Vertical vs. Horizontal: How Strategic Alliance Type Influence Firm Performance?
Vertical vs. Horizontal: How Strategic Alliance Type Influence Firm Performance?
Vertical vs. Horizontal: How Strategic Alliance Type Influence Firm Performance?
Article
Vertical vs. Horizontal: How Strategic Alliance Type
Influence Firm Performance?
Baojun Yu 1 , Hangjun Xu 2, * and Feng Dong 3
1 Department of Management Science and Engineering, School of Management, Jilin University,
Changchun 130022, China; [email protected]
2 Department of Marketing, McAfee School of Business, Union University, Jackson, TN 38305, USA
3 Department of Finance, School of Business, Siena College, Loudonville, NY 12211, USA; [email protected]
* Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +1-5412855919
Received: 11 September 2019; Accepted: 17 November 2019; Published: 22 November 2019
Abstract: Strategic alliances have become a key focus in the management and marketing literature.
However, much of the previous research in this area has focused on the antecedents and accounting
effects of strategic alliances. There is an opportunity to more closely examine how alliance types
might influence the public equity markets. As a result, this study summarizes the literature for the
theoretical foundation of strategic alliances to increase the understanding of the two main types of
strategic alliances, that is industry scope (vertical vs. horizontal alliances) and size scope (asymmetric
vs. symmetric alliances). Then, this study proposes a conceptual framework to examine the main
and relative effects between different types of strategic alliances and firm performance. Using the
Bloomberg Mergers and Acquisitions (M&A) database from 1 January 2010 to 1 January 2016, we find
that vertical symmetric alliances gain more abnormal returns than others. Finally, implications and
limitations are also discussed.
Keywords: asymmetric alliances; average abnormal return; horizontal alliances; strategic alliances;
symmetric alliances; vertical alliances
1. Introduction
Over the last two decades, the merger and acquisition (M&A) and strategic alliance research
have gained increasing popularity. Scholars have taken many different perspectives, such as the
formation of strategic alliances [1–3], factors contributing to the success of alliances [4,5], and the
outcome performance of alliances [6,7].
Although strategic alliances are often viewed as a key strategic resource and much research has
found that the announcement of a strategic alliance can positively relate to firm abnormal returns [8–10],
limited research has offered a complementary explanation for how different perspectives of alliance
announcement types affect the stock market’s evaluation, especially alliances with a firm’s rivals or
asymmetrical partners. Therefore, it is an imperative question for both scholars and practitioners:
traditionally, alliances have been conceived of as ad hoc arrangements serving specific needs—is it
worth engaging extensively in multiple simultaneous alliances to gain more competitive advantages?
To fill this research gap, this study summarizes the literature for the theoretical foundation of
strategic alliances to increase the understanding of two main types of strategic alliances, that is industry
scope (vertical vs. horizontal alliances) and size scope (asymmetric vs. symmetric alliances). Then,
this study takes the case study findings of an alliance matrix [11] and extends their matrix to create a 2
(industry scope: vertical vs. horizontal alliances) * 2 (size scope: asymmetric vs. symmetric alliances)
matrix to identify four different types of strategic alliances. We also propose that each of these alliance
announcements can help the company gain positive firm abnormal returns and further examine
the relative relationship between strategic alliance type and firm alliance performance. Using the
Bloomberg M&A database from 1 January 2010 to 1 January 2016, we find that vertical symmetric
alliances gain more abnormal returns than others.
This study contributes to strategic alliance literature and practice. First, while interdependencies
between business partners have been studied in the strategic alliance literature, the relationship
between alliances of different types has not received due attention in prior studies. The most novel
theoretical contribution for this study is that it not only shows the differential impacts of a firm’s
different types of strategic alliances (industry scope: vertical vs. horizontal alliances and size scope:
asymmetric vs. symmetric alliances) on firm alliance performance, but it also discovers how a firm’s
vertical symmetric alliances gain more abnormal returns than others. Our fresh findings may extend
strategic alliance and corporate governance literature by advancing our understanding of how good
governance with business partners maximizes the value of the strategic alliance. Clearly, combining the
different dimensions of alliance portfolios suggests a decent avenue for future research. Moreover,
this study may offer essential suggestions to managers on where to allocate their precious resources
and efforts, and when and how they collaborate with their organizational network partners to enhance
competitive advantages.
