The European Sovereign Debt Crisis: Philip R. Lane
The European Sovereign Debt Crisis: Philip R. Lane
Philip R. Lane
T
he capacity of the euro-member countries to withstand negative macroeco-
nomic and financial shocks was identified as a major challenge for the success
of the euro from the beginning (in this journal, for example, see Feldstein
1997; Wyplosz 1997; Lane 2006). By switching off the option for national currency
devaluations, a traditional adjustment mechanism between national economies was
eliminated. Moreover, the euro area did not match the design of the “dollar union”
of the United States in key respects, since the monetary union was not accompa-
nied by a significant degree of banking union or fiscal union. Rather, it was deemed
feasible to retain national responsibility for financial regulation and fiscal policy.
On the one side, the ability of national governments to borrow in a common
currency poses obvious free-rider problems if there are strong incentives to bail out
a country that borrows excessively (Buiter, Corsetti, and Roubini 1993; Beetsma and
Uhlig 1999). The original design of the euro sought to address the over-borrowing
incentive problem in two ways. First, the Stability and Growth Pact set (somewhat
arbitrary) limits on the size of annual budget deficits at 3 percent of GDP and the
stock of public debt of 60 percent of GDP. Second, the rules included a “no bailout”
clause, with the implication that a sovereign default would occur if a national
government failed to meet its debt obligations.
On the other side, the elimination of national currencies meant that national
fiscal policies took on additional importance as a tool for countercyclical macroeco-
nomic policy (Wyplosz 1997; Gali and Monacelli 2008; Gali 2010). Moreover, since
Public debt for the aggregate euro area did not, at least at first glance,
appear to be a looming problem in the mid 2000s. During the previous decade, the
euro area and the United States shared broadly similar debt dynamics. For example,
the ratio of gross public debt to GDP in 1995 was about 60 percent for the United
States and 70 percent for the set of countries that would later form the euro area,
based on my calculations with data from the IMF Public Debt Database. In both the
United States and the euro area, the debt/GDP ratios declined in the late 1990s, but
had returned to mid 1990s levels by 2007. The debt/GDP ratios then climbed during
the crisis, growing more quickly for the United States than for the euro area.1
However, the aggregate European data mask considerable variation at the indi-
vidual country level. Figure 1 shows the evolution of public debt ratios for seven key
euro area countries over 1982–2011. These countries were chosen because Germany,
France, Italy, and Spain are the four largest member economies, while the fiscal
crisis so far has been most severe in Greece, Ireland, and Portugal (of course, Italy
1
For a detailed country-by-country breakdown of the evolution of public sector debt across these seven
countries from 1992–2011, see the Appendix available online with this paper at 〈http://e-jep.org⟩.
Philip R. Lane 51
Figure 1
The Evolution of Public Debt, 1982–2011
165
France
150 Germany
Italy
135 Greece
Ireland
120 Portugal
Public debt (ratio to GDP)
Spain
105
90
75
60
45
30
15
1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2011
and Spain have also been flagged as fiscally vulnerable countries during the crisis).
Clearly, these countries have quite different debt histories.
In one group, both Italy and Greece had debt/GDP ratios above 90 percent
since the early 1990s; these countries never achieved the 60 percent debt/GDP limit
specified in the European fiscal rules. Ireland, Portugal, and Spain each achieved
significant declines in debt ratios in the second half of the 1990s, dipping below
the 60 percent ceiling. While the Portuguese debt ratio began to climb from 2000
onwards, rapid output growth in Ireland and Spain contributed to sizable reductions
in debt–output ratios up to 2007. Finally, France and Germany had stable debt/GDP
ratios at around 60 percent in the decade prior to the onset of the crisis; indeed,
their debt ratios were far above the corresponding values for Ireland and Spain
during 2002–2007. Thus, circa 2007, sovereign debt levels were elevated for Greece
and Italy, and the trend for Portugal was also worrisome, but the fiscal positions of
Ireland and Spain looked relatively healthy. Moreover, the low spreads on sovereign
debt also indicated that markets did not expect substantial default risk and certainly
not a fiscal crisis of the scale that could engulf the euro system as a whole.
However, with the benefit of hindsight, 1999 –2007 looks like a period in which
good growth performance and a benign financial environment masked the accumu-
lation of an array of macroeconomic, financial, and fiscal vulnerabilities (Wyplosz
2006; Caruana and Avdjiev 2012).
52 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Table 1
Private Credit Dynamics
Table 2
Current Account Balances
(percent of GDP)
The credit boom in this period was not primarily due to government
borrowing. For Ireland and Spain, the government was not a net borrower
during 2003 –2007. Rather, households were the primary borrowers in Ireland
and corporations in Spain, with the property boom fueling debt accumulation in
both countries. In Portugal and Greece, the government and corporations were
both significant borrowers, but these negative flows were partly offset during this
period by significant net accumulation of financial assets by the household sector
in these countries.
August 2007 marked the first phase of the global financial crisis, with the initia-
tion of liquidity operations by the European Central Bank. The high exposure of
major European banks to losses in the U.S. market in asset-backed securities has been
well documented, as has the dependence of these banks on U.S. money markets as a
source of dollar finance (McGuire and von Peter 2009; Acharya and Schnabl 2010;
Shin 2012). The global crisis entered a more acute phase in September 2008 with
the collapse of Lehman Brothers. The severe global financial crisis in late 2008 and
early 2009 shook Europe as much as the United States.
gave some comfort that these countries could absorb the likely fiscal costs associated
with a medium-size banking crisis. Demand for sovereign debt of euro area coun-
tries was also propped up by banks that valued government bonds as highly rated
collateral in obtaining short-term loans from the European Central Bank (Buiter
and Sibert 2006).
In late 2009, the European sovereign debt crisis entered a new phase. Late that
year, a number of countries reported larger-than-expected increases in deficit/GDP
ratios. For example, fiscal revenues in Ireland and Spain fell much more quickly than
GDP, as a result of the high sensitivity of tax revenues to declines in construction
activity and asset prices. In addition, the scale of the recession and rising estimates
of prospective banking-sector losses on bad loans in a number of countries also had
a negative indirect impact on sovereign bond values, since investors recognized that
a deteriorating banking sector posed fiscal risks (Mody and Sandri 2012).
