Child Labor and School Achievement in Latin America
Child Labor and School Achievement in Latin America
Child Labor and School Achievement in Latin America
8-1-2003
Peter F. Orazem
Iowa State University, [email protected]
Mario A. Sánchez
Inter-American Development Bank, [email protected]
Recommended Citation
Gunnarsson, Victoria; Orazem, Peter F.; and Sánchez, Mario A., "Child labor and school achievement in Latin America" (2003).
Economics Working Papers (2002–2016). 208.
http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/econ_las_workingpapers/208
This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics at Iowa State University Digital Repository. It has been accepted for
inclusion in Economics Working Papers (2002–2016) by an authorized administrator of Iowa State University Digital Repository. For more
information, please contact [email protected].
Child labor and school achievement in Latin America
Abstract
Child labor's effect on academic achievement is estimated, using unique data on 3rd and 4th graders in 9 Latin
American countries. Cross-country variation in truancy regulations provides an exogenous shift in the ages of
children normally in these grades, providing exogenous variation in opportunity cost of child time. Least-
squares estimates of the impact of child labor on test scores are biased downward, but corrected estimates are
still negative and statistically significant. Children working one standard deviation above the mean have
average scores that are 16% lower on mathematics exams and 11% lower on language exams, consistent with
estimates of the adverse impact of child labor on returns to schooling.
Keywords
child labor, Latin America, academic achievement, schooling, education
Disciplines
Economics
This working paper is available at Iowa State University Digital Repository: http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/econ_las_workingpapers/208
Child Labor and School Achievement in Latin America
Abstract
Child labor’s effect on academic achievement is estimated, using unique data on 3rd and 4th
an exogenous shift in the ages of children normally in these grades, providing exogenous
variation in opportunity cost of child time. Least-squares estimates of the impact of child labor
on test scores are biased downward, but corrected estimates are still negative and statistically
significant. Children working one standard deviation above the mean have average scores that
are 16% lower on mathematics exams and 11% lower on language exams, consistent with
_______________
Corresponding author: Peter F. Orazem, Department of Economics, 267 Heady Hall, Iowa State
[email protected].
Child Labor and School Achievement in Latin America
Abstract: Child labor’s effect on academic achievement is estimated, using unique data on 3rd
and 4th graders in 9 Latin American countries. Cross-country variation in truancy regulations
provides an exogenous shift in the ages of children normally in these grades, providing
exogenous variation in opportunity cost of child time. Least-squares estimates of the impact of
child labor on test scores are biased downward, but corrected estimates are still negative and
statistically significant. Children working one standard deviation above the mean have average
scores that are 16% lower on mathematics exams and 11% lower on language exams, consistent
About one of every eight children in the world is engaged in market work. Despite
general acceptance that child labor is harmful and despite international accords aimed at its
eradication, progress on lowering the incidence of child labor has been slow. While often
associated with poverty, child labor has persisted in some countries that have experienced
substantial improvements in living standards. For example, Latin America, with several
countries in the middle or middle-upper income categories, still has child labor participation rates
Countries have adopted various policies to combat child labor. Most have opted for legal
prohibitions, but these are only as effective as the enforcement. As many child labor
relationships are in informal settings within family enterprises, enforcement is often difficult.
Several countries, particularly in Latin America, have initiated programs that offer households an
income transfer in exchange for the household keeping their children in school and/or out of the
labor market.
1
Presumably, governments invest resources to lower child time in the labor market in
anticipation that the child will devote more time to acquisition of human capital. The
government’s return will come from higher average earnings and reduced outlays for poverty
alleviation when the child matures. However, despite a huge acceleration in the research on
child labor, there is surprisingly little evidence that relates child labor to schooling outcomes in
developing countries.1 In fact, most children who work are also in school, suggesting that
perhaps child labor does not lower schooling attainment. Additionally, studies that examine the
impact of child labor on test scores have often found negligible effects, although most of these
are in developed country contexts. More recently, Heady (2003), and Rosati and Rossi (2003)
have found some evidence that child labor lowers primary school test scores in developing
countries.
This study builds on these last two papers by examining the linkage between child labor
and school achievement in 9 countries in Latin America. The current study benefits from more
detailed data sets that allow controls for child, household, school, and community variables, and
it makes use of an empirical strategy that controls for the likely endogeneity of child labor. Our
results are very consistent: in all 9 countries, child labor lowers performance on tests of language
and mathematics proficiency, even when controlling for school and household attributes and for
the joint causality between child labor and school outcomes. To the extent that lower cognitive
attainment translates to lower future earnings, as argued by Glewwe (2002), these results suggest
that there is a payoff in the form of higher future earnings from investing in lowering the
2
I. LITERATURE REVIEW
Most studies that analyze the relationship between time at work and school attainment
have focused on high school or college students in developed countries.2 These studies have
generally found little evidence that part-time work combined with schooling hurts school
achievement. When adverse effects are found, they are only apparent at relatively high work
hours. Important exceptions include recent papers by Tyler (2003) and Stinebrickner and
Stinebrickner (2003) that found that after controlling for likely endogeneity of child labor,
working while in school led to much larger implied declines in high school math scores and in
college G.P.A.s than had been found previously. Post and Pong (2000) also found a negative
association between work and test scores in samples of 8th graders in many of the 23 countries
they studied.3
There are several reasons why the experience of older working students may not extend
to the experience of young children working in developing countries. Young children may be
less physically able to combine work with school, so that working children may be too tired to
learn efficiently in school or to study afterwards. Children who are tired are also more prone to
illness or injury that can retard academic development. It is possible that working at a young age
disrupts the attainment of basic skills more than it disrupts the acquisition of applied skills for
older students. School and work, which may be complementary activities once a student has
mastered literacy and numeracy, may not be compatible before those basic skills are mastered.
