Profit Functions: Epresentation of Echnology
Profit Functions: Epresentation of Echnology
Profit Functions: Epresentation of Echnology
1. R EPRESENTATION OF T ECHNOLOGY
1.1. Technology Sets. The technology set for a given production process is defined as
T = {(x, y) : x ² Rn+ , y ² Rm :
+ x can produce y}
where x is a vector of inputs and y is a vector of outputs. The set consists of those combinations
of x and y such that y can be produced from the given x.
1.2. The Output Correspondence and the Output Set.
1.2.1. Definitions. It is often convenient to define a production correspondence and the associated
output set.
n n
1: The output correspondence P, maps inputs x ² R+ into subsets of outputs, i.e., P: R+ →
m
R+
2 . A correspondence is different from a function in that a given domain is mapped into
a set as compared to a single real variable (or number) as in a function.
m
2: The output set for a given technology, P(x), is the set of all output vectors y ² R+ that are
n m
obtainable from the input vector x ² R+ . P(x) is then the set of all output vectors y ² R+
n
that are obtainable from the input vector x ² R+ . We often write P(x) for both the set based
on a particular value of x, and the rule (correspondence) that assigns a set to each vector x.
1.2.2. Relationship between P(x) and T(x,y).
P (x) = (y : (x, y ) ² T )
1.2.3. Properties of P(x).
n
P.1a: P.1 No Free Lunch. 0 ² P(x) ∀ x ² R+ .
P.1b: y 6∈ P(0), y > 0.
n
P.2: Input Disposability. ∀ x ² R+ , P(x) ⊆ P(θx), θ ≥ 1.
n
P.2.S: Strong Input Disposability. ∀ x, x’ ² R+ , x’ ≥ x ⇒ P(x) ⊆ P(x’).
n
P.3: Output Disposability. ∀ x ² R+ , y ² P(x) and 0 ≤ λ ≤ 1 ⇒ λy ² P(x).
n
P.3.S: Strong Output Disposability. ∀ x ² R+ , y ² P(x) ⇒ y’ ² P(x), 0 ≤ y’ ≤ y.
P.4: Boundedness. P(x) is bounded for all x ² Rn + .
m
P.5: T(x) is a closed set P: R+ n
→ 2R+ is a closed correspondence, i.e., if [x` → x0 , y` → y0 and
y` ² P(x` ), ∀ `] then y0 ² P(x0 ).
P.6: Attainability. If y ² P(x), y ≥ 0 and x ≥ 0, then ∀ θ ≥ 0, ∃ λθ ≥ 0 such that θy ² P(λθ x).
P.7: P(x) is convex
n
P(x) is convex for all x ² R+ .
P.8: P is quasi-concave.
n n
The correspondence P is quasi-concave on R+ which means ∀ x, x’ ² R+ , 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1, P(x)
∩ P(x’) ⊆ P(θx + (1-θ)x’)
n n
P.9: Convexity of T(x). P is concave on R+ which means ∀ x, x’ ² R+ , 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1, θP(x)+(1-
θ)P(x’) ⊆ P(θx + (1-θ)x’)
T.9: T is a convex set. This is not implied by the convexity of P(x) and V(y). Specifically, a
technology could exhibit a diminishing rate of technical substitution, a diminishing rate of
product transformation and still exhibit increasing returns to scale.
2.1.1. Setup of problem. The general firm-level maximization problem can be written in a number of
alternative ways.
m
X n
X
π = max [ pj yj − wi xi ], such that (x, y) ∈ T. (1)
xy
j=1 i=1
where T is represents the graph of the technology or the technology set. The problem can also
be written as
m
X n
X
π = max [ pj yj − wi xi ] such hat x ∈ V(y) ] (2a)
xy
j=1 i=1
m
X n
X
π = max [ pj yj − wi xi ] such that y ∈ P(x) ] (2b)
xy
j=1 i=1
where the technology is represented by V(y), the input requirement set, or P(x),the output set.
Though T is non-empty, closed and convex, profit may not attain a maximum on T, i.e. profit can be
unbounded even when the technology set is well behaved if output price is higher than input price.
Consider for example the production function f(x)= x + x1/2 . The production function is concave
but profit will go to infinity if p > w. Therefore we often write
Xm n
X
π = sup [ pj yj − wi xi ], such that (x, y) ∈ T. (3)
xy
j=1 i=1
where sup stands for supremum and could be infinity. We understand that in all practical prob-
lems the sup is a max.
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 3
π = p f (x1 , x2 ) − w1 x1 − w2 x2 (4)
If we differentiate the expression in equation 4 with respect to each input we obtain
∂π ∂f (x1 , x2 )
=p − w1 = 0
∂ x1 ∂x1
(5)
∂π ∂f (x1 , x2 )
=p − w2 = 0
∂ x2 ∂x2
If we solve the equations in 5 for x1 and x2 , we obtain the optimal values of x for a given p and
w. As a function of w for a fixed p, this gives the vector of factor demands for x.
x∗ = x(p, w1 , w2 )
(6)
= ( x1 (p, w1 , w2 ), x2 (p, w1 , w2 ) )
The optimal output is given by
To help understand how π(p,w) only depends on p and w, consider the profit function for the
case of two inputs.
∂π(p, w) ∂f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w)) ∂x1 (p, w) ∂f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w)) ∂x2 (p, w)
=p + p
∂p ∂x1 ∂p ∂x2 ∂p
(10)
∂x1 (p, w)) ∂x2 (p, w))
+ f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w)) − w1 − w2
∂p ∂p
∂x1 (p,w) ∂x2 (p,w)
Now collect terms containing ∂p and ∂p .