However, the most shocking news originated in Greece. After the general
election in October 2009, the new government announced a revised 2009 budget
deficit forecast of 12.7 percent of GDP—more than double the previous estimate
of 6.0 percent.2 In addition, the Greek fiscal accounts for previous years were also
revised to show significantly larger deficits. This revelation of extreme violation of
the euro’s fiscal rules on the part of Greece also shaped an influential political
narrative of the crisis, which laid the primary blame on the fiscal irresponsibility of
the peripheral nations, even though the underlying financial and macroeconomic
imbalances were more important factors.
These adverse developments were reflected in rising spreads on sovereign
bonds. For example, the annual spread on ten-year sovereign bond yields between
Germany and countries such as Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Spain, and Italy was close
to zero before the crisis. Remember that sovereign debts from these countries are
all denominated in a common currency, the euro, so differences in expected yield
mainly represent perceived credit risks and differences in volatility.
Figure 2 shows the behavior of country-level ten-year bond yields for seven euro
area countries from October 2009 through June 2012. Three particularly problem-
atic periods stand out. First, the Greek yield began to diverge from the group in
early 2010, with Greece requiring official assistance in May 2010. Second, there
was strong comovement between the Irish and Portuguese yields during 2010 and
the first half of 2011 (Ireland was next to require a bailout in November 2010, with
Portugal following in May 2011). Third, the yields on Italy and Spain have moved
together, with these spreads at an intermediate level between the bailed out coun-
tries and the core countries of Germany and France. For Italy and Spain, the spread
against Germany rose above 300 basis points in July 2011 and remained at elevated
levels thereafter. In 2011, a visible spread also emerges between the French and
2
See also Gibson, Hall, and Tavlas (2012). These authors also point out that the Greek announcement
was coincidentally soon followed by the surprise request from Dubai World for a debt moratorium, such
that the climate in international debt markets markedly deteriorated in October/November 2009.
The European Sovereign Debt Crisis 57
Figure 2
Yields on Ten-Year Sovereign Bonds, October 2009 to June 2012
(percent)
50
France
Germany
Greece
Ireland
40
Italy
Portugal
Ten-year bond yield (percent)
Spain
30
20
10
0
01
01
01
01
01
/1
/0
/0
/0
/0
0/
1/
1/
1/
7/
20
20
20
20
20
09
10
11
12
German yields, although the greater relative vulnerability of France is not pursued
in this paper.
Union was the major provider of funding. At that time, it was also decided to set
up a temporary European Financial Stability Facility that could issue bonds on the
basis of guarantees from the member states in order to provide official funding in
any future crises. In addition, the pre-existing European Stability Mechanism, which
had previously only been used for balance-of-payments foreign currency support for
non–euro member countries, was adapted to also provide funding for euro member
countries.
In principle, a temporary period of official funding can benefit all parties. For
the borrower, it can provide an opportunity for a government to take the typically
unpopular measures necessary to put public finances on a trajectory that converges
on a sustainable medium-term path, while also implementing structural reforms
that can boost the level of potential output. For the lender, avoiding default can
benefit their creditor institutions (especially banks), while guarding against possible
negative international spillovers from a default.
The details of the funding plans for Greece, Ireland, and Portugal largely
copied standard IMF practices, but they faced a number of potential problems.
Here are six issues, in no particular order.
First, given the scale of macroeconomic, financial, and fiscal imbalances, the
plausible time scale for macroeconomic adjustment was longer than the standard
three-year term of such deals. In particular, fiscal austerity by individual member
countries cannot be counterbalanced by a currency devaluation or an easing in
monetary conditions, which is especially costly if a country has to simultaneously
close both fiscal and external deficits. By June 2011, it was clear that Greece would
need a second package, while it is also likely that Ireland and Portugal will not be
able to obtain full market funding after the expiry of their current deals. The slow
pace of adjustment was also recognized in Summer 2011 through the extension of
the repayment period on the official debt from 7.5 years to 15 –30 years.
Second, in related fashion, excessively rapid fiscal consolidation can exacerbate
weaknesses in the banking system. Falling output and a rising tax burden shrinks
household disposable income and corporate profits, increasing private sector
default risk. This was identified as an especially strong risk in the Irish program in
view of the scale of household debt.
Third, the fiscal targets were not conditional on the state of the wider European
economy. As growth projections for the wider European economy declined throughout
2011, the country-specific targets looked unobtainable for external reasons.
Fourth, the original bailouts included a sizable penalty premium of 300 basis
points built into the interest rate, which is standard IMF practice. A penalty rate
discourages countries from the moral hazard of taking such loans when not really
needed and also compensates the funders for the nontrivial default risk. However,
it also makes repaying the loans harder and gives an appearance that the creditor
EU countries are profiteering at the expense of the bailed-out countries. This
penalty premium on the European component of the official loans was eliminated
in July 2011, although the interest rate on the IMF-sourced component of the funds
continued to include a penalty premium.
Philip R. Lane 59
Fifth, the bailout funds have been used to recapitalize banking systems, in
addition to covering the “regular” fiscal deficits. So far, this element has been most
important in the Irish bailout, but it was also a feature of the Greek and Portuguese
bailouts; it is also the primary element in the official funding requested by Spain in
June 2012. While publicly funded recapitalization of troubled banks can ameliorate
a banking crisis, this strategy is problematic if it raises public debt and sovereign risk
to an excessive level (Acharya, Drechsler, and Schnabl 2010). Moreover, excessive
levels of sovereign debt can amplify a banking crisis for several reasons: domestic
banks typically hold domestic sovereign bonds; a sovereign debt crisis portends
additional private sector loan losses for banks; and a highly indebted government is
likely to lean on banks to provide additional funding (Reinhart and Sbrancia 2011).
Furthermore, the generally poor health of major European banks and the cross-
border nature of financial stability inside a monetary union means that national
governments are under international pressure to rescue failing banks in order to
avoid the cross-border contagion risks from imposing losses on bank creditors.3
Despite these international externalities, at least until mid 2012, the only type of
European funding for bank rescues was plain-vanilla official loans to the national
sovereign, with fixed repayment terms. Under this approach, the fates of national
sovereigns and national banking systems remain closely intertwined.
