2 PS Birthal PDF
2 PS Birthal PDF
2 PS Birthal PDF
Abstract
1. Introduction
Market liberalization and globalization are causing a transformation in
agriculture and agri-food markets in India. Food basket is changing towards
high-value food products like fruits, vegetables and animal products, and in
response, the agricultural production portfolio is diversifying. Simultaneously,
food procurement and distribution system is also witnessing institutional
innovations like contract farming, producers’ associations, cooperatives and
supermarkets. These changes are creating opportunities as well as challenges
for farmers. They are expected to benefit from diversification into high-
value commodities that have a strong potential for higher returns to land,
labour and capital. Institutional innovations in marketing enhance their access
National Centre for Agricultural Economics and Policy Research (NCAP), Pusa,
New Delhi 110 012
426 Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 20 (Conf. Issue) 2007
households grow vegetables, 4.6 per cent fruits and 44.2 per cent dairy
animals. Participation of smallholders in fruits and vegetables production is
higher compared to any other category of landholders. However, participation
of smallholders in dairying is less as compared to others.
Smallholders have a larger presence in the high-value segment; over 84
per cent vegetable growers and 88 per cent fruit growers are smallholders.
They account for 61 per cent of the vegetable area and 52 per cent of the
fruit area. Their presence in milk production is also considerable; over 77
per cent milk producers belong to smallholders and contribute 69 per cent to
total milk production.
estimated the marketing costs to be around 20 per cent of the sale price of
vegetables. Marketing costs are also high in the case of milk, 15-20 per cent
(Birthal et al. 2005; 2006).
Institutional Approaches
High marketing and transaction costs act as a barrier to farmers’
participation in markets. Institutions such as cooperatives, growers’
associations and contract farming are considered to reduce marketing and
transaction costs and risks by providing ‘markets’ to the farmers at their
doorsteps (Eaton and Shepherd, 2001). In this section, we have examined
some successful models of such institutions.
Cooperatives
India’s dairy cooperative model is one of the successful models linking
farmers to markets. The first dairy cooperative was established in the Kheda
district of Gujarat in 1946, primarily to save producers from exploitation by
the middlemen/informal traders, and improve their bargaining strength and
economies of scale in marketing. In 2004-05, there were more than 11.3
thousand village level dairy cooperative societies in India with 12.3 million
members. These procured 7.3 million tonnes of milk, equivalent to 7.9 per
cent of the total milk produced in the country (NDDB, 2005). Cooperatives
also provide inputs, services and information to the producers-members. In
recent years, some dairy cooperatives have started using information and
communication technology for milk procurement and information
dissemination systems to improve efficiency and transparency in marketing.
Cooperatives market the milk and milk products in over 800 cities and towns
through their retail outlets.
Cooperatives also exist for other products, including oilseeds, fruits and
vegetables. Two important cooperatives in horticulture are Mahagrapes in
Maharashtra and HOPCOMS (Horticulture Produce Cooperative Marketing
and Processing Society Limited) in Karnataka. Mahagrapes is an association
of grape growers’ cooperative societies. It was established in 1991 to improve
the grape growers access to domestic and international markets, which
otherwise was difficult for individual producers or cooperative societies. It
now has 16 growers’ cooperatives with 2500 farmer-members.
Mahagrapes supplies inputs, technology, and extension services to
farmers through cooperatives and empowers them to produce quality output
conforming to food safety and quality standards of the importing countries.
Cooperatives associated with Mahagrapes have refrigerated transport and
cold storage facilities, for which cooperatives charge a fixed amount, on per
kg basis from the farmers.
Birthal et al.: Linking Farmers to Markets 433
Growers’ Associations
Growers’ associations are informal cooperatives managed by the farmers
themselves. SAFAL — a village level association promoted by the Mother
Dairy Fruits and Vegetables Limited (MDFVL), has been quite successful
in linking fruit and vegetable farmers to markets. SAFAL was established in
1988 to cater to the growing demand for fruits and vegetables in the
metropolitan city of Delhi. At present, there are 250 SAFAL associations
with about 20,000 farmer-members in the country.
