Gijsbert - Oonk Indian Economic and Political History
Gijsbert - Oonk Indian Economic and Political History
Gijsbert - Oonk Indian Economic and Political History
This article is based on research in various archives and libraries in Bombay, Ahmedabad,
New Delhi, and London between 1993 and 1994. The research was made possible by a grant
from WOTRO Science for Global Development of NWO (Netherlands Organization for Scien-
tific Research), the Dutch foundation for tropical research. I would like to thank my colleagues
in the history department of Erasmus University for creating the environment to write and
develop new ideas, especially H. W. van Schendel for supervising my Ph.D. project. Ferry de
Goey has become a fine and critical colleague over the years, and I would also like to thank
Ellen Bal for her support. In India I wish to thank Dwijendra Tripathi and M. M. Mehta for
their detailed comments. I am also grateful to the editors for encouraging me to rewrite this
earlier published paper and make it accessible to a wider Western academic audience. See
Vipin Gupta (and others), “Culturally-Sensitive Models of Family Business in Southern Asia:
A Compendium using the GLOBE Paradigm,” Hyderabad, 2008; and Nasreen Taher and
Swapna Gopalan, eds., Business Communities of India (Hyderabad, 2006). I have entirely
revised and updated this article for this publication.
Kennedy, “The Protestant Ethic and the Parsees,” American Journal of Sociology 68 (1962):
11–20; Makrand Mehta, The Ahmedabad Cotton Textile Industry: Genesis and Growth
(Ahmedabad, 1982); Eckhard Kulke, The Parsees: A Minority as Agents of Social Change
(Munich, 1974); and Dwijendra Tripathi, ed., Business Communities of India: A Historical
Perspective (New Delhi, 1984).
5
Claude Markovits makes a useful comparison between Bombay and Ahmedabad:
“Bombay as a Business Centre in the Colonial Period: A Comparison with Calcutta,” in
Bombay: Metaphor for Modern India, ed. Sujata Patel and Alice Thorner (New Delhi,
1995), 26–46.
Gijsbert Oonk / 46
6
For an excellent overview of this debate, see Mario Rutten, Asian Capitalists in the Euro-
pean Mirror (Amsterdam, 1994). In this article, I follow his lead.
7
See William Roger Louis, ed., Imperialism: The Robinson and Gallagher Controversy
(New York, 1976); D. R. Gadgil, The Origins of the Indian Business Class (New York, 1959);
A. D. D. Gordon, Businessmen and Politics: Rising Nationalism and a Modernising
Economy in Bombay, 1918–1933 (New Delhi, 1978); and Claude Markovits, Indian Business
and Nationalist Politics, 1931–1939 (Cambridge, U.K., 1985).
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 47
would not develop a “hard working and saving money” ethic comparable
to that displayed by Protestants.8 As a result, he did not foresee long-
term investment in large-scale industries in India. Social historians
from the 1960s to the 1980s seriously questioned Weber’s theory.9
The most important economic historians on the Indian economy
have largely ignored Weber’s explanations. D. R. Gadgil, Amiya Kumar
Bagchi, Rajat Kanta Ray, and Amartya Sen have argued that the for-
mation of the European cartel and social ethos led to the Indian business
community refraining from investing long-term in large-scale industries.
They show that, when the rates of return were favorable for Indian
business, Indian entrepreneurs would stand up and enter large-scale
industry, rather than question ethics.10
Sociologist Edna Bonacich and social historian Christine Dobbin
built on Simmel’s and Weber’s work by arguing that minorities in par-
ticular became successful entrepreneurs; because of their minority
status (and, as a consequence, having confronted all kinds of discrimi-
nation, such as not being allowed to own land or to undertake certain
jobs), they developed a stronger desire to become successful.11
Social background. Within the predominant Marxist literature, the
transition from mercantile to industrial capital is of primary importance.
Here we find that Asian assumptions about the European transition to
industrialization (especially in the British cotton textile industry)
greatly influenced the Indian historiography on indigenous industrializ-
ation.12 Central to the Asian notion of the background of early European
industrialists is the fact that they did not belong to the trading or
merchant-manufacturer community. This view is a consequence of
dated European literature on the industrial transformation in Europe.