The sixth issue involves a standard IMF principle that funding is only provided
if the sovereign debt level is considered to be sustainable. If it is not sustainable, the
traditional IMF practice has been to require private sector creditors to agree to a
reduction in the present value of the debt owed to them. Under the joint EU– IMF
programs, such “private sector involvement” was not initially deemed necessary in
the three bailouts of 2010 and 2011.
The argument against requiring private sector involvement is that it can spook
an already nervous sovereign debt market. For example, when the prospect of
requiring private sector involvement was broached in October 2010 (in the Franco-
German “Deauville Declaration”), interest rate spreads immediately increased,
especially for Greece, Ireland, and Portugal. Ireland’s efforts to avoid a bailout came
to a halt soon thereafter in early November 2010. European banks also had increased
difficulties in raising funds, especially the local banks in the troubled periphery, in
line with the increase in the perceived riskiness of their home governments.
The March 2012 agreement to provide Greece with a second bailout package
did require that private sector creditors accept a haircut, which eventually turned
out to be about 50 percent of value, which is equal to 47 percent of Greek GDP.4 But
3
The poor design of European bank resolution regimes has also increased the fiscal cost of rescuing
banks, since it is difficult to shut down failing banks and impose losses on holders of the senior bonds
issued by banks.
4
Although the plausibility of this projection has been disputed by many commentators, the second
bailout package is officially projected to deliver a Greek debt/GDP ratio of 120 percent by 2020, which
is a shade above the debt ratios of the some of the other troubled euro member countries. See also
Ardagna and Caselli (2012) for an account of the Greek crisis.
60 Journal of Economic Perspectives
as this requirement was discussed during the course of 2011, it contributed to the
sharp widening of the spreads on Spanish and Italian debt.
Listing some of the difficulties in this way may make the European response to
its sovereign debt issues appear more coherent than it has actually been. Instead, it
may be fair to characterize Europe’s efforts to address its sovereign debt problem as
makeshift and chaotic, at least through the middle of 2012.
one level, it could increase the firepower of the European Stability Mechanism by
allowing it to borrow from the ECB. Going further, the ECB could announce a
ceiling to the interest rate it would tolerate on the sovereign debt of countries that
meet certain fiscal criteria (such as taking credible steps to ensure debt declines
to a safe level over the medium term), and guarantee to buy the debt at that price
if needed.
Even more controversially, outright debt monetization might be viewed in some
quarters as preferable to outright default by large member countries if it becomes
clear that solvency concerns are so great that market funding will not be available for
an extended period. While debt monetization exceeds the current legal mandate
of the European Central Bank, debate over these proposals might heat up if a more
acute and severe phase of the crisis were to take hold. At least for now, it is hard
to envisage that such a change would be supported by all member countries of the
euro area. However, it is also important to appreciate that the reserve capacity to
monetize debt is commonly cited as the reason why highly indebted governments
such as Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States are still able to borrow
at low interest rates.
The legacy of the euro area sovereign debt crisis is that a number of countries
will have dangerously elevated public debt ratios, while others will have debt levels
that are lower by comparison but still high relative to long-term normal values. Even
if current austerity programs are sufficient to stabilize debt ratios, there remains
the post-crisis adjustment challenge of gradually reducing government debt to safer
levels. This medium-term challenge is viewed with trepidation in European circles.
Consider four reasons why the underlying fundamentals for reducing the debt/
GDP ratio are not promising.
First, growth in nominal GDP is likely to be low. Debt/GDP ratios are stickier
in high-income countries than in emerging economies in part because there is less
scope for rapid output growth in the former group of countries. There is nothing to
suggest that real growth rates for advanced economies should exceed a long-term
annual average of about 2 percent. Indeed, real annual growth of 2 percent may be
optimistic given several factors: the erosion of human capital from the prolonged
unemployment of the last few years (DeLong and Summers 2012); the likelihood
of tax increases and reduced public investment; and the historical pattern that
output growth can be compromised for a decade in the aftermath of a banking
crisis (Reinhart and Rogoff 2010). For the most-indebted countries, nominal GDP
is unlikely to grow much faster than real GDP. The European Central Bank has
a 2 percent aggregate inflation target (approximately), and the most indebted
member countries are likely to have average inflation substantially below that level
in view of the correlation between domestic demand and the price level of nontrad-
ables (Lane and Milesi-Ferretti 2004).
62 Journal of Economic Perspectives
The high outstanding sovereign debt levels and the importance of avoiding
future fiscal crises in the euro area have induced reforms to the fiscal rules for the
euro area, with a new Fiscal Compact Treaty that is scheduled to go into effect at
the start of 2013 (if it is ratified by 12 members of the euro area by then). The Fiscal
Compact requires that the new fiscal principles be embedded in each country’s
national legislation. These fiscal governance reforms are based on two principles:
first, high public debt levels pose a threat to fiscal stability; and, second, the fiscal
balance should be close to zero “over the cycle.”
The operation of the pre-crisis fiscal rules focused on the overall budget
balance, with a maximum annual budget deficit set at 3 percent of GDP, while
there was no strong pressure on highly indebted countries (such as Greece and
Italy) to reduce debt levels below the specified 60 percent ceiling. Even on its own
terms, this approach had two main defects: it did not adequately allow for cyclical
variation in budget positions, and it did not provide much discipline for countries
inside the limit.
In contrast, the new system focuses on the structural budget balance, thus
stripping out cyclical effects and one-off items. A structural budget balance
Philip R. Lane 63
5
A temporary type of eurobond has been suggested by the German Council of Economic Experts
(Bofinger, Feld, Franz, Schmidt, and Weder di Mauro 2011). Under this proposal, a jointly-backed Debt
Redemption Fund would refinance the excess debt above 60 percent of GDP, thereby relieving the roll-
over pressures facing highly-indebted countries. Once debt levels fall back to the 60 percent ceiling, the
Debt Redemption Fund would be wound up.
The European Sovereign Debt Crisis 65
■ I thank Michael Curran, Michael O’Grady, and Clemens Struck for diligent research
assistance. I am grateful to my fellow members of the euro-nomics group for many insightful
discussions of the euro crisis and Claudio Borio, Giancarlo Corsetti, Jordi Gali, Paolo Mauro,
Ashoka Mody, Maury Obstfeld, and the JEP editors for helpful suggestions.
References
Acharya, Viral V., and Philipp Schnabl. 2010. Performance Special Paper No. 25, London
“Do Global Banks Spread Global Imbalances? The School of Economics.