Past research on the consequences of child labor on schooling in developing countries has
concentrated on the impact of child labor on school enrollment or attendance. Here the evidence
is mixed. Patrinos and Psacharopoulos (1997) and Ravallion and Wodon (2000) found that child
labor and school enrollment were not mutually exclusive activities and could even be
complementary activities. However, Rosenzweig and Evenson (1977) and Levy (1985) found
3
evidence that stronger child labor markets lowered school enrollment. There is stronger evidence
that child labor lowers time spent in human capital production, even if it does not lower
enrollment per se. Psacharopoulos (1997) and Sedlacek et al. (2005) reported that child labor
lowered years of school completed and Akabayashi and Psacharopoulos (1999) discovered that
Nevertheless, school enrollment and attendance are not ideal measures of the potential
harm of child labor on learning because they are merely indicators of the time input into
schooling and not the learning outcomes. Even if child labor lowers time in school, it may not
hinder human capital production if children can use their limited time in school efficiently. This
is particularly true if the schools are of such poor quality that not much learning occurs in the
first place. On the other hand, the common finding that most working children are enrolled in
school may miss the adverse consequences of child labor on learning if child labor is not
complementary with the learning process at the lower grades. A more accurate assessment of the
impact of child labor on human capital production requires measures of learning outcomes, such
as test scores rather than time in school, to determine whether child labor limits or enhances
human capital production. Moreover, evidence suggests that cognitive skills, rather than years of
schooling, are the fundamental determinants of adult wages in developing countries (Glewwe
1996; Moll 1998). Therefore, identifying the impact of child labor on school achievement will
yield more direct implications for child labor’s longer term impacts on earnings and poverty
Direct evidence of child labor on primary school achievement is quite rare. Heady (2003)
found that child work had little effect on school attendance but had a substantial effect on
learning achievement in reading and mathematics in Ghana. Rosati and Rossi (2003) report that
in Pakistan and Nicaragua, rising hours of child labor is associated with poorer test scores. Both
4
of these studies have weaknesses related to data limitations. Heady treated child labor as
exogenous, but it is plausible that parents send their children to work in part because of poor
academic performance. Rosati and Rossi had no information on teacher or school characteristics,
although these are likely to be correlated with the strength of local child labor markets.
This study makes several important contributions to existing knowledge of the impact of
child labor on schooling outcomes in developing countries. First, it shows how child labor affects
test scores in 9 developing countries, greatly expanding the scope of existing research. Because
the same exam was given in all countries, we can illustrate how the effect of child labor on
cognitive achievement varies across countries that differ greatly in child labor incidence, per
capita income, and school quality. Because the countries also differ in the regulation and
enforcement of child labor laws, we can utilize cross-country variation in schooling ages and
truancy laws to provide plausible instruments for endogenous child labor. Finally, because the
data set includes a wealth of information on parent, family, community, and school attributes, we
can estimate the impact of child labor on schooling outcomes, holding fixed other inputs
commonly assumed to explain variation in schooling outcomes across children. The results are
very consistent. Child labor lowers student achievement in every country. The conclusions are
robust to alternative estimation procedures and specifications. We conclude that child labor has a
significant opportunity cost in the form of foregone human capital production, a cost that may
not be apparent when only looking at enrollment rates for working children.
5
II. EMPIRICAL MODEL
Ben Porath (1967) laid out the classic model of human capital investments over the life
cycle. There are diminishing marginal returns to time in school because of concavity in the
human capital production process and because the opportunity cost of allocating time to further
skill acquisition increases as skills are accumulated. In addition, finite life spans limit the length
of time to capture returns from schooling as age increases, further decreasing the marginal
returns to time in school as age rises. All of these factors suggest that time invested in human
capital production will decrease as an individual ages. However, early in life, children may
specialize in schooling if the present value of the return is sufficiently high relative to its current
marginal cost.4
We are interested in the tradeoff parents face in deciding whether the child should
specialize in schooling or should divide time between school and work. By age t, the child has
completed Et years of schooling. In addition, the child has matured for t years. The opportunity
cost of child school time is assumed to rise with Et and t, and is also a function of local labor
market conditions Zt. The returns to time in school will depend on how much the child is
expected to learn, Qt. A vector of observable parent, home, school and community variables, Ht
may affect tastes for child labor as well as affecting the productivity of child time in school
through Qt. The child’s labor supply function will be of the form
The human capital production process is assumed to depend on past human capital
accumulations, current factors that would make the child’s time in school more productive and
the time spent in school. Letting Qt be an observable measure of cognitive skills produced in
6
(2) Qt = q(Et, t, C t, H t, η t )
where η t is a component of cognitive ability that the parents can observe but not the
econometrician.
