Lewis and Roehrich 09 Libre PDF
Lewis and Roehrich 09 Libre PDF
Lewis and Roehrich 09 Libre PDF
Lewis, MA & Roehrich, JK 2009, 'Contracts, relationships and integration: Towards a model of the procurement
of complex performance', International Journal of Procurement Management, vol. 2, no. 2, pp. 125-142.
https://doi.org/10.1504/IJPM.2009.023403
DOI:
10.1504/IJPM.2009.023403
Publication date:
2009
Document Version
Peer reviewed version
Link to publication
University of Bath
General rights
Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners
and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights.
Version 1.7.
May 19, 2008
* Corresponding Author
Abstract
Although there is a growing body of research exploring
the transition to a more service-based orientation in
complex product markets, the majority of this
literature adopts what mighty be classified as a
‘manufacturer-active’ point of view; that is it
explores the challenges faced by firms (e.g. aircraft
and capital equipment manufacturers, building firms,
etc.) seeking to ‘sell’ their re-conceptualized streams
of revenue. There has been much less research exploring
the challenges associated with the transition from
traditional asset acquisition processes to ‘buying’ or
procuring complex performance (PCP) – here defined as a
combination of transactional and infrastructural
complexity. This paper explores the macro and micro-
economic context to this specific problem space and
develops a preliminary conceptualisation of the process
of PCP. It draws on two principle literatures: one
focused on the boundary conditions firms consider when
choosing to ‘make or buy’ a range of different
activities from the market (e.g. Fine and Whitney,
1999; Gilley and Rasheed, 2000; Williamson, 1985;
Grover and Malhotra, 2003) and, the other on public
procurement (e.g. Thai and Piga, 2006; Knight et al.,
2007) and Public-Private Partnerships in particular
(Broadbent and Laughlin, 2005; Froud, 2003). Three
distinct governance challenges are presented: (1)
contractual, (2) relational and (3) integration. The
paper explores the implications of the conceptual model
by developing a range of research propositions that are
intended to be the foundations for future research.
Acknowledgements
We would like to express our gratitude to the EPSRC KIM
Grand Challenge Programme for funding the research that
forms the background to this paper.
1. Introduction
Buying the performance outcomes of a resource-in-use,
rather than acquiring the resource and using it, is not
a novel phenomenon: from the laundry where a customer
purchases ‘cleaned clothes’ to the vehicle-leasing firm
where a client contracts for ‘miles travelled’. Today
however, this approach is being increasingly applied to
the procurement of complex performance: DuPont for
instance, after years of outsourcing non-core services,
awarded a long-term contract to Convergys to redesign
and deliver the various HRM programs for its 60,000
employees in 70 countries (Engardio et al., 2006).
Likewise, in the computing and telecommunications
sectors for example, the volume of outsourced R&D and
manufacturing services is forecast to grow to almost
$350 billion by 2009 (Carbone, 2005). Similarly firms
like Infosys are developing and maintaining a range of
mission critical IT applications for numerous
international financial institutions. The same trend is
evident in public procurement: UK government for
example has long commissioned specific research
projects from universities and private-sector
institutions but in recent years more and more complex
research performance is being outsourced and contracted
for: for instance, Serco has managed the national
standards laboratory, a large scale, internationally
respected centre of excellence in measurement and
materials science R&D, since 1995.
Interestingly, although there is a growing body of
research exploring different aspects of this transition
to a more complex service-based orientation (Potts,
1988; Armistead and Clark, 1992; Mathe and Shapiro,
1993; Miller et al., 1995; Hobday, 1998; Gadiesh and
Gilbert, 1998; Wise and Baumgartner, 1999; Kumaraswamy
and Zhang, 2001; Mathieu 2001a, 2001b; Brady et al.,
2005; Davies et al., 2007), the majority of this
literature adopts a ‘provider-active’ point of view;
that is it explores the challenges faced by firms (e.g.