Here, economic historian Maurice Dobb, for example, argues that mer-
chant capital could not, ultimately, be responsible for the Industrial
8
See Max Weber, Die Wirstschaftsethic der Welreligionen II: Hinduismus und Buddhis-
mus (Tübingen, 1922). For a fair summary of Weber’s work, see Reinhard Bendix, Max Weber:
An Intellectual Portrait (London, 1966). For a fundamental critique, see Morris D. Morris,
“Values as an Obstacle to Economic Growth in South Asia: A Historical Survey,” Journal of
Economic History 27, no. 4 (1976): 588–91.
9
Among others: Timberg, The Marwaris; Kennedy, “The Protestant Ethic and the
Parsees,” 11–20; Mehta, The Ahmedabad Cotton Textile Industry.
10
Bagchi, Private Investment in India, 1900–1939; Ray, Growth and Conflict in the
Private Corporate Sector, 1914–1947; Gadgil, Business Communities in India; Amartya K.
Sen, “The Pattern of British Enterprise in India, 1854–1914: A Causal Analysis,” in Social
and Economic Change, ed. B. Singh and V. B. Singh (Bombay, 1967).
11
Edna Bonacich, “A Theory of Middleman Minorities,” American Sociological Review 38
(1973): 583–94; Christine Dobbin, Asian Entrepreneurial Minorities (Richmond, U.K., 1996).
Georg Simmel, “The Stranger,” in The Sociology of George Simmel, ed. K. H. Wolf (New York,
1950).
12
“Asian assumptions” refers to assumptions made by Asian historians as well as by Euro-
pean historians concerned with the industrialization debate on South Asia.
Gijsbert Oonk / 48
At the end of World War I, the imperial sun was probably at its
highest in Calcutta. The most important buildings of the British
managing-agency houses of Andrew Yule, Bird and Heilgers, and the
13
Karl Marx, Capital, vol. 3, 388–96, as quoted in Maurice Dobb, Studies in the Develop-
ment of Capitalism (New York, 1976 [1st ed. 1947, rev. ed. 1963]). For an excellent overview of
how a selection of the European historiography influenced notions on the Asian transform-
ation to industrialization, see Rutten, Asian Capitalists in the European Mirror.
14
Rutten, Asian Capitalists in the European Mirror.
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 49
Calcutta served as the capital city of British India until 1911, after
which this role shifted to Delhi. The city had the largest concentration
of Europeans and capital in India. The Indian government, and therefore
the city of Calcutta, played an important role in the allocation of resources
between regions, particularly in the development of railway companies
and railway lines. The European business community in Calcutta used
its influence and networks to serve European (mainly Scottish) business
interests in the jute trade and tea production. In this context, less dis-
crimination and shared resentment marked the business relationship
between Indian and European businessmen.16 Claude Markovits argues
that historians have put forward the main explanation for this difference:
made them unpopular with the more formally organized British. Take,
for example, the attitude of British jute mill owners in the early 1920s.
One of them, M. P. Thomas of Bird, singled out G. D. Birla, the
Marwari business spokesman at that time, as the main villain: “He has
done more to encourage new mills than anyone. If he can’t get us out
by kicking us out, he will try to get us out by unfair competition.”19
During the 1930s depression, when there were internal problems in
the Indian Jute Mill Association, the British frequently referred to the
Marwaris as “short-sighted industrialists,” “mugs with money,” and
“pirates.”20 Whenever a Marwari attempted to enter the industry, he
was “up to do some dirty work.”21 Claude Markovits even argues that
the “racial arrogance of the Scots, signaled by their refusal to seek a com-
promise with the Marwaris, was partly responsible for the long-term
decline of the industry in the post-1947 period.”22 So, which Marwaris
eventually emerged in the industry that the British had dominated
from its very beginnings in the 1850s?
Middleman Minority?
adulteration proved to be a rallying point for the emergence of Marwari political solidarity.”
Hardgrove, Community and Public Culture: The Marwaris in Calcutta, c. 1897–1997
(New York, 2004), 127.
19
Thomas Benthall, 12 Dec. 1928, Benthall papers, Center for South Asians Studies, Cam-
bridge, U.K., cited in Goswami, “Then Came the Marwaris,” 150.
20
Morton Benthall, 16 Sept. 1935, Benthall papers, Centre for South Asian Studies, Cam-
bridge, U.K.; Indian Jute Mill Association, Report of the Committee (1934), 12; as cited in
Goswami, “Then Came the Marwaris.”