Case of Asset-Backed Commercial Paper during Beetsma, Roel, and Harald Uhlig. 1999. “An
the Financial Crisis of 2007–09.” IMF Economic Analysis of the Stability and Growth Pact.” Economic
Review 58(1): 37–73. Journal 109(458): 546–71.
Acharya, Viral V., Itamar Drechsler, and Philipp Benetrix, Agustin, and Philip R. Lane. 2012.
Schnabl. 2010. “A Pyrrhic Victory? Bank Bailouts “Fiscal Cyclicality and EMU.” Unpublished paper,
and Sovereign Credit Risk.” CEPR Discussion Paper Trinity College Dublin.
8679. Blanchard, Olivier. 2007. “Current Account
Allen, Franklin, Thorsten Beck, Elena Carletti, Deficits in Rich Countries.” IMF Staff Papers 54(2):
Philip R. Lane, Dirk Schoenmaker, and Wolf 191–219.
Wagner. 2011. Cross-Border Banking in Europe: Blanchard, Olivier, and Francesco Giavazzi.
Implications for Financial Stability and Macroeconomic 2002. “Current Account Deficits in the Euro
Policies. CEPR Report. Center for Economic Policy Area: The End of the Feldstein–Horioka Puzzle?”
Research. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 2, pp.
Ardagna, Silvia, and Francesco Caselli. 2012. 147–86.
“The Political Economy of the Greek Debt Crisis: Bofinger, Peter, Lars P. Feld, Wolfgang Franz,
A Tale of Two Bailouts.” Centre for Economic Christoph M. Schmidt, and Beatrice Weder di
66 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. to be Joined at the Hip.” Economic Policy 27(70):
2004. “The Transfer Problem Revisited: Real 199–230.
Exchange Rates and Net Foreign Assets.” Review of Muellbauer, John. 2011. “Resolving the Euro-
Economics and Statistics 86(4): 841–57. zone Crisis: Time for Conditional Eurobonds.”
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. CEPR Policy Insight No. 59.
2007. “Europe and Global Imbalances.” Economic Philippon, Thomas, and Christian Hellwig. 2011/
Policy 22(51): 519–73. “Eurobills, Not Eurobonds.” VoxEU, December 2.
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. http://www.voxeu.org/article/eurobills-not-euro
2011. “The Cross-Country Incidence of the Global -bonds.
Crisis.” IMF Economic Review 39(1): 77–110. Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff.
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. 2009. This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Finan-
Forthcoming. “External Adjustment and the cial Folly. Princeton University Press.
Global Crisis.” Journal of International Economics. Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff.
Lane, Philip R., and Barbara Pels. 2012. 2010. “Growth in a Time of Debt.” American
“Current Account Imbalances in Europe.” Moneda Economic Review 100(2): 573–78.
y Credito, forthcoming. Reinhart, Carmen M., and M. Belen Sbrancia.
Lane, Philip R., and Peter McQuade. 2012. 2011. “The Liquidation of Government Debt.”
“Domestic Credit Growth and International NBER Working Paper 16893.
Capital Flows.” Unpublished paper, Trinity College Sargent, Thomas J. 2012. “United States Then,
Dublin. Europe Now.” Journal of Political Economy 120(1):
Marzinotto, Benedicta, Andre Sapir, and 1–40.
Guntram B. Wolff. 2011. “What Kind of Fiscal Shambaugh, Jay. 2012. “The Euro’s Three
Union?” Bruegel Policy Brief No. 2011/06. Crises.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
McGuire, Patrick, and Goetz von Peter. 2009. forthcoming.
“The US Dollar Shortage in Global Banking and Shin, Hyun Song. 2012. “Global Banking Glut
the International Policy Response.” BIS Working and Loan Risk Premium.” IMF Economic Review,
Paper No. 291. forthcoming.
Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, and Cedric Tille. Wyplosz, Charles. 1997. “EMU: Why and How
2011. “The Great Retrenchment: International It Might Happen.” Journal of Economic Perspectives
Capital Flows during the Global Financial Crisis.” 11(4): 3–22.
Economic Policy 26(66): 285–342. Wyplosz, Charles. 2006. “European Monetary
Mody, Ashoka, and Damiano Sandri. 2012. “The Union: The Dark Sides of a Major Success.”
Eurozone Crisis: How Banks and Sovereigns Came Economic Policy 21(46): 207–261.
68 Journal of Economic Perspectives
This article has been cited by:
1. Martin Eling, Philipp Schaper. 2017. Under pressure: how the business environment affects
productivity and efficiency of European life insurance companies. European Journal of Operational
Research 258:3, 1082-1094. [CrossRef]
2. Myeong Hyeon Kim, Lingxia Sun. 2017. Dynamic conditional correlations between Chinese sector
returns and the S&P 500 index: An interpretation based on investment shocks. International Review
of Economics & Finance 48, 309-325. [CrossRef]
3. Marta Degl'Innocenti, Stavros A. Kourtzidis, Zeljko Sevic, Nickolaos G. Tzeremes. 2017. Bank
productivity growth and convergence in the European Union during the financial crisis. Journal of
Banking & Finance 75, 184-199. [CrossRef]
4. Tero Kuusi. 2017. Does the Structural Budget Balance Guide Fiscal Policy Pro-Cyclically? Evidence
from the Finnish Great Depression of the 1990s. National Institute Economic Review 239:1, R14-
R31. [CrossRef]
5. Raouf Boucekkine, Kazuo Nishimura, Alain Venditti. 2017. Introduction to international financial
markets and banking systems crises. Journal of Mathematical Economics 68, 87-91. [CrossRef]
6. Jin Cheng, Meixing Dai, Frédéric Dufourt. 2017. Banking and sovereign debt crises in a monetary
union without central bank intervention. Journal of Mathematical Economics 68, 142-151. [CrossRef]
7. Massimo Guidolin, Manuela Pedio. 2017. Identifying and measuring the contagion channels at work
in the European financial crises. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money
. [CrossRef]
8. Leonardo MorlinoWirtschaftskrise und Demokratie: Eine Wirkungsanalyse 447-465. [CrossRef]
9. Alyssa Schneebaum, Miriam Rehm, Katharina Mader, Katarina Hollan. 2016. The Gender Wealth
Gap Across European Countries. Review of Income and Wealth . [CrossRef]
10. Petre Caraiani. 2016. Business Cycle Accounting for Peripheral European Economies. Scottish Journal
of Political Economy 63:5, 468-496. [CrossRef]
11. Param Silvapulle, Jean Pierre Fenech, Alice Thomas, Rob Brooks. 2016. Determinants of sovereign
bond yield spreads and contagion in the peripheral EU countries. Economic Modelling 58, 83-92.