Services industry [27]. Some other empirical research focused on particular strategic alliances to
test the relationship between strategic alliance announcements and firm performance. For example,
Chan and his colleagues (1999) also examined 345 technical and marketing alliances and concluded
that the overall average abnormal return is around 0.64%, while the high-technology firms can gain
more benefit, amounting to 1.12%, and the overall average abnormal return benefit by technical
horizontal alliances and marketing non-horizontal alliances can be even higher, up to 3.5% and 1.45%,
respectively [28]. Swaminathan and Moorman (2009) only picked up 230 marketing alliances and
found that marketing alliance announcements can create an average abnormal return value of 1.4% [10].
These research streams enhance our understanding of alliances and firm performance but fall short
of fully accounting for how different perspectives of alliance announcement types affect the stock
market’s evaluation. Therefore, it is still imperative to answer the question: how does a firm develop
and choose strategic alliance partners to improve and maintain their competitive advantages?
Size scope of strategic alliance. Kalaignanam, Shankar, and Varadarajan (2007) considered
asymmetric alliances as those alliances in which the ratio of the larger firm’s assets to that of the
smaller firm is greater than five [29]. Following their work, we also consider the symmetric alliances as
those alliances in which the ratio of the firm’s assets to that of the other firm is close to or less than
five. Previous research suggests that the size of a potential partner is an important criterion in partner
selection. Firstly, let us take a look at the motivation of symmetric alliances. A possible reason is
that both firms would place the same importance on the alliance and bargaining power would be
almost equal. Similarly, Williams and Lilley (1993) argued strongly that an alliance may have the best
chance of long-term success when both partners are comparable in sophistication and size [32]. On the
other hand, earlier research analyzed the asymmetric distribution of common and private benefits
in alliances and underscored the incentives that such benefits provide for continued collaboration.
The major reason for asymmetric alliances is to access complementary resources from each other [33].
For example, small biotech firms often form alliances with large pharmaceutical firms with the purpose
of utilizing the latter’s expertise in the US Food and Drug Administration agency’s approval process
and in market coverage. Table 2 summarizes the empirical results of the literature on the size scope of
strategic alliances.
Sustainability 2019, 11, 6594 5 of 14
them access more resources to maintain a competitive advantage [38]. In addition, vertical symmetric
companies can typically offer greater “staying power”, being able to commit a greater volume of
resources over a longer time horizon [32]. Therefore, they argued that joint ventures have the best chance
of long-term success when both partners are comparable in sophistication and size [32]. Stuart (2000)
also took the high-technology industry as the research context and concluded that technology alliances
with symmetric and larger partners improved baseline innovation and growth rates, while alliances
with smaller firms had an immaterial effect on performance. Moreover, significant size differences
between vertical alliances led to other problems [33]. One concern is the possibility of the domination
of one firm over the other. The smaller firm may share its innovative technology with a larger firm
offering finance, marketing, distribution resources, etc. until the larger firm learns and executes the
technology. This vertical asymmetric alliance could not have a longer duration, because the small firm
could be a burden for the larger firm. Therefore, we made the following proposition:
H2: Vertical symmetric alliances gain more abnormal returns than vertical asymmetric alliances.
players in the Information Technology and Pharmaceutical industries. The advent of new technologies
presents unique opportunities for smaller entrepreneurial firms in the same industry to pursue targeted
innovation [53]. Therefore, such horizontal asymmetric partners can share their information or
knowledge efficiently to speed their new product to market [39]. Therefore, we argue that an alliance
with asymmetric partners gains more benefits for shareholders.
H4: Horizontal asymmetric alliances gain more abnormal returns than horizontal symmetric alliances.