21
Thomas Benthall, 12 Dec. 1928, Benthall papers, cited in Goswami, “Then Came the
Marwaris.”
22
Markovits, “Bombay as a Business Centre in the Colonial Period,” 43.
23
Bengali businessmen burnt their fingers in Indo-British partnerships in the 1830s and
1840s, and remained too cautious to become involved with further initiatives. Blair B. Kling,
Partner in Empire: Dwarkarnath Tagore and the Age of Enterprise in Eastern India (Berke-
ley, 1976); Bagchi, Private Investment in India, 203–6.
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 51
any clues about these kinds of questions, as his primary examples mainly
related to the Jews in Europe. Other Europeans in the nineteenth
century viewed Jews in racial terms, as well as being members of a differ-
ent religion. The Marwaris, however, have the same religion, but have a
different regional background and culture. On the other hand, the
sources do indicate that Marwaris were also seen as an outsider minority
group, as they were, for example, counted separately in the census.
Nevertheless, there is no real evidence that Marwaris were, because
of their minority status, more motivated to become successful
entrepreneurs.24
In addition, the negative qualifications of Max Weber towards the
economic potential of Indian entrepreneurs raised enormous counterar-
guments and inspired empirical research to prove that Hindu business-
men could become successful. In one well-known example on Calcutta,
The Marwaris: From Traders to Industrialists (Delhi, 1978), Thomas
A. Timberg revealed how a small part of the Marwari community in Cal-
cutta became competitors of the British jute mill owners. Timberg argues
that Hindus could very well become great entrepreneurs. At the same
time, as we can see from the book’s title, he emphasizes that religious
background is not important, but occupational background is.
29
Omkar Goswami, “Sahibs, Babus, and Banias: Changes in Industrial Control in Eastern
India, 1918–50,” Journal of Asian Studies 48, no. 2 (1989): 292. Goswami estimates that the
trading profits of the Marwaris were around Rs. 440 million per year in this period. This esti-
mate excludes their profits from different future markets and from trade in jute bags and cloth;
see Goswami, “Sahibs, Babus, and Banias,” 293.
30
L. C. Jain, Indigenous Banking in India (London, 1929); Rajat Kanta Ray, “The Bazaar:
Changing Structural Characteristics in the Indigenous Section of the Indian Economy before
and after the Great Depression,” Indian Economic Social History Review 25, no. 3 (1988):
263–318; Rajat Kanta Ray, “Pedhis and Mills: The Historical Integration of the Formal and
the Informal Sectors in the Economy of Ahmedabad,” Indian Economic and Social History
Review 19, nos. 3–4 (1982): 387–96.
31
Goswami described this process well in “Sahibs, Babus, and Banias.”
Gijsbert Oonk / 54
32
The Jatia family, for example, developed close ties to the Andrew Yule Company. David
Yule was a close friend of Onkarmull Jatia. The Goenka family had a close connection to Bird
and Heilgers, and the Kanorias were connected to McLeod.
33
Goswami, “Then Came the Marwaris,” 228–36.
34
However obvious this may be, this observation developed after intensive discussions and
correspondence with Dr. Raman Mahadevan, whom I thank for his time and insights.
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 55
35
G. D. Birla, In the Shadow of the Mahatma (Calcutta, 1953), xv.
36
D. K. Taknet, Industrial Entrepreneurship of the Shekhawati Marwaris (Columbia,
Mo., 1986), 179–228.
37
Sarupchand Hukumchand made his money in banking and speculating on the opium
market. In the early twentieth century he settled in Calcutta, where he was very lucky in his
speculative business. In 1910, he used borrowed money to buy Rs. 200,000 worth of opium,
which within a month yielded him ten times that amount. In 1915, he opened a very profitable
trading office in Calcutta. By then, he already owned a cotton mill in Indore. However, without
much knowledge of jute industries, he became a partner in Birla’s first jute venture. Neverthe-
less, speculation and the opium trade remained his most important sources of income.
Gijsbert Oonk / 56
Table 1
The Transformation from Traders to Industrialists of Some
Marwari Families
Board of Director of
Family Name of Trader/ British Managing
Industrialist Banker Broker Speculator Agency
Birla Yes Yes Yes Yes
Goenka Yes Yes Yes Yes*
Bangur Yes - Yes Yes**
Hukumchand Yes No No Yes
Jalan Yes No No Yes
Jatia Yes No Yes No
Singhania Yes No Yes Yes
- No information available.