[CrossRef]
12. Mario Coccia. 2016. Asymmetric paths of public debts and of general government deficits across
countries within and outside the European monetary unification and economic policy of debt
dissolution. The Journal of Economic Asymmetries . [CrossRef]
13. Leonardo Morlino, Mario Quaranta. 2016. What is the impact of the economic crisis on democracy?
Evidence from Europe. International Political Science Review 37:5, 618-633. [CrossRef]
14. Monica Billio, Roberto Casarin, Michele Costola, Andrea Pasqualini. 2016. An entropy-based early
warning indicator for systemic risk. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money
45, 42-59. [CrossRef]
15. David Matesanz Gomez, Hernan J. Ferrari, Benno Torgler, Guillermo J. Ortega. 2016. Synchronization
and diversity in business cycles: a network analysis of the European Union. Applied Economics 1-15.
[CrossRef]
16. Kae-Yih Tzeng, Joseph Chang Pying Shieh. 2016. The transmission from equity markets to
commodity markets in crises periods. Applied Economics 48:48, 4666-4689. [CrossRef]
17. Raul Caruso, Marco Di Domizio. 2016. Military spending and budget deficits: the impact of
US military spending on public debt in Europe (1988–2013). Defence and Peace Economics 1-16.
[CrossRef]
18. Roberto Censolo, Caterina Colombo. 2016. The impact of the crisis on fiscal convergence in the EU:
the early signs. Journal of European Integration 38:6, 703-717. [CrossRef]
19. David Hope. 2016. Estimating the effect of the EMU on current account balances: A synthetic control
approach. European Journal of Political Economy 44, 20-40. [CrossRef]
20. Andrew Glencross. 2016. The European Council and the legitimacy paradox of new
intergovernmentalism: constitutional agency meets politicisation. Journal of European Integration 38:5,
497-509. [CrossRef]
21. Ulla Pape, Rafael Chaves-Ávila, Joachim Benedikt Pahl, Francesca Petrella, Bartosz Pieliński, Teresa
Savall-Morera. 2016. Working under pressure: economic recession and third sector development in
Europe. International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy 36:7/8, 547-566. [CrossRef]
22. George S. Atsalakis, Eftychios E. Protopapadakis, Kimon P. Valavanis. 2016. Stock trend forecasting in
turbulent market periods using neuro-fuzzy systems. Operational Research 16:2, 245-269. [CrossRef]
23. Benedetta Bianchi. 2016. Sovereign Risk Premia and the International Balance Sheet: Lessons from
the European Crisis. Open Economies Review 27:3, 471-493. [CrossRef]
24. Alice Albonico, Alessia Paccagnini, Patrizio Tirelli. 2016. In search of the Euro area fiscal stance.
Journal of Empirical Finance . [CrossRef]
25. Paul A. Grout, Anna Zalewska. 2016. Stock market risk in the financial crisis. International Review
of Financial Analysis 46, 326-345. [CrossRef]
26. Tiago Cardao-Pito, Diogo Baptista. 2016. Portugal’s banking and financial crises: unexpected
consequences of monetary integration?. Journal of Economic Policy Reform 1-27. [CrossRef]
27. Kim Abildgren. 2016. Household micro-data, regulation and financial stability: the case of Denmark
in the 1950s. Studies in Economics and Finance 33:2, 320-335. [CrossRef]
28. Bodo Herzog. 2016. Modelling Monetary and Fiscal Governance in the Wake of the Sovereign Debt
Crisis in Europe. Economies 4:2, 9. [CrossRef]
29. Matias Cabrera, Gerald P. Dwyer, Margarita Samartín-Saénz. 2016. Government finances and bank
bailouts: Evidence from European stock markets. Journal of Empirical Finance . [CrossRef]
30. Ivo J.M. Arnold, Beau Soederhuizen. 2016. Internal or external devaluation? What does the EC
Consumer Survey tell us about macroeconomic adjustment in the Euro area?. Journal of International
Money and Finance 64, 88-103. [CrossRef]
31. Mark Copelovitch, Jeffry Frieden, Stefanie Walter. 2016. The Political Economy of the Euro Crisis.
Comparative Political Studies 49:7, 811-840. [CrossRef]
32. Torben Iversen, David Soskice, David Hope. 2016. The Eurozone and Political Economic Institutions.
Annual Review of Political Science 19:1, 163-185. [CrossRef]
33. Nikolaos Artavanis, Adair Morse, Margarita Tsoutsoura. 2016. Measuring Income Tax Evasion Using
Bank Credit: Evidence from Greece. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131:2, 739-798. [CrossRef]
34. Anna Ruščáková, Jozefína Semančíková. 2016. The European Debt Crisis: A Brief Discussion of its
Causes and Possible Solutions. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 220, 399-406. [CrossRef]
35. GIULIA M. DOTTI SANI, BEATRICE MAGISTRO. 2016. Increasingly unequal? The economic
crisis, social inequalities and trust in the European Parliament in 20 European countries. European
Journal of Political Research 55:2, 246-264. [CrossRef]
36. Klaus Grobys. 2016. Another look at momentum crashes: momentum in the European Monetary
Union. Applied Economics 48:19, 1759-1766. [CrossRef]
37. Guido Baldi, Karsten Staehr. 2016. The European debt crisis and fiscal reactions in Europe 2000–
2014. International Economics and Economic Policy 13:2, 297-317. [CrossRef]
38. Alison Johnston, Aidan Regan. 2016. European Monetary Integration and the Incompatibility of
National Varieties of Capitalism. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies 54:2, 318-336. [CrossRef]
39. Carla Fernandes, Paulo M. Gama, Elisabete Vieira. 2016. Does local and Euro area sentiment matter for
sovereign debt markets? Evidence from a bailout country. Applied Economics 48:9, 816-834. [CrossRef]
40. Juan Gabriel Brida, David Matesanz, Maria Nela Seijas. 2016. Network analysis of returns and volume
trading in stock markets: The Euro Stoxx case. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications
444, 751-764. [CrossRef]
41. J. Scott Davis, Adrienne Mack, Wesley Phoa, Anne Vandenabeele. 2016. Credit booms, banking crises,
and the current account. Journal of International Money and Finance 60, 360-377. [CrossRef]
42. Daniel Buncic, Gion Donat Piras. 2016. Heterogeneous agents, the financial crisis and exchange rate
predictability. Journal of International Money and Finance 60, 313-359. [CrossRef]
