Real World Examples of Oligopoly
Real World Examples of Oligopoly
THEIR FUNCTIONING.
INTRODUCTION
The Oligopoly market structure is where, in which there are only few sellers who offer similar or
identical products. The market is imperfectly competitive market and it falls between the two
extremes i.e. between the perfect competition and monopoly.
The market having only few small groups of sellers a key feature of such kind of market is the
tension between them regarding co-operation and self-interest. This small group is best off co-
operating and acting like a monopolist - producing small amount of quantity of output and
charging price above marginal cost. The basic motive of each of the oligopolist is that, he cares
about his own profit, there are powerful incentives as well which hinders a group of firms
maintaining monopoly outcome. The simple type of oligopoly market situation where two
members are present is the case of duopoly. The Nash Equilibrium situation where participants
interacting with one another each choose their best strategy given the strategies that all others
have chosen.
Oligopolies are prevalent throughout the world and appear to be increasing ever so rapidly.
Unlike a monopoly, where one corporation dominates a certain market, an oligopoly consists of a
select few companies having significant influence over an industry. Oligopolies are noticeable in
a multitude of markets. While these companies are considered competitors within the specific
market, they tend to cooperate with each other to benefit as a whole, which can lead to higher
prices for consumers.
Here, the demand curve would be elastic and the change in price would again cause total revenue
to fall - OP3 x OQ3 is smaller than OP x OQ. The logical conclusion from this analysis would
therefore be that oligopolists would benefit from keeping prices stable so long as all could enjoy
reasonable profits at the established price.
The kinked demand curve theory also has other implications. A normal demand curve becomes
less elastic as price falls, but the oligopolist's demand curve becomes less elastic suddenly at the
kink. Mathematically, this causes the MR curve to suddenly change to a different position, so
that a discontinuity exists along the vertical line YZ above output OQ1.
This implies that the MC curve can increase or decrease between this discontiuity, without
necessitating a change in the profit maximising output OQ1 or price OP1 - the oligopolist will
absorb the higher costs. According to normal demand and supply analysis, an increase in costs
would cause a fall in output and an increase in price. An example of cost absorption in practice is
when the price of crude oil rises and petrol companies wish to increase price, but do not as no
company wants to be the first to do so.
2. Collusive Oligopoly
A central feature of competitive or non-collusive oligopoly is the existence of uncertainty
amongst the interdependent firms. Although these firms may utilise informed guesswork and
calculation to cope with such uncertainty, they can never be entirely sure as to how their
competitors will react to any given marketing strategy. Thus instead of living with uncertainty,
firms may adopt a policy of reducing, or even eliminating, it by some form of central co-
ordination, co-operation or collusion. Such collusion may occur where firms attempt to maximise
their joint profits, by reaching agreement on their price, output and other policies, or where firms
seek to prevent the entry of new firms into the industry so as to protect their longer run profits.
Formal Collusion
The most common type of formal collusion is through the cartel; where a small number of rival
firms, selling a similar product, come to the conclusion that it is in their joint interests to
formally collude rather than compete, they may establish a cartel arrangement in which they
agree to set an industry price and output which enables them to achieve a common objective.
This is likely to involve the setting of agreed output quotas for each member in order to maintain
the agreed price. A successful cartel arrangement, from the point of view of the participating
firms, would be one in which the cartel acts like a single monopolist to maximise profits of
individual members.
In practice, cartels may tend to be rather fragile and may not last for very long. This is because
individual members may have an incentive to renege on the agreement by secretly undercutting
the cartel price. The almost inevitable necessity to limit output to keep price high will tend to
leave individual firms with spare productive capacity, and provide the temptation to increase
profits by expanding output. Such an expansion would not only generate profit on the additional
sales, but would also increase the profits on existing sales, as average fixed costs would fall as
output expanded.
As the end result of successful collusion will be to create a situation similar to monopoly, with its
consequent drawbacks and loss of economic efficiency, cartels are illegal in many countries,
including the UK and the USA. Various cartels do, however, operate internationally, the most
famous of which is OPEC. Another example of an international cartel is IATA (The International
Air Transport Association) which has sought to set prices for international airline routes.
However, the experience of both these cartels has been one of price cutting amongst its
members, particularly during periods of declining product demand and competition from non-
members.
Informal Collusion
The most usual method of tacit collusion is priceleadership which occurs where one firm sets a
price which is subsequently accepted as the market price by the other producers. There need be
no formal or written agreement for this to happen; it is sufficient that firms believe this to be the
best way of maintaining or increasing their profits. Price leadership may take various forms:
Dominant firm price leadership - This type of price leadership occurs where a firm,
probably by virtue of its size comes to dominate an industry in terms of its power to
influence market supply. The dominant firm sets a price to suit its own needs and the
smaller firms then adjust their planned output in line with the market price that has been
set for them. An example of such price leadership is provided by Ford Motor Company,
who have often been the first to raise prices in the car industry.
Barometric price leadership - A barometric price leader need not necessarily be the
dominant firm in the industry; rather it will be a firm, possibly small in size, which is
acknowledged by others in the industry as having an informed insight into current market
conditions, perhaps because it employs the best team of accountants and market analysts.
The firm's reputation will therefore enable it to act as a 'barometer' to others in the
industry, and its price movements will be closely followed.
Collusive price leadership - This involves a form of tacit group collusion in which
prices within an industry change almost simultaneously and is linked to price parallelism
where there are identical prices and price movements in a given market. In practice
collusive price leadership might be difficult to distinguish from dominant firm leadership,
especially in circumstances where the price leader is quickly followed.
Tacit collusion may also occur where firms in the industry follow a set of 'rules of thumb'
instead of a price leader. Such rules may be designed to prevent destructive competition
and thus maintain longer term profitability, although some short run profitability may be
sacrificed as the rules do not require MC and MR to be equated. One such rule of thumb
is cost-plus pricing.
Cost-plus pricing - This is also known as average cost pricing, mark-up pricing and full-
cost pricing, and empirical evidence suggests that it is the most common pricing
procedure adopted by firms. It involves firms setting price by adding a standard
percentage profit margin to average costs, so that:
Price = AFC+ AVC + profit margin
Cost-plus pricing is consistent with the idea of relatively stable oligopoly prices as,
providing costs are stable, prices will also remain stable in the short run, even though
demand might be changing. Conversely, if costs rise on average by 5%, then prices in the
industry will also be rising by a similar percentage.
If one were to assess the Big Three, the takeaway would have to be that while General Motors is
bigger currently, Ford is healthier and bears the most potential to be the market leader in the
future & Chrysler is managing itself with other two industries. This, however, is secondary to the
fact that the American automotive industry is significantly stronger than it was ten years ago and
all three major players have taken steps to ensure this in the years to come and stay in the
Oligopoly Market.
Case II –
References
http://www.sanandres.esc.edu.ar/secondary/economics%20packs/microeconomics/page_124.htm
Stigler, G. (1964). A Theory of Oligopoly. Journal of Political Economy, 72(1), 44-61. Retrieved from
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1828791
https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/10195316.pdf