* Due to the failure of two British managing agencies, McLeod and Octavius Steel; not by
setting up a mill themselves.
** By buying the British managing agency Kettlewell Bullen & Co.
Sources: See Gijsbert Oonk, “Het geheim van de Marwaris: Een onderzoek naar Indiaas onder-
nemerschap, 1900–1939” [Secrets of the Marwaris: A Study of Indian Entrepreneurship,
1900–1939], unpublished MA thesis, Erasmus University Rotterdam, 1991, 61.
emergence in the jute mill industry, but did not. They simply had to
choose the right moment to emerge.
The Marwaris can be seen as an example of a migrant Hindu/Jain
minority that was able to follow the British example of jute industrialists
and flourish economically within a politically and economically unfavor-
able colonial context. However, their status as outsider minority could
not explain their success. In this section, we have raised questions
about what an outsider is. According to the Bengalis, Marwaris were out-
siders, although according to many British businessmen they were just
seen as locals or Indian. Simmel and Dobbin do not provide us with
the tools to distinguish between types of outsiders. Yet, outsider or
not, Timberg and others agree that the Hindu/Jain religion of the Mar-
waris did not hinder their economic development. One commonsense
explanation for the success of the Marwaris as a community is that
those who did not succeed in Calcutta generally returned to their prop-
erties in Marwar and Shekawati. Only those who were successful
remained in the city.38 Accordingly, it is fair to describe the Marwaris
in Calcutta as successful traders or bankers from Marwar, Rajasthan.
38
For more details on success and failure stories of migrant businessmen see: Gijsbert
Oonk, Settled Strangers: Asian Business Elites in East Africa, 1800–2000 (Delhi, 2013).
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 57
The imperial sun in Bombay never shone with the same intensity as
it did in Calcutta. Up to 1750, Surat—not Bombay—was the economic
center of West India. The establishment of the headquarters of the
English East India Company (EIC) in Bombay in 1672 was not enough
to secure its prosperity. The socioeconomic development of the city
was due to a symbiotic relationship between Parsis and Britons. The Vic-
toria railway station currently symbolizes this relationship; across the
main road in front of the station is a statue of Daoroji Naoroji, an impor-
tant Parsi spokesman and founder of the Indian National Congress.
41
Holden Furber in Ashok V. Desai, “The Origins of Parsi Enterprise,” Indian Economic
and Social History Review 5, no. 4 (1968): 307–17.
42
Bombay Public Proceedings, 8 Feb., 13 Aug., 27 Sept. 1723; 18 Oct. 1728; 3 Sept. and 3
Dec. 1731. Maharasthra State Archives, Mumbai.
43
Ashin Das Gupta, Indian Merchants and the Decline of Surat, 1700–1750 (Wiesbaden,
1979), 8.
44
This is explained by their “minority status” in Kulke, Parsees, or by their supposed “Pro-
testant Ethic,” in Kennedy, “The Protestant Ethic and the Parsees,” 11–20.
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 59
their desire to build a bureing [sic] place for their dead on the
Island.45
Throughout the Rebellion [1857] in the East, the Parsees have main-
tained an unshaken loyalty to the British whom they are proud to call
their fellow subjects, and while preserving their own independence of
religion and customs, their chief desire is that British rule in India
should be consolidated upon a basis of strict justice and mutual
interest.46
family worked for several European firms, such as the traders Goddam
Bythel & Co. and Soloman Betch & Co.50 With the exception of the
Birla and Jatia families, this work pattern did not occur in Calcutta.
Accordingly, this evidence supports Markovits’s thesis that Bombay
benefited from a “more dynamic atmosphere of emulation and compe-
tition” and “less racial and communal strife,” with the consequence
being the more rational use of capital resources and knowledge.51
Middleman minority? The minority and Protestant ethic theses
seem to apply in the Bombay case.52 However, in spite of apparent evi-
dence, I have some serious doubts about these viewpoints. The minority
thesis certainly has its drawbacks in the Bombay case. First of all, the
Parsis were a minority in Western India and in Surat, where they
started their trading careers in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries.
The Parsi migration to Bombay had drawbacks. Initially, they were not a
minority, but a majority group within Bombay Fort. However, owing to
the accelerated urban growth that took place, mainly due to Hindu
migrants, the Parsis became a minority group in Bombay proper from
the 1850s onwards. However, by then, they had already developed
their trading firms and their transition to industry was only a matter
of time.