aircraft and capital equipment manufacturers, building
firms, etc.) seeking to ‘sell’ their re-conceptualized
streams of revenue. There has been much less research
on the challenges associated with the transition from
traditional asset acquisition processes to ‘buying’
complex performance (e.g. Lindberg and Nordin 2008, van
der Valk 2008). This represents a significant empirical
and theoretical research opportunity because it is a
global phenomenon that necessitates understanding of
the factors that influence both private and public-
sector organisational scale and scope. This exploratory
paper comprises two main sections. The first introduces
the content of, and context to, the research – offering
a model of performance complexity. In the second, the
additive process of procuring complex performance (PCP)
problem space is presented as a series of three
governance challenges: contractual, relational and,
integration. The implications of the conceptualization
are discussed in a range of propositions that can be
viewed as foundations for subsequent research in this
increasingly significant area of public and private
sector procurement.
Infrastructural
Complexity
H III IV
L I II
L H Performance
Complexity
Category Example
I Domestic waste collection service. Here, a public
authority (e.g. Minneapolis, one of the first US cities
to introduce competition in refuse collection) procures a
service with a simple specification and stable demand
patterns (low performance complexity); based on well-
known technologies operating in a fixed area (low
infrastructural complexity)
II Management consultancy services, in particular ‘grey
matter’ assignments such as senior-level policy guidance
(Maister, 1995), are a good example of high performance
complexity (i.e. knowledge intensive and strongly client
relationship/interaction driven) and low infrastructural
complexity.
III An off-shored IT support service with a call centre where
customer interactions are limited in scope and carefully
scripted (i.e. low performance complexity) is delivered
via a relatively sophisticated and complex technological
infrastructure.
IV The UK governments’ (long delayed and expensive)
replacement of its airborne surveillance and counter-
measures aircraft (Nimrod/MRA4) for instance. The prime
contractor, BAe Systems, won the contract to develop and
manufacture a small batch of technologically advanced
aircraft (albeit based on a very old airframe) and
provide their supporting operational and training
infrastructure together with various second line training
and maintenance services (high infrastructural
complexity); all procured under an availability contract
that provided for different levels of mission hours under
different operating conditions, etc. (high performance
complexity).
Proposition 1:
PCP arrangements are considered where organizations can
rely on markets for specialized capabilities, able to
1
An asset is transaction specific if its value in a transaction
with another party is reduced and correspondingly, the larger the
value ‘gap’ between its best and best-alternative use, the greater
the specificity of the asset.
2
Although governance through hierarchy necessitates high fixed set-
up costs, its use of authority rather than court enforced contract
law (for market governance) provides greater control over specific
capability investments (Masten, 1988).
3
See also earlier work by Poppo and Zenger, 1998; Combs and
Ketchen, 1999; Madhok, 2002; Jacobides and Winter, 2005 and Hoetker,
2005.
deliver complex performance, that supplement existing
capabilities deployed along a firms value chain and
create value beyond that achieved through cost
economies.
4
Leaving aside specific (sometimes ideological) concerns, such as
whether the policy is legitimate, cost-effective, actually results
in risk transfer or is sufficiently accountable (e.g. Froud, 2003)
this paper argues that PFI is still innovative public procurement
practice.
5
It has been argued that many of the UK Private Finance Initiative
contracts have been influenced more by politics than economic
rationality (Lonsdale, 2005a).
provision6 and processes of encouraging (via development
funding, etc.) one or two specialized private firms to
develop/offer new services that the state can
eventually buy! In the construction sector for example,
it was arguably the emergence of public sector Build-
Operate-Transfer (BOT) infrastructure projects that
created the ex-ante need for firms to develop their
complex performance provision capabilities (Gann and
Salter 2000). Similarly, Boeing, following an order in
2006 from Air India for 68 aircraft (worth over $11
billion - at 2006 list price!), also agreed to create a
Maintenance, Repair and Overhaul (MRO) facility in
Nagpur and further fund a number of existing Indian
flying schools. Therefore it is proposed that:
Proposition 2:
Public-Private PCP arrangements are considered where a
public buyer is seeking (for a variety of policy
motivations) to create/support markets for specialized
capabilities that replace and/or supplement existing
state provision and create value beyond that achieved
through cost economies.