4 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
· ¸
∂π(p, w) ∂x1 (p, w) ∂f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w))
= p − w1
∂p ∂p ∂x1
· ¸
∂x2 (p, w)) ∂f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w)) (11)
+ p − w2
∂p ∂x2
+ f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w))
But the first order conditions in equation 5 imply that
∂f (x1 x2 )
p − wi = 0, i = 1, 2 (12)
∂xi
This means that the two bracketed terms in equation 11 are equal to zero so that
∂π(p, w)
= f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w)) (13)
∂p
which depends only on p and w.
4.1. π.1. π(p, w) is an extended real valued function (it can take on the value of +∞ for finite prices)
defined for all (p, w) = (0m , 0n )) and π(p, w) ≥ pa - wb for a fixed vector (a, b) ≥ (0m , 0n ). This
implies that π(p, w) = 0.
The profit function can be infinity due to the fact that maximum profits may be infinity as dis-
cussed in section 2.1.1. π(p, w) ≥ pa - wb for a fixed vector (a, b) because π(p, w) is the maximum
profit at output prices p and input prices w. Any other input combination is bounded by π(p, w).
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 5
Let optimal input be x̃(p,w) with prices p and w̃ and x̂(p,w) with prices p and ŵ. Now assume
that ŵ > w̃. It is clear that pf(x̂(p,w) ) - w̃ x̂(p,w) ≤ pf(x̃(p,w)) - w̃ x̃(p,w) because the optimal x with
w̃ is x̃. However, pf(x̂) - ŵ x̂ < pf(x̂ ) - w̃ x̂ because ŵ > w̃ by assumption. So we obtain
Let profit be π̃ (p̃,w) with prices p̃ and w and π̂(p̂,w) with prices p̂ and w. Now assume that p̂ >
p̃. It is clear that
p̃f (x̃(p, w) ) − w x̃(p, w) < p̂ f (x̃(p, w)) − w x̃(p, w) ≤ p̂ f (x̂(p, w)) − w x̂(p, w)
(18)
⇒ p̃f (x̃(p, w) ) − w x̃(p, w) ≤ p̂ f (x̂(p, w)) − w x̂(p, w)
Let (y,x) be the profit maximizing choices of y and x when prices are(p, w) and let (y’,x’) be
profit maximizing maximizing choices of y and x when prices are(p’, w’). Let (p” w”) be a linear
combination of the price vectors (p,w) and (p’,w’), i.e.
= [ λ p + (1 − λ) p0 ] y 00 − [ λ w + (1 − λ) w0 ] x00
(22)
= λ p y 00 − λ w x00 + (1 − λ) p0 y 00 − (1 − λ) w0 x00
= λ [ p y 00 − w x00 ] + (1 − λ) [ p0 y 00 − w0 x00 ]
Be the definition of profit maximization, we know that when prices are (p,w) any output input
combination other than (y,x) will yield lower profits. Similarly when prices are (p’, w’). We then
can write
λ [ p y 00 − w x00 ] ≤ λ [ p y − w x] = λ π (p, w)
(23)
(1 − λ) [ p0 y 00 − w0 x00 ] ≤ (1 − λ) [ p0 y 0 − w0 x0 ] = (1 − λ )π (p0 , w0 )
Now write equation 23 without the middle terms
λ [ p y 00 − w x00 ] ≤ λ π (p, w)
(24)
(1 − λ) [ p0 y 00 − w0 x00 ] ≤ (1 − λ )π (p0 , w0 )
Now add the two inequalities in equation 24 to obtain
Xm n
X
π(p, w) = max [ pj yj − wi xi ], such that (x, y) ∈ T. (27)
xy
j=1 i=1
Now multiply all prices by λ and denote the new profit mximization problem as
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 7
L
ΠHp,w
~ L=py*-w
x*
PHp*,w
L
ΠHp*,w
p
p*
Xm n
X
π ∗ (p, w) = max [ λ pj yj − λ wi xi ], such that (x, y) ∈ T
xy
j=1 i=1
Xm n
X (28)
= λ max [ pj yj − wi xi ]
xy
j=1 i=1
∗
⇒ π (p, w) = λ π(p, w)
∂π(p, w) ∂f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w)) ∂x1 (p, w) ∂f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w)) ∂x2 (p, w)
=p + p
∂w1 ∂x1 ∂w1 ∂x2 ∂w1
(31)
∂x1 (p, w)) ∂x2 (p, w))
− w1 − x1 (p, w) − w2
∂w1 ∂w1
∂x1 (p,w) ∂x2 (p,w)
Now collect terms containing ∂w1 and ∂w1 .
8 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
· ¸
∂π(p, w) ∂x1 (p, w) ∂f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w))
= p − w1
∂w1 ∂w1 ∂x1
· ¸
∂x2 (p, w)) ∂f (x1 (p, w), x2 (p, w)) (32)
+ p − w2
∂w1 ∂x2
− x1 (p, w1 , w2 )
But the first order conditions in equation 5 imply that
∂f (x1 x2 )
p − wi = 0, i = 1, 2 (33)
∂xi
This means that the two braketed terms in equation 32 are equal to zero so that
∂π(p, w)
= − x1 (p, w1 , w2 ) (34)
∂w1
We can show this in a more general manner as follows. Define a function g(p,w) as follows
∂g(p∗ , w∗ ) ∂π(p∗ , w∗ )
= − yj∗ = 0, j = 1, 2, . . . , m
∂pj ∂pj
(36)
∂g(p∗ , w∗ ) ∂π(p∗ , w∗ )
= + x∗j = 0, i = 1, 2, . . . , n
∂wi ∂wi
Rearranging equation 36 we obtain
∂π(p∗ , w∗ )
− yj∗ = 0, j = 1, 2, . . . , m
∂pj
∂π(p∗ , w∗ )
⇒ = yj∗ , j = 1, 2, . . . , m
∂pj
(37)
∂π(p∗ , w∗ )
+ x∗j = 0, i = 1, 2, . . . , n
∂wi
∂π(p∗ , w∗ )
⇒ = − x∗i , i = 1, 2, . . . , m
∂wi
A number of important implications come from equation 37.