The question remains as to why, more than other communities, the
Parsis decided to settle in Bombay. Most of the regulations that encour-
aged local businessmen to remain in the city did not apply just to the
Parsis, but to the entire Indian business community. Sometimes,
however, there is evidence that the English invited the Parsis in particu-
lar to move to Bombay. This favor was certainly the case when Aungier
allowed Parsis to build a Tower of Silence (a resting place for the Parsi
dead) in Bombay, and when the EIC sent George Dudley to Surat to
invite well-known Parsi shipbuilders to settle in the city.53
The Weber thesis confronts us with more complex issues. I am
inclined to accept historian Robert Kennedy’s comparison of the Protes-
tant and the Parsi ethic. In addition, he demonstrates how this ethic of
hard work and saving money is part of Parsi daily experience.54 Never-
theless, unlike Kennedy, we cannot ignore the fact that the Parsis were
invited to settle in Bombay. Indeed, the English offered them all kinds
of economic and social benefits, which, at the very least, helped them
50
Bombay Dyeing: The First Hundred Years, 1879–1979 (Bombay, 1979).
51
Markovits, “Bombay as a Business Centre in the Colonial Period,” 44–45.
52
Kennedy, “The Protestant Ethic and the Parsees,” 11–20; Kulke, The Parsis in India;
David L. White, Competition and Collaboration: Parsi Merchants and the English East
India Company in Eighteenth-Century India (New Delhi, 1995).
53
H. D. Darukhanawala, Parsi Lustre on Indian Soil (Bombay, 1939).
54
Kennedy, “The Protestant Ethic and the Parsees.”
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 61
55
S. M. Rutnagur, Bombay Industries: The Cotton Mills (Bombay, 1927), 54; Bombay Mill
Owners’ Association, The Annual Report of the Bombay Mill-Owners’ Association (1878).
56
According to Markovits, the more “cosmopolitan character” of the Bombay business
community (as compared with Calcutta) is a key factor in explaining its success. Markovits,
“Bombay as a Business Centre in the Colonial Period,” 26–46.
57
Rutnagur, Bombay Industries.
Gijsbert Oonk / 62
58
See Appendix A in Oonk, Ondernemers in Ontwikkeling.
59
Ibid.
60
G. N. Natesan, ed., Famous Parsis (Madras, 1930), 217–21; F. R. Harris, J. N. Tata
(Bombay, 1958); Dwijendra Tripathi and Makrand Mehta, Business Houses in Western
India: A Study in Entrepreneurial Response, 1850–1956 (New Delhi, 1990).
61
That the Bombay mill industry was merely a matter of the diversification of cotton and
opium traders can be found in Chandavarkar, The Origins of Industrial Capitalism in
India, ch. 6. However, Chandavarkar does not include its consequences for the industry.
62
A summary of annual reports of cotton textile mills can be found in the Indian Textile
Journal 23, no. 267 (1913): 290. Similar examples can be found in various places in
the Indian Textile Journal: “Annual Meeting of the Swam Mills and the Finlay mills were
held. . . . Both have shown good profits thanks to adventurous variations in the price of
cotton as the supplies have been bought greatly in advance of requirements and this proved
profitable.” Indian Textile Journal 38, no. 449 (1928): 160. The Colaba Land and Mill
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 63
Company was accused of speculating in land and raw cotton. The profits of these mills were not
made by spinning and weaving, but by trading and speculating: Indian Textile Journal 10, no.
109 (1899): 2; 22, no. 253 (1911): 25.
63
I deal more thoroughly with this in Gijsbert Oonk, “Motor or Millstones? The Managing
Agency System in Bombay and Ahmedabad, 1850–1930,” Indian Economic and Social History
Review 4 (2001): 419–52.
64
Desai, “Origins of Parsi Enterprise,” 307–17.