43. Mouhamadou Sy. 2016. Overborrowing and Balance of Payments Imbalances in a Monetary Union.
Review of International Economics 24:1, 67-98. [CrossRef]
44. Filippo Brutti, Philip Sauré. 2016. REPATRIATION OF DEBT IN THE EURO CRISIS. Journal
of the European Economic Association 14:1, 145-174. [CrossRef]
45. Servaas Storm, C.W.M. Naastepad. 2016. Myths, Mix-ups, and Mishandlings: Understanding the
Eurozone Crisis. International Journal of Political Economy 45:1, 46-71. [CrossRef]
46. Sascha Engel. 2016. An Alternative Approach to the Institutional Economics of the Eurozone Crisis.
Journal of Economic Issues 50:1, 145-164. [CrossRef]
47. Stavros Degiannakis, David Duffy, George Filis, Alexandra Livada. 2016. Business cycle
synchronisation in EMU: Can fiscal policy bring member-countries closer?. Economic Modelling 52,
551-563. [CrossRef]
48. John PetersonIntroduction: Where Things Stand and What Happens Next 1-18. [CrossRef]
49. Jonathan LuckhurstStrategic Economic Effects of the GFC 23-61. [CrossRef]
50. Servaas Storm, C. W. M. NaastepadStructural Divergence and Crisis in the Eurozone: The Role of
NAIRU Economics 101-128. [CrossRef]
51. Atif Ansar, Bent Flyvbjerg, Alexander Budzier, Daniel Lunn. 2016. Does infrastructure investment
lead to economic growth or economic fragility? Evidence from China. Oxford Review of Economic
Policy 32:3, 360-390. [CrossRef]
52. Barry Eichengreen, Ugo Panizza. 2016. A surplus of ambition: can Europe rely on large primary
surpluses to solve its debt problem?. Economic Policy 31:85, 5. [CrossRef]
53. Robert KissackThe Global Financial Crisis and Emerging Economies: EU Accommodation and
Entrenchment in the IMF 157-177. [CrossRef]
54. Caroline BradleyChanging Perceptions of Systemic Risk in Financial Regulation 75-106. [CrossRef]
55. Nicolò Conti, Vincenzo MemoliThe Context of Opposition to and Support for the EU in the Member
States 85-95. [CrossRef]
56. Beata Szetela, Grzegorz Mentel, Jacek Brożyna. 2016. In search of insolvency among European
countries. Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja 29:1, 839-856. [CrossRef]
57. Tatiana Covalschi, Sebastian Lazăr. 2016. The Sustainability of Public Finances in Republic of
Moldova Under EU Fiscal Rules. Scientific Annals of Economics and Business 63:2. . [CrossRef]
58. Rients Galema, Michael KoetterEuropean Bank Efficiency and Performance: The Effects of
Supranational Versus National Bank Supervision 257-292. [CrossRef]
59. Nikos Paltalidis, Dimitrios Gounopoulos, Renatas Kizys, Yiannis Koutelidakis. 2015. Transmission
channels of systemic risk and contagion in the European financial network. Journal of Banking &
Finance 61, S36-S52. [CrossRef]
60. Michael Olabisi, Howard Stein. 2015. Sovereign bond issues: Do African countries pay more to
borrow?. Journal of African Trade 2:1-2, 87-109. [CrossRef]
61. Servaas Storm, C.W.M. Naastepad. 2015. NAIRU economics and the Eurozone crisis. International
Review of Applied Economics 29:6, 843-877. [CrossRef]
62. Piotr Ciżkowicz, Andrzej Rzońca, Rafał Trzeciakowski. 2015. Windfall of Low Interest Payments and
Fiscal Sustainability in the Euro Area: Analysis through Panel Fiscal Reaction Functions. Kyklos 68:4,
475-510. [CrossRef]
63. David Matesanz, Guillermo J. Ortega. 2015. Sovereign public debt crisis in Europe. A network analysis.
Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 436, 756-766. [CrossRef]
64. Víctor Manuel Cuevas Ahumada. 2015. La arquitectura de la eurozona y la crisis de su periferia.
Contaduría y Administración 60, 24-53. [CrossRef]
65. Hung Xuan Do, Robert Brooks, Sirimon Treepongkaruna. 2015. Realized spill-over effects between
stock and foreign exchange market: Evidence from regional analysis. Global Finance Journal 28, 24-37.
[CrossRef]
66. John Phelan. 2015. The Road Not Taken: A Comparison Between the Hard ECU and the Euro.
Economic Affairs 35:3, 397-415. [CrossRef]
67. Jędrzej Białkowski, Martin T. Bohl, Patrick M. Stephan, Tomasz P. Wisniewski. 2015. The gold price
in times of crisis. International Review of Financial Analysis 41, 329-339. [CrossRef]
68. PAMI DUA, DIVYA TUTEJA. 2015. IMPACT OF EUROZONE SOVEREIGN DEBT CRISIS
ON CHINA AND INDIA. The Singapore Economic Review 1550099. [CrossRef]