Because the decision on whether or how much the child works is based in part on the
parents’ knowledge of η t , and because student outcomes are influenced by child labor,
Var( ε t ,η t ) ≠ 0 , and ordinary least squares estimation of (2) will be biased. Short of a
randomized experiment that assigns children into working and not working groups, the best
candidate to resolve the problem will be to find variables that shift the probability that a child
works but do not directly affect child learning in school. We will rely on variables that alter the
local labor market for child labor, Zt, to provide exogenous shifts in the child labor equation in
We require elements of the vector Zt that alter the local labor market for children but do
not affect test scores. Because the probability of working rises with age, factors that alter the age
at which a child would normally be in a given grade will also affect the probability that the child
will be working. In Latin America, the age at which children are expected to start school varies
across countries from 5 to 7 years of age. The age until which children must remain in school
varies from 12 to 16 years of age. As a consequence, children must attend school as few as five
These differences in laws regulating child labor and school attendance alter the age at
which children would normally enter grades 3 and 4, and thus vary the opportunity costs between
countries of being in those grades. Children starting school earlier will be younger at grade 3
and will be more likely to attend school full time without working. Third and fourth graders in
7
countries with the lowest working ages are more likely to appear legal, even if they are under 12
years of age. Therefore, children in countries with low truancy ages will be more likely to be
An alternative measure of the opportunity cost of attending school would be the local
market wage for children. Because most child labor is unpaid work for family enterprises,
however, market wages would not adequately capture the value of time outside school even if
such information were available. Instead, we utilize the presumed upward relationship between
the marginal productivity of child labor and the child’s age which we assume is driven largely by
physical stature.5 Interactions between measures of a country’s school starting age or truancy
age and child age are used to capture exogenous variation across countries in the probability that
third and fourth graders work. These shifts in the net return to time in school provide the needed
Within countries, the largest source of variation in demand for child labor occurs across
rural and urban areas. There are more uses for child labor in rural markets, and so rural child
labor force participation rates exceed that for urban children in all the countries in this study. We
capture that source of variation with interactions between child age and a dummy variable
We will illustrate how these elements of Zt affect the probability of engaging in child
8
Estimation of equation (2) follows the educational production function literature in that Q
is measured by test scores that are explained by variables characterizing the student’s parents,
household, teacher, school and community (Hanushek 1995). Measures used include most of
those that have been found to be important in developing country settings (Hanushek 1995;
Kremer 1995).
the most commonly discussed is the lack of adequate control for the student's innate ability.8
Many studies have attempted to correct for the problem by using two test scores taken at
different times. If ability has an additive effect on school achievement, the difference between
the two output measures will be purged of the ability effect. The data for the current study only
includes tests taken at one point in time, so the differencing option is not available. However,
there are reasons why undifferenced data may yield satisfactory or even preferred estimates to
the differenced data. As Glewwe (2002) argues, if measures of Ht vary slowly over time, the
value of the differenced measure of achievement is minimal. This is more likely to be true at the
earliest stages of schooling where there is less variation in curriculum, educational materials or
teacher training. Furthermore, the use of parental attributes such as education and income should
partially control for inherited ability. Finally, if there is considerable measurement error in
estimates of Qt, the level of Qt may be measured more reliably than the change in Qt. In any
event, the results of the production function estimation in this study should be interpreted as
cumulative as of grade 3 or 4 rather than the additional learning obtained in that grade.
9
III. DATA
In 1997, the Latin-American Laboratory of Quality of Education (LLECE) carried out the
First Comparative International Study on Language, Mathematics and Associated Factors for 3rd
and 4th graders in Latin America. LLECE collected data initially in 13 countries, but the required
information for our regression analysis was only available for 9: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil,
The data set is composed of a stratified sample designed to insure sufficient observations
of public, private, rural, urban and metropolitan students in each country. Data were collected on
40 children from each of 100 schools in each country for a total of 4,000 observations per
country. Half of the students were in the 3rd grade and half in the 4th grade. For budgetary
reasons, LLECE had to use a priori geographic exclusions to limit the transportation and time
costs of data collection. Very small schools with too few 3rd and 4th graders and schools in
remote, difficult to access, or sparsely inhabited regions were excluded. Because of the cost of
translating exams, schools with bilingual or indigenous language instruction were also
excluded.10 As the excluded schools would cater to relatively more disadvantaged populations,
our results should be viewed as applying to school populations that are less rural, from more
majority ethnic groups and somewhat more advantaged than average for all Latin American
children.
Test Scores
sampled schools, and self-applied questionnaires to school principals (Pr), to the teachers (T) and
parents (or legal guardians) (P) of the tested children, and to the children themselves (C). In
10
(S). A description of the variables used in the Latin America analysis can be found in Table 1.
All children were tested in mathematics, and all were tested in Spanish except the
Brazilian children who were tested in Portuguese. It should be noted that the tests and
questionnaires were given only to children who attend school, so no information was obtained on
children who are not in school. Therefore the results can only be applied to enrolled children. If
working children who perform most poorly in school drop out to work full time, our estimate of
the consequences of child labor on schooling outcomes may miss some of those most harmed by
child labor while including children who can work and still perform well in school. However,
95% of children aged 9-11 are enrolled in Latin America, so the bias is likely to be modest.12 In
other settings where primary enrollment rates are much lower, the bias could be substantial.