1: We can obtain output supply and input demand equations by differentiating the profit
function.
2: If we have an expression (equation) for the profit function, we can obtain output supply
and input demand equations or functional forms for such equations by differentiating the
profit function as compared to solving a maximization problem. This would allow one to
find functional forms for estimating supply and demand without solving maximization
problems.
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 9
3: Given that the output supply and input demand functions are derivatives of the profit
function, we can determine many of the properties of these response functions by under-
standing the properties of the profit function. For example, because the profit function is
homogeneous of degree one in p and w, its derivatives are homogeneous of degree zero.
This means that output supply and input demand equations are homogeneous of degree
zero, i.e., multiplying all prices by the same constant will not change output supply or
input demand.
4: The second derivatives of the profit function are the first derivatives of the output supply
and input demand functions. Properties of the second derivatives of the profit function
are properties of the first derivatives of the output supply and input demand functions.
5: The symmetry of second order cross partial derivatives leads to symmetry of first cross
price derivatives of the output supply and input demand functions.
5. N UMERIC E XAMPLE
5.1. Production function. Consider the following production function.
y = f (x1 , x2 )
(38)
= 24x1 + 14x2 − x21 + x1 x2 − x22
The first and second partial derivatives are given by
∂f (x1 , x2 )
= 24 − 2x1 + x2
∂x1
∂f (x1 , x2 )
= 14 + x1 − 2x2
∂x2
∂ 2 f (x1 , x2 )
= −2 (39)
∂x21
∂ 2 f (x1 , x2 )
=1
∂x1 ∂x2
∂ 2 f (x1 , x2 )
= −2
∂x22
The Hessian is
à !
2
−2 1
∇ f (x1 , x2 ) = (40)
1 −2
The determinant of the Hessian is given by
¯ ¯
¯ −2 1 ¯
¯ ¯
¯ ¯ = 4 − 1 = 3 (41)
¯ 1 −2 ¯
The rate of technical substitution is given by
−f1 f2 (x1 f1 + x2 f2 )
σ12 =
x1 x2 (f11 f22 − 2f12 f1 f2 + f22 f12 )
(43)
−(14 + x1 − 2x2 )(24 − 2x1 + x2 ) (x21 − 12x1 − 7x2 − x1 x2 + x22 )
=
x1 x2 1108 + 3x21 − 72x1 − 42x2 − 3x1 x2 + 3x22 )
π = p f (x1 , x2 ) − w1 x1 − w2 x2
£ ¤ (44)
= p 24x1 + 14x2 − 2x21 + x1 x2 − 2x22 − w1 x1 − w2 x2
We maximize profit by taking the derivatives of 44 setting them equal to zero and solving for x1
and x2 .
∂π
= p [ 24 − 2x1 + x2 ] − w1 = 0
∂x1
(45)
∂π
= p [ 14 + x1 − 2x2 ] − w2 = 0
∂x2
Rearranging 45 we obtain
w1
24 − 2x1 + x2 = (46a)
p
w2
14 + x1 − 2x2 = (46b)
p
24p − w1 + px2
x1 = (47)
2p
µ ¶
24p − w1 + px2 w2
14 + − 2x2 =
2p p
µ ¶
28p + 24p − w1 + px2 − 4px2 w2
⇒ =
2p p
µ ¶
52p − w1 − 3px2 w2
⇒ =
2p p
µ ¶ µ ¶
−3px2 w2 52p − w1
⇒ = −
2p p 2p (48)
µ ¶
2w2 − 52p + w1
=
2p
⇒ −3px2 = 2w2 − 52p + w1
−2w2 + 52p − w1
⇒ x2 =
3p
52p − w1 − 2w2
=
3p
24p − w1 + px2
x1 =
2p
24p − w1 p
= + x2
2p 2p
µ ¶
24p − w1 1 52p − w1 − 2w2
= +
2p 2 3p
(49)
72p − 3w1 + 52p − w1 − 2w2
=
6p
124p − 4w1 − 2w2
=
6p
62p − 2w1 − w2
=
3p
5.3. Necessary and sufficient conditions for a maximum. Consider the Hessian of the profit equa-
tion.
à ! à !
2
−2 1 −2p p
∇ π(x1 , x2 ) = p = (50)
1 −2 p −2p
For a maximum we need the diagonal elements to be negative and the determinant to be positive.
The diagonal elements are negative. The determinant of the Hessian is 4p2 -p2 = 3p2 , which is
positive.
12 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
5.4. Optimal output. We can obtain optimal output as a function of p, w1 and w2 by substituting
the optimal values of x1 and x2 into the production function.
Now put everything over a common denominator and multiply out as follows
Notice that we have terms in the following p2 , pw1 pw2 , w21 , w1 w2 and w22 . Now rearrange
terms in equation 52 combining like terms.
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 13
5.5. The example numerical profit function. We obtain the profit function by substituting the op-
timal values of x1 and x2 into the profit equation
5.6. Optimal input demands via Hotelling’s lemma. We can find the optimal input demands by
taking the derivative of equation 86 with respect to w1 and w2 . First with respect to w1
14 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
5.7. Optimal output via Hotelling’s lemma. Take the derivative of the profit function with respect
to p using the quotient rule
6. A LGEBRAIC E XAMPLE
6.1. Production function. Consider the following production function.
y = f (x1 , x2 )
(59)
= α1 x1 + α2 x2 + β11 x21 + β12 x1 x2 + β22 x22
∂f (x1 , x2 )
= α1 + 2β11 x1 + β12 x2
∂x1
∂f (x1 , x2 )
= α2 + β12 x1 + 2β22 x2
∂x2
∂ 2 f (x1 , x2 )
= 2β11 (60)
∂x21
∂ 2 f (x1 , x2 )
= β12
∂x1 ∂x2
∂ 2 f (x1 , x2 )
= 2β22
∂x22
The Hessian is
à !