6
Noting that state service provision is often the result of market
failure.
introduce further uncertainty and complexity. This
paper focuses on three areas of specific conceptual and
practical concern:
Proposition 3:
The greater the complexity of the performance solution
being procured, the greater the time and costs
associated with the contracting process.
7
The buyer - responsible for designing and proposing the contract.
8
The supplier – who will perform the task and must decide if
interested in signing or not (Macho-Stadler and Pérez-Castrillo,
2001)
highlighted this as the PCP challenge (Walder and
Amenta, 2004). Others have proffered the complementary
argument that effective governance in long-term supply
relationships is linked to effective knowledge and
information management over the whole lifecycle, based
on reliable and consistent data. (El-Haram et al.,
2002; Brady et al., 2005; Schofield, 2004; Tranfield et
al., 2005). Thus it is proposed that:
Proposition 4:
The greater the complexity of the performance solution
being procured, the more significant the ex-post
contract monitoring costs (design and implementation of
incentive structures, resource intensity, time
commitment, etc.).
Proposition 5:
PCP arrangements will not be replicated by prime
suppliers with their suppliers (in particular with
smaller firms) in subsequent network tiers.
9
It has consistently been argued that many of the UK Private
Finance Initiative contracts have been influenced more by politics
interest it can yield blind trust, which can be
(rationally) exploited in competitive environments
(Williamson, 1993). Thus it is proposed:
Proposition 6:
In PCP governance joint use of contractual and
relational mechanisms generates more efficient outcomes
than the use of either in isolation but contractual
governance will tend to dominate.
Proposition 7:
The greater the complexity of the performance solution
being procured, the greater the benefits to all PCP
exchange parties from investments in relational
governance during the contracting process.
Proposition 8:
The risk of potentially significant sunk costs will
prevent PCP exchange parties from investing in the
development of relational governance before a contract
has been signed
Proposition 9:
10
A joint-venture between the Australian Macquarie Infrastructure
Group and the Spanish Cintra Concesiones de Infraestructuras de
Transporte S.A.
The greater the complexity of the performance solution
being ‘substituted’ through procurement, the more
significant the technical systems integration challenge
(i.e. time for pre-contractual appraisal, pre-transfer
preparation and post-contractual systems migration).
Proposition 10:
The greater the transactional complexity of the
performance solution being ‘substituted’ through
11
The Transfer of Undertakings (Protection of Employment)
Regulations 2006 (TUPE) is the main piece of UK legislation
governing the transfer of an undertaking (e.g. contracting out of a
service) or part of one, to another organization. Designed to
protect employees in a transfer situation enabling them to enjoy
procurement, the more significant the employee
integration challenge (i.e. time for pre-contractual
appraisal, pre-transfer preparation and post-
contractual incentivization and management).
Proposition 11:
The greater the infrastructural complexity (i.e. long
duration contract integrating multiple design/operating
phases) of the performance solution being procured,
rather than developed in-house, the more significant
the opportunity for supplier innovation.
4. Empirical Research
This is not an empirical paper. The concepts and
specific propositions presented are however intended to
provide a clear starting point for further theory-
driven empirical research (Melnyk and Handfield, 1998).
The authors themselves for instance, have conducted a
large-scale (100+ interviews, 6 supply networks) case
based investigation of propositions 6 and 7 (Zheng et
al. 2008 report preliminary findings from this
project). Specifically the work seeks to explore the
changing significance of contractual and relational
governance over time in the long-term relationships
between public buyers and private service providers.
Although a longitudinal approach in its pure form (i.e.
following the contract over 25 or 30 years) was
impractical, retrospective data was collected using the
respondent-driven critical incident technique. Critical
incidents or events that had a positive or negative
impact on the relationship that occurred during the
different project phases (i.e. procurement/bidding,
construction and operation phases) were mapped along a
timeline.