69. Yu Hsing. 2015. Determinants of the Government Bond Yield in Spain: A Loanable Funds Model.
International Journal of Financial Studies 3:3, 342-350. [CrossRef]
70. Herbert Brücker. 2015. Migration und Finanzkrise. KZfSS Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und
Sozialpsychologie 67:S1, 165-191. [CrossRef]
71. Yoichi Tsuchiya. 2015. Simple Analytics of the Dynamic Laffer Curve Under Alternative Financing
Schemes. Applied Economics Quarterly 61:3, 199-227. [CrossRef]
72. Brigitte Granville, Dominik Nagly. 2015. Conflicting Incentives for Public Support for EMU. The
Manchester School 83, 142-157. [CrossRef]
73. Jørgen Bølstad, Christoph Elhardt. 2015. To bail out or not to bail out? Crisis politics, credibility,
and default risk in the Eurozone. European Union Politics 16:3, 325-346. [CrossRef]
74. Berend van der Kolk, Henk J. ter Bogt, Paula M.G. van Veen-Dirks. 2015. Constraining and
facilitating management control in times of austerity. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal
28:6, 934-965. [CrossRef]
75. Christian Keuschnigg, Klaus Weyerstrass. 2015. Macroeconomic Adjustment and Institutional
Reforms in the Euro Area. International Advances in Economic Research 21:3, 275-285. [CrossRef]
76. Òscar Jordà, Moritz Schularick, Alan M. Taylor. 2015. Betting the house. Journal of International
Economics 96, S2-S18. [CrossRef]
77. Udechukwu Ojiako, Thanos Papadopoulos, Teta Stamati, Dimosthenis Anagnostopoulos, Alasdair
Marshall. 2015. Collaborative governance in Greek infrastructure projects. Proceedings of the Institution
of Civil Engineers - Management, Procurement and Law 168:3, 135-145. [CrossRef]
78. Gilles Ivaldi, Andrej Zaslove. 2015. L’Europe des populismes : confluences et diversité. Revue
européenne des sciences sociales :53-1, 121-155. [CrossRef]
79. Pier Domenico Tortola. 2015. Coming Full Circle: The Euro Crisis, Integration Theory and the
Future of the EU. The International Spectator 50:2, 125-140. [CrossRef]
80. Agustín S. Bénétrix, Philip R. Lane. 2015. International Differences in Fiscal Outcomes during the
Global Crisis. Fiscal Studies 36:1, 1-27. [CrossRef]
81. Umberto Muratori. 2015. Contagion in the Euro Area Sovereign Bond Market. Social Sciences 4:1,
66-82. [CrossRef]
82. Daniel E. Nolle. 2015. Who's in Charge of Fixing the World's Financial System? The Un[?]der-
Appreciated Lead Role of the G20 and the FSB. Financial Markets, Institutions & Instruments 24:1,
1-82. [CrossRef]
83. Wasim Ahmad, N. R. Bhanumurthy, Sanjay Sehgal. 2015. Regime dependent dynamics and European
stock markets: Is asset allocation really possible?. Empirica 42:1, 77-107. [CrossRef]
84. Andrea Cipollini, Jerry Coakley, Hyunchul Lee. 2015. The European sovereign debt market: from
integration to segmentation. The European Journal of Finance 21:2, 111-128. [CrossRef]
85. Jeffrey Frankel. 2015. The euro crisis: Where to from here?. Journal of Policy Modeling 37:3, 428.
[CrossRef]
86. References 337-340. [CrossRef]
87. Carmen Reinhart, M. Belen Sbrancia. 2015. The Liquidation of Government Debt. IMF Working
Papers 15:7, 1. [CrossRef]
88. Hafiz Hoque, Dimitris Andriosopoulos, Kostas Andriosopoulos, Raphael Douady. 2015. Bank
regulation, risk and return: Evidence from the credit and sovereign debt crises. Journal of Banking &
Finance 50, 455-474. [CrossRef]
89. Michael G. ArghyrouFrom the Euro-Crisis to a New European Economic Architecture 308-328.
[CrossRef]
90. Arturo Bris, Yrjö Koskinen, Mattias Nilsson. 2014. The euro and corporate financing before the crisis.
Journal of Financial Economics 114:3, 554-575. [CrossRef]
91. Gernot J. Müller. 2014. The Debate Over Austerity. International Finance 17:3, 403-418. [CrossRef]
92. Alison Johnston, Bob Hancké, Suman Pant. 2014. Comparative Institutional Advantage in the
European Sovereign Debt Crisis. Comparative Political Studies 47:13, 1771-1800. [CrossRef]
93. Christopher Holmes. 2014. ‘Whatever it takes’: Polanyian perspectives on the eurozone crisis and the
gold standard. Economy and Society 43:4, 582-602. [CrossRef]
94. Silvia Ardagna, Francesco Caselli. 2014. The Political Economy of the Greek Debt Crisis: A Tale
of Two Bailouts. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 6:4, 291-323. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
95. Leo de Haan, Jeroen Hessel, Jan Willem van den End. 2014. Are European sovereign bonds fairly
priced? The role of modelling uncertainty. Journal of International Money and Finance 47, 239-267.
[CrossRef]
96. Alexander Michaelides. 2014. Cyprus: from boom to bail-in. Economic Policy 29:80, 639-689.
[CrossRef]
97. Jonathan A. Batten, Niklas F. WagnerIntroduction to Risk Management Post Financial Crisis: A
Period of Monetary Easing 3-13. [CrossRef]
98. Christiane Lübke, Marcel Erlinghagen. 2014. Self-perceived job insecurity across Europe over time:
Does changing context matter?. Journal of European Social Policy 24:4, 319-336. [CrossRef]
99. Akira Yakita. 2014. Involuntary unemployment and sustainability of bond-financed fiscal deficit.
Journal of Macroeconomics 41, 79-93. [CrossRef]
100. Christian Schweiger. 2014. The EU-25 Fiscal Compact : Differentiated Spillover Effects under Crisis
Conditions. Perspectives on European Politics and Society 15:3, 293-304. [CrossRef]
101. Selin Sayek, Fatma Taskin. 2014. Financial crises: lessons from history for today. Economic Policy
29:79, 447-493. [CrossRef]
102. Juan Carlos Cuestas, Luis A. Gil-Alana, Karsten Staehr. 2014. Government debt dynamics and the
global financial crisis: Has anything changed in the EA12?. Economics Letters 124:1, 64-66. [CrossRef]
103. Sven Steinkamp, Frank Westermann. 2014. The role of creditor seniority in Europe's sovereign debt
crisis. Economic Policy 29:79, 495-552. [CrossRef]
104. Roel Beetsma, Kostas Mavromatis. 2014. An analysis of eurobonds. Journal of International Money
and Finance 45, 91-111. [CrossRef]
105. Jens Klose, Benjamin Weigert. 2014. Sovereign Yield Spreads During the Euro Crisis: Fundamental
Factors Versus Redenomination Risk. International Finance 17:1, 25-50. [CrossRef]
106. Financial Crises . [CrossRef]
107. Abderrazak Elkhaldi, Tarek Chebbi, Kamel Naoui. 2014. Measuring Contagious Effects on Euro Area
Debt Crisis Using Daily CDS Spreads Changes. Procedia Economics and Finance 13, 14-29. [CrossRef]