2
2β11 β12
∇ f (x1 , x2 ) = (61)
β12 2β22
The determinant of the Hessian is given by
¯ ¯
¯ 2β11 β12 ¯
¯ ¯ 2
¯ ¯ = 4β11 β22 − β12 (62)
¯ β12 2β11 ¯
The rate of technical substitution is given by
−f1 f2 (x1 f1 + x2 f2 )
σ12 =
x1 x2 (f11 f22 − 2f12 f1 f2 + f22 f12 )
−(α1 + 2x1 β11 + x2 β12 )(α2 + x1 β12 + 2x2 β22 ) (2x21 β11 + x1 (α1 + 2x2 β12 ) + x2 (α2 + 2x2 β22 ))
=
x1 x2 (2 (α1 + 2x1 β11 + x2 β12 )2 β22 − 2β12 (α1 + 2x1 β11 + x2 β12 ) (α2 + x1 β12 + 2x2 β22 ) + 2β11 (α2 + x1 β12 + 2x2 β22 )2 ))
(64)
π = p f (x1 , x2 ) − w1 x1 − w2 x2
£ ¤ (65)
= p α1 x1 + α2 x2 + β11 x21 + β12 x1 x2 + β22 x22 − w1 x1 − w2 x2
We maximize profit by taking the derivatives of 65 setting them equal to zero and solving for x1
and x2 .
∂π
= p [ α1 + 2β11 x1 + β12 x2 ] − w1 = 0
∂x1
(66)
∂π
= p [ α2 + β12 x1 + 2β22 x2 ] − w2 = 0
∂x2
Rearranging 66 we obtain
16 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
w1
α1 + 2β11 x1 + β12 x2 = (67a)
p
w2
α2 + β12 x1 + 2β22 x2 = (67b)
p
Now solve equation 67a for x1 as follows
¡ 2
¢
p 4β11 β22 − β12 (w1 − pα1 ) − pβ12 (2β11 w2 − 2pα2 β11 − w1 β12 + pα1 β12 )
x1 = 2 )
2pβ11 p (4β11 β22 − β12
¡ 2
¢
4β11 β22 − β12 (w1 − pα1 ) − β12 (2β11 w2 − 2pα2 β11 − w1 β12 + pα1 β12 )
= 2 )
2pβ11 (4β11 β22 − β12
2 2 2 2
4w1 β11 β22 − w1 β12 − 4pα1 β11 β22 + pα1 β12 − 2β11 β12 w2 + 2pα2 β11 β12 + w1 β12 − pα1 β12
= 2
2pβ11 (4β11 β22 − β12 )
4w1 β11 β22 − 4pα1 β11 β22 − 2β11 β12 w2 + 2pα2 β11 β12
= 2 )
2pβ11 (4β11 β22 − β12
2w1 β22 − 2pα1 β22 − β12 w2 + pα2 β12
= 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
2w1 β22 − β12 w2 + p (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 )
= 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
(72)
6.3. Necessary and sufficient conditions for a maximum. Consider the Hessian of the profit equa-
tion.
à ! à !
2β11 β12 2pβ11 pβ12
∇2 π(x1 , x2 ) = p = (73)
β12 2β22 pβ12 2pβ22
For a maximum we need the diagonal elements to be negative and the determinant to be positive.
The diagonal elements will negative if β11 and β22 are negative. The determinant of the Hessian is
given by
¯ ¯
¯ 2pβ11 pβ12 ¯¯ ¡ ¢
¯
¯ ¯ = 4p2 β11 β22 − p2 β12
2
= p2 4β11 β22 − β12
2
(74)
¯ pβ12 2pβ22 ¯
2
So the solution will be a maximum if β11 and β22 are both less than zero and 4β11 β22 > β12 .
2
Notice that if 4β11 β22 = β12 , the test fails.
6.4. Optimal output. We can obtain optimal output as a function of p, w1 and w2 by substituting
the optimal values of x1 and x2 into the production function.
18 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
à ! µ ¶
2w1 β22 − 2pα1 β22 − β12 w2 + pα2 β12 2w1 β22 − 2pα1 β22 − β12 w2 + pα2 β12
x21 = 2 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12 ) p (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
2
4w12 β22 2
− 4pw1 α1 β22 − 2w1 w2 β12 β22 + 2pw1 α2 β12 β22
= 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
2
−4pw1 α1 β22 2
+ 4p2 α12 β22 + 2pw2 α1 β12 β22 − 2p2 α1 α2 β12 β22
+ 2 (76)
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
2
−2w1 w2 β12 β22 + 2pα1 w2 β12 β22 + w22 β12 2
− pw2 α2 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
2pw1 α2 β12 β22 − 2p2 α1 α2 β12 β22 − pw2 α2 β12
2 2
+ p2 α22 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
4w12 β22
2 2
− 8pw1 α1 β22 − 4w1 w2 β12 β22 + 4pw1 α2 β12 β22
x21 = 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
4p2 α12 β22
2
+ 4pw2 α1 β12 β22 − 4p2 α1 α2 β12 β22
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à ! (77)
w22 β12
2 2
− 2pw2 α2 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
p2 α22 β12
2
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
2
4p2 α12 β22 2
− 4p2 α1 α2 β12 β22 + p2 α22 β12
x21 = 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
2 2
4pw1 α2 β12 β22 − 8pw1 α1 β22 + 4pw2 α1 β12 β22 − 2pα2 w2 β12
+ 2
p2 (4β11 β22 − β122 )
à !