Further investigations should seek to challenge, test
and modify this set of propositions that are inevitably
‘work-in-progress’. The paper makes no specific
recommendations for methodologies other than to
encourage the widest possible range of methods, with
the recognition that some of the propositions will
probably be better suited to different approaches. An
investigation of propositions 1 and 2 for example,
requires researchers to understand the strategic PCP-
related motivations of a range of stakeholders who may
not themselves recognise the phenomenon being
addressed. This is likely to be best suited to
exploratory case study work or possible a range of
Delphi investigations. Conversely, proposition 3 could,
with suitable refinement and operationalisation of the
PCP matrix (probably via discrete Likert scales), be
analysed with quantitative methods using either
questionnaire data or secondary sources as an input.
5. Conclusions
This paper set out to investigate the integrated
solution or complex performance phenomenon and then
provide some initial conceptualization, via a set of
twelve research propositions, of the distinct practical
and conceptual procurement challenges it creates. The
performance/infrastructural dimension of complexity
presented in section 2 offered a simple definitional
schema for clarifying what exactly is meant by PCP –
noting that buying performance outcomes rather than
acquiring resources and using them is not itself a
novel phenomenon (e.g. leasing). The complexity model
allowed us to focus on the distinct notion of PCP. It
is clear from this preliminary exploration that any
complex phenomenon will generate myriad issues of
conceptual and practical interest and as a result the
core of the paper was a more focused discussion of
distinct governance challenges associated with PCP.
Accepting this limitation, conclusions emerged in three
principal areas.
First, it is critical to set the PCP phenomenon in a
broader economic and political context and highlight
the central role of de-regulation/globalization and
evolving public sector procurement in the emergence of
the phenomenon. The work argues that a purely
transaction-based logic is insufficient to understand
why the phenomenon has emerged (e.g. Transaction Cost
Economics would suggest that PCP is an inappropriate
make v buy solution) and that PCP buying organizations
are therefore motivated by a combination of cost
economies and capabilities management. The more
‘strategic’ or ‘(public) policy’ (i.e. long term,
ambiguous, risk bearing) nature of this type of
decision-making renders it more controversial, as
particularly evident in the critiques of PPP/PFI. The
paper also argues that although buyers may have
distinct strategic motivations, public and private PCP
can be, a priori, examined as a common process.
Second, PCP arrangements introduce a number of specific
challenges for contractual and relational governance.
Complexity has the potential to render any contracting
process both more expensive and more ‘incomplete’,
opening up the intriguing possibility that although PCP
exchange may be heavily reliant on contractual
mechanisms, it may actually lack enforcement
capabilities. As a result there will be significant
benefits to all PCP parties from greater interaction
but the potential risk of sunk costs determines the
precise level of investment in the development of
relational governance.
Third, both ‘substitution-based’ but more significantly
‘abstention-based’ PCP are likely, over time, to result
in capability gaps emerging between buying
organizations and their intermediate markets. The
experienced supplier develops a breadth and depth of
capabilities that it can apply to any individual
transaction but the PCP buyer it is likely that, over
time, capabilities will relate to older performance
characteristics.
References
1. Armistead, C. G. and Clark, G. (1992). Customer
service and support: Implementing effective
strategies. London: Financial-Times Pitman
Publishing.
2. Baiman, S. and Rajan, M. V. (2002). The role of
information and opportunism in the choice of
buyer-supplier relationships. Journal of
Accounting Research, Vol. 40, No. 2, pp.247-278.
3. Baker, G., Gibbons, R. and Murphy, K. J. (1994).
Subjective performance measures in optimal
incentive contracts. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 109, No. 4, pp.1125-1156.
4. Baker, G., Gibbons, R. and Murphy, K. J. (2002).
Relational contracts and the theory of the firm.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No.
1, pp.39-84.
5. Bennett, J. and Iossa, E. (2006). Building and
managing facilities for public services. Journal
of Public Economics, Vol. 90, No. 10-11, pp.2143-
2160.
