Manufacturing Discontent Accepted
Manufacturing Discontent Accepted
net/publication/326281730
CITATIONS READS
7 403
3 authors:
Gerhard Schnyder
Loughborough University
61 PUBLICATIONS 428 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Gerhard Schnyder on 05 December 2019.
Manufacturing Discontent:
Economies
ABSTRACT
Research summary: There is mounting evidence of a widespread popular
multinational companies’ (MNCs) interests. In this paper we argue that MNCs are
preventing them from doing so. Where institutional constraints lead firms to adopt
across countries. We also discuss the strategic options available to firms facing
backlash.
that directly hurt their interests. Yet little is known about the link of this
1
Manufacturing Discontent
analysis to show that national institutions play a key role in determining the
also present and discuss the strategic options available to firms facing backlash.
2
Manufacturing Discontent
Introduction
Since the late 1990s, multinational companies (MNCs) have found themselves in a much
characterized not just by recurring crises (the dot-com bubble, the Global Financial
Crisis) but also by growing skepticism towards the benefits of globalization, which we
define as relatively unfettered global flows of goods, services, and capital. There is
in the past two decades (Micklethwait & Wooldridge, 2001; O’Brien, 2000; Cuervo-
Cazurra et al., 2017; Kobrin, 2017), but recent years have witnessed much more dramatic
election of Donald J. Trump as American president and the United Kingdom’s June 2016
Backlash may lead governments to adopt concrete and intentional steps to reverse
pro-globalization policies, which we call policy reversal. While backlash does not
automatically lead to policy reversal, the connection between the two is that ceteris paribus
the greater the level of backlash the greater the likelihood of policy reversal. Both backlash
and policy reversal potentially constitute major challenges for MNCs which rely on open
borders to spread their activities globally. While implications of backlash for firm strategy
have recently been explored (Kobrin, 2017), the extant literature neglects the institutional
occurring. Here we use a comparative capitalist perspective (Hall and Soskice 2001; Jackson
1
It is important to note that emphasizing electoral expressions of anti-globalization discontent makes sense
given that the set of advanced economies under examination in this paper (see Table 1) are all
democracies i.e. hold elections to determine their political leadership although one of these economies
has biased laws heavily favoring the ruling party (Singapore). Our population of advanced economies
excludes one non-democratic, advanced economy (Hong Kong) (Fuller, 2010), because Hong Kong is officially
a self-governing special administrative zone of China rather than a fully sovereign and independent country
and the elections with popular suffrage component of Hong Kong’s governance system is very limited.
3
Manufacturing Discontent
& Deeg, 2008; Saka-Helmhout et al., 2016; Fainshmidt et al., 2016) to show that
institutions shape firm strategies in ways that may favor or prevent the socio-economic
conditions for backlash to emerge in advanced economies (detailed definition of this set of
firm behavior at the same time that they provide comparative institutional advantages
where the national institutions bolster specific firm-level capabilities. Here we use these
strategy consisting in tapping into cheap labor markets overseas or preventing them from
doing so. We propose that those countries hewing closely to liberal market economy
globalization-induced economic losses. They also do the least to constrain firms from
at home in favor of cheaper workers abroad. Thus, such economies are likely to
Further, we show what strategic responses firms may adopt when faced with
4
Manufacturing Discontent
backlash are often entangled with economic ones (see, for instance, Inglehart & Norris,
economic globalization. Thus, when we refer to backlash in the rest of this paper, we
advanced economies and then analyze the causal pathways of backlash and policy reversal
in wealthy economies. Finally, we show how our argument departs from previous
capitalism under study and which economies conform to which type of capitalism.
In line with the political economy and empirical literature on the impact of
trade liberalization and trade openness on advanced economies (Rodrik, 2011, 2017;
Milanovic 2016), we argue that economic globalization ceteris paribus has negatively affected
via globalization (or at least radical expansion) of labor markets to include large numbers of
relatively low wage workers in developing economies. This literature stresses the negative
are more likely than university-educated workers to find themselves in direct competition
with workers from developing economies. However, as Milanovic (2016) has shown, the
economies has not been felt equally. Indeed, some of these advanced countries have been
5
Manufacturing Discontent
able to limit the general upward swing in inequality driven by the relative wage losses of
that domestic institutions account for much of the variation in the negative impact on
groups, non-university educated workers are at its core (Eatwell & Goodwin, 2018). The
reason for this is that it is these strata of society that are most vulnerable to the downsides
reconfigure their operations by accessing low and semi-skilled workers in low wage
locations at little additional cost due to lowered legal trade barriers, the "box" transportation
educated workers who have the most to lose from globalization and may feel most strongly
about policies promoting or reversing it. Research from the US has shown the negative
economic impact of the globalization of labor markets – and trade with low-wage China
in particular (Autor et al. 2013) – on non-university educated workers (Lin 2016). Areas
most negatively impacted by trade with China have been most supportive of anti-
research from political science has shown that working class socio-economic strata and
education levels were critical determinants in the Brexit backlash (Goodwin & Heath,
2016; Antonucci, Horvath, Kutiyski, & Krouwel, 2017). We therefore consider that this
Drawing on Hall and Soskice (2001), we posit that the globalization of labor
markets offers opportunities (firms can utilize new sources of labor directly and indirectly)
and threats (firms may face new challenges as existing or emerging competitors utilize
6
Manufacturing Discontent
these new sources of labor) for firms, and institutions encourage or constrain firms to
either take what we call the “upgrading” or the “labor arbitrage” strategy. In the labor
in place of workers in the advanced economies. In the upgrading strategy, firms seek
workforce of the developing world and instead pursuing the more costly process of re-
investing in their home country-based capabilities. While both strategies can be successful in
terms of sustained firm profitability over time, we hypothesize that the dominant strategy
variable, but a range. Firms typically have relatively more or less exploitation of labor
savings via engagement with the developing economies rather than solely relying upon or
completely forsaking the cost savings offered by utilizing cheap labor in emerging
economies.
It is important to note that here we talk of firms rather than MNCs (and will
continue to do so in most of the remainder of this paper) because not all of the firms
confronted with these opportunities and threats from globalization are or become MNCs.