108. Richard Pomfret. 2014. European crises and the Asian economies. Journal of Asian Economics .
[CrossRef]
109. Soodabeh Sarafrazi, Shawkat Hammoudeh, Paulo AraújoSantos. 2014. Downside risk, portfolio
diversification and the financial crisis in the euro-zone. Journal of International Financial Markets,
Institutions and Money 32, 368. [CrossRef]
110. David E. Allen, Petko S. Kalev, Michael J. McAleer, Abhay K. SinghNonparametric Multiple Change-
Point Analysis of the Responses of Asian Markets to the Global Financial Crisis 267-284. [CrossRef]
111. Fernando Broner, Aitor Erce, Alberto Martin, Jaume Ventura. 2014. Sovereign debt markets in
turbulent times: Creditor discrimination and crowding-out effects. Journal of Monetary Economics 61,
114-142. [CrossRef]
112. Mark A. Johnson, Douglas J. Lamdin. 2014. Investment and saving and the euro crisis: A new look
at Feldstein–Horioka. Journal of Economics and Business 76, 101. [CrossRef]
113. Giancarlo Corsetti, Keith Kuester, André Meier, Gernot J. Müller. 2014. Sovereign risk and belief-
driven fluctuations in the euro area. Journal of Monetary Economics 61, 53-73. [CrossRef]
114. Iain BeggGenuine Economic and Monetary Union 1-12. [CrossRef]
115. Jan Hanousek, Evžen Kočenda, Jan Novotný. 2013. Price jumps on European stock markets. Borsa
Istanbul Review . [CrossRef]
116. Hafiz Hoque. 2013. From the credit crisis to the sovereign debt crisis: Determinants of share price
performance of global banks. International Review of Financial Analysis 30, 334-350. [CrossRef]
117. Inna Cábelková, Wadim Strielkowski. 2013. Is the level of taxation a product of culture? A cultural
economics approach. Society and Economy 1:-1, 1-17. [CrossRef]
118. Eleftherios Goulas, Athina Zervoyianni. 2013. Growth, deficits and uncertainty: Theoretical aspects
and empirical evidence from a panel of 27 countries. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance
53:4, 380-392. [CrossRef]
119. Luigi Bonatti, Andrea Fracasso. 2013. The German Model and the European Crisis. JCMS: Journal
of Common Market Studies 51:6, 1023-1039. [CrossRef]
120. Karl Farmer. 2013. Financial Integration and EMU’s External Imbalances in a Two-Country OLG
Model. International Advances in Economic Research . [CrossRef]
121. Gonzalo Caballero. 2013. Effects of Fiscal and Monetary Policy in the Great Recession. Economies
1:2, 15-18. [CrossRef]
122. Nik Hynek. 2013. Coping with U.S. and EU's challenges? Strategic confusion in the Czech foreign
and security policy. Communist and Post-Communist Studies 46:3, 373-385. [CrossRef]
123. László Fikó. 2013. Válságkezelés: Mit tanulhat az Európai periféria Ázsiától?. Társadalomkutatás 31:3,
305-316. [CrossRef]
124. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde,, Luis Garicano,, Tano Santos. 2013. Political Credit Cycles: The Case of
the Eurozone. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27:3, 145-166. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
125. Enrico Spolaore. 2013. What Is European Integration Really About? A Political Guide for Economists.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 27:3, 125-144. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
126. Christoph M. Schmidt, Benjamin Weigert. 2013. Weathering the crisis and beyond: perspectives for
the Euro area. International Tax and Public Finance 20:4, 564-595. [CrossRef]
127. Philip R. Lane. 2013. Financial Globalisation and the Crisis. Open Economies Review 24:3, 555-580.
[CrossRef]
128. Jeromin Zettelmeyer, Christoph Trebesch, Mitu Gulati. 2013. The Greek debt restructuring: an
autopsy. Economic Policy 28:75, 513-563. [CrossRef]
129. Stephen Kinsella, G. Tiou-Tagba Aliti. 2013. Modeling Moments of Crisis: The Case of Ireland.
Journal of Economic Issues 47:2, 561-566. [CrossRef]
130. Catalin Dragomirescu-Gaina, Dionisis Philippas. 2013. Is the EMU government bond market a
playground for asymmetries?. The Journal of Economic Asymmetries 10:1, 21-31. [CrossRef]
131. Agustín S. Bénétrix, Philip R. Lane. 2013. Fiscal cyclicality and EMU. Journal of International Money
and Finance 34, 164-176. [CrossRef]
132. Giancarlo Corsetti, Keith Kuester, André Meier, Gernot J. Mueller. 2013. Sovereign Risk and Belief-
Driven Fluctuations in the Euro Area. IMF Working Papers 13:322, 1. [CrossRef]
133. Fernando Broner, Aitor Erce, Alberto Martin, Jaume Ventura. 2013. Sovereign Debt Markets in
Turbulent Times: Creditor Discrimination and Crowding-Out. IMF Working Papers 13:270, 1.
[CrossRef]
134. Stijn Claessens, M. Ayhan Kose. 2013. Financial Crises Explanations, Types, and Implications. IMF
Working Papers 13:28, 1. [CrossRef]
135. David Peón, Fernando Rey. 2013. Playing with Fire: Internal Devaluation for the GIPSI Countries.
ISRN Economics 2013, 1-20. [CrossRef]
136. 499-571. [CrossRef]
137. Martina Krásnická. 2013. Legal and economic aspects of deeper EU integration in the Czech Republic.
Acta Universitatis Agriculturae et Silviculturae Mendelianae Brunensis 61:7, 2351-2355. [CrossRef]
138. Stephanos Papadamou, Eleftherios SpyromitrosThe Twin Deficit as an Early Warning Sign in
Avoiding Crises: 310-331. [CrossRef]
139. Serkan CuraThe Impact of Sovereign Debt Crisis on the EU Economy: 1-11. [CrossRef]