6. Brady, T., Davies, A. and Gann, D. (2005).
Creating value by delivering integrated services.
International Journal of Project Management, Vol.
23, No. 5, pp.360-365.
7. Broadbent, J. and Laughlin, R. (2005). The role of
PFI in the UK Government’s Modernisation Agenda.
Financial Accountability & Management, Vol. 21,
No. 1, pp.75-97.
8. Carbone, J. (2005). Worldwide outsourcing rises.
Electronics Purchasing. Retrieved 1st December 2007
from http://www.purchasing.com/
article/CA501253.html .
9. Carney, M. (1998). The competitiveness of
networked production: The role of trust and asset
specificity. Journal of Management Studies, Vol.
35, No.4, pp.457-479.
10. Combs, J. G. and Ketchen Jr., D. J. (1999).
Explaining Interfirm Cooperation and Performance:
Toward a Reconciliation of Predictions from the
Resource-Based View and Organizational Economics.
Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 20, No. 9,
pp.867-888.
11. Danaher, P. J. and Mattsson, J. (1998). A
comparison of service delivery processes of
different complexity. International Journal of
Service Industry Management, Vol. 9, No. 1, pp.48-
63
12. Davies, A., Brady, T. and Hobday, M. (2007).
Organizing for solutions: Systems seller vs.
systems integrator. Industrial Marketing
Management, Vol. 36, No. 2, pp.183-193.
13. Deakin, S. and Wilkinson, F. (1998). Contract
Law and the Economics of Interorganisational
Trust. In: Lane, C. and Bachmann, R. (eds.)
(1998). Trust Within and Between Organisations:
Conceptual Issues and Applications. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, pp.146-172.
14. Dixon, T., Pottinger, G. and Jordan, A.
(2005). Lessons from the private finance
initiative in the UK: Benefits, problems and
critical success factors. Journal of Property
Investment and Finance, Vol. 23, No. 5, pp.412-
423.
15. El-Haram, M. A., Marenjak, S. and Horner, M.
W. (2002). Development of a generic framework for
collecting whole life cost data for the building
industry. Journal of Quality in Maintenance
Engineering, Vol. 8, No. 2. pp.144- 151.
16. Engardio, P., Arndt, M. and Foust, D. (2006).
Outsourcing. Business Week, 30th January, 2006.
17. Erridge, A. and Greer, J. (2002).
Partnerships and public procurement: building
social capital through supply relations. Public
Administration, 80(3): 503-522.
18. Fine, C. H. and Whitney, D. E. (1999). Is the
make-buy decision a core competence? In: Muffatto,
M. and Pawar, K. (eds.), Logistics in the
Information Age, Servizi Grafici Editoriali,
Padova, Italy, 1999, pp.31-63.
19. Flowers, S. (2007). Organizational
capabilities and technology acquisition: why firms
know less than they buy. Industrial and Corporate
Change, Vol. 16, No. 3, pp.317-346.
20. Froud, J. (2003). The Private Finance
Initiative: risk, uncertainty and the state.
Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 28,
No. 6, pp.567-589.
21. Gadiesh, O. and Gilbert, J. L. (1998). Profit
Pools: a fresh look at strategy. Harvard Business
Review, Vol. 76, No. 3, pp.139-147.
22. Gann, D. M and Salter, A. J. (2000).
Innovation in project-based, service-enhanced
firms: the construction of complex products and
systems. Research Policy, Vol. 29, No. 7-8,
pp.955–972.
23. Gaski, F. F. (1984). The theory of power and
conflict in channels of distribution. Journal of
Marketing, Vol. 48, No. 3, pp.9-29.
24. Gilley, K. M. and Rasheed, A. (2000). Making
more by doing less: An analysis of outsourcing and
its effects on firm performance. Journal of
Management, Vol. 26, No. 4, pp.763-790.
25. Granovetter, M. S. (1973). The strength of
weak ties. American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 78,
No. 6, pp.1360-1380.
26. Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and
social structure: The problem of embeddedness.
American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 91, No. 3,
pp.481-510.
27. Grimshaw, D. Vincent, S. and Willmott, H.
(2002). Going privately: partnership and
outsourcing in UK public services, Public
Administration, Vol. 80, No. 3, pp.475-502.
28. Grover, V. and Malhotra, M. K. (2003).
Transaction cost framework in operations and
supply chain management research: theory and
measurement. Journal of Operations Management,
Vol. 21, No. 4, pp.457-473.
29. Gulati, R. (1995). Does familiarity breed
trust? The implications of repeated ties for
contractual choice in alliances. Academy of
Management Journal, Vol. 38, No. 1, pp.85-112.
30. Halldórsson, Á. and Skjøtt-Larsen, T. (2006).
Dynamics of relationship governance in TPL
arrangements – a dyadic perspective. International
Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics
Management, Vol. 35, No. 7, pp.490-506.
31. Håkansson, H. and Snehota, I. (1995)
Developing Relationships in Business Networks.
London: International Thomson Business Press.
32. Hobday, M. (1998). Product complexity,
innovation and industrial organization. Research
Policy, Vol. 26, No. 6, pp.689–710.
33. Hoetker, G. (2005). How much you know versus
how well I know you: selecting a supplier for a
technically innovative component. Strategic
Management Journal, Vol. 26, No. 1, pp.75 – 96
34. Holcomb, T. R. and Hitt, M. A. (2007) Toward
a model of strategic outsourcing. Journal of
Operations Management, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp.464-481.
35. Jacobides, M. G. (2005). Industry change
trough vertical disintegration: How and why
markets emerged in mortgage banking. Academy of
Management Journal, Vol. 48, No. 3, pp.465-498
36. Jacobides, M. G. and Winter, S. G. (2005).
The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction
costs: explaining the institutional structure of
production. Strategic Management Journal, Vol.
26, No. 5, pp.395-413.
37. Klein Woolthuis, R., Hillebrand, B. and
Nooteboom, B. (2005). Trust, contract and
relationship development, Organization Studies,
Vol. 26, No. 6, pp.813-840.
38. Knight, L. A., Harland, C. M., Telgen, J.,
Callender, G., Thai, K. V. and McKen, K. E. (eds.)
(2007). Public Procurement: International Cases
and Commentary. London: Routledge.
39. Koppenjan, J. F. M. (2005). The formation of
public-private partnerships: Lessons from nine
transport infrastructure projects in the
Netherlands. Public Administration, Vol. 83, No.
1, pp.135-157.
40. Kumaraswamy, M. M. and Zhang, X. Q. (2001).
Governmental role in BOT-led infrastructure
development. International Journal Project
Management, Vol. 19, No. 4, pp.195–205.
41. Larson, A. (1992). Network dyads in
entrepreneurial settings: A study of the
governance of exchange relationships.
Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 37, No. 1,
pp.76-104.
42. Leiringer, R. (2006). Technological
innovation in PPPs: incentives, opportunities and
actions. Construction Management & Economics, Vol.
24, No. 3, pp.301-308.
43. Lindberg, N. and Nordin, F. (2008). From
products to services and back again: Towards a new
service procurement logic. Industrial Marketing
Management, Vol. 37, No. 1, pp.292-300.
44. Lonsdale, C. (2005a). Risk transfer and the
UK private finance initiative: a theoretical
analysis. Policy and Politics, Vol. 33, No. 2,
pp.231-249.
45. Lonsdale, C. (2005b). Post-contractual lock-
in and the UK Private Finance Initiative (PFI):
The cases of national savings and investments and
the Lord Chancellor's Department. Public
Administration, Vol. 83, No. 1, pp.67-88.
46. Lui, S. S. and Ngo, H.-Y. (2004). The role of
trust and contractual safeguards on cooperation in
non-equity alliances. Journal of Management, Vol.
30, No. 4, pp.471-485.