Many may remain domestic firms, but their very choices still help to shape the likelihood
The foundational framework for much of the comparative capitalism literature has
been the “Varieties of Capitalism” framework (Soskice, 1999; Hall and Soskice, 2001). The
Varieties of Capitalism framework posits that differences across four institutional spheres
7
Manufacturing Discontent
complementarities lead most economies to cluster around the LME type or the
Coordinated Market Economy (CME) type, where the organization of economic activities
occurs through non-market coordination between major economic and social actors.
firms’ behavior but also provide them with institutionally-determined input factors that
lead to institutional competitive advantage and hence specialization of firms from a given
& Jackson, 2016; Schneider et al., 2010; Hotho 2014; Fainshmidt et al., 2016) has typically
used Varieties of Capitalism as the main or at least partial foundation of its analysis. Here we
will follow suit while pointing out as others have done (e.g. Schneider and Paunescu 2012)
where our analysis and Varieties of Capitalism part ways. In particular, we accept that LMEs
number of advanced economies. For the other advanced economies’ capitalist systems, we
acknowledge that the CME ideal-type, as laid out in Hall and Soskice (2001), is too
specific (it may only really describe German capitalism) even as the four institutional
spheres that Varieties of Capitalism emphasizes are critical to all advanced economies.
Acknowledging the limited applicability of the CME category, we prefer to use the broader
Institutional complementarities across these spheres may also exist in other non-LMEs
in the underlying definition of the corporate purpose. The purpose of the public
generally considered a quasi-public institution with responsibilities beyond the profit motif
(Weimer & Pape, 1999; Höpner, 2007). As a result, non-LMEs attribute higher importance to
the survival of companies than LMEs where bankruptcies, takeovers, and other forms of
dissolution of a corporation are mainly seen as beneficial market-driven processes that free
up assets for more productive uses. These differential conceptions and priorities are reflected
in the institutional setup of different types of capitalisms: Institutions in LMEs are structured
in a way that enhances and encourages competition between firms and encourages firms
to respond quickly in ever changing markets. In non-LMEs, the institutions are structured
in a way that allows firms to adjust their strategies and restructure their capabilities over
The institutions of classic CMEs as well as other non-LMEs do not make possible
this longer-term orientation solely through providing the necessary inputs (e.g. training
workers, and other relevant actors within the wider national economy from economic
Capitalism literature, two aspects of the economy that were given relatively short shrift in
that literature (and only partially incorporated elsewhere in the comparative capitalism
literature) are the role of the state intervention in the economy and the state’s social welfare
systems. The latter especially looms much larger than the relatively narrow role the
and buffering from globalization. Thus, the next section will consider these six
institutional domains and how they mediate firms’ and individuals’ reactions to the
structural challenges of globalization that Kobrin (2017) highlights. This allows us, in
9
Manufacturing Discontent
To be sure, the differences between LMEs and non-LMEs are not dichotomous,
and for a given institutional sphere may be conceived of as a range with pure non-LME on
one end and pure LME on the other. Ideal, pure LME institutions would be those where
market mechanisms with the bare minimum of regulation necessary to sustain such market
and Jackson 2016; Schneider and Paunescu 2012). However, such approaches assume that
countries fit comfortably on the CME-LME range and do not take into account other
institutional configurations that actually exist in the world as critiques of the original
Varieties of Capitalism model have pointed out (Allen 2004; Crouch 2005). Furthermore,
given that our model includes two institutional spheres not fully included in Varieties of
Capitalism, the labeling of capitalist systems as CME-lite or LME-lite does not make much
in outcomes, in this case buffering workers and firms from globalization’s competitive
pressure. Classic CMEs’ institutions buffer workers and firms, but we argue that alternative
non-LME institutional arrangements that do not look like Germany can buffer workers and
For buffering workers from globalization and constraining firms from adopting
labor arbitrage, different domestic institutions may act in very different ways to
face of globalization. We opt for the term hybrid to denote those economies in which the
institutions do not all manifest purely liberal market tendencies or their opposite in terms
of the long-termism and buffering against short- term market forces across institutional
spheres in pure non-LMEs (see Tables 1 and 2 below). In other words, instead of
assuming equal levels of buffering across institutional spheres as denoted by terms such
10
Manufacturing Discontent
as CME or CME-lite (the latter having slightly less buffering across the spheres than the
firms. For example, Sweden now has increasingly equity-based finance relying on
external shareholders, which is a typical LME feature (Schnyder 2012). This feature may
However, Sweden also has one of the most developed, solidaristic welfare states in the
world and this non-LME feature works against the propensity to backlash. The typical
comparative capitalist approaches, such as Jackson and Witt (2016)’s labeling of Sweden
as LME-lite, obscure rather than illuminate how different institutions interact with the
opportunities of globalization and firms to produce very different pressures for or against
labor arbitrage.
advanced economies. Hall and Soskice (2001) and their academic antecedents were
concerned with institutional processes in wealthy capitalist systems, but they tended to use
less than rigorous definitions, such as OECD membership, which has included developing
countries such as Mexico and Turkey for quite some time. The past comparative capitalist
scholarship was concerned with studying wealthy countries that did not rely solely on
natural resources or serving as offshore banking hubs and thus they excluded oil/petrol-
dependent economies and offshore banking centers from their studies. However, beyond
economies is needed. Here we use Woo and colleagues’ (Woo et al 2012) definition of
advanced economies as those that have attained at least 60 percent of US GDP in purchasing
power parity (PPP) terms, but following along the lines of the previous comparative
Table 1 below lists the countries that meet these criteria, how we classify each economy’s
capitalist system and how other scholars have classified the same economies.
11
Manufacturing Discontent
Backlash
different incentives and capabilities to firms to deal with technological and economic
pressures from abroad. Our propositions follow the above-mentioned six institutional
spheres and are divided into two sub-propositions involving (a) non-firm actors and (b)
firms, respectively, because non-firm actors and firms both interact with institutions to
otherwise specified, all the firms and non-firm actors in the propositions below are from
relatively weak vocational training programs for secondary and tertiary students (Thelen
2001). In contrast, non-LMEs have generally put in place institutions that increase
firms to do so through institutions that lower the risk of poaching of trained workers by
competitors. Thus, some non-LMEs use extensive training programs for vocational
students sometimes in conjunction with industrial associations (e.g. Austria, Germany, and
12
Manufacturing Discontent
Switzerland), through active national public skills training (Sweden), or through in-house
educated workers for industry (Jackson & Deeg, 2012; Jackson & Sorge, 2012; Hall &
tend to have lower, more general skills that are transferable across employers, while non-
stronger firm-specific component, making them less transferable (Hall & Soskice, 2001).
that firms from the advanced world can utilize either internally by moving activities abroad or
goods and services sectors would feel the brunt of globalization (Kobrin, 2017) in a
not (Baccaro & Benassi, 2016). Thus, we formulate the following propositions:
At the firm level, the skills profiles of non-university-educated workers in the two
types of advanced economies also lead to the specialization of firms from these countries
in activities where these types of skills are most appropriate. Thus, firms from LMEs tend to
specialize in the mass production of tradable goods that can be standardized or R&D-
hand tend to utilize their respective training systems to train their non-university-educated
workers deeply in industry- or firm-specific skills (Thelen 2001). These skills develop in the
nexus of interactions between firms, industries and national training systems in these
national institutional contexts so are not so easily replicated in other countries (Sorge and
Streeck 2016, Thelen 2004 and De Massis et al. 2018). Non-LME firms, which have co-
evolved their own competencies to depend on the unique skill sets offered by their
respective training systems, will therefore find it harder to relocate their production to
Proposition 1b: The more the national and/or supra-firm-level training and education
university -educated workers from their home economy to compete rather than utilizing
backlash.