2
4w12 β22 2
− 4w1 w2 β12 β22 + w22 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à ¡ ¢!
2
p2 4α12 β22 2
− 4α1 α2 β12 β22 + α22 β12 (78)
= 2
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12 2 )
à ¡ ¢!
2
4pw1 α2 β12 β22 − 2α1 β22
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à ¡ ¢!
2
2pw2 2α1 β12 β22 − α2 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
4w12 β22
2
− 4w1 w2 β12 β22 + w22 β12
2
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
Similarly for x2
20 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
à !
4w22 β11
2 2
− 8pw2 α2 β11 + 4p2 α22 β11
2
− 4w1 w2 β11 β12
x22 = 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
4pα1 w2 β11 β12 + 4pw1 α2 β11 β12 − 4p2 α1 α2 β11 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
w12 β12
2 2
− 2pw1 α1 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
p2 α12 β12
2
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à (79)
2
¡ ¢!
p 4α22 β11
2
− 4α1 α2 β11 β12 + α12 β12
2
= 2
p2
(4β11 β22 − β12 2 )
à ¡ ¢!
2
2pw1 2α2 β11 β12 − α1 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à ¡ ¢!
2
4pw2 2α1 β11 β12 − 2α2 β11
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β11
à !
2
w12 β12 2
− 4w1 w2 β11 β12 + 4w22 β11
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶ µ ¶
2w1 β22 − β12 w2 + p (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) 2β11 w2 − w1 β12 + p (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
x1 ∗ x2 = 2 ) 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12 p (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
4w1 w2 β11 β22 − 2w12 β12 β22 + 2pw1 β22 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
= 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
−2w22 β11 β12 + w1 w2 β12
2
− pw2 β12 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶
2pw2 β11 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − pw1 β12 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) + p2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 )
+ 2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
(80)
Now collect terms in equation 80
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 21
à !
p2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) + 2pw1 β22 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − pw2 β12 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
x1 ∗ x2 = 2
p2 (4β11 β22 − β122 )
à !
2pw2 β11 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − pw1 β12 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 )
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
2
−2w12 β12 β22 + w1 w2 β12 + 4w1 w2 β11 β22 − 2w22 β11 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
p2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 )
= 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
pw1 (2β22 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − β12 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ))
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à !
pw2 (2β11 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − β12 (α1 β12 − 2α1 β11 ))
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
à ¡ ¢ !
−2w12 β12 β22 + w1 w2 4β11 β22 + β12
2
− 2w22 β11 β12
+ 2
2 )
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
(81)
Now substitute the results from equations 70, 72 78 , 79 and 81 into equation 75
22 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
!
2
2pw2 2α1 β12 β22 − α2 β12 + 4w12 β22
2 − 4w w β β 2 2
1 2 12 22 + w2 β12
+β11
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
p2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) pw1 (2β22 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − β12 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ))
+ β12 +
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2 p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
pw2 (2β11 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − β12 (α1 β12 − 2α1 β11 )) −2w12 β12 β22 + w1 w2 4β11 β22 + β122 − 2w22 β11 β12
+ β12 +
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2 p2 4β11 β22 − β122 2
!
p2 4α22 β11
2 − 4α α β β
1 2 11 12 + α1 β12
2 2 2pw1 2α2 β11 β12 − α1 β12 2
+ β22 +
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2 p2 4β11 β22 − β122 2
!
2
4pw2 2α1 β11 β12 − 2α2 β11 w12 β12
2 − 4w w β β 2 2
1 2 11 12 + 4w2 β11
+ β22 +
p2 4β11 β22 − β11 2 2 p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
(82)
To start simplifying, we need to put everything over a common denominator
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 23
!
2pw2 α2 β11 4β11 β22 − β12 2 − pw1 α2 β12 4β11 β22 − β12 2 + p2 α2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
+
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
p2 β11 4α21 β22
2 − 4α α β β 2 2
1 2 12 22 + α2 β12 + 4pw1 β11 α2 β12 β22 − 2α1 β22
2
+
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
2pw2 β11 2α1 β12 β22 − α2 β12 2 + 4w12 β11 β222 − 4w w β β β 2 2
1 2 11 12 22 + w2 β11 β12
+
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
p2 β12 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) pw1 β12 (2β22 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − β12 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ))
+ +
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2 p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
pw2 β12 (2β11 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − β12 (α1 β12 − 2α1 β11 ))
+
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
−2w12 β12
2 β 2
22 + w1 w2 β12 4β11 β22 + β12 − 2w2 β11 β12
2 2
+
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
p2 β22 4α22 β11
2 − 4α α β β
1 2 11 12 + α1 β12
2 2 2pw1 β22 2α2 β11 β12 − α1 β12 2
+ +
p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2 p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
!
2
4pw2 β22 2α1 β11 β12 − 2α2 β11 w12 β12
2 β 2 2
22 − 4w1 w2 β11 β12 β22 + 4w2 β11 β22
+ +
p2 4β11 β22 − β11 2 2 p2 4β11 β22 − β12 2 2
(83)
Notice that we have terms in the following p2 , pw1 pw2 , w21 , w1 w2 and w22 . Now rearrange
terms in equation 83 combining like terms. After some manipulations we obtain
¡ ¢
w22 β11 − w1 w2 β12 + w12 β22 − p2 α22 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α12 β22
y(p, w1 , w2 ) = 2 )
(84)
p2 (4β11 β22 − β12
6.5. The example profit function. We obtain the profit function by substituting the optimal values
of x1 and x2 into the profit equation
à ¡ ¢!
w22 β11 − w1 w2 β12 + w12 β22 − p2 α22 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α12 β22
π(p, w1 , w2 ) = 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶ µ ¶
2w1 β22 − β12 w2 + p (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) 2β11 w2 − w1 β12 + p (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
− w1 2 ) − w2 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12 p (4β11 β22 − β12
à ¡ ¢!
w22 β11 − w1 w2 β12 + w12 β22 − p2 α22 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α12 β22
= 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶
−2w12 β22 + w1 w2 β12 − pw1 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 )
+ 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶
−2w22 β11 + w1 w2 β12 − pw2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
+ 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
à ¡ ¢!