Child Labor
Child labor is measured by each child’s response to a question asking whether s/he is
engaged in work outside the home.13 Our concentration on paid work outside the home avoids
some definitional problems related to distinguishing between unpaid work for home enterprise
from household chores. However, it is also apparent in our application that child labor in the
home does not have the same apparent negative consequences on student achievement as does
Table 3 reports child labor participation rates and average test scores for children by
whether they work inside and/or outside the home. The first two columns give the average
language and mathematics test scores for children reporting they worked outside the home often,
sometimes or never for nine of the countries.14 The percentage increase or decrease in average
11
test scores for the groups working less intensively relative to the average for those who work
often are reported in parentheses. Across all 9 countries and two achievement tests, 18 cases in
all, the pattern never varies. Children who work only some of the time outperform those who
often work. Children who almost never work outperform those who work sometimes or often.
The differences are almost always statistically significant. The advantage is large for children
who almost never work over those who often work, averaging 22% on the mathematics exam
and 27% on the language exam. The test advantage for occasional child laborers is smaller but
Children were asked a similar question regarding how intensively they worked inside the
home. It seems that working inside the home is less costly in terms of human capital
development in schools. Taking the average across all countries, those who work often inside
the home have average test scores only 7% lower than those who almost never work inside the
home, and only 4% lower than those who sometimes work in the home. The test score gaps for
those working outside the home were considerably larger. Furthermore, in only 3 of the 9
countries were average test scores significantly higher for children almost never working in the
home relative to those often working in the home. In 3 other countries, those often working in
the home had higher average test scores than did those rarely working in the home.
Nevertheless, there is a more basic reason that we do not analyze the implications of
working inside the home on student achievement: over 95% reported working in the home
sometime or often with nearly identical incidence of reported home work for girls and boys and
for urban and rural children. This lack of meaningful variation in child work in the home means
that the pattern of test scores against home work intensity is unlikely to be reliable. In fact,
empirical models we attempted could not distinguish statistically between children who did or
12
did not work in the home—everyone was predicted to participate in household labor. It is
possible that work in the home is damaging to schooling outcomes, but our data lack sufficient
variation in measured household work to capture the effect. For these reasons, we concentrate
Exogenous Variables
We rely on the presumed positive relationship between age and the value of child time
working outside the home to identify the child labor equation. This relationship varies across
urban and rural areas and between boys and girls. It also appears to shift as children reach 10
years of age or more. We allow this effect with a spline defined as follows. A dummy variable,
d10, takes the value of one for children under 10 and zero otherwise. For children aged 10 and
over, the age effect is allowed to captured by interactions between (1-d10) and age.
The countries included in our data differ in legal regulations governing the age at which
children enter school and when they can legally exit. Information on compulsory schooling laws
for each country was obtained from the UNESCO (2002). These laws were allowed to shift the
age-child labor relationship beyond age 10, using interaction terms of the form AGE*(1-
d10)*LAGE where LAGE is the legal age of school entry or school exit.15
The child’s value of time in school will depend on how much the child can learn. This
will depend on the availability of home attributes that are complementary with child time in
school such as books and parental education; and on the quality of the school. Most of these
measures are self-explanatory. However, some of the school variables merit some comment. The
poor school infrastructure and supplies. Teachers were asked the extent to which they judged
13
acoustics, language textbooks, mathematics textbooks and other textbooks to be inadequate. The
weighted sum of the responses is used as the aggregate index of school shortages, where the
weights were taken as the first principal component from a factor analysis of the teachers’
the cost of providing schooling services. As the number of nonnative speakers of the language
The results in Table 3 suggest a strong negative effect of child market labor on school
achievement, but the effect may be in the reverse direction–poor schooling outcomes leading to
child labor. The direction of this bias is difficult to predict. The most plausible is that poor
school performers are sent to work so that the least squares coefficient on child labor will be
biased downward. However, Both Tyler (2003) and Stinebrickner and Stinebrickner (2003)
found biases in the opposite direction for older students, so the better students were more likely
to work. Measurement error in the self-reported incidence of child labor could also bias the
estimated coefficient of child labor on schooling outcomes. The cumulative direction of these
sources of bias cannot be established, but both simultaneity and measurement error can be
handled by the use of plausible instruments that alter the probability of engaging in child labor
The first step in the estimation process is to predict child labor. Our categorical measure
of child market work includes 0 (almost never work); 1 (sometime work); and 2 (often work).
We use an ordered probit specification to estimate equation (1), using child, parent, school, and
community variables to explain variation in market work. Predicted child labor from (1) is used
14
as the measure of C in estimating equation (2). This two-stage estimation leads to consistent, but
inefficient estimates of the parameters of the achievement equation. To correct for the
inefficiency in the estimators we utilize a bootstrapping method in which 100 samples with
replacement are drawn from the original data, subjected to the ordered probit estimation and then
inserted into the second stage achievement equation in order to simulate the sampling variation
in the estimates. The bootstrap standard errors are reported for the test score equations.
Estimates from the probit child labor supply equation are reported in Table 4. These
estimates are needed to identify the effect of child labor on test scores, but also have interest in
their own right. The estimation makes use of the dependent variables reported in Table 3 except
that data for Venezuela and Mexico had to be dropped because child age was not reported.