Inter-company relations
LME firms typically engage in arm’s-length, market-based transactions with other firms,
while firms in non-LMEs often produce a variety of stable, longer-term, and thus more
cooperative relationships. This is the case even among firms competing in the same
industry who coordinate their activities via unwritten ‘relational contracts’, for instance in
the areas of training and R&D, to pool resources and produce collective goods. In non-
LMEs more extensive formal cooperative relationships exist than in LMEs. Thus, non-
LME firms are typically interconnected through a dense network of shareholding ties and
board overlaps, although some of these ties have recently started to decline in some cases
14
Manufacturing Discontent
(Heemskerk & Schnyder, 2008; Höpner & Krempel, 2004). Such inter-company networks
provide the ‘social infrastructure’ for coordination amongst legally independent economic
units, shape corporate behaviors by allowing the diffusion of practices among firms, and
create a certain ‘shared business ethics’ among the business elite (Windolf, 2002; Mizruchi,
1996). Inter-company networks and relationships insulate companies to some extent from
Beyond Europe, in East Asia, both Korea and Japan have produced large business
groups spanning many sectors. These structures insulate group firms to some extent from
the full might of market forces (Gerlach and Lincoln 2004). Indeed, such relationships give
these firms a buffer from short-term pressures brought about by sudden technological
and other changes. In the face of globalization and firms creating competitive challenges via
labor arbitrage, the stable inter-company relations common in non-LMEs buffers non-LME
firms embedded in such stable inter-company structures from having to respond in the
short- term to these competitive pressures. Thus, firms in non-LMEs can forgo taking labor
arbitrage and have more time to seek out and develop new, viable upgrading strategies.
Proposition 2a: Long-term, stable inter-company relations buffer non-university-educated workers from
competition with developing economies’ labor because long-term, stable inter-company relations constrain
firms from taking labor arbitrage strategies. Thus, long-term, stable inter-company relations
Proposition 2b: Long-term, stable inter-company relations lower firms’ cost of adjustments to the external
market shock of competitors using workers in developing economies. As a result, in economies with stable
15
Manufacturing Discontent
inter-company relations, firms are more willing to adjust to competition from companies relying on workers from
developing economies via upgrading strategies, and therefore reduce the likelihood of backlash.
Comparative capitalism research has shown that labor markets in LMEs are less regulated
than in non-LMEs, and trade unions are much smaller, weaker, and fragmented in the
former too (Thelen 2001). This has often given raise to concerns about flexibility in heavily
regulated and/or unionized labor markets. Yet, more “rigid” labor markets have the
advantage of providing buffers for workers in tradable sectors from the economic
non-LMEs even help to better protect workers in non-tradable sectors. In other words,
these industrial relations systems tend to dampen the shock and burden of globalization
across society. For example, Carre and Tilly (2017) demonstrate that retail workers have
better pay and working conditions in a number of non-LMEs than they do in liberal market
Proposition 3a: The higher the level of unionization and/or labor market regulation, the more non-
university-educated workers will be protected from competition with developing economies’ workers,
2
Even non-LMEs that have recently liberalized their labor market institutions, still may provide higher
levels of buffering than LMEs. Thus, some non-LMEs have been able to create new flexicurity systems
where workers’ livelihoods are still protected but employment is flexible (e.g. Denmark).
16
Manufacturing Discontent
The non-LME labor market institutions described above do not only directly affect
workers by guaranteeing a certain level of income and social security, but also by
constraining firm’s strategic choices. There is therefore also an indirect, firm-level, channel
through which labor market institutions affect the likelihood of a backlash. Indeed, strong
unions and labor market regulations constrain companies’ strategic decisions regarding
labor market issues, such as mass layoffs and redundancies, because such actions either
cannot be taken in non-LMEs or they incur very high costs, such as paying the laid-off
workers higher portions of their salary for longer periods of time than in LMEs (Gospel
and Pendleton 2003). These stronger constraints make it therefore more difficult for firms in
non-LMEs to take advantage of the global economy by re-locating operations to low- wage
countries. These constraints may have negative impacts on firm profitability in the short-
run because they incur higher restructuring costs and/or labor costs, but essentially push
firms in non-LMEs to seek out viable upgrading strategies since pursuing labor arbitrage
strategies is either too costly in terms of pay-outs to laid-off workers and/or virtually
impossible due to rigid labor regulations in some non-LMEs. These strong industrial
relations and labor regulation institutional pressures on firms in non-LMEs thus provide
employment impacts from globalization than exist in LMEs. Therefore, we formulate the
Proposition 3b: The higher the level of unionization and/or labor market regulation, the lower the
likelihood that firms can take advantage of the opportunities of globalization via labor arbitrage strategies
17
Manufacturing Discontent
The comparative capitalism literature further distinguishes institutions that shape the ways
in which corporations are governed and financed. In particular, a long line of studies has
emphasized the difference between equity- and banked-based financial systems (cf
Zysman 1983).
LMEs tend to be equity finance-based systems where banks do not enter into long-
term relationships with client firms. In contrast, non-LMEs generally have less developed
equity and bond markets but have strong banking sectors that provide long-term finance to
based ones for firm growth (Beck et al., 2000; La Porta et al. 2008; see Armour et al., 2009
for a critical view). The key advantage of the equity finance-based system is considered to
be the fact that it pools large amounts of capital through small investments by
households and institutions and allows firms to minimize their capital costs by
maximizing their share prices (Beck et al., 2000). Moreover, equity-market based systems
generally have deeper venture capital markets, allowing start-up companies to easily access
whereby relationships between banks and firms are long-lasting. Thus, the time horizons
for return on investment can be elongated (patient capital) (Deeg et al., 2016). Also,
personal, long-term ties lower the cost of capital due to better (insider) information and
the possibility of relational monitoring by banks of their industrial clients (Khan 2000).
