country number 2 number 3 number 4 number 5 policy for the
nort hern part
of the country
A course in strategic choice, even a short one, goes beyond the scope of
this contribution. All we need, at any rate, is some kind of a checklist cap-
able of being used as a framework for judging ISP. More detailed informa-
tion on the strategic choice approach and the closely related technique of
AIDA (Analysis of Interconnected Decisions Areas) is provided by Friend
and Jessop (1969) who first developed this approach and, e.g., by Hickling
(1974), Friend et al. (1974), Bather et al. (1975,1976).
9.2.1 A checklist
Our checklist will be described in terms of phases in the planning process
and prominent features of each phase. We shall also indicate our motives
for choosing this particular framework. In describing the checklist we are
Working parties Additional research Products
Integrative Facet-planning Others Pu blished reports and
others
Progress report 1 continues 2 continues 7 continues 10 con tinues 7 ISP 8 (1975) (final report)
number 4 3 continues 8 continues 11 continues Inauguration departmental
4 continues 12 popUlation commission for ISP
development
Northern sub-regions
13 Regionalization Formation ofa
national multi-year socioeconomic
financial budget policy group
Progress report 1 continues 2 continues 10 continues 2 ISP 9a (1976)
number 5 4 continues 11 continues (part 1: economic
sectors)
ISP 9b (1976)
(part 2: provinces)
4 ISP 10 (1976)
Formation of a socio-
cultural policy group
Report on socio-
economic policy for
Northern part (1976):
'policy report'
Given its rather complex task, a critical evaluation of ISP should also
cover the way complexity has been handled. The strategic choice
approach emphasizes the interrelatedness o/issues. To manage complexity
it proceeds through progressive reformulation. This implies a cyclic
instead of a linear-deductive planning process (Figure 4).
2 generation of alternatives
I 1
3 evaluation of alternatives and
choice of action
\ f
I b
I I b
I
/' ~ /t ~
c c c
II c
II c
t t t t t
d d d
II d
II d
t t ~ t ~
e e e
II e
II e
a Prime objective
d Instruments
e Activities
1
Industry Services
(e.g. effectiveness (such as retail function
present poliCY in rural areas)
Instruments)
Economic development 1
SOCIO -cultural development 2
Spatial development 3
General problems 4
a Compare Figure 1.
b Including Southern Ysselmeerpolders.
c Migration according to trend.
d Zero net-migration.
e Annual net-migration 4,000.
f Net-migration rate 1% per annum.
Source: ISP 8, 1975, p. 4-based on the Third report on physical planning in the Netherlands,
part one (1974).
Netherlands, part one, 1974, part two a, 1976, part two d, 1977; Drewe
1977a). These uncertainties mainly pertain to the long run. As to 1980,
they are far less important compared to those attached to future em-
ployment.
Second, 'The Hague' and 'the North' may propose different courses of
action. A sketch of regionalized development per sector at the national
level does not necessarily coincide with a sketch per facet from a Northern
point of view. Instead of settling for an 'early compromise', divergence of
views could also be translated into alternatives.
Third, 'the Hague' is, of course, concerned about maintaining a national
balance in interregional development (see also Friedmann 1972). This fact
may also account for differences of view between 'nation' and 'region'.
Excluding external migration, population (re)distribution turns into a
zero-sum problem, i.e. there can be no 'winners' without 'losers' (Drewe
1977b). But even if the reduction of unemployment does not present
itself as a 'zero-sum problem', the labour market situation in the rest
of the country (including repercussions of policy intervention in the
North and elsewhere) may give rise to meaningful alternatives.
What we have said about potential fields of searching for alternatives
refers to broad alternatives only. But the ISP work also provides entries
into more detailed alternatives, especially when an attempt is made to
derme policy options per decision area.
Given the overriding priority of dealing with relative socioeconomic
underdevelopment of the North, scenarios of labour market develop-
ment are called for, somewhere along the line of what the working
parties on socioeconomic development and population aspects already
have produced. Once the assumption of 'no policy change' is relaxed,
various meaningful alternative futures open up.
Table 3. Testing four models of regional population distribution against eight criteria:
summary of the results.
Figure 8 leaves no doubt about what facet 'is to be master'. Except for
some policy recommendations related to physical planning and natural
environment (Figure 8, headings 3 and 5.6), the task of making an inte-
grated structure plan is far from being completed. It is not altogether
abandoned either, but the report does not indicate how to achieve
integration. Although a commitment to 'progressive reformulation' is
revealed, it is rather limited to sub-regional and sectoral differentiation
of economic policy instead.
As the policy report sticks to the 'initial focus' of relative economic
backwardness, and, as no alternative solutions have been generated, this
report hardly gives a full policy context.