MDFVL provides technical support to these associations in preparation
of crop calendar and showing schedules to get the desired supply on a
regular basis. The firm also provides inputs like quality seeds, bio-pesticides
and bio-fertilizers, and extension services to the producer-members. The
MDFVL is an ISO-9002 and HACCP certified firm. Quality standards for
each fruit and vegetable are defined in respect of size, weight, colour and
appearance, and are displayed at each SAFAL collection centre for farmers
to comply with.
Daily wholesale market prices in the Delhi wholesale market serve as
the base price for the producers. Farmers are paid the modal price plus a 5-
10 per cent premium for quality. The firm does not share any production
and price risk.
MDFVL has a 100 per cent export-oriented fruit-processing unit in
Mumbai. The MDFVL markets produce in fresh, frozen and processed
forms with brand name ‘SAFAL’. Retailing activity in fresh fruits and
vegetables is restricted to the metropolitan area of Delhi through its network
of about 300 retail outlets. The processed products are meant for domestic
as well as export markets. Major export destinations for SAFAL products
are: Europe, USA, Australia, Middle East, Japan, Singapore and Hong Kong.
In 2004, SAFAL had a turnover of about Rs1.5 billion.
434 Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 20 (Conf. Issue) 2007
Contract Farming
In India, contract farming is in the nascent stage, but is likely to emerge
as an important form of vertical coordination with unfolding of market
liberalization and globalization. Recent reforms in agricultural markets have
opened up new avenues for agribusiness in India, and many a big business
houses have started entering the agricultural markets, and use contract
farming as a means to source their raw material requirements. Contract
farming is practised in many agricultural commodities including wheat,
Basmati rice, fruits, vegetables and medicinal plants, but is prominent in
poultry and dairy. About 40 per cent broiler production in the country is
under contract. For milk, no such estimate is available, but the private sector
procures nearly 8-10 per cent of the total milk produced in the country.
The agri-business firms follow different models of contract farming,
ranging from bi-partite to multi-partite agreements. A bi-partite contract is
an agreement between producers and firms, which may take the form of a
market specification or resource providing contract. Inclusion of other
agencies by the agri-business firms to provide inputs, credit and insurance
gives rise to multi-partite contracts. In India, bi-partite contracts are common
in poultry. Firms provide critical inputs like day-old chicks, feed, medicines,
vaccines and extension services. Poultry farmers bear the cost of labour,
shed, litter, water and electricity. Farmers are provided a guaranteed
remuneration in the fixed growing charges based on bodyweight of the
birds. The firms lift the entire output and thus farmers are insulated against
market risks.
From farmers’ perspective, most important benefit of contract farming
is their insulation against price risk which is very high in poultry production.
Ramaswami et al. (2006) have shown that through contract farming farmers
could shift as much as 88 per cent income risk to the firms. Another benefit
is the access to interest-free credit in the form of inputs. In a study, Birthal
et al. (2005) have estimated 58 per cent reduction in marketing and transaction
costs and 13 per cent increase in net profits due to contract farming.
Birthal et al.: Linking Farmers to Markets 435
Inclusion/Exclusion of Smallholders
Marketing and transaction costs are higher for smallholders. They are
expected to benefit most from institutional marketing arrangements. The
question however is: ‘Are they included in the supply chains?’ Often agri-
business firms hesitate contracting with smallholders because of their small-
scale and inability to comply with food and quality standards. Contracting
with smallholders thus raises transaction costs (search, monitoring and
enforcement) to the firm.
There is a mixed evidence regarding participation of smallholders in the
coordinated marketing systems. In contract farming of spinach (Birthal and
436 Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 20 (Conf. Issue) 2007
Joshi, 2007) and gherkin (Erappa, 2006) more than 50 per cent farmers
were found small landholders (d”2ha). Birthal et al. (2005) have reported
considerable involvement of small-scale producers in contract farming of
milk, but not in broiler production. In dairying, 56 per cent contract farmers
had d”5 milch animals, while in broiler production, only about one-third of
the contract producers had d”5000 birds/cycle. On the other hand, Kumar
(2006) has found very little involvement (15%) of small landholders in crop
production in Punjab.
Thailand, processed foods are either exempted from taxes or attract very
low taxes. In India, packaging cost is also high, ranging between 12 and 20
per cent of the total cost. High tax incidence and packaging costs raise
retail prices, making products unaffordable to large masses.