4. Methodology
in the alliances j on that day t; єijt is the random-error term), then we calculated daily abnormal returns
as follows: ARijt = Rijt – (ai + βi Rmjt ) (where ARijt is the daily abnormal returns for firm i’s stock return
in its alliances j on that day t). Following previous research, we defined the event window as a period
of five trading days centered on the event day (day 0) [56]. Finally, the cumulative abnormal returns
(CARs) from day −5 to day +5 were calculated.
Table 3 shows the abnormal returns calculated across 305 alliance announcements and the
aggregated cumulative abnormal returns over five trading days. The cumulative abnormal return on
event day 0 was not significant. We found that the cumulative abnormal return for vertical alliances
from day −5 to day −1 (2.6%) was significantly bigger than horizontal alliances (−1.0%) and we found
that same pattern for the abnormal return on event days −5 and +5 (4.4% > −2.3%). The cumulative
abnormal return for symmetric alliances from day −5 to day −1 (2.7%) was significantly bigger than
asymmetric alliances (−1.4%) and we found that same pattern for the abnormal return on event days
−5 and +5 (2.5% > −1.0%).
Event Window
(−5, −1) (0) (+1, +5) (−5, 5)
Parameter 0.00639 0.01062 0.00164 0.00803
All alliances
t Value 0.31 1.30 0.12 0.24
Parameter −0.01008 0.01774 −0.01242 −0.0225
Horizontal alliances
t Value −0.28 1.35 −0.52 −0.39
Parameter 0.02553 0.00660 0.01836 0.04389
Vertical alliances
t Value 1.65 * 0.67 1.41 2.25 **
Parameter 0.02687 0.01754 −0.00202 0.02485
Symmetric alliances
t Value 2.46 ** 1.60 −0.26 1.93 *
Parameter −0.01408 0.00799 0.00626 −0.00782
Asymmetric alliances
t Value −0.39 0.5281 0.25 −0.13
Horizontal symmetric Parameter 0.02139 0.02187 −0.01211 0.00928
alliances t Value 1.35 1.25 −1.10 0.51
Horizontal asymmetric Parameter −0.05914 0.01154 −0.01629 −0.07543
alliances t Value −0.85 0.52 −0.35 −0.66
Parameter 0.04203 −0.00343 0.01240 0.05443
Vertical symmetric alliances
t Value 1.74 * −0.21 0.64 1.79 *
Parameter 0.03465 0.00572 0.01263 0.04727
Vertical asymmetric alliances
t Value 1.51 0.40 0.66 1.64 *
Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
H1a and H1b attempt to examine how both vertical asymmetric and vertical symmetric alliances
may gain positive firm abnormal returns. We found that the cumulative abnormal return for vertical
asymmetric alliances from day −5 to day −1 was 4.2%, significantly at the 0.1 level, which supports H1b.
However, we did not find statistically significant evidence to support our H1a. H2 investigates how
the vertical symmetric alliances can gain more abnormal returns than vertical asymmetric alliances.
From the above empirical results, we found that H2 can be supported. We also found that same pattern
for the abnormal return on event days −5 and +5 (5.4% > 4.7%). Surprisingly, we did not find any
other evidence to support the following three hypotheses related to the horizontal symmetric and
horizontal asymmetric alliances.
We also conducted a multivariate regression analysis by regression firm 10-day (−5, 5) CARs
around announcement day on dummy variables indicating vertical alliances (Vertical Dummy = 1),
symmetric alliances (Symmetric Dummy = 1), and vertical symmetric deals (Vertical * Symmetry = 1),
controlling other firm level characteristics. We set up dummy variables based on the results, as presented
Sustainability 2019, 11, 6594 9 of 14
in Table 3, that vertical and symmetric deals yield significantly higher CARs than others. The regression
results are reported in Table 4.
The results shown in Table 4 further confirmed our hypothesis that vertical (10.55051, t = 1.68, as in
regression [3]) and symmetric (17.76671, t = 2.58, as in regression [3]) alliances lead to higher firm abnormal
returns around announcement days. Furthermore, the interactive variable, Vertical * Symmetry, shows a
significant positive relation between vertical symmetric alliances and firm performance (CARs). Table 4
offers strong evidence that industry scope (vertical vs. horizontal alliances) and size scope (asymmetric
vs. symmetric alliances) play essential roles in strategic alliance outcomes.