Elements and functions of the policy statement. The forty-one policy
recommendations are mainly addressed to central government. As to their
implementation one is, therefore, referred to a national Report on
regional socioeconomic policy (Minister van Economische Zaken 1977,
pp. 98-102). It has been suggested that the content of policy statements
asking 'how much?', 'of what type?', 'when?', 'where?' and 'who will
benefit and who will lose?' should be examined. The policy report, how-
ever, contains only few specific statements. The target has been quantified
(the famous 20,000 jobs to be created), and the target year (1980) has
been fixed. Statements about locations are deferred to follow-up planning.
There is a strong emphasis on 'quality' in most of the recommendations.
But the question of 'who will benefit and who will lose?' has not been
discussed at all. Considering the wording of the policy statements, one
notices a striking difference between, on the one hand, the specificity of
the employment target and the ambiguity of most of the policy
recommendations on the other. An indicative figure would fit the policy
proposals much better than a target. The target may quickly be outdated
while the proposed means, allowing for a large amount of discretion,
might also easily be contested unless they are at least defmed.
Reasoned justification for the policy. This part of policy design covers
policy effectiveness, consistency with other policies, and explanation of
policy statements linked to technical work.
Assessing policy effectiveness means checking the feasibility of alterna-
tive solutions prior to the choice of a certain course of action, the assess-
ment based on past experience with policy instruments as well as on
impact prediction. We should not expect this to be a strong point of the
policy report, given our above-mentioned diagnosis. The working par-
ties charged with a systematic inventory and with public participation
242 INTEGRATED REGIONAL PLANNING: THE NETHERLANDS
PART A PARTB
Development sketch Regional development planning
(substantial aspects of sociocultural (administrative and organizational side
development) of social welfare policy)
Policy recommendations per sector: Planning concept covering:
1. education 1. basic principles of social planning
2. labour 2. participants
3. health (care) 3. coordination and cyclic process
4. social work 4. policy proposals
5. art and culture
6. housing
7. leisure, sport and recreation
8. public transport (appendix)
Monitoring and review. ISP has not yet reached this stage. But our critical
examination of policy design and the preceding phases show that it is ill-
prepared for it. Among the missing essentials to be monitored are, e.g.:
ISP: ITS CREATION AND PRODUCTS 245
search side. Note that the working party on integrated planning has
presented its final report (ISP 11 a, 1977) as a comprehensive analysis
of development. Given our present state of knowledge and technique,
such an attempt to analyze the way in which 'everything depends on
everything else' is doomed to failure. It certainly neglects the pragmatic,
problem-solving character of plan-making which 'only' requires a selective,
though adapted analysis, implying a selective use of analytical techniques.
As important changes in the planning environment have occurred, ISP
met with a crisis - some time between September 1976 and May 1977
(as documented in Progress report number 4). ISP, which had been
primarily geared into plan-making for the long range, suddenly had to take
into account the economic crisis of the 1970s as well as counteracting
government measures. As a result the original 'comprehensive' approach
has been replaced by a short-cut with special emphasis on the relative
socioeconomic backwardness of the North. This step, which on the one
hand, has brought ISP nearer to commitment, on the other hand also
seems to have provoked the abortion of integrated planning. The Report
on socioeconomic policy for the Northern part, the formation of separate
policy groups and the aftermath (described in Section 9.3.2) testify to
this. Surprising changes in the planning environment are quite normal in
planning practice, especially when it takes several years to prepare a plan.
However, allowing these changes to upset your planning approach in such
a way as to lose its reason for being (reducing 'ISP' to 'SP' so to speak)
once again points to serious shortcomings in the planning of the planning.
solved (lSP 5, 1975), there was really no need to start from scratch.
More time should have been spent on investigating the feasibilty of
policy proposals (the effectiveness of policy instruments) instead. Some
of the instruments have been applied for quite some time now (Cremers
1976). The probable impact of newly proposed policy instruments could
at least have been explored or subjected to experimentation. But a feasi-
bility test prior to the choice of action does not seem to be a standard
operating procedure in Dutch planning. The choice of a policy course
almost always precedes a listing of instruments whose effectiveness
seems often to be taken for granted. This practice surely does not stimul-
ate the assessment of policy effectiveness. The 'state-of-the-art' is reflected
in the 'Report on regional socioeconomic policy 1977-1980' (1977, pp.
29-37) dealing with investment subsidies, improvement of infrastructure,
selective investment policy, migration subsidies and relief work. The
gloomier the outcome of a feasibility test, the more pressing the need for
a more direct state intervention (Holland 1976). The latter may imply a
more or less gradual change of the existing socioeconomic order (see
also Chapter 8).
To propagate the target of ceating 20,000 jobs by 1980, hoping that
it turns into a self-fulfilling prophecy (Policy report, p. 28), can hardly
be a substitute for a proper feasibility test. Good intentions alone tend to
breed false hope. George Henry Moulds' plea for 'thinking straighter'
would certainly not be wasted on ISP:
Much advertising and salesmanship, both of goods and of ideas, makes the Appeal to
Practical Consequences. Use this soap and you will be more beautiful. Wear this suit
and you will get ahead in business. What is there that is not sold by such an appeal?