Foreign direct investment (FDI) in retailing is not allowed, except in
single brand. There is an apprehension that entry of multinationals would
displace workers in the unorganized food retailing. Nevertheless, FDI can
strengthen agribusiness supply chains, improve competitiveness in production
and marketing, and enable farmers to participate in quality-driven global
food chains.
Integration of smallholders on the supply chain is a major challenge.
Exclusion of smallholders from the supply chain is politically unacceptable
and socially undesirable. Their integration requires collectivization into
cooperatives and self-help groups or intermediary contracts, which reduce
transaction costs to both firm and farmers. The government should facilitate
such institutors.
Production of most of the high-value agricultural commodities is capital-
and information/knowledge-intensive and riskier, while smallholders lack
access to capital, improved technologies, quality inputs, extension services
needed for entry into the high-value segment. It is therefore essential to
strengthen institutional mechanisms that improve smallholders’ access to
credit, insurance, technology and support services.
By amending the Agricultural Produce Market Committee Act, the
Government of India has allowed agri-business firms to source raw materials
directly from the farmers through contract farming. The revised Act however
does not provide for any legal measures to overcome disputes arising due to
breach of contract and other opportunistic tendencies. Contract farming is
emerging in a big way in India, and there is all likelihood of rise of such
problems in the future. Policies to facilitate transparency in contract
arrangements and stringent rules to safeguard the interest of farmers as
well as firms are imperative.
An enabling policy environment is essential to strengthen the supply
chain and value addition. There are considerable opportunities for agri-
business development. India has diverse agro-climatic conditions, offering a
tremendous potential for growing a wide range of commodities round the
year. It is the largest producer of milk (14.6%, 97 million tonnes), second
largest producer of fruits and vegetables (9.2%, 128 million tonnes), and
sixth largest producer of meat (2.3%, 6 million tonnes) in the world. It
produces 40 per cent of world mangoes, 35 per cent of green peas, 29 per
cent of cauliflowers, 22 per cent of bananas and 20 per cent of cashew
nuts.
438 Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 20 (Conf. Issue) 2007
References
Aksoy, M.A., (2005) The evolution of agricultural trade flows. In: Global
Agricultural Trade and Developing Countries, Eds: M.A. Aksoy and J.C.
Beghin. The World Bank, Washington D.C.
Bakshi, K., D. Roy and A. Thorat, (2006) Small they may be and Indian farmers they
are but export they can — the case of Mahagrapes farmers in India. Paper
presented at the Workshop ‘From Plate to Plough- Agricultural Diversification
and Its Implications for Smallholders’, organized by the International Food
Policy Research Institute, New Delhi Office, and Institute of Economic Growth,
New Delhi, India, 20-21 September.
Birthal, P.S., A.K. Jha, M. Tiongco, C. Delgado, C. Narrod and P.K. Joshi, (2006)
Equitable intensification of smallholder market-oriented dairy production in
India through contract farming. Annexure I of the IFPRI-FAO final report
“Contract Farming of Milk and Poultry in India: Partnerships to Promote
the Environmental Friendly and Equitable Intensification of Smallholder
Livestock Production”. International Food Policy Research Institute,
Washington DC, USA.
Birthal, P.S., P.K. Joshi and Ashok Gulati, (2005) Vertical Coordination in High-
value Food Commodities: Implications for Smallholders. MTID Discussion
Paper 85. International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington D.C.
Birthal, P.S. and P.K. Joshi, (2007) Institutional innovations for improving
smallholder participation in high-value agriculture: A case of fruit and
vegetable growers’ associations. Quarterly Journal of International
Agriculture, 46(1): 49-68.
Diaz-Bonilla, E., and L. Recca, (2000) Trade and agro-industrialization in developing
countries. Agricultural Economics, 23(3): 219-230.
Eaton, C., and A.W. Shepherd, (2001) Contract farming: Partnerships for growth.
FAO Agricultural Services Bulletin 145. Food and Agriculture Organization,
Rome, Italy.
Erappa, S., (2006) Contract Farming in Karnataka: A Boon or a Bane? Research
report 9/ ADRT 113. Agricultural Development and Rural Transformation Centre,
Institute for Social and Economic Change, Bangalore.
Birthal et al.: Linking Farmers to Markets 439