Because the two samples are not identical, we report separate estimates for the samples of
children taking the mathematics and language exams. The coefficients on the age interacted
variables differ somewhat across the two samples, but the overall relationship between age and
child labor is similar between the two samples. The other coefficient estimates are very similar
Boys are more likely than girls to work outside the home, and rural boys and girls work
more than their urban counterparts, who in turn work more than their metropolitan counterparts.
Children of more educated parents and children who have access to more books in the home are
less likely to work outside the home. School quality also affects the incidence of child labor.
Schools with inadequate supplies encourage child labor. Children in schools with more non-
Spanish or non-Portuguese language speakers among their peers are also more likely to work
15
outside the home. Schools that offer more classes in Spanish/Portuguese and mathematics per
week also lower the incidence of child labor. In general, these results suggest that better
schooling inputs in the home or at school lower the incidence of child labor. The exception is
that attending preschool does not have a significant effect on child labor in this sample.
The joint test of the null hypothesis that the instrumental variables have no effect on child
labor is easily rejected. Variation in truancy laws across countries and in the market for boys
within countries do shift the probability that children work. We illustrate the impact of these
laws on the average incidence of child labor in Figures 1 and 2. Figure 1 illustrates how raising
the school starting age affects child labor outside the home by age. The effect was disabled
below age 10. As the school starting age rises from age 5 to 7, the probability of child labor rises
about 6 percentage points for a ten year old, all else equal. The effect increases to 10 percentage
points by age 14. Figure 2 shows how child market labor changes with the school leaving age.
As the truancy age rises from 12 to 16, the probability of child labor falls by 8.5 percentage
points for a ten year old. By age 14, the effect rises to 11.5 percentage points by age 14. These
results suggest that truancy laws do have an effect on child labor on average.
Figure 3 illustrates how regional variation in the market for child labor shifts child labor
supply for boys and girls. The dummy variable spline effectively fixes child labor intensity for
children under ten. After age ten, child labor intensity rises for both boys and girls. In each
market, boys work more than girls.16 The higher market labor force participation for boys is
consistent with the presumption that the marginal product of child labor is higher for boys than
girls. However, rural girls have higher labor force participation than metropolitain boys.
16
VI. CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOL ACHIEVEMENT
Table 5 reports the results from estimating equation (2) both with and without controls
for the endogeneity of child labor. In the specification in Table 5, when child labor is treated as
exogenous, it takes the values of 0 (almost never work); 1 (sometime work); or 2 (often work).
When treated as endogenous, child labor is a continuous variable with domain over the real line
taken as the fitted values from the ordered probit estimation in Table 4. The rest of the
regressors are the child, household, parent and school variables used as regressors in Table 4.17
The impact of child labor on test scores is negative and significant whether or not child
labor is treated as exogenous or endogenous. 18 Because of the difference in the scale of the
measured child labor across the two specifications, it is difficult to directly compare the
magnitude of the implied effect of child labor on test scores. We compare the results in two
ways. First, we compute the implied effect of a one standard deviation increase above the mean
in child labor in each of the equations. These beta coefficients are reported in brackets below the
child labor coefficients. When treated as exogenous, a one standard deviation increase in child
labor causes both mathematics and language tests scores to fall by about .2 standard deviations.
In other words, children working one standard deviation above the mean score on average 8%
lower on mathematics exams and 6% lower on language exams than do otherwise identical
children working at the mean level. When controlling for endogeneity, the effect increases to .4
standard deviation (16%) drop in the mathematics exam and a .3 standard deviation (11%) drop
in the language exam. This finding that the magnitude of the child labor effect on academic
achievement rises after controlling for endogeneity is consistent with results reported by Tyler
(2003) and Stinebrickner and Stinebrickner (2003) for older U.S. students.
17
Another way to compare the two sets of estimates can be found in Figures 4-5 which
trace out the predicted mathematics and language test scores at each decile of the reported and
predicted child labor distributions. At the break points of the exogenous measure (i.e. going
from child labor level 0 to level 1 at the 40th percentile and from level 1 to level 2 at the 74th
percentile) the predicted test scores using the reported and corrected measures. However, the
relationship is steeper at the upper and lower tails of the distribution of predicted child labor,
particularly for the mathematics test. The implication is that by restricting the range of child
labor to three discrete levels, the impact of child labor on test scores in the first two columns of
Table 5 is understated.
Glewwe’s (2002) review of the human capital literature in developing countries argued
that cognitive ability as measured by test scores is strongly tied to later earnings as an adult. We
would therefore expect that returns to schooling for those who worked as children should be
lower than for those who did not work, all else equal. Consistent with that expectation, Ilahi et
al. (2003) found that, holding constant years of schooling completed, Brazilian adults who
worked as children received 4 to 11 percent lower returns per year of schooling completed. Our
estimates suggest that child labor outside the home reduces achievement per year of schooling
attended by 11 to 16%. Because many of the third and fourth graders in our sample will repeat
the grade, our estimates are an upper-bound measure of the lost human capital per year
completed, and so our results correspond closely in magnitude to their estimates of adverse
Most of the other variables have similar effects across the two sets of estimates in Table
5. There are two main exceptions. The adverse effects of being a boy or being in a rural school
disappear in the instrumented equations. Gender and rural residence are closely tied to the
18
incidence of child labor. It is likely that the negative effects of being male and being in a rural
area on test scores is related to the indirect effect of these variables on the higher probability that
Parental education and availability of books in the home lose influence on test scores
after controlling for the endogeneity in child labor. School attributes also becomes less
important in explaining test scores. Again, these factors had strong negative effects on child
labor, and so part of their positive effect on school outcomes presumably works through their
impact on child school attendance and reduced time at work. The literature on the extent to
which school quality can explain variation in school achievement has emphasized the large
variation in coefficients for the same school inputs across studies and country settings (Hanushek
and Luque 2003). Our results suggest that one reason for the uncertain impact of school
attributes may be that school quality is more important in affecting child school attendance and
VII. CONCLUSIONS
Working outside the home lowers average school achievement in samples of 3rd and 4th
graders in each of the 9 Latin American countries studied. Child labor is shown to have
significant adverse effects on mathematics and language test scores using various specifications
correcting for possible endogeneity and measurement error in self-reported child labor intensity.