The differences in corporate governance and finance systems also have important
implications for corporate control and firm strategy. As a result of their reliance on equity
towards shareholders (Fainshmidt et al., 2016; Hall & Soskice, 2001; Weimer & Pape, 1999;
Shleifer & Vishny, 1997). Moreover, the absence of long-term patient capital providers in
LMEs makes ownership structures more fluid and also exposes firms to the threat of
hostile takeover. Indeed, in LMEs, firms themselves can become commodities in the so-
called ‘market for corporate control,’ which is seen as a key disciplinary corporate
value (see the classical statements by Manne, 1965; Jensen & Ruback, 1983). Non-LME
power. To the contrary, long-term bank finance and the existence of large, patient
blockholders have made external minority shareholder interests a secondary concern for
non-LME managers.
These differences in stakeholder power have implications for firm strategy vis-à-vis
workers. Institutionally reinforced capital market pressures incentivize LME firms often to
use layoffs as a first measure in a crisis to reduce costs, but keep up dividend payments
(Gospel & Pendleton, 2003). Conversely, patient capital allows firms in a bank-based
system to retain their workforce during times of crisis, sacrificing dividends and financial
Proposition 4a: The more bank-based the economy, the less power external shareholders can exert and the
more influence non-university-educated workers will exert on firms to protect domestic jobs and wages.
Thus, the more bank-based the economy is the lower the likelihood of backlash.
Proposition 4b: The more bank-based economy, the less power external shareholders can exert to
pressure firms to adopt labor arbitrage strategies and thus the lower the likelihood of backlash.
19
Manufacturing Discontent
Welfare systems
attention to state welfare systems. Yet, work preceding the Varieties of Capitalism approach
delineated three explicit welfare regimes in advanced economies; namely, the liberal
These systems are critical for understanding how some economies have coped better than
Kobrin cites Dobbs et al (2016) to the effect that 65-70% of households across twenty-
five advanced economies had real market incomes that were flat or had fallen over 2005-
2014. While this is an undisputed reality, the welfare state in many of these countries goes
far to supplement these market incomes, making falling or flat real incomes (relatively)
less of a problem for the poorest strata of society in some countries than in others. Thus,
to the globalization of labor markets in which they are forced to compete with lower
cost workers in developing economies are buffered from these costs of adjustment to the
extent that they live in states with more generous welfare systems (Anderson and
Pontusson, 2007). More generous welfare systems also provide better living conditions for
retirees and thereby lower the level of economic anxiety for retirees and soon-to-retire
Proposition 5: The larger the welfare state, the more individuals are protected from bearing the costs of
20
Manufacturing Discontent
State intervention
The state fulfills a variety of roles in organizing finance, labor, and even business
voluntary private organization with only a subsidiary role for the helping hand of
government (Sallai & Schnyder, 2019). Both in East Asia (Wade, 1990) and in certain
Western European countries (e.g. France and Italy) (Zysman, 1983), there have been
traditions of proactive state intervention in the economy. For our purpose, state intervention
in the global economy takes two main forms, trade policy and industrial policy.
In terms of trade policy, Kim (2010) argues that protection of agriculture via high
tariffs in advanced East Asian economies (Japan, Korea, and Taiwan) should be viewed as a
form of welfare policy for a disadvantaged group, farmers, and one that has widespread
legitimacy within East Asian societies. Similarly, Taiwan, despite being a wealthy economy,
was able to negotiate to retain a large tariff on automobiles (one higher than those in place in
Japan, the EU and North America) under WTO rules. While this protectionist barrier has not
allowed Taiwan to become an auto manufacturing powerhouse due to its small domestic
market (cf. Cunningham et al., 2005), it did protect three percent of Taiwan’s manufacturing
workforce from being displaced by trade as would have happened in LMEs with more liberal
trade policies. Critically, state intervention to protect against the costs of trade is
considered entirely legitimate by Taiwanese firms and the wider public. This consensus
Taiwan has often violated its WTO commitments without any substantial political fallout
at home. Taiwan’s ideological acceptance of state intervention to block many of the costs
of free trade is one shared with its wealthy Northeast Asian neighbors, Korea and Japan
(Fuller 2014).
21
Manufacturing Discontent
(including formal tariffs, non-tariff barriers, and regulations), which may affect economic
growth, but can also serve to shield certain sectors from competitive pressures. These
interventions have also strengthened many of the buffers that cushion the blows of
globalization.
Thus, we propose the following proposition about the impact of state intervention
Proposition 6a: The more the state intervenes in the economy via trade protection, the greater the
likelihood that non-university-educated workers will be less exposed to competition from developing
As in other institutional areas, state intervention also has a more indirect effect on
backlash via its impact on firm strategies. Firstly, protectionist trade policies reduce
competitive pressures on those firms who would otherwise have to compete with cheaper
imported goods. This reduces cost pressure on the firm, which in turn reduces their
intervene in the economy through industrial policy. These interventions have served to
encourage home country firms to enter new sectors and place the core activities of the
new ventures at home. In Taiwan, for example, state influence over the formal banking
sector still looms large and this state intervention has been directed at creating patient
capital for strategic sectors that Taiwan’s relatively weak business groups and bank-
firm linkages cannot provide (Fuller, 2007; Wong, 2011). In Korea, the state has provided
policy and financing for Korean chaebol to enter new sectors, such as green energy, while
centering the high value-added activities of these new sectors in Korea (Thurbon, 2016).
These industrial polices via creating high-value activities at home have helped deter de-
industrialization and provided profound socio-economic benefits for Korean workers (Kim
22
Manufacturing Discontent
and Kwon, 2017), making them less fearful of globalization. Based on these examples, we
propose:
Proposition 6b: The more the state intervenes in the economy via trade protection or industrial policy,
the greater the likelihood that firms will place their activities and concomitant employment inside the
Sectoral characteristics
There are five ideal-typical value chain governance structures that typify the organization
of modern industries: hierarchical, captive, relational, modular and market value chains
(Gereffi et al. 2005). Non-LME firms are more likely to eschew using modular and market
value chains, which are organized on the basis of weak ties and no ties respectively.
Moreover, non- LME firms have greater institutional support to foster and sustain
industrial organizations relying on either stronger ties (captive and relational value chains)
firms are more likely to embrace modular and market value chains. This difference in fit
with particular value chains is due to all of the comparative capitalist institutional spheres
except welfare systems and state intervention. LMEs favor modular and market value
chains because their lack of patient capital and quarterly demands for positive corporate
financial performance, educational and training systems favoring general skills, weak
inter-firm ties and cooperation, and weak unions either push them or allow them to
outsource value chain segments in which they underperform (Lane 2008; Fuller et al.