47. Lyons, B. and Mehta, J. (1997). Contracts,
opportunism and trust: self-interest and social
orientation. Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol.
21, No. 2, pp.239-257.
48. Macaulay, S. (1963). Non-contractual
relations in business: a preliminary study.
American Sociological Review, Vol. 28, No. 1,
pp.55-67.
49. Macho-Stadler, I. and Pérez-Castrillo, J. D.
(2001). An Introduction to the Economics of
Information: Incentives and Contracts. Oxford:
University Press.
50. Macneil, I. R. (1978). Contracts: adjustment
of long-term economic relations under classical,
neoclassical, and relational contract law.
Northwestern University Law Review, Vol. 72, No.
6, pp.854-905.
51. Macneil, I. R. (1980). The New Social
Contract: An Inquiry into Modern Contractual
Relations. London: Yale University Press.
52. Madhok, A. (2002). Reassessing the
fundamentals and beyond: Ronald Coase, the
transaction cost and resource-based theories of
the firm and the institutional structure of
production. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 23,
No. 6, pp.535-550.
53. Masten, S. E. (1988). A Legal Basis for the
Firm. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization,
Vol. 4, No. 1, pp.181-198.
54. Mathe, H. and Shapiro, R. D. (1993).
Integrating service strategy in the manufacturing
company. London: Chapman and Hall.
55. Mathieu, V. (2001a). Service strategies
within the manufacturing sector: benefits, costs
and partnership. International Journal of Service
Industry Management, Vol. 12, No. 5, pp.451-475.
56. Mathieu, V. (2001b). Product services: from a
service supporting the product to a service
supporting the client. The Journal of Business and
Industrial Marketing. Vol. 16, No. 1, pp.39–61.
57. Melnyk, S. A. and Handfield, R. B. (1998).
May you live in interesting times … the emergence
of theory-driven empirical research. Journal of
Operations Management, Vol. 16, No. 4, pp.311-319.
58. Miller, R., Hobday, M., Leroux-Demers, T. and
Olleros, X. (1995). Innovation in complex system
industries: the case of flight simulators.
Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 4, No. 2,
pp.363–400.
59. MOD – Ministry of Defence. (2005) Defence
Industrial Strategy - Defence White Paper. Ref: Cm
6697.
60. Mont, O. (2000). Product-Service Systems.
International Institute of Industrial
Environmental Economics, Lund University.
61. NAO – National Audit Office (2003). Through-
life Management – Report by the Controller and
Auditor General. HC 698 / May.
62. Nisar, T. M. (2007). Risk management in
Public–Private Partnership contracts. Public
Organization Review, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp.1-19.
63. North, D.C. (1990). Institutions,
Institutional Change and Economic Performance.
Cambridge: University Press.
64. Oliva, R. and Kallenberg, R. (2003). Managing
the transition from products to services.
International Journal of Service Industry
Management, Vol. 14, No. 2, pp.160-172.
65. Olsen, B. E.; Haugland, S. A.; Karlsen, E.
and Husøy, G. J. (2005). Governance of complex
procurements in the oil and gas industry. Journal
of Purchasing & Supply Management, Vol. 11, No. 1,
pp.1-13.
66. Parkhe, A. (1993). Strategic alliance
structuring: A game theoretic and transaction cost
examination of interfirm cooperation. Academy of
Management Journal, Vol. 36, No. 4, pp.794-829.
67. Poppo, L. and Zenger, T. (1998). Testing
alternative theories of the firm: transaction
cost, knowledge‐based, and measurement
explanations for make‐or‐buy decisions in
information services. Strategic Management
Journal, Vol. 19, No. 9, pp.853-877.
68. Poppo, L. and Zenger, T. (2002). Do formal
contracts and relational governance function as
substitutes or complements? Strategic Management
Journal, Vol. 23, No. 8, pp.707-725.
69. Potts, G. W. (1988). Exploiting your
product’s service life cycle. Harvard Business
Review, Vol. 66, No. 5, pp.32-35.