−w22 β11 + w1 w2 β12 − w12 β22 − p2 α22 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α12 β22
= 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶
−pw1 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 )
+ 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶
−pw2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
+ 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
(86)
We can write equation 86 in the following useful fashion
!
−w22 β11 + w1 w2 β12 − w12 β22 − pw1 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − pw2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − p2 α22 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α21 β22
π(p, w1 , w2 ) = 2
p 4β11 β22 − β12
(87)
6.6. Optimal input demands. We can find the optimal input demands by taking the derivative of
equation 86 with respect to w1 and w2 . First with respect to w1
µ ¶
∂π(p, w1 , w2 ) β12 w2 − 2β22 w1 − p (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 )
= 2 )
∂w1 p (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶ (88)
−β12 w2 + 2β22 w1 + p (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 )
⇒ x1 = 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
Then with respect to w2
µ ¶
∂π(p, w1 , w2 ) −2w2 β11 + w1 β12 − p (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
= 2 )
∂w2 p (4β11 β22 − β12
µ ¶ (89)
2w2 β11 − w1 β12 + p (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 )
⇒ x2 = 2 )
p (4β11 β22 − β12
0 1
2 2
−w2 β11 + w1 w2 β12 − w1 β22 − pw1 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − pw2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − p2 α2 2
2 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α1 β22
π(p, w1 , w2 ) = @ A
2
p 4β11 β22 − β12
2
∂π(p, w1 , w2 ) p 4β11 β22 − β12 −w1 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − w2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − 2p α2 2
2 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α1 β22
=
2 2
∂p p2 4β11 β22 − β12
2 2
−w2 β11 + w1 w2 β12 − w1 β22 − pw1 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − pw2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − p2 α2 2
2 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α1 β22
2
4β11 β22 − β12
−
2
2
p2 4β11 β22 − β12
−pw1 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) − pw2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) − 2p2 α2 2
2 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α1 β22
2
4β11 β22 − β12
=
2
2
p2 4β11 β22 − β12
2 2
w2 β11 − w1 w2 β12 + w1 β22 + pw1 (α2 β12 − 2α1 β22 ) + pw2 (α1 β12 − 2α2 β11 ) + p2 α2 2
2 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α1 β22
2
4β11 β22 − β12
+
2 2
p2 4β11 β22 − β12
−p2 α2 2
2 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α1 β22 + 2
w2 2
β11 − w1 w2 β12 + w1 β22 2
4β11 β22 − β12
=
2 2
p2 4β11 β22 − β12
−p2 α2 2
2 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α1 β22 + 2
w2 2
β11 − w1 w2 β12 + w1 β22
=
2
p2 4β11 β22 − β12
2 2
w2 β11 − w1 w2 β12 + w1 β22 − p2 α2 2
2 β11 − α1 α2 β12 + α1 β22
=
2
p2 4β11 β22 − β12
(90)
m
X Xn
∂π ∂π
pj + wi = π(p, w) (92)
j=1
∂(t pj ) i=1
∂(t wi )
Differentiate equation 92 with respect to t again. Each term in equation 92 will yield a sum of
derivatives so the result will be a double sum as follows
m X
X m Xm Xn
∂2π ∂2π
pk pj + w` pj
j=1 k=1
∂(t pk ) ∂(t pj ) j=1
∂(t w` ) ∂(t pj )
`=1
(93)
n X
X m Xn Xn
∂2π ∂2π
+ pk wi + w` wi = 0
i=1 k=1
∂(t pk ) ∂(t wi ) i=1
∂(t w` ) ∂(t wi )
`=1
∂ f (x) 1 ∂ f (x)
= (94)
∂ (t x) t ∂x
This will give
26 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
m m m n
1 X X ∂2π 1 X X ∂2π
p k pj + w` pj
t2 j=1 ∂pk ∂pj t2 j=1 ∂w` ∂pj
k=1 `=1
(95)
n
X m
X n n
1 ∂2π 1 X X ∂2π
+ 2 pk wi + 2 w` wi = 0
t i=1 k=1
∂pk ∂wi t i=1 ∂w` ∂wi
`=1
This then implies that
m X
X m Xm Xn
∂2π ∂2π
pk pj + w` pj
j=1 k=1
∂pk ∂pj j=1
∂w` ∂pj
`=1
(96)
n X
X m Xn Xn
∂2π ∂2π
+ pk wi + w` wi = 0
i=1 k=1
∂pk ∂wi i=1
∂w` ∂wi
`=1
The last expression in equation 96 is actually a quadratic form involving the Hessian of π(p,w).
To see this write out the Hessian and then pre and post multiply by a vector containing output and
input prices.
2 ∂2 π ∂2 π ∂2 π ∂2 π ∂2 π
32 3
∂ p2 ∂p2 ∂p1
... ∂pm ∂p1 ∂w1 ∂p1
... ∂wn ∂p1 p1
6 1
∂2 π ∂2 π ∂2 π ∂2 π ∂2 π 7 6 p2 7
6 ... ... 7 6 7
6 ∂ p1 ∂p2 ∂p2 ∂pm ∂p2 ∂w1 ∂p2 ∂wn ∂p2 7 6 . 7
6 ..