Gijsbert Oonk / 64
No Colonial Attitude
as was often the case in Bombay. Three short biographies will confirm
this. Lalbhai Dalpathi (1863–1912) inherited the family business in
1885. His family had made its fortune as bankers and cotton traders
between 1861 and 1864. During the American Civil War, the price of
raw cotton increased spectacularly, and those involved in the trade prof-
ited. Some of this money was invested in the cotton textile industry. After
his death in 1912, Dalpathi’s son, Kasturbhai Lalbhai, made his name in
the Ahmedabad cotton textile industry.68 In a second example, the young
entrepreneur Manganbhai Sarabhai started the Ahmedabad Manufac-
turing and Calico Printing Co. in 1881. His father was a banker/financier
who died at an early age, but had asked Ranchhodlal Chhotalal and Bho-
lanath Sarabhai to take care of his son. Accordingly, it was foreseeable that
some of the banking profits would be invested in the cotton textile indus-
try.69 Lastly, Jamnabhai Bagubhai (1859–1924) started the Gujarat Spin-
ning and Weaving Co. in 1877. His family had made its fortune by
speculating during the American Civil War. However, they did not have
any prior experience with cotton trade or finance.70 (See Table 2.)
Of the thirty-five mill owners whose initial occupational background
I traced, twenty (63 percent) were originally bankers. Eight mill owners
(23 percent) in Ahmedabad were initially traders, but they were not
guaranteed brokers to British trading houses. Some of the mill owners
were known as speculators, but these cases were exceptional. We do
not know the occupational background of the others, but in some cases
this was a combination of banker, trader, and/or speculator.
The banking background of Ahmedabad’s cotton industrialists influ-
enced the way in which the cotton mills were financed. Banks and share-
holders financed Bombay’s mills to a greater extent than in Ahmedabad.
This was mainly because a formal (Western) banking system was more
developed in Bombay than it was in Ahmedabad. However, the Ahmeda-
bad mill owners accumulated capital in the form of deposits made by
individuals for a fixed interest rate. Normally, these deposits were
made for a period of three to twelve months. Up to the First World
War, the public in Ahmedabad believed that it was more secure to
deposit their money with one of the Ahmedabadi bankers or mill
owners than with a “modern” bank.71 Most of the deposits were fairly
68
A. D. Shroff, Kasturbhai Lalbhai: A Biography (Bombay, 1978); Tripathi and Mehta,
Business Houses, 88–105; and Dwijendra Tripathi, Dynamics of a Tradition: Kasturbhai
Lalbhai and his Entrepreneurship (New Delhi, 1981).
69
A. K. Rice, Productivity and Social Organisation: The Ahmedabad Experiment
(London, 1958), 23; Mehta, The Ahmedabad Cotton Textile Industry, 87–89; Leadbeater,
The Politics of Textiles, 66–71.
70
Mehta, The Ahmedabad Cotton Textile Industry, 87.
71
This changed after the First World War, when the Indian government sold government
securities against a relatively high interest rate. The Ahmedabad Mill Owners’ Association
Gijsbert Oonk / 66
Table 2
Typical Examples of the Ahmedabad Path from Financier to
Industrialist
Social/ Occupational Background
Family Name of Trade Finance in Cotton
Industrialist Banking (Cotton) Textile Industries Industry
Sarabhai Yes Yes Yes Yes
Lalbhai Yes Yes No Yes
Bhagubai Yes No No Yes
Source: Gijsbert Oonk, Ondernemers in Ontwikkeling: Fabrieken en fabrikanten in de
Indiase katoenindustrie, 1850–1930 [Entrepreneurs in Development: Mills and Mill
Owners in the Indian Cotton Industry, 1850–1930] (Hilversum, 1998), 117.
small; building an average cotton mill cost about Rs. 30,000 in Ahmeda-
bad, and most deposits were between Rs. 500 and Rs. 2000.
Table 3 reveals three striking differences between Bombay and
Ahmedabad in the financing of cotton mills. First, the banks in
Bombay supported the mills to a greater extent than their counterparts
in Ahmedabad. In the former, banks lent an average of 9 percent of
capital, whereas in the latter this figure did not exceed 4 percent. Sec-
ondly, shareholders in Bombay invested 49 percent of capital, whereas
in Ahmedabad they only put up 32 percent.72 Thirdly, cotton manufac-
turers in Ahmedabad depended more on deposits from small investors
than the cotton manufacturers in Bombay; in the latter, depositors
raised only 11 percent of capital, whereas in Ahmedabad this figure
was 39 percent.
It was well known that banks in India were not inclined to issue sub-
stantial loans to cotton mills.73 It was also known that cotton manufac-
turers in Bombay could expect slightly more support from banks than
manufacturers in Ahmedabad. The reluctance of banks to back industrial
enterprises may have been due to a lack of capacity to estimate the value
of such undertakings.74 Moreover, Indian banks had not yet developed
complained about the loss of deposit holders. See, Report of the Indian Tariff Board, 1927, vol.