2003). Modular and market value chain governance in turn makes it much easier for firms
to engage in labor arbitrage because in these value chains there is extremely low
interchangeable while incurring minimal costs (Gereffi et al. 2005; Gereffi 2018). Thus,
we propose:
Proposition 7a: The less exposed non-university-educated workers are to modular and market
value chain sectors, the less likely they will be displaced by labor arbitrage strategies, and thus the
Proposition 7b: The less engaged firms are in sectors characterized by modular and market value
chain governance structures, the more costly it will be for such firms to use labor arbitrage
one of the institutional spheres, a key argument of the comparative capitalism literature is
that institutions do not just work in isolation but may deploy their effects in combination.
effects of these complimentary institutions are greater than the sum of their parts
(Amable, 2016; Crouch, 2005; Deeg and Jackson, 2008; Hall and Soskice, 2001). It is
therefore important to also consider the impact that the above-mentioned institutional
arrangements have in the aggregate because when working in concert they amplify the
with the result that these institutions' mutual reinforcement produces a stronger
institutional push to pursue the labor arbitrage route than the simple addition of one or
24
Manufacturing Discontent
configurations where there is sand thrown into the LME gearbox because some
institutions are not mutually reinforcing with other LME-like institutions, the result is
something quite far from LMEs' strong push for firms to pursue labor arbitrage. To
provide examples, Japan has adopted some LME-style reforms, but the system in other
employment, strong/rigid inter-firm supplier networks) so the economy has not moved
Taiwan has weak labor protections and strong equity markets that encourage labor
arbitrage, and yet due to government intervention and informal inter-firm networks, it
too has not coalesced around the heightened push for labor arbitrage strategies that
Correspondingly, there are mutually reinforcing institutions at the other end of the
comparative capitalism spectrum (what we term the pure non-LMEs). Here various
upgrade. Germany's Mittelstand firms are not explained simply by labor protections or
skills formation or financial arrangements, but how the combination of these institutions
leads to heightened incentives and capabilities to upgrade (De Massis et al., 2018).
Therefore, we propose:
Proposition 8a: The further an economy’s institutions are from the ideal-typical LME model of
institutions, the less non-university-educated workers will be exposed to competing with labor from
At the firm level, LME institutions imply that companies are more exposed to competition,
both domestic and international. Yet, they are also less constrained in their strategic choices,
25
Manufacturing Discontent
which allow them to take advantage of the opportunities afforded by globalization more
incentivize firms to pursue labor arbitrage strategy of relying on cheap, low-skilled workers
in other parts of the globe. Thus, financial market pressures and the threat of hostile
workers in LMEs are often not a valuable resource that the firm invested in, but a
LMEs combine to produce the exact opposite effect: Not only are firms less exposed to
pressure to increase profitability and reduce costs due to their embedding in long-term,
personal relationship both with capital providers and other firms, but they also rely on a
higher-skilled workforce, which they invest in and therefore often consider as a valuable asset
Proposition 8b: The further an economy’s institutions are from the ideal-typical LME model of
institutions, the less companies will be pressured/incentivized to pursue labor arbitrage strategies, and thus
The six institutional features directly influence the level of backlash within a given
advanced economy. They also indirectly affect the level of backlash by influencing value
chain specialization and by sometimes enhancing the effects of other institutional spheres
chain specialization and LME institutional complementarity (or its polar opposite) in turn
directly affect the level of backlash. Finally, the higher the level of backlash ceteris
paribus the higher the likelihood of policy reversal. The proposed causal pathways are
26
Manufacturing Discontent
When faced with populist backlash in their country of origin that threatens the liberal
market order and the trade ties that the country has with its partners, MNCs are likely to
strategically adapt to these new circumstances. In this section we thus shift the focus of
the analysis to firm-level strategic choices (post-backlash) - while the previous section
To be sure, the options available to MNCs facing backlash are constrained by the
same institutions that shaped their backlash-inducing strategic choices in the first place.
However, the strategic options selected below fit within an LME context associated with
comparative capitalism literature, that within any given institutional framework, firms
have some room for maneuver. In addition, we assume that the occurrence of anti-
globalization backlash will provide firms with incentives to explore the opportunities to
We assume that top managers of MNCs in the face of backlash increasingly accept
the reality of the costs of globalization in terms of job displacement and income inequality
(Kobrin, 2017). Based on this assumption, we focus on three types of strategic options
available to MNCs, each of which is tied to a different source of backlash: the strategic
choice between off-shoring and re-shoring, the strategic choices around firm capabilities,
responses can either aim at making the firm resilient to backlash by increasing its
legitimacy (Stevens et al., 2016), or can seek to address the actual “macro” sources of
backlash (such as the education and training system). In the former case, firms will adapt
27
Manufacturing Discontent
their market strategy to eschew practices that may lead to backlash and public blame of
individual firms. In the latter case, firms may resort to corporate political strategy to either
Re-shoring
productive activities to a firm’s home country. Given the negative impact borne by non-
may represent a suitable strategic response for firms facing backlash. Yet no study has, to
our knowledge, explored the causal links between backlash against globalization and re-
shoring strategies.
The usual factors for re-shoring, explored in a growing number of studies within
the management and business literature, include the erosion of cost advantages of
emerging economies, the underestimation of the full costs of offshoring, the need for
activities, the protection of intellectual property, and the need to reduce supply risk
The expectation raised by re-shoring is that it may help re-create jobs in home
countries. In the early 2010s, several studies by consulting firms, such as the Boston
Consulting Group for the US (in 2011 and 2013) or PricewaterhouseCoopers for the UK
(in 2014) estimated large gains for home economies in terms of job creations (see De
Backer et al., 2016). As such, managers may consider it a viable option to maintain or
28
Manufacturing Discontent
foreign operations.
rationale for the decision to re-shore part of its offshore operations to its home country
would likely lie in (a) the higher costs generated by backlash-induced policy reversal (for
instance, tariffs on key supplies or more stringent tax regulations on revenue generated
above) that may exceed the benefits of offshoring and (b) the higher uncertainty linked to
global operations, thus increasing the risks associated with global supply chains.