Children who work even occasionally score an average of 7 percent lower on language exams
and 7.5 percent lower on mathematics exams. There is some evidence that working more
intensely lowers achievement more, but these results are more speculative in that empirical
models were unable to distinguish clearly between working “sometime” versus working “often”.
19
These adverse effects of child labor on cognitive ability are consistent in magnitude with
estimated adverse effects of child labor on earnings as an adult. Thus, it is plausible that child
empirical evidence presented by Emerson and Souza (2003) and the theoretical models of
poverty traps advanced by Basu (2000), Basu and Van (1998), and Baland and Robinson (2000).
Such large effects suggest that efforts to combat child labor may have substantial payoffs
in the form of increased future earnings or lower poverty rates once children become adults.
How to combat child labor is less clear. Our child labor supply equations suggest that truancy
laws appear to have some effect in lowering the incidence of child labor. However, most of the
variation in child labor occurs within countries and not across countries, so policies must address
local child labor market and poverty conditions as well as national circumstances in combating
child labor. Policies that alter the attractiveness of child labor or bolster household income, such
as income transfer programs that condition receipt on child enrollment or reduced child labor, are
likely candidates. Recent experience on such programs in Brazil, Honduras, Mexico and
Nicaragua would appear to support further development and expansion of such conditional
transfer programs.
20
NOTES
Victoria Gunnarsson is a research officer in the Fiscal Affairs Department at the International Monetary Fund; her e-
mail address is [email protected]. Peter F. Orazem is a university professor at Iowa State University; his e-mail
address is [email protected]. Mario A. Sánchez is a social development specialist at the InterAmerican Development
Bank; his e-mail address is [email protected]. We thank Wallace Huffman, Robert Mazur, three referees, the
editor, and seminar participants at Iowa State and Minnesota for numerous comments and suggestions. The
findings, interpretations and conclusions are the authors’ own and should not be attributed to the World Bank or the
InterAmerican Development Bank, their Boards of Directors or any of their member countries.
1 Two excellent recent reviews of the recent literature include Basu and Tzannatos (2003) and Edmonds
and Pavcnik (2005).
2 D’Amico (1984); Ehrenberg and Sherman (1987); Howard (1998); Lillydahl (1990); Singh (1998); Stern
(1997); and Singh and Ozturk (2000).
3 This study included several developing countries including Colombia, Iran, South Africa, Thailand, and
the Philippines which had the largest estimated negative effects of child labor on school achievement. However, the
estimates do not control for school attributes or possible joint causality between school achievement and child labor.
4 The main predictions are not altered if leisure is added to the model. It will still be optimal to invest more
intensively in human capital early in life and decreasing investment intensity with age. In addition, because the cost
of leisure is the value of work time, individuals will consume the least leisure when wages are highest. In our
application, children will consume less leisure as they age, and so older children will still be expected to work more
than younger children. Heckman (1976) presents a detailed model of human capital investment, leisure demand and
consumption over the life cycle. Huffman and Orazem (2005) present a much simplified model that generates the
predictions discussed in the text.
5 Rosenzweig (1980) found that in a sample of adults, wages for day labor in India were primarily driven
by stature and not by acquired education. Wage patterns reported by Ray (2000) for boys and girls in Pakistan and
Peru suggest rising opportunity costs of child time as age increases.
6 Angrist and Krueger (1991) use variation in compulsory school starting ages across states to instrument
for endogenous time in school in their analysis of returns to schooling using U.S. Census data. Tyler (2003) uses
variation in state child labor laws to instrument for child labor in his study of U.S. high school tests scores. We
began with a large number of interactions, but the resulting variables were highly collinear, and so we used a
parsimonious subset of the fuller specification.
7 See Glewwe (2002) for a comprehensive review of the problems associated with estimating educational
production functions.
8 Ability bias has also been the subject of numerous papers estimating returns to schooling. The consensus
is that the bias is small (Card 1999). If earnings and cognitive skills are closely tied, as argued by Glewwe (2002),
then the role of ability bias should be small in educational production estimates also.
9 Costa Rica was included in the initial data collection but LLECE dropped their data due to consistency
problems. Cuba was excluded due to missing data on child labor. Mexico and Venezuela lacked required
information on child age.
10 For a detailed description of the a priori exclusions in each country, consult Table III.6 of the Technical
Bulletin of the LLECE.
11 For some reason, language scores were reported for two percent fewer students than were mathematics
scores. The missing scores appear to be due to random reporting errors as there were no large differences between
21
the sample means of the group taking the mathematics and language tests. We report the means from the sample
taking the mathematics exam.