2
.. .. .. 7 6 . 7
6 .. .. 7 6 . 7
6 . . . . . . 7 6 7
6 7 6 pn 7
wn 6
2 2 2
∂ π ∂ π ∂ π ∂2 π ∂2 π 7
p1 p2 ... pm w1 ... 6 ... ∂p2
... 7 6 7
6
∂ p1 ∂pm ∂p2 ∂pm m ∂w1 ∂pm ∂wn ∂pm
7 6 w1 7
6 ∂2 π ∂2 π
... ∂2 π ∂2 π
... ∂2 π 7 6 7
6 ∂ p1 ∂w1 ∂p2 ∂w1 ∂pm ∂w1 ∂w12 ∂wn ∂w1 7 6 w2 7
6 7 6 7
6 .. .. .. .. .. .. 7 6 .. 7
4 . . . . . . 5 4 . 5
2 2 2
∂ π ∂ π ∂ π ∂2 π ∂2 π wn
∂ p1 ∂wn ∂p2 ∂wn
... ∂pm ∂wn ∂w1 ∂wn
... ∂wn2
(97)
Equation 96 implies that this quadratic form is zero for this particular vector (p,w). This means
that the Hessian matrix is singular. The profit function is convex so we know that its Hessian
is positive semi-definite. This implies that it is positive semidefinite only and cannot be positive
definite.
8.1. Response of Output Supply. Consider first the response of any output to its own price.
∂ yj ∂2 π
= ≥ 0 (98)
∂ pj ∂ p2j
Supply curves derived from profit maximization will always slope upwards because this deriv-
ative is on the diagonal of the Hessian. Now consider the response of an output to another product
price.
∂ yj ∂2 π
= (99)
∂ pk ∂ pk ∂pj
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 27
This element is not on the diagonal of the Hessian of the profit function and so we cannot deter-
mine its sign.
Similarly we cannot sign the response of an output to an input price.
∂ yj ∂2 π
= (100)
∂ wi ∂ wi ∂pj
8.2. Response of Input Supply. Consider first the response of any input to its own price.
∂ xi ∂2 π
= − ≤ 0 (101)
∂ wi ∂ wi2
Demand curves derived from profit maximization will always slope downwards because this
derivative is on the diagonal of the Hessian and input demand is the negative of the derivative of
the profit function with respect to input price. Now consider the response of an input to another
input price.
∂ xi ∂2 π
= − (102)
∂ w` ∂ w` ∂wi
This element is not on the diagonal of the Hessian of the profit function and so we cannot deter-
mine its sign.
Similarly we cannot sign the response of an input to an output price.
∂ xi ∂2 π
= − (103)
∂ pk ∂ pk ∂wi
8.3. Homogeneity. Because output supply and input demand are derivatives of a function which
is homogeneous of degree one, they are homogeneous of degree zero.
∂2π ∂2π
=
∂pi ∂pj ∂pj ∂pi
∂2π ∂2π
= (105)
∂pk ∂wi ∂wi ∂pk
∂2π ∂2π
=
∂wi ∂wj ∂wj ∂wi
This then implies
∂yj ∂yi
=
∂pi ∂pj
∂wi ∂yk
− = (106)
∂pk ∂wi
∂xi ∂xj
=
∂wj ∂wi
28 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
The response of any output to a different output price is symmetric, i.e. cross price derivatives
are equal. Similarly with input demand response. The way an output responds to a particular
input price is the same as the response of that input to the output’s price.
8.5. Own and cross price response. Because any principal submatrix of a positive semi-definite
matrix is also positive semidefinite (Hadley [9, p. 262]), we also have the following results.
m
X n
X
π = max [p1 f (ỹ, x) + pj yj − wi xi ] (112a)
x ỹ
2=1 i=1
p̃ = (p2 , p3 , . . . , pm ), ỹ = (y2 , y3 , . . . , ym ),
w = (w1 , w2 , . . . , wn ) x = (x1 , x2 , . . . , pn )
If f(ỹ,x) is differentiable, then the first order conditions for maximizing profit are as follows.
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 29
∂π ∂f (ỹ, x)
= p1 − wi = 0, i = 1, 2, . . . , n
∂ xi ∂xi
(113)
∂π ∂f (ỹ, x)
= p1 + pj = 0, j = 2, 3, . . . , m
∂ yj ∂yj
We can then obtain marginal products by rearranging the first order conditions. We can find the
impact on y1 of an increase in any of the inputs as
∂f (ỹ, x) wi
= , i = 1, 2, . . . , n (114)
∂xi p1
We can find the impact on y1 of an increase in any of the other outputs as
∂f (ỹ, x) pj
= − , j = 2, 3, . . . , m (115)
∂yj p1
We can find other marginal products by solving the profit maximization problem with a different
normalization than the one on y1 .
∂f (x) wi
= , i = 1, 2, . . . , n (116)
∂xi p
This is clear from figure 2. The isoprofit line is given by
π̄ = py − wx
Solving for y we obtain
π̄ w
y = + x
p p
fHxL
x
30 PROFIT FUNCTIONS
10.2. Output elasticity. We normally think of output elasticity in terms of one output and many
inputs so define it as follows.
∂f (x) xi
²i = (117)
∂xi y
∂f (x)
If we substitute for ∂xi from equation 116 we obtain
wi xi
²i = (118)
p y
10.3. Elasticity of scale. Elasticity of scale is given by the sum of the output elasticities,i.e.,
Xn
∂f (p, w) xi
² =
i=1
∂xi y
Xn
wi xi
=
p y
i=1 (119)
Pn
wi xi
= i=1
py
Cost
=
Revenue
A profit maximizing firm will never produce in a region of the production function with in-
creasing returns to scale assuming the technology eventually becomes locally concave and remains
concave. As the result for a profit maximizing firm, returns to scale is just the ratio of cost to rev-
enue.