motivations behind the choice to relocate (see Fratocchi et al., 2015). Therefore, we would
expect that the potential costs added by backlash to the foreign operations of multinationals
backlash on firms’ strategic choices will be mediated by the government’s policy reaction
to the backlash. Backlash against globalization may provoke a mixed “sticks and carrots”
policy response by the government: the higher costs provoked by new tariffs and
tax- and regulatory incentives for multinationals to relocate part of their operations to their
home country. For instance, the current US administration recently adopted, on top of new
multinationals to export from the US rather than keep their production offshore (Davison
alleviating the pressures on home country labor markets. This is especially the case for
non-university educated workers - who are, in LMEs more exposed to world market
fluctuations and thus more prone to backlash. Re-shoring may also imbue individual
MNCs with higher public legitimacy in the face of backlash, thus potentially shielding
29
Manufacturing Discontent
them from the negative consequences of such backlash on their operations. Finally, re-
shoring may also lead MNCs to invest in longer-term, more stable inter-company networks
and relational value chains at home, which are another important factor influencing the
likelihood of backlash (see Propositions 2a, 2b, 7a and 7b in the previous section), because
these types of networked production are more viable in advanced economies in the face of
Beyond rethinking the question of where to locate production, a second strategic choice
for MNCs to revisit in the face of anti-global backlash in their home country is how to
produce i.e. what basic strategy and business model to adopt in different markets as part
of the firm’s global strategy. Scholars have long recognized that capability-exploiting
(Dunning, 2001; Makino et al., 2002) and capability-augmenting strategies are both
motivations for firms to operate abroad (Bartlett and Ghoshal, 1989; Dunning, 2001;
while in the former case the focus is on using home-grown capabilities in order to gain
competitive advantage in the foreign market, capability augmenting strategies are aimed
Lucea, & Vives, 2013). To be sure, such capability augmenting strategies do not
necessarily imply that they make workers better off in the home market. However, contrary
to capability exploiting strategies, they are more likely to change the company’s global
strategy in a way that provides home country workers with new opportunities. Thus, new
technological capabilities acquired abroad can lead to the development of new products
and even entirely new markets that provide more jobs in the home country. Lessard and
30
Manufacturing Discontent
his colleagues (2013) argue that Walmart’s capability enhancing strategy led it to discover
the success of small stores in its Latin American markets. As a result, it decided to
introduce similar Walmart-express stores in its home market the US to serve rural
communities. This provided low-skilled workers in the US with new opportunities and
employment that a capability exploitation strategy focused on foreign markets would not
provide.
pursued by MNCs, especially LME-based MNCs, are a primary source for anti-
globalization backlash. While labor arbitrage and capability exploitation are not
synonymous, the shift away from capability exploitation to capability augmentation may
offset the negative effects on non-university educated workers in MNCs’ home country of
– to shed modular and market value chain governance structures (a major source of
backlash - see Propositions 7a and 7b above), given the higher premium on the capabilities
applications of global strategy and how managers would react to such a shift in popular
generating knowledge (and other capabilities) (Ghemawat, 2007). Ghemawat argues that
these six strategies are the primary global strategies for MNCs to add value.
31
Manufacturing Discontent
In the face of backlash, the key problematic global strategy is decreasing costs,
because in the current era of globalization many of the opportunities to decrease cost
involve going the labor arbitrage route that further exacerbates backlash at home.
globalization. Other strategies appear to run much less of a political risk of exacerbating
because these strategies can be done without negatively impacting the firm’s domestic
workforce. Indeed, these strategies are more likely to be top-line enhancing as well as
bottom line-enhancing and can be executed without a ruthless quest for labor arbitrage.
Finally, normalizing risk itself demands that the firm try to pursue strategies that do not
So far, we have described the market strategies available to multinational companies faced
with backlash, taking for granted that a backlash would have negative consequences for
their operations or profits mainly because backlash will translate into actual policy
reversal. However, the latter does not necessarily ensue. Indeed, while a backlash against
globalization might directly harm a firm’s interests – through, for instance, damaging its
brand and provoking a drop in the firm’s share price – its negative consequences are often
backlash, the latter might have limited effects on the firm’s operations and profits. Higher
tariffs or regulatory restrictions are the typical policy outcomes of a backlash - made
possible once the backlash has been translated from the ballot box into concrete policy
reversals.
32
Manufacturing Discontent
because once a backlash occurs, firms may still be able to prevent such backlash from
turning into policy reversal. Firms can do this through non-market or political strategies,
which have now been widely acknowledged by the management and strategy literatures
(Baron, 1995; Shaffer, 1995; Hillman et al., 2004; Hadani, 2016; Mellahi et al. 2016). The
core idea behind non-market or corporate political strategies is simple: Confronted with
widespread uncertainty, firms are induced to seek to shape their environment in a way that
is more favorable to their interests by weighing in on the policies and regulations that (at
least in part) constitute that environment (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978; Hillman et al., 2009).
By doing so, firms may be able to improve both their performance and their public
legitimacy (Banerjee et al., 2018). Various instruments are available to that end: engaging
trade associations (Hadani, 2016). These instruments are used to obtain political access
and influence (Hillman and Hitt, 1999), which are then levered to the firm’s benefits
their large size and their exposure to foreign competition, two of the key drivers of
corporate political strategies identified in the literature (Lux et al., 2011). However, most
interaction with host countries (for instance, Hillman, 2003; Banerjee et al., 2008), while
home-country institutional determinants of CPS have seen less attention (White et al.,
2018; Schnyder & Sallai, 2019). To our knowledge, to date no study of backlash-induced
CPS in the home country has been conducted. Yet, it is well-established that firms can use
defensive or pro-active influence strategies to seek legislative changes that protect their
interests or create new opportunities (Oliver & Holzinger, 2008). From this perspective,
33
Manufacturing Discontent
individual MNCs or groups of MNCs may be effective in stopping or hindering the policy
(Culpepper, 2010). Faced with the possibility of new tariffs or a trade war, both instances
of what we call policy reversal following a backlash against globalization, firms may
could mention the sharp increase in “pro-trade” corporate lobbying in the US in the fall of
In this paper we argued that national institutions affect the likelihood of backlash against
Our framework opens up venues for future research. This framework obviously
needs refinement and empirical validation. In particular, the political systems in these
advanced economies are likely to add a further mediating factor to both the likelihood of
backlash and policy reversal (Culpepper, 2010; Lijphart, 1999). For example, one could
argue that Trump’s election thus far has not led to much true reversal of pro-globalization
policies other than the failure to enact further globalization-deepening policies (e.g. TPP).
However, the executive branch of the US government has many levers over trade policies
that the president can wield without permission from the legislative branch. Thus, it is likely
going forward that Trump will use presidential power to enact some reversals of pro-
globalization policies, such as the “trade war” with China and the multiple trade disputes with
erstwhile allies.