In every case let us ask for proof that the promised benefit will actually be delivered
(Moulds 1966, p. 36).
If doubts about policy effectiveness are not cleared during policy prepara-
tion, then they just live on. Once a course has been adopted, it usually
takes some time before it will be reviewed. If the enterprise of ISP is going
to be perceived as a failure, then it is highly uncertain whether a timely
review along the lines of 'integrated planning' will be launched at all.
As a consequence, regional policy will most probably return to 'where it
belongs', i.e. to the realm of traditional regional economic policy. Time is
running out too. ISP was begun in May 1973, the target year is 1980, and
by the end of 1977 the socioeconomic policy had not even been politic-
ally endorsed.
ISP/SPATIAL INEQUALITIES/REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT 249
will distinguish three types of knowledge (cf. for the following argument,
Working Group CES 1973):
a. community and environment knowledge,
b. organization knowledge,
c. operations knowledge.
Operations knowledge refers to knowledge of techniques and procedures
that help in the operations of regional governance. 'Procedures' refer to
the design of a planning cycle and the pursuit of its stages as, for example,
in the strategic choice framework. By 'techniques' we mean 'the use of
more discrete and specialised elements of procedure? e.g. a labour
market model for the Northern Netherlands used to quantify future mis-
matches between regional labour demand and supply (F.N.E.I. 1978).
Knowledge about the region, including its economic, spatial and
sociocultural aspects, is called community and environment knowledge,
while organization knowledge can be illustrated as knowledge about
horizontal relationships between departments at the national (institutions
at the regional and local) level as well as about vertical relations between
'the Hague' and 'the North'.
Regional science (education and research), in order to be relevant to real
world cases of regional governance, calls for an integration of all three
types of planning knowledge into a problem-solving learning method and a
concept of problem-centered education. It is this type of learning method
and education which provides planning capability. In other words, a
regional science focusing on spatial statistical analysis alone will most
certainly fall short of providing assistance to (integrated) regional
planning. Even 'analytical studies' (combining operations with community
and environment knowledge) alone will not be sufficient. We also need
'policy studies' (integrating organizations and community and environ-
ment knowledge) and 'meta-planning studies' or 'organization-planning'
(organization plus operations knowledge). And there is even more to it.
If regional science would just produce more relevant information, we
would still be facing the gap between planning methodology generated
and disseminated, on the one hand, and, on the other, the utilization of
this methodology in practice. Striving for a 'full entry into the problem-
solving space of all potentially relevant users' (Havelock 1974) demands a
close investigation of the reasons why the results of policy research are not
2. For a recent comparison between available planning methods and techniques and
information needs arising at different stages of plan preparation, see Drewe (1977 d).
ISP/SPATIAL INEQUALITIES/REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT 253
REFERENCES
Ashby, W.R.,An introduction to cybernetics. Chapman and Hall, New York, 1956.
Bather, N.J. et al., A strategic choice approach to structure planning. Proceedings of the PTRC
Summer Annual Meeting: Structure Plan Practice, PTRC, London, 1975.
Bather, N.J. et al., Strategic choice in practice: the West Berkshire structure plan experience.
Geographical Papers, University of Reading, 1976.
Bauvir, L. and C. Jaumotte, Le planijication regionale et l'amenagement du territoire en Belgique.
Paper presented at the annual meeting of the French-speaking section of the Regional Science
Association, Aix-en-Provence, September 15-17, 1977.
Beleidsanalyse, Driemaandelijks Bericht van de Commissie voor de Ontwikkeling van Beleids·
analyse ('National commission charged with the improvement of policy analysis'), no. 3, 1973.
Cremers, W.J.M., 'Het Nederlandse regionale beleid sinds 1945' (,Dutch regional policy since
1945'), Intermediair, vol. 12,45-53,1976.
Drewe, P., 'Migration in the Netherlands: policies and models', Delft Progress Report Quarterly,
vol. 2, 343-369, 1977a.
Drewe, P., Inte"egionale migratie en spreidingsbeleid, deelrapport 3, berekening implikaties
spreidingsbeleid (,Population (re) distribution policy and intervention rates implied'). Memoran-
dum, Institute for Town Planning Research, Delft University of Technology, August, 1977b.
Drewe, P., Segregatie in Rotterdam, beleidsanalyse: sociale segregatie en grootstedelijke politiek -
een referentiekader (,Social segregation and urban politics - a framework'). Internal research
paper, Delft University of Technology, 1977c.