To show that T is in fact equal to T∗ , we need to show that T∗ ⊆ T. We do this by assuming that
some particular input output combination (x0 , y0 ) ∈ T∗ but (x0 , y0 ) ∈
/ T. If (x0 , y0 ) ∈
/ T, then (x0 ,
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 31
THx,yL
THx,yL
y0 ) can be separated from T by a hyperplane (py0 - wx0 ). But T∗ consists of points lying below the
hyperplane defined by the maximal profits with prices p and w. This means that the point (x0 , y0 )
cannot be in T∗ . We can show this in figure 6. Consider point a in figure 6 which is not in T(x,y). It
is in T∗ if we only consider the half spaces defined by the hyperplanes intersecting T(x,y) at points
c and d. But at the prices defined by a hyperplane with ”slope” as the one passing through b, point
a is not in T∗ . If we consider any other point not in T, there exists a hyperplane that also excludes
it from T∗ . This implies than that T∗ ⊆ T and so T∗ ≡ T. For more on this topic consult McFadden
[12] or Fare and Primont [6].
11.2. Using the properties of the profit function to recover properties of the technology. We
repeat here for convenience the properties of T(x,y) and π(p,w).
THx,yL
d
c
b THx,yL
a
n m
T.1a: Inaction and No Free Lunch. (0,y) ² T ∀ x ² R+ and y ² R+ . This implies that T(x,y) is a
m+n
non-empty subset of R+
T.1b: (0,y) 6∈ T, y = 0, y 6= 0.
T.2: Input Disposability. If (x,y) ² T and θ ≥ 1 then (θx, y) ² T.
T.2.S: Strong Input Disposability. If (x,y) ² T and x’ = x, then (x’, y) ² T.
n+m
T.3: Output Disposability. ∀ (x,y) ² R+ ,if (x, y) ² T and 0 < λ 5 1 then (x, λy) ² T.
T.3.S: Strong Output Disposability. If (x,y) ² T and y’ 5 y, then (x, y’) ² T.
T.4: Boundedness. For every finite input vector x = 0, the set y ² P(x) is bounded from above.
This implies that only finite amounts of output can be produced from finite amounts of
inputs.
T.5: T(x) is a closed set. The assumption that P(x) and V(y) are closed does not imply that T
is a closed set, so it is assumed. Specifically, if [x` → x0 , y` → y0 ) and (x` , y` ) ² T, ∀ `] then
(x0 y0 ) ² T.
PROFIT FUNCTIONS 33
T.9: T is a convex set. This is not implied by the convexity of P(x) and V(y). Specifically, a
technology could exhibit a diminishing rate of technical substitution, a diminishing rate of
product transformation and still exhibit increasing returns to scale.
11.2.2. Properties of the profit function.
π.1: π(p, w) is an extended real valued function (it can take on the value of +∞ for finite
prices) defined for all (p, w) = (0m , 0n )) and π(p, w) ≥ pa - wb for a fixed vector (a, b) ≥
(0m , 0n ). This implies that π(p, w) = 0 if (0m , 0n ) ∈ T(x,y),which we normally assume.
π.2: π is nonincreasing in w
π.3: π is nondecreasing in p
π.4: π is a convex function
π.5: π is homogeneous of degree 1 in p and w.
We will consider only a few of the properties of T(x,y)
11.2.3. T(x,y) is non-empty. By π.1, π(p, w) ≥ pa - wb for a fixed vector (a, b) ≥ (0m , 0n ) or π(p, w)
≥ 0 if (0m , 0n ) ∈ T(x,y). Given that π(p, w) ≥ 0, with x zero, there are obviously values of y (for
example 0) which make (py - wx) less than π(p, w). So T∗ (x,y) is not empty and (0,y) ∈ T∗ (x,y).
11.2.4. Strong Input Disposability. If (x,y) ² T and x’ = x, then (x’, y) ² T. .
R EFERENCES
[1] Chambers, R. G. Applied Production Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988.
[2] Diewert, W. E. ”Functional Forms for Profit and Transformation Functions.” Journal of Economic Theory.6(1973):284-316.
[3] Diewert, W. E. ”Applications of Duality Theory” in Frontiers of Quantitative Economics, Vol. 2, ed. M. Intriligator and D.
Kendrick. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1974.
[4] Diewert, W.E. ”Duality Approaches to Microeconomic Theory” in Handbook of Mathematical Economics, Vol 2, ed. K.J.
Arrow and M.D. Intriligator. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1982
[5] Fare, R. Fundamentals of Production Theory. New York: Springer-Verlag, 1988.
[6] Fare, R. and D. Primont. Multi-output Production and Duality: Theory and Applications. Boston: Kluwer Academic Pub-
lishers, 1995.
[7] Ferguson, C. E. The Neoclassical Theory of Production and Distribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1971.
[8] Fuss, M. and D. McFadden. Production Economics: A Dual Approach to Theory and Application. Amsterdam: North Hol-
land, 1978.
[9] Hadley, G. Linear Algebra. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 1961.
[10] Lau, L. J. ”Characterization of the Normalized Restricted Profit Function” Journal of Economic Theory12(Feb. 1976):131-
163.
[11] Lau, L. J. ”Applications of Profit Functions” in Production Economics: A Dual Approach to Theory and Applications, ed. M.
Fuss and D. McFadden, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1978.
[12] McFadden, D. ”Duality of Production, Cost and Profit Functions” in Production Economics: A Dual Approach to Theory
and Applications, ed. M. Fuss and D. McFadden, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1978.
[13] Rockafellar, R. T. Convex Analysis. Princeton New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1970.
[14] Shephard, R. W. Theory of Cost and Production Functions. Princeton New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1970.
[15] Varian, H. R. Microeconomic Analysis. 3rd Edition. New York: Norton, 1992.