3 (Calcutta, 1927), 396.
72
I found hardly any supplementary information in the sources about the role played by
letters of credit in financing, so do not discuss this question.
73
Report of the Indian Industrial Commission, 1916–1918, vol. 2 (Calcutta, 1919), 178.
Basu also confirmed this, Industrial Finance, 99–142. For a detailed discussion on the role
attributed to the Managing Agency System, see Oonk, “Motor or Millstones,” 419–52.
74
Indian Central Banking Enquiry Committee, Cotton Textile Industry, vol. 1 (Calcutta,
1927), 270, 271, 776.
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 67
Table 3
Sources of Capital of the Cotton Mills in Bombay and
Ahmedabad in 1930
Bombay Ahmedabad
Sources of Capital Rs. (1000s) % Rs. (1000s) %
Borrowed by Managing 53.2 21.4 26.4 24.4
Agents
Bank Loan 22.6 9.1 4.2 3.9
Deposits 27.3 11.0 42.6 39.4
Shares 121.4 48.9 34.0 31.5
Debentures 23.8 9.5 0.8 0.7
Total 248.3 100* 108.0 100*
Number of Factories 64 56
* rounded
Source: The Indian Central Banking Enquiry Commission, vol. 1 (Calcutta, 1931), 278.
75
Meetings of the Boards of Directors of the Saraspur Mills, Calico Mills, Raipur Mills, and
New Shorrock Mills over various years. Private Company archives of the respective mills,
Ahmedabad. After the First World War, the pace of change slowed because the Indian govern-
ment issued loans with high security and interest. The Ahmedabad Mill Owners’ Association
accordingly complained about this. Indian Tariff Board vol. 3, 396.
76
Bombay Provincial Banking Enquiry Committee, vol. 3, 408–16. Rajat Kanta Ray has
written an interesting but speculative article on this topic, in which he shows how formal
and informal relationships were integrated in Ahmedabad. Ray, “Pedhis and Mills,” 387–96.
Gijsbert Oonk / 68
77
Indian Central Banking Enquiry Committee, Cotton Textile Industry, vol. 3, 480.
78
Prajabandhu, 4 Feb. 1909, 2.
79
Members of the Board of Directors, New Shorrock Mill, Company Archive, Ahmedabad,
1905.
80
P. S. Lokanathan, Industrial Organisation in India (London, 1935), 182.
81
Mehta, The Ahmedabad Cotton Textile Industry.
The Emergence of Indigenous Industrialists / 69
Conclusion
them insiders but the Bengalis considered them outsiders. In the case of
the Parsis of Bombay, it may be argued that they were a minority from
the 1850s onwards, but were a majority group before that, as I have
shown. Last, but not least, the example of the Hindus in Ahmedabad
demonstrates that the Hindu majority in Gujarat was well able to
develop indigenous industries at the right time and in the right place.
The Weber thesis cannot explain the emergence of industrialists in
Ahmedabad (who had a Hindu-majority background), which Weber
and others would not have anticipated.
In all of these debates it is striking that the research on India under-
estimates the occupational background of the industrialists. In all three
cities, most future industrialists had a background in finance and trade.
They were by no means people of humble origins or self-made men, as
the classic rags-to-riches stories go. Indeed, they were not craftsmen, tech-
nicians, or mechanics who had owned small workshops and then
expanded. Most of them had virtually no idea how to build factories,
use mechanized (steam) power, and manage large-scale production units.
Despite their backgrounds, an indigenously owned and managed
large-scale industry emerged. Indigenous industrialists were new men
in the history of India, but they had experience in finance and trade.
Despite differences in financing cotton textile mills, small-scale investors
in Ahmedabad seemed to be more important than in Bombay. Neverthe-
less, whatever the colonial attitude and the community background of
indigenous industrialists (Marwaris in Calcutta, Parsis in Bombay, and
Hindu Gujaratis in Ahmedabad), creative indigenous traders and inves-
tors found room to step into profitable large-scale industries. At the
beginning of the second half of the nineteenth century, Indians built
the first indigenous cotton mills in Bombay and Ahmedabad. Not until
1919 was the first Indian mill (jute) built in Calcutta. In all cases, these
industrialists, the new men in history in India, were traders and bankers.
. . .