0% found this document useful (0 votes)
91 views14 pages

Mathematics For Economics: Euncheol Shin

The document summarizes key concepts from optimization theory in economics. It discusses how economists seek to maximize profits, utility, or minimize costs by finding the extreme values of objective functions. The document outlines the terminology, conditions, and methods used to find local and global maxima/minima, including the first-order condition of setting the derivative equal to zero and the second-order condition of checking the concavity of functions. It provides an example of applying these concepts to find the profit-maximizing quantity a firm should produce.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
91 views14 pages

Mathematics For Economics: Euncheol Shin

The document summarizes key concepts from optimization theory in economics. It discusses how economists seek to maximize profits, utility, or minimize costs by finding the extreme values of objective functions. The document outlines the terminology, conditions, and methods used to find local and global maxima/minima, including the first-order condition of setting the derivative equal to zero and the second-order condition of checking the concavity of functions. It provides an example of applying these concepts to find the profit-maximizing quantity a firm should produce.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 14

Mathematics for Economics

Euncheol Shin

Kyung Hee University


[email protected]

Optimization Theory

1 / 14
Recall

Exponential function

Logarithmic function

2 / 14
Outline

Optimization theory I (Chapter 9)

3 / 14
Terminology

Maximization problems in economics: maximizing a firm’s profit, a


consumer’s utility, etc.

Minimization problems in economics: minimizing the cost of


producing a given output.

In mathematics: finding extreme values of an objective function.

Example: π(q) = R(q) − C(q)


q is the choice variable (quantity)
R is the revenue function
C is the cost function

4 / 14
General form: y = f (x).

We assume that f is continuously differentiable.

f (x0 ) is called a local maximum if there exists ε > 0 such that


f (x0 ) ≥ f (x) for all x ∈ (x0 − ε, x0 + ε).

f (x0 ) is called the global maximum if f (x0 ) ≥ f (x) for all


x ∈ (x0 − ε, x0 + ε).

[Figures 9.1]

5 / 14
First-Order Condition
Proposition
Suppose f 0 (x0 ) = 0. Then, f (x0 ) is
(a) a local maximum if the derivative f 0 (x) changes its sign from
positive to negative from the immediate left of x0 to its immediate
right.
(b) a local minimum if f 0 (x) changes its sign from negative to positive
from the immediate left of x0 to its immediate right.
(c) Neither a local maximum nor a local minimum if f 0 (x) has the
same sigh on both the immediate left and the right of x0 .

x0 is called a critical value.

f (x0 ) is called a stationary point.

Because of (c), f 0 (x) = 0 can’t be a sufficient condition for a local


maximum.
6 / 14
Second Derivative

The second derivative of f is the derivative of f 0 (x).

f 00 (x) measures the rate of change of the first derivative of f .

Example 1: f (x) = x ⇒ f 00 (x) = 0.

Example 2: f (x) = ex ⇒ f 00 (x) = ex .

f 00 (x) > 0 means that the slope of the graph tends to increase.

f 00 (x) < 0 means that the slope of the graph tends to decrease.
[Figure 9.5]

7 / 14
Concave and Convex Functions
f is called concave if f 00 (x) < 0 for all x.

f is called concave if f (x) ≤ f (a) + f 0 (a)(x − a) for all x and a.

f is called concave if f (tx + (1 − t)y) ≥ tf (x) + (1 − t)f (y) for


all t ∈ [0, 1].

[Figures Here]

f is called convex if f 00 (x) > 0 for all x.

f is called convex if f (x) ≥ f (a) + f 0 (a)(x − a) for all x and a.

f is called convex if f (tx + (1 − t)y) ≤ tf (x) + (1 − t)f (y) for all


t ∈ [0, 1].

8 / 14
Second-Order Condition
If a function is concave around x0 , then the first-order condition is
sufficient to obtain a local maximum.

That is, f 0 (x0 ) = 0 and f 00 (x0 ) < 0 imply that f (x0 ) is a local
maximum.

[Figure Here]

If a function is concave everywhere, then the first-order condition


is sufficient to obtain a global maximum.

That is, f 0 (x0 ) = 0 and f 00 (x) < 0 everywhere imply that f (x0 ) is
the global maximum. [Proof Here]

[Figure Here]

9 / 14
Application: Firm’s Problem

Demand function: D(q) = A − q with A > 0 is large.

Revenue function: R(q) = q × D(q) = Aq − q 2 .

Cost function: C(q) = cq. That is, c > 0 is a unit cost.

Profit function: Π(q) = R(q) − C(q) = Aq − q 2 − cq.

10 / 14
Application: Firm’s Problem

A = 5 and c = 1

4
Profit (Π(q))

0
0 1 2 3 4 5
Quantity (q)

11 / 14
Application: Firm’s Problem

Cookbook Approach:

Π0 (q) = (A − c) − 2q.

FOC: Π0 (q) = (A − c) − 2q = 0 if and only if q = q ∗ = A−c


2 .

SOC: Π00 (q) = −2 < 0. Therefore, Π is concave!

q ∗ is the global maximum!

Verify that q ∗ = 2 if A = 5 and c = 1.

12 / 14
Economist’s Viewpoint

The mountain is concave!

13 / 14
Next Week

Optimization theory II (Chapter 11)

We will consider functions of two variables.

14 / 14

You might also like