Sourcing Decisions in Supply Chain: Benefits of Effective Sourcing
Sourcing Decisions in Supply Chain: Benefits of Effective Sourcing
Sourcing Decisions in Supply Chain: Benefits of Effective Sourcing
Purchasing: Also called the procurement, is the process by which companies acquire raw materials, components,
product, services or other resources from suppliers to execute their operations.
Sourcing: The entire set of business process required to purchase goods and services.
In-house or Outsource
A firm should consider outsourcing if the growth in supply chain surplus is large with a small increase in risk.
Performing the function in-house is preferable if the growth in surplus is small or the increase in risk is large.
1. Capacity aggregation: Surplus can be created by aggregating demand across multiple firms and gaining
production economies of scale that no single firm can on its own.
The growth in surplus from outsourcing is highest when the needs of the firm are significantly lower than
the volumes required to gain economies of scale.
2. Inventory aggregation: Surplus can be created by aggregating inventories across a large number of customers.
Aggregation allows them to significantly lower overall uncertainty and improve economies of scale in purchasing
and transportation.
The third party performing inventory aggregation adds most to the supply chain surplus when demand
from customers is fragmented and uncertain.
3. Transportation aggregation by transportation intermediaries: Surplus can be created by aggregating the
transportation function to a higher level than any shipper can on its own. The transportation intermediary
aggregates shipments across multiple shippers, thus lowering the cost of each shipment below what could be
achieved by the shipper alone.
This is particularly true if the shipper's transportation flows are highly unbalanced, with the quantity
coming into a region very different from the quantity leaving the region.
4. Transportation aggregation by storage intermediaries: Surplus can be created by aggregating in bound and out
bound transportation.
This form of aggregation is most effective if the intermediary stocks products from many suppliers and
serves many customers, each ordering in small quantities.
5. Warehousing aggregation: Surplus can be created by aggregating warehousing needs over several customers. (in
terms of lower real estate cost and lower processing cost).
Savings through warehousing aggregation arise if a supplier's warehousing needs are small or if its needs
fluctuate over time
6. Procurement aggregation: Surplus can be created if a third party if it aggregates procurement for many small
players and facilitates economies of scale in production and inbound transportation.
Procurement aggregation is most effective across many small buyers.
7. Information aggregation: Supply chain surplus can be increased by aggregating information to a higher level
than can be achieved by a firm performing the function in-house. This information aggregation reduces search
costs for customers.
Information aggregation increases the surplus if both buyers and sellers are fragmented and buying is
sporadic.
8. Receivables aggregation: Supply Chain surplus cab be increase if third party can aggregate the receivables risk to
a higher level than the firm or it has a lower collection cost than the firm. Collecting receivables from each retail
outlet is a very expensive proposition for a manufacturer.
Receivables aggregation is likely to increase the supply chain surplus if retail outlets are small and
numerous and each outlet stocks products from many manufacturers that are all served by the same
distributor.
9. Lower costs and higher quality: A third party can increase the supply chain surplus if it provides lower cost or
higher quality relative to the firm. If these benefits come from specialization and learning, they are likely to be
sustainable over the longer term. A specialized third party that is further along the learning curve for some
supply chain activity is likely to maintain its advantage over the long term.
A firm gains the most by outsourcing to a third party if its needs are small, highly uncertain and shared by
other firms sourcing from the same third party.
Buyback or returns contracts: A buy-back or returns clause in a contract allows a retailer to return unsold inventory
up to a specified amount, at an agreed-upon price.
c: wholesale price, b: buy back price, sM: Salvage Value, O*: Optimal Order Quantity
In some instances, manufacturers use holding-cost subsidies or price protection to encourage retailers to order
more. In the high-tech industry, in which products lose value rapidly, manufacturers share the risk of product
becoming obsolete by providing price support to retailers.
A downside to the buy-back clause (or any equivalent practice such as holding cost subsidy or price support) is
that it leads to surplus inventory that must be salvaged or disposed. The task of returning unsold product
increases supply chain costs. The cost of returns can be eliminated if the manufacturer gives the retailer a
markdown allowance and allows it to sell the product at a significant discount.
Revenue-Sharing Contracts:
In revenue-sharing contracts, the manufacturer charges the retailer a low wholesale price c, and shares a fraction f of
the retailer's revenue. Even if no returns are allowed, the lower wholesale price decreases the cost to the retailer in
case of an overstock. The retailer thus increases the level of product availability resulting in higher profits for both
the manufacturer and the retailer. If the production cost v, retail price p, salvage value is sR , optimal order quantity
O*, where the cost of under stacking is Cu = (1 - f)p - c and the cost of overstocking is Cu = c - sR. We thus obtain
One advantage of revenue-sharing contracts over buy-back contracts is that no product needs to be returned, thus
eliminating the cost of returns. Revenue sharing contracts are best suited for products with low variable cost and a
high cost of return.
Revenue sharing contracts counter double marginalization by decreasing the cost per unit charged to the
retailer thus decreasing the cost of over stocking. They increase information distortion and lead to lower
retailer effort in case of over stocking, just as but back contracts do.
Quantity Flexibility Contracts:
Under quantity flexibility contracts, the manufacturer allows the retailer to change the quantity ordered after
observing demand. If a retailer orders 0 units, the manufacturer commits to providing Q = (1 + α)O units, whereas
the retailer is committed to buying at least q = (1 - β )O units. Both α and β are between 0 and 1.
Quantity flexibility contracts are common for components in the electronics and computer industry. If the supplier
has flexible capacity, a quantity flexibility contract increases profits for the entire supply chain and also each party.
The quantity flexibility contract requires either inventory or excess flexible capacity to be available at the supplier. If
the supplier is selling to multiple retailers with independent demand, the aggregation of inventory leads to a smaller
surplus inventory with a quantity flexibility contract compared to either a buy-back or revenue-sharing contract.
Relative to buy-back and revenue-sharing contracts, quantity flexibility contracts have less information distortion.
Quantity flexible contracts counter double marginalization by giving the retailer the ability to modify the
order based on improved forecasts closer to the point of sale. They result in lower information distortion than
buy back or revenue contacts when a supplier sells to multiple buyers or supplier has excess flexible capacity.
Based on the value and criticality of the product, they are classified into four groups:
1. General Items: Low value, Low Criticality. Mostly Indirect Items. Aim: Lower the cost of acquisition.
2. Bulk purchase items: High value, Low Criticality. Method: well-designed auctions.
3. Strategic Items: Low value, High Criticality. Components with long lead times. Aim: ensure availability
4. Critical Items: High value, High Criticality. Aim: Long term buyer-supplier relationship