However, we hold the propositions in this paper to be valid first steps towards an
variation in the likelihood, the extent, and the consequences of a backlash against
across the advanced economies. Furthermore, future conceptual and empirical research
should explore the motivations and institutional factors behind backlash in developing
everywhere. In particular, the role of regional trade institutions, such as the ASEAN, EU,
constraining backlash and policy reversal is a critical topic to explore in future research.
the different types of capitalist systems, such as hierarchical market economies (Schneider,
Our paper’s main managerial implication centers on how firms in LMEs can try to
pursue politically sustainable globalization because our work suggests that the current
manner in which many firms in LMEs pursue globalization enhances risks of backlash and
ultimately policy reversal that would eventually constrain firms’ freedom to reap the
benefits of globalization. Beyond the firm-level strategic decisions laid out in the previous
section, what else can individual firms, even large and powerful ones, do to make their
acknowledges that such an upgrading strategy in the US is made much more difficult by the
lack of the type of supportive institutions for such engagement that are commonly found
in non-LMEs. Thus, a further implication is that firms could engage in political strategies
that seek to build such institutions that make upgrading strategies more feasible (less costly)
for individual firms. There is historical precedent for this type of endeavor because many
of the training and welfare institutions within continental Europe were driven in large part
35
Manufacturing Discontent
by demands and needs of capitalist entrepreneurs (Estevez-Abe et al., 2001). Our analysis
thus highlights a critical collective action problem facing firms in LMEs. Individually, firms
in LMEs have incentives to pursue a labor arbitrage strategy, but collectively firms would
suffer the costs of such strategies via anti-globalization policy reversal if many firms were to
36
Manufacturing Discontent
References
Aguilera, R.V., Flores R., & Kim J.U. (2015). Re-examining regional borders and the
Allen, M. (2004). The varieties of capitalism paradigm: not enough variety? Socio-Economic
Ancarani, A., Di Mauro, C., & Mascali, F. (2019). Backshoring strategy and the adoption
of Industry 4.0: Evidence from Europe. Journal of World Business (in press).
Anderson, C. J., &Pontusson, J. (2007). Workers, worries and welfare states: Social
Antonucci, L., Horvath L., Kutiyski ,Y., & Krouwei, A. (2017). The malaise of the squeezed
Armour, J., & Cumming, D. (2006). The legislative road to Silicon Valley. Oxford
Armour, J., Deakin, S., Lele, P., & Siems, M.M. (2009). How do legal rules evolve? Evidence
Autor, D., Dorn, D., & Hanson, G. (2013). The China syndrome: Local labor market
effects of import competition in the United States. American Economic Review, 103(6),
2121-2168.
Autor, D., Dorn, D., Hanson, G., & Majlesi, K. (2016). A note on the effect of rising trade
37
Manufacturing Discontent
Baccaro, L., & Benassi, C. (2017). Throwing out the ballast: growth models and the
Bailey, D., & De Propris, L. (2014). Manufacturing reshoring and its limits: the UK
automotive case. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 7(3), 379-
395.
Banerjee, S., Venaik, S., & Brewer, P. (2018). Analysing corporate political activity in
Baron, D.P. (1995). Integrated strategy: Market and nonmarket components. California
Bartlett, C., & Ghoshal, S. (1989). Managing across borders: the transnational solution.
Beck, T., Levine, R., Loayza, N. ( 2000). Finance and the sources of growth. Journal of
Breznitz, D. (2007). Innovation and the state. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A., Mudambi, R., & Pedersen, T. (2017). Globalization: rising skepticism.
Culpepper, P. ( 2010). Quiet politics and business power. Cambridge University Press:
Cambridge.
Cunningham, E., Lynch, T., &Thun, E. (2005). A tale of two sectors. Divergent paths in
Taiwan’s automotive industry. In S. Berger & R.K. Lester (Eds.) Global Taiwan:
Davison, L., & Gottlieb, I. (2019). Make-In-America Tax Break Not Enough to Spur
https://www.industryweek.com/leadership/made-america-tax-break-not-enough-
spur-reshoring-experts-say
De Backer, K., Menon, C., Desnoyers-James, I., & Moussiegt, L. (2016). Reshoring:
Myth or reality?. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers n.27.
De Massis, A., Audrestch, D., Uhlaner, L., & Kammerlander, N. (2018). Innovation with
Deeg, R., Hardie, I., &Maxfield, S. (2016). What is patient capital, and where does it exist?
Djelic, M.L., & Quack, S. (2003). Globalization and institutions: redefining the rules of the
Dobbs, R., Madgavkar, A., Manyika, J., Woetzel, J., Bughin, J., Labaye, E., & Kashyap, P.
(2016). Poorer than their parents? Flat or falling incomes in advanced economies. San
Eatwell, R., & Goodwin, M. J. (2018). National Populism. The Revolt against Liberal
Democracy. London: Pelican Books.
39
Manufacturing Discontent
Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. New York: John
Estes, C.L., & Phillipson, C. (2002). The globalization of capital, the welfare state, and old age
Fainshmidt, S., Judge, W.Q., Aguilera, R.V., & Smith, A. (2018). Varieties of institutional
53(3), 307-322.
Fratocchi, L., Di Mauro, C., Barbieri, P., Nassimbeni, G., & Zanoni, A. (2014). When
Fuller, D.B. (Ed). ( 2010). Innovation and the Limits of Laissez-Faire. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Fuller, D. B. (2014). ECFA’s empty promise and hollow threat. In J.P. Cabestan & J. deLisle
Fuller, D.B. (2016). Paper tigers, hidden dragons: firms and the political economy of
Fuller, D.B., Akinwande, A.I., & Sodini, C.G. (2003). Leading, following or cooked
University Press.
Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J., &Sturgeon, T. (2005). The governance of global value chains.
40
Manufacturing Discontent
Gerlach, M., & Lincoln, J. (2004). Japan’s Network economy: structure, persistence, and
Ghemawat, P. (2007). Redefining global strategy. Boston, MA: Harvard University Press.
Gospel, H., & Pendleton, A. (2003). Finance, corporate governance and the management
41(3), 557–582.
Gough, I. (2001). Globalization and regional welfare regimes: the East Asian case. Global
Hadani, M. (2016). Corporate political activity and public policy outcomes: New realities
and increasing challenges. In P. Harris and C.S. Fleischer (Eds.). The SAGE handbook
Hall, P.A., & Soskice, D. (2001). Varieties of capitalism: the institutional foundations
Heemskerk, E.M., & Schnyder, G. (2008). Small states, international pressures, and
Hillman, A.J., & Hitt, M.A. (1999). Corporate political strategy formulation: a model of
825–842.
Hillman, A.J., & Keim, G.D., & Schuler, D. (2004). Corporate political activity: A
Hillman, A.J., Withers, M.C., & Collins, B.J. (2009). Resource dependence theory: A
41
Manufacturing Discontent
Höpner, M., & Krempel, L. (2004). The politics of the German company network.
Hoskisson, R.E., Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., & Peng, M.W. (2013). Emerging
business systems and their explanatory power. Organization Studies, 35(5), 671-702.