12 Sedlacek et al. (2005) present data on enrollment by age for 18 Latin American countries. Even for the
poorest quintile of children, enrollments rates are over 90% for children aged 9-11.
13 As pointed out by a referee, it would be better to have information on hours of work rather than these
more vague measures of work intensity. Our instrumental variables procedure later is an attempt to correct for
biases due to measurement error in child labor.
14 We only report the averages for the subset of countries for which we had data on both language and test
scores and for which we could match responses for working inside and outside the home. We only had partial
information from Mexico and Venezuela, but we can report that the pattern of average test scores for children
working outside the home in Venezuela and Mexico were the same—children working more outside the home had
significantly lower average test scores. Data limitations prevented us from generating the corresponding average
test scores for children working inside the home for those two countries.
15 We report a more parsimonious specification than the one with all possible interaction terms. In
particular, separate coefficients on the dummy variable (1-d10) and their interactions with age, gender and rural
residence did not add to the explanatory power of the child labor equation.
16 We truncate ages below eight (0.4% of the sample) and above 15 (0.8% of the sample) as we do not
have sufficient observations at the lower and higher ages to generate reliable child labor supply trajectories.
17 We obtained similar estimates of the adverse effect of child labor on test scores when we used a school-
specific fixed effect to control for the impact of variation in school and community variables instead of the vector of
school and community variables.
18 The Davidson-MacKinnon (1993, pp. 237-240) variant of the Hausman test easily rejected the
assumption of exogeneity of child labor. The overidentification tests of the instruments failed to reject the null
hypothesis of exogeneity at the 10th percentile in the language test sample and at the 5th percentile for the
mathematics test sample.
22
REFERENCES
Akabayashi, Hideo, and George Psacharopoulos. 1999. “The Trade-off between Child Labor and
Human Capital Formation: A Tanzanian Case Study.” Journal of Development Studies 35
(June): 120-40.
Angrist, Joshua D., and Alan B. Krueger. 1991. “Does Compulsory School Attendance Affect
Schooling and Earnings?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (November): 979-1014.
Baland, Jean-Marie, and James A. Robinson. 2000. “Is Child Labor Inefficient?” Journal of
Political Economy 108 (August): 663-679.
Basu, Kaushik. 2000. Analytical Development Economics: The Less Developed Economy
Revisited. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Basu, Kaushik, and Pham Honang Van. 1998. “The Economics of Child Labor.” American
Economic Review 88 (June): 412-427.
Basu, Kaushik, and Zafiris Tzannatos. 2003. “The Global Child Labor Problem: What do we
know and what can we do?” The World Bank Economic Review 17: 147-173.
Card, David. 1999. “The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings.” In Ashenfelter and Card, eds.
Handbook of Labor Economics Vol. 3A. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V.
D’Amico, Ronald. 1984. “Does Employment During High School Impair Academic Progress?”
Sociology of Education 3 (July): 152-164.
Davidson, Russell, and James G. MacKinnon. 1993. Estimation and Inference in Econometrics
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Edmonds, Eric V., and Nina Pavcnik. 2005. “Child Labor in the Global Economy.” The Journal
of Economic Perspectives 19 (Winter): 199-220.
Ehrenberg, Ronald G., and Daniel R. Sherman. 1987. “Employment While in College, Academic
Achievement, and Postcollege Outcomes.” The Journal of Human Resources 22
(Winter): 1-23.
Glewwe, Paul. 1996. “The Relevance of Standard Estimates of Rates of Return to Schooling for
Educational Policy: A Critical Assessment.” Journal of Development Economics 51 (2):
267-290.
Glewwe, Paul. 2002. “Schools and Skills in Developing Countries: Educational Policies and
Socioeconomic Outcomes.” Journal of Economic Literature 50 (June): 436-482.
Hanushek, Eric A. 1995. “Interpreting Recent Research on Schooling in Developing Countries.”
The World Bank Research Observer 10 (August): 227-246.
Hanushek, Eric A., and Javier A. Luque. 2003. “Efficiency and Equity in Schools around the
World.” Economics of Education Review 22: 481-502.
Heady, Christopher. 2003. “What is the Effect of Child Labour on Learning Achievement?
Evidence from Ghana.” World Development 31 (February): 385-398.
Heckman, James J. 1976. “A Life-Cycle Model of Earnings, Learning, and Consumption”
Journal of Political Economy 84 (4) (August): S11-44.
Howard, Ian. 1998. “Does Part-Time Employment Affect A-level Grades Achieved?” PSSI
Forum N26 (October): 10-11.
Huffman, Wallace E., and Peter F. Orazem. 2005. “Agriculture and Human Capital in Economic
Growth: Farmers, Schooling and Nutrition.” In Evenson, R.E., P. Pingali, and T.P.
Schultz, eds. Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 3, North-Holland Publ.,
forthcoming.
23
Ilahi, Nadeem, Peter F., Orazem, and Guilherme Sedlacek. 2003. “How Does Working as a
Child Affect Wages, Income and Poverty as an Adult?” In Peter F. Orazem and
Guilherme Sedlacek eds. Eradicating Child Labor in Latin America in the 90s: The
Promise of Demand Side Interventions. Forthcoming.
