Port Administration: Public Vs Private Sector John Lethbridge and Zvi Ra'anan
Port Administration: Public Vs Private Sector John Lethbridge and Zvi Ra'anan
Port Administration: Public Vs Private Sector John Lethbridge and Zvi Ra'anan
November 1991
Transport No. PS-5
Governments around the world are improving the operational efficiency of national ports through institutional
reform, changing the role of port authorities and increasing use of the private sector.
Many governments have begun to deregulate economic activities and decentralize decision making, with the
objective of increasing financial viability and productive efficiency in the public sector. In this context,
governments worldwide are presently reformulating the way they control, regulate, and manage ports, with the
general principle of reducing direct intervention. Where feasible, the use of the private sector for typical port
operations is being introduced. At present, a wide variety of institutional structures can be found. On one extreme
there are ports like Dar-es-Salaam, Tanzania, where the port authority is responsible for all port activities as a
parastatal body, and on the other, typical US landlord ports which do not engage in any operational activities. There
is also the example of Southampton, UK, which is now a totally private common user port. The most important
issues relate to the degree of centralization and government control and the role of the private sector.
In the past, advice from the Bank has been mixed, but tended to promote centralized port authorities at the national
level. Recently, however, the trend has been to encourage decentralization and the privatization of port activities.
When considering port reform, there are three institutional issues which must be examined: the role of the national
port authority, the role of the local port authority, and the role of the private sector.
Bank lending operations in the past have often encouraged the establishment of autonomous national port
authorities, which were judged to be the most appropriate form of administration during periods of heavy port
investments. Unfortunately, they often grew out of control, became overstaffed and over-regulated the ports under
their jurisdiction (Brazil, for example, prior to reform). The current belief is that the role of a national port authority
should be reduced to a few major tasks and the staff kept to a minimum. Appropriate tasks are: (a) to coordinate
port investments so as to avoid wasting scarce resources to ensure that sufficient capacity exists to meet the
country's trade needs; (b) to guarantee an adequate quality of service; (c) to exert some control over pricing of port
services (to ensure government receives a return on its investments and port profit levels are not excessive); and (d)
to act as the body representing the ports industry in discussions with government, port users and the public.
At a local level, the first major step in reform is to establish the port as if it were a commercial enterprise. The port
enterprise which is created needs to be carefully structured and balanced, and it must be both responsible and
accountable for its actions. Essential elements are the freedom to recruit staff at competitive salaries and the
existence of responsible financial management and accounting practices.
http://www.worldbank.org/transport/publicat/td-ps5.htm 06/01/2005
Page 2 of 3
The second step is to divide port functions into a number of areas -- safety, security and environment; investment
and maintenance of major infrastructure (berths, breakwaters, channels, etc.); superstructure investment and
maintenance (workshops, equipment, lighting, etc.); port operations (cargo handling, berthing, etc.); and pricing --
and to retain in the public sector only those areas necessary to ensure the safe functioning of the port (harbour
master's activities, vessel traffic control, maintenance of navigation, oil spill contingency, etc.).
The apparent superior efficiency of private sector operations has to do with constraints imposed on public sector
ports through long established rules, traditions and practices which are difficult to change. Since most ports are
monopolies, simply transferring their activities to private enterprise without carefully designed, appropriate
regulations could easily be against the public interest. However, it is probably easier to control private sector
participation especially where competition can be developed than to try to motivate the public sector to operate
efficiently.
Where the private sector is being introduced for the first time, caution is advised in preparing the lease or operating
agreement for negotiation or bidding with potential operators while private monopolies should be avoided. Many
ports throughout the industrialized and developing world have learned bitter lessons through not paying sufficient
attention in the preparation of bid documents (Tacoma, USA).
For those ports currently carrying out all tasks a logical first step is to consider the use of the private sector for
stevedoring (general cargo); the provision of floating craft (tugs, mooring boats, work boats, pilot boats); certain
aspects of port maintenance (See Infrastructure Note PS-1); and electronic data processing systems. A second step
is to use the private sector for container and bulk terminal management and operation. Eventually, with growing
participation by private sector companies, the port will retain only certain key activities - a good example is the role
of the harbour master and his office (responsible for the safety of navigation, hazardous vessels, traffic control, and
other important tasks); another example is the responsibility for maintaining dredged depths and channels (not
doing the actual dredging but managing the task and its implementation). Canada and New Zealand offer examples
of ports that have reached this stage.
GUIDELINES
When a port invites the private sector to manage and operate a major element of the port there are a number of key
factors to be considered. Some of these are:
z Ownership of all land should preferably be retained by the port authority so as to permit some measure of
future government control over the operating monopolies.
z Great care and consideration needs to be given to the terms of concessions and their future impact on the
public and private returns on investments. Too often ports have found that they have leased the profit centers
to others, leaving themselves with seriously depleted revenues (Malaysia, Port Kelang, for example).
z If the private operator is responsible for the maintenance of both infrastructure and equipment, the port
should ensure that his standards are adequate and that the facility does not deteriorate. If the port is
responsible it should avoid confrontation and claims when equipment is not available. (USA, Tacoma and
Canada, Vancouver, have good examples of contracts).
z The port must be sure that the quality of service provided is adequate to maintain or enhance its reputation
and that the pricing structure is appropriate. Measures must be included in the agreements enabling the port to
control both and to terminate (or extend) the operating leases.
z The agreements must include clauses terminating the agreement if the operator is taken over by an
organization that could threaten the freedom of the common user facility (i.e. by a shipping line or a major
freight forwarder) or introduce other forms of discrimination.
z An overriding requirement is that port labor be involved in the decision-making well in advance. Labor
redundancy schemes or other similar programs will probably be necessary if a smooth transition from public
to private sector is to be achieved.
TO LEARN MORE
Richard A. P. Douglas, "Port Administration: A Review of the Structural and Legal Aspects", INUTD, April 1990.
http://www.worldbank.org/transport/publicat/td-ps5.htm 06/01/2005
Page 3 of 3
Hernan Levy and Aurelio Menendez, "Privatization in Transport: The Case of Port Kelang (Malaysia) Container
Terminal", EDI Working Papers, World Bank, July 1989.
Nigel J. Gould, "Port Privatization", IAPH Conf. Proc., Port of Wellington, N.Z., May 1991.
Robert Cooper, "New Zealand Ports: Corporatization and Change", IAPH Conf. Proc., Port of Auckland Ltd., May
1991.
T. J. David, "US Container Terminal Leasing and Pricing", Maritime Policy Management, Vol. 11/4, 1984.
ECLAC, "The Distribution Chain and the Competitiveness of Latin American Exports: Port Modernisation in
Chile", December 1989.
Institute of Management Services, "British Ports Privatisation", proceedings of one day conference (sponsored by
KPMG Peat Marwick McLintock), London, UK, May 1990 - described in summary in FAIRPLAY, September 6,
1990.
Zvi Ra'anan, "Should Public Ports Be Privatized?" - INU Technical Discussion Paper (forthcoming).
http://www.worldbank.org/transport/publicat/td-ps5.htm 06/01/2005