70. Quinn, J.; Doorley, T. and Paquette, P. C.
(1990). Beyond Products: Service-based Strategy.
Harvard Business Review, Vol. 68, No. 2, pp.58-67.
71. Ratcliffe, A. (2004). The Real Benefit of the
PFI? Public Money & Management, Vol. 24, No. 3,
pp.134-135.
72. Rindfleisch, A. and Heide, J. B. (1997).
Transaction Cost Analysis: Past, Present, and
Future Applications. The Journal of Marketing,
Vol. 61, No. 4, pp.30-54.
73. Ring, P. S. and Van de Ven, A. H. (1994).
Developmental processes of cooperative
interorganizational relationships. The Academy of
Management Review, Vol. 19, No. 1, pp.90-118.
74. Schofield, J. (2004). A Model of learned
implementation. Public Administration, Vol. 82,
No. 2, pp.283-308
75. Staughton, M. and Votta, T. (2003).
Implementing service-based chemical procurement:
lessons and results. Journal of Cleaner
Production, Vol. 11, No. 8, pp.839-849.
76. Stephen, A. T. and Coote, L. V. (2007).
Interfirm behaviour and goal alignment in
relational exchanges. Journal of Business
Research, Vol. 60, No. 4, pp.285-295.
77. Thai, K. and Piga, G. (eds.) (2006).
Advancing Public Procurement: Practices,
Innovation and Knowledge-sharing. Boca Raton, Fl,
USA: Pracademics Press.
78. Teisman, G. R. and Klijn, E. H. (2004). PPPs:
Torn between two lovers. EBF Debate, Vol. 18,
pp.27-29.
79. Tranfield, D.; Rowe, A.; Smart, P. K.;
Levene, R.; Deasley, P. and Corley, J. (2005).
Coordinating for service delivery in public-
private partnership and private finance initiative
construction projects: early findings from an
exploratory study. Proceedings of the Institution
of Mechanical Engineers Part B-Journal of
Engineering Manufacture, Vol. 219, No. 1, pp.165-
175.
80. UK Stationery Office (2000). Public Private
Partnerships, The Government’s Approach. HM
Treasury, UK.
81. Vandaele, D., Rangarajan, D, Gemmel, P. And
Lievens, A. (2007). How to govern business
services exchanges: Contractual and relational
issues. International Journal of Management
Reviews, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp.237-258.
82. van der Valk, W. (2008). Service procurement
in manufacturing companies: Results of three
embedded case studies. Industrial Marketing
Management, Vol. 37, No. 1, pp.301-315.
83. Walder, J. H. and Amenta, T. L. (2004).
Financing New Infrastructures: Public/Private
Partnerships and Private Finance Initiatives. In
Hanley, R. (ed.) (2004). Moving People, Goods and
Information in the 21st century. New York: Spoon
Press, pp.79-97.
84. Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and
hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications:
a study in the economics of internal organization.
New York: Free Press.
85. Williamson, O.E. (1985). The Economic
Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.
86. Williamson, O.E. (1993). Calculativeness,
trust and economic organization. Journal of Law
and Economics, Vol. 36, No. 1, pp.453-486.
87. Wise, R. and Baumgartner, P. (1999). Go
downstream: the new imperative in manufacturing.
Harvard Business Review, Vol. 77, No. 5, pp.133-
141.
88. Youngdahl, W. and Ramaswamy, K. (2007).
Offshoring knowledge and service work: A
conceptual model and a research agenda. Journal of
Operations Management. (In Press).
89. Zand, D. E. (1972). Trust and managerial
problem solving. Administrative Science Quarterly,
Vol. 17, No. 2, pp.229-239.
90. Zheng, J., Roehrich, J.K. and Lewis, M.A.
(2008). The dynamics of contractual and relational
governance: evidence from long-term public-private
procurement arrangements. Journal of Procurement
and Supply Management, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp.43-54.
91. Zucker, L. G. (1986). Production of trust:
Institutional sources of economic structure, 1840-
1920. Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 8,
No. 1, pp.53-111.