Inglehart, R., & Norris, P. ( 2018). Trump and the xenophobic populist parties: the
diversity and its implications for international business. Journal of International Business
Jackson, G., & Deeg, R. (2012). The long-term trajectories of institutional change in
Jackson, G., & Sorge, A. (2012). The trajectory of institutional change in Germany, 1979–
Jensen, M.C., & Ruback, R.S. (1983). The market for corporate control: the scientific
Khan, M.H. (2000). Rents, efficiency and growth. In Rents, Rent-seeking and Economic
Development, Jomo KS, Khan MH (eds). Cambridge University Press: New York.
Kim, K.M., & Kwon, H.K. (2017). The State’s role in globalization: Korea’s experience
Kim, P.H. ( 2010). The East Asian welfare state debate and surrogate social policy: an
Kobrin, S.J. (2017). Bricks and mortar in a borderless world: globalization, the backlash, and
Kochan, T. ( 2017). “Shaping the future of work.” P resentation at the Watson Institute,
Kogut, B., & Zander, U. (1993). Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities and the
Kostova, T., Roth, K., & Dacin, M.T. (2008). Institutional theory in the study of
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 2008. The economic consequences of
Lessard, D., Lucea, R., & Vives, L. (2013). Building Your Company’s Capabilities
Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy: government forms and performance in thirty- six
43
Manufacturing Discontent
Lin, K.-H. (2016). The rise of finance and firm employment dynamics. Organization
Lux, S., Crook, T., & Woehr, D. (2011). Mixing business with politics: A meta-analysis
Makino, S., Lau, C.M., & Yeh, R.S. (2002). Asset-exploitation versus asset-seeking:
Implications for foreign direct investment choice from newly industrialized economies.
Manne, H.G. (1965). Mergers and the market for corporate control. Journal of Political
Mellahi, K., Frynas, J.G., Sun, P., & Siegel, D. (2016). A review of the nonmarket
42(1), 143-173.
Micklethwait, J., & Wooldridge, A. (2001). The globalization backlash. Foreign Policy, 126,
16-26.
Milanovic, B. (2016). Global inequality: a new approach for the age of globalization.
Mizruchi, M.S. (1996). What do interlocks do? an analysis , critique , and assessment of
Oldenski, L. (2015). Reshoring by US firms: what do the data say? Peterson Institute for
Oliver, C., & Holzinger, I. (2008). The effectiveness of strategic political management:
44
Manufacturing Discontent
Ornston, D. (2012). When small states make big leaps: Institutional innovation and high-tech
Peng, M.W., Sun, S.L., Pinkham, B.C., & Chen, H. (2009). The institution-based view as a
third leg for a strategy tripod. Academy of Management Perspectives, 23(4), 63-81.
Peng, M.W., Wang, D., & Jiang, Y. (2008). An institution-based view of international
Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G.R. (1978). The external control of organizations: A resource
Saka-Helmhout, A., Deeg, R., & Greenwood, R. (2016). The MNE as a challenge to
Schneider, B.R. (2012). Hierarchical capitalism in Latin America. Cambridge, MA: The MIT
Press.
Schneider, C.J. (2017). The political economy of regional integration. Annual Review of
comparative advantages from 1990 to 2005 : a test of the Hall and Soskice claims. Socio-
Schneider, M.R., Schulze-Bentrop, C., Paunescu, M. (2010). Mapping the institutional capital
Schnyder, G. (2012). Like a phoenix from the ashes ? Reassessing the transformation of the
Swedish political economy since the 1970s Journal of European Public Policy, 19(8),
1126–1145.
Schnyder, G., & Sallai, D. (2019). Between a Rock and a Hard Place: Developing
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3373607 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3373607
514.
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. (1997). A Survey of corporate governance. The Journal of
Sorge, A., & Streeck, W. (2016). Diversified quality production revisited: the
Sun, S.L., Peng, M.W., Lee, R.P., & Tan, W., (2015). Institutional open access at home and
Thelen, K. (2001). Varieties of labor politics in developed democracies. In Hall, P.A,, &
46
Manufacturing Discontent
Thelen, K. (2004). How institutions evolve: The political economy of skills in Germany,
Britain, the United States, and Japan. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Weimer, J., & Pape, J.C. (1999). A taxonomy of systems of corporate governance.
Whitle,y R. (1999). Divergent capitalisms: the social structuring and change of business
Windolf, P. (2002). Corporate networks in Europe and the United States. Oxford, UK:
778–806.
Woo, W.T., Lu, M., Sachs, J.D., & Chen, Z. (2012). A new economic growth engine for
C hina: escaping the middle-income trap by not doing more of the same. Singapore:
Zysman, J. (1983). Governments, markets and growth. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
47
Manufacturing Discontent
2003;
1987;
Tiberghien
2007; Vogel
Netherlands CME Non-LME, NA LME-lite Hybrid Culpepper
LME, LME 2010
Norway CME Hybrid, NA CME-lite Non-LME Höpner, 2007
Hybrid, Hybrid
New Zealand LME LME, LME, LME NA LME LME Höpner, 2007
Höpner, 2007
Taiwan NA NA Hierarchically NA Hybrid Breznitz 2007;
Coordinated Fuller 2007;
Wade 2004;
UK LME LME, LME, LME NA LME LME
USA LME LME, LME, LME NA LME LME
*Hall and Soskice (2001: p. 21) tentatively argue that certain Mediterranean countries share their own coherent type of capitalism, which they refer to as Mediterranean Market
Economies(MMEs).
**Based on Schneider and Paunescu’s Table 1 (p. 740) cluster analysis, the column takes the results for 1990, 1999 and 2005 and combines the state-dominated and CME categories as
constituting the Non-LME category in the column, the hybrid category from the original table remains the hybrid category and the LME and LME-like categories are listed as LMEs. Each
country entry has three separate categories in chronological order for 1990, 1999 and 2005.
***Fainschmidt et al. (2016) argue that Hierarchically Coordinated economies feature a modicum of labor coordination but substantial indirect state intervention via their developmental
states so we consider the Hierarchically Coordinated category a form of non-LMEs. We left their category of Emergent LME as is.
Note: The calculations of GDP PPP per capita were made for 2007 and 2016 using World Bank data as well as data from Taiwan’s statistical agency for
Taiwan. Two years were used because PPP calculations can vary widely, especially over time. Countries with populations of less than one million
people were also excluded. The economic calculations led to the inclusion of important, but all too often ignored East Asian cases, such as Singapore and
48
Manufacturing Discontent
Taiwan.
49
Manufacturing Discontent
Proposition 5 Welfare state Small in coverage and stingy Generous and extensive
Proposition 7 Sectoral Focus on market and modular Focus on relational, captive and
specialization value chains hierarchical value chains
50
Manufacturing Discontent
View publication stats
51