Drewe, P., Planning methods and techniques, the state-of·the art. Paper prepared for the Inter-
national Colloquium on Recent Developments in Planning Methodology (Committee on
Housing, Building and Planning of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe), The
Hague, October, 1977d.
F.N .E.I., De kwalitatieve structuur van de noordelijke arbeidsmarkt: een eerste kwalitatieve analyse
('A labour market model for the Northern Netherlands'}. Federatie van Noordelijke Econo-
mische Instituten, Assen; 1978.
Friedmann, J., 'The implementation of regional development policies: lessons of experience',
International Social Development Review, 45-105, 1972.
Friend, J.K. and W.N. Jessop, Local government and strategic choice. Tavistock, London, 1969.
Friend, J.K. et al.,Public planning: the inter·corporate dimension. Tavistock, London, 1974.
Hage, J., Techniques and problems of theory construction in sociology. Wiley, New York, 1972.
Havelock, R., Research on the utilization of knowledge. Paper presented at the AAAS-ASIS
Symposium, San Francisco, 1974.
Haveman, R.H., 'Evaluating the impact of public policies on regional welfare', Regional Studies,
vol. 10,449-463,1976.
Hickling, A., Managing decisions. The strategic choice approach. Mantec, Rugby, 1974.
Holland, S., Capital versus the regions. MacMillan, London, 1976.
ISP 2, Rapport van de werkgroep beleidsdoelstellingen analyse noorden. January, 1974.
254 REFERENCES
ISP 3, Rapport van de werkgroep SJlstel'Nltische inventarisatie van studies en plannen inzake het
noorden. January, 1974.
ISP 4, Rapport van de werkgroep inspraak. December, 1974.
ISP 5, Interim-rapport van de werkgroep economilche ontwickkeling. March, 1975.
ISP 6, Interim-4'apport van de werkgroep ruimtelijke ontwikkeling. March, 1975.
ISP 7, Interim-4'apport van de werkgroep sociaal-culturele ontwikkeling. March, 1975.
ISP 8, Eindvenlllg van de werkgroep bevolkingsaspecten. October, 1975.
ISP 9a, Eindrapport van de werkgroep economische ontwikkeling, deel I: bedrijfstakvooruit-
zichten. 1976.
ISP 9b, Eindrapport van de werkgroup economische ontwikkeling, deel il: provincia1e vooruit-
zichten. 1976.
ISP 10, Eindrapport van de werkgroep wcilzal-culturele ontwikkeling. October, 1976.
ISP lla, Rapport van de werkgroep integrale planning, deelI: het noorden in nationaal penpectief.
March, 1977.
ISP 11 b, Rapport van de werkgroep integrale planning, deel II: departementale sektor-verkenningen.
August, 1977.
Jones, J.C.,Design methods. Wiley, London, 1973.
Manheim, M.L., The emerging planning proce,,: neither long-range nor short-range, but adaptive
and (hopefully) decisive. Paper presented at the 56th Annual Meeting of the Transportation
Research Board, Washington, D.C., January, 1977.
Minister van Economische Zaken,Nota regionaal socilzal-economilch be1eid 1977-1980 ('Report on
regional socioeconomic policy 1977-1980'). 's-Gravenhage, 1977.
Moulds, G.H., Thinking straighter. Kendall/Hunt. Dubuque, Iowa, 1961i.
Nederlands Economisch Instituut, Kampen en Zwolle na tien jaar stimuliering ('A case study of
regional policy'). Rotterdam, 1972.
Report on population aspects, Het noorden, een venterkte bevolkingsgroei? Of juist niet!. Staats-
uitgeverij, 's-Gravenhage, 1974.
Report on socioeconomic policy for the Northern part, Het socilzal-economish beleid voor het
Noorden des Lands. Staatsuitgeverij, 's-Gravenhage, 1976.
Report on the Northern part of the country, Nota Noorden des Lands. Tweede Kamer der Staten-
Generaal, 's-Gravenhage, 1972.
Third report on physical planning in the Netherlands, part one, Oril!nteringmota. Minister van
VRO, Staatsuitgeverij, 's-Gravenhage, 1974.
Third report on physical planning in the Netherlands, part two a, Verstedelijkingmota. Minister
van VRO, Staatsuitgeverij, 's-Gravenhage, 1976.
Third report on physical planning in the Netherlands, part two d, Ventedelijkingmota. Minister
van VRO, Staatsuitgeverij, 's-Gravenhage, 1977.
Van de Klundert, T., 'Het Centraal Economisch Plan 1977' ('The Central Economic Plan 1977'),
Economisch Statistische Berichten, vol. 62,490495,1977.
Working Group CES, 'Education for planning, the development of knowledge and capability for
urban governance' (Report of a Working Group at the Centre for Environmental Studies,
London), in D. Diamond and J.B. McLoughlin (eds.), Progre" in planning, vol. 1, Pergamon,
Oxford, 1973.
Subject index