Kremer, Michael R. 1995. “Research on Schooling: What We Know and What We Don't: A
Comment on Hanushek.” The World Bank Research Observer 10 (August): 247-254.
Levy, Victor. 1985. “Cropping Pattern, Mechanization, Child Labor, and Fertility Behavior in a
Farming Economy: Rural Egypt.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 33
(July): 777-791.
Lillydahl, Jane H. 1990. ”Academic Achievement and Part-Time Employment of High School
Students.” Journal of Economic Education 21 (Summer): 307-316.
Moll, Peter. 1998. “Primary Schooling, Cognitive Skills and Wages in South Africa.” Economica
65: 263-284.
Patrinos, Harry A., and George Psacharopoulos. 1997. “Family Size, Schooling and Child Labor
in Peru - An Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Population Economics 10 (October): 387-
405.
Post, David, and Suet-ling Pong. 2000. “Employment During Middle School: The Effects on
Academic Achievement in the U.S. and Abroad.” Educational Evaluation and Policy
Analysis 22 (Fall): 273-298.
Psacharopoulos, George. 1997. “Child Labor versus Educational Attainment: Some Evidence
from Latin America.” Journal of Population Economics 10: 337-386.
Ray, Ranjan. 2000. “Child Labor, Child Schooling and their Interaction with Adult Labor:
Empirical Evidence for Peru and Pakistan.” The World Bank Economic Review 13: 3-19.
Ravallion, Martin, and Quentin Wodon. 2000. “Does Child Labor Displace Schooling? Evidence
on Behavioral Responses to an Enrollment Subsidy.” Economic Journal 110: C158-
C175.
Rosati, Furio Camillo, and Mariacristina Rossi. 2003. “Children’s Working Hours and School
Enrollment: Evidence From Pakistan and Nicaragua.” The World Bank Economic Review
17 (2): 283-295.
Rosenzweig, Mark R. 1980. “Neoclassical Theory and the Optimizing Peasant: An Econometric
Analysis of Market Family Labor Supply in a Developing Country.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 94 (February): 31-55.
Rosenzweig, Mark R., and Robert Evenson. 1977. “Fertility, Schooling and the Economic
Contribution of Children in Rural India: An Econometric Analysis.” Econometrica 45
(July): 1065-79.
Sedlacek, Guilherme, Susanne Duryea, Nadeem Ilahi, and Masaru Sasaki. 2005. “Child Labor,
Schooling, and Poverty in Latin America.” in Peter F. Orazem and Guilherme Sedlacek
eds. Child Labor and Schooling in Latin America. Forthcoming.
Singh, Kusum. 1998. ”Part-Time Employment in High School and its Effect on Academic
Achievement.” The Journal of Educational Research 91 (January/February): 131-139.
Singh, Kusum, and Mehmet Ozturk. 2000. “Effect of Part-time Work on High School
Mathematics and Science Course Taking.” Journal of Educational Research, 91(2): 67–
74.
Stern, David. 1997. “Learning and Earning: The Value of Working for Urban Students.” ERIC
Digest #128.
24
Stinebrickner, Ralph, and Todd R. Stinebrickner. 2003. “Working During School and Academic
Performance.” Journal of Labor Economics 21 (April): 473-491.
Tyler, John H. 2003. “Using State Child Labor Laws to Identify the Effect of School-to-Work
on High School Achievement.” Journal of Labor Economics 21 (April): 381-408.
UNESCO. 2002. Education Statistics 2001-Regional Report on Latin America.
(http://portal.unesco.org/uis). November, 2002.
25
TABLE 1. Variable Description
Endogenous variables
Exogenous variables
Child
Age Student age (years) (C)
d10 Dummy if student is below 10 years old
Boy Dummy if student is a boy (C)
No Preschool Student did not attend preschool/kindergarten (C)
Parents/Household
Parent Education Average education of parent(s) or guardian(s) (P)
Books at Home Number of books in student’s home (P)
School
Spanish Enrollment Total number of Spanish (Portuguese) speaking students enrolled (Pr)
Inadequate Supply Index of school supply inadequacy (Pr)
Math/week Number of mathematics classes per week (Pr)
Spanish/week Number of Spanish (Portuguese) classes per week (Pr)
Instruments
Legal structure
Compulsory Start Compulsory school ending age in the country (U)
Compulsory End Compulsory school ending age in the country (U)
Sources: C: Child survey or test; P: Parent’s survey; T: Teacher’s survey; Pr: Principle’s survey; S: Survey
Designer’s observation; U: UNESCO estimate (2002).
26
TABLE 2. Summary Statistics
Endogenous variables
Child
27
TABLE 3. Unconditional Average Language and Mathematics Test Scores, By Country and Type and Level
28
Working outside of the home Working in the home
29
TABLE 4. Ordered Probit Regression Results on Child Labor
Standard errors in parentheses. Regressions also include dummy variables that control for missing values.
30
TABLE 5. Least Squares and Instrumental Variables Equations on Test Scores
31
32
33
34
35
36
Iowa State University does not discriminate on the basis of race, color, age,
religion, national origin, sexual orientation, gender identity, sex, marital
status, disability, or status as a U.S. veteran. Inquiries can be directed to
the Director of Equal Opportunity and Diversity, 3680 Beardshear Hall, (515)
294-7612.