To further test the differential impacts of the different types of strategic alliances on a firm’s
long-term performance after the announcement, we regressed a firm’s operating efficiency, which is
estimated as the firm’s operating income/loss over total firm assets, in the first, second, and third year
after the announcement year, on firm level control variables. The results are presented in Table 5.
The long-term firm efficiency analysis, along with our short-term firm performance analysis
results, show that vertical and symmetric alliances improve a company’s performance significantly and
consistently. The positive relation exists for at least three years. To exam the sensitivity of our results,
we also used return on invested capital (ROIC), which measures the percentage return from their
invested capital, as an alternative firm efficiency measurement, and the results are highly consistent,
as shown by the results in Table 5.
Sustainability 2019, 11, 6594 10 of 14
Table 5. Multivariable analysis of company long-term efficiency on vertical and symmetric alliances.
Operating Income
One Year after Announcement Two Years after Announcement Three Years after Announcement
Vertical Dummy 0.098403 * 0.101069 ** 0.220634 * 0.221164 * 0.254759 ** 0.253414 **
(1.93) (2.02) (1.88) (1.88) (2.53) (2.51)
Symmetric Dummy 0.179181 *** 0.175606 *** 0.219822 * 0.217770 * 0.072113 0.066710
(3.41) (3.37) (1.79) (1.79) (0.68) (0.64)
Log (Size) −0.018687 * −0.018990 ** −0.016243 * −0.002504 −0.006126 0.002564 0.006194 −0.000111 0.008259
(−1.92) (−2.00) (−1.71) (−0.11) (−0.27) (0.11) (0.32) (−0.01) (0.43)
Return of Assets (ROA) 0.000593 0.000141 0.000125 0.000637 −0.000125 −0.000069 0.004817 *** 0.004590 ** 0.004619 **
(0.67) (0.16) (0.14) (0.32) (−0.06) (−0.03) (2.65) (2.44) (2.50)
Price to Book −0.003676 −0.004102 −0.004133 −0.000771 −0.001319 −0.001578 0.015957 0.016348 0.015370
(−1.31) (−1.49) (−1.51) (−0.13) (−0.22) (−0.27) (0.98) (0.99) (0.94)
Intercept −0.002840 −0.022692 −0.078594 −0.254227 −0.220694 −0.360316 ** −0.352838 ** −0.239521 * −0.387813 ***
(−0.04) (−0.35) (−1.13) (−1.59) (−1.44) (−2.12) (−2.58) (−1.74) (−2.63)
Adjust R-Square 0.0272 0.0614 0.0743 0.001 −0.0027 0.0113 0.0628 0.0236 0.0589
Number of Observations 228 226 226 185 184 184 146 146 146
Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Sustainability 2019, 11, 6594 11 of 14
5. Conclusion
5.1. Conclusions
This study summarized the literature for the theoretical foundation and definition of strategic
alliances to increase the understanding of the types of strategic alliances. Then, by extending Yasuda
and Iijima (2005)’s alliance matrix, we identified four different types of strategic alliances [11]. We also
proposed that each of these alliance announcements helped the company gain positive firm abnormal
returns and further examined the relative relationship between strategic alliance type and firm alliance
performance. Using the Bloomberg M&A database from 1 January 2010 to 1 January 2016, we found
that vertical symmetric alliances gain more abnormal returns than others.
mainly focused on exploring the relationship between different types of alliances and firm performance.
More and more empirical tests may also provide insights on the firm-level antecedents of different
types of alliances. Finally, it was only focused on the bright side of strategic alliances, while there
are many cases of failure regarding strategic alliances and some strategic alliances have a very short
duration. In the future, there should be an attempt to find some boundary conditions and empirical
tests interested in the marketing or management discipline.
Author Contributions: Conceptualization, B.Y. and H.X.; methodology, F.D.; writing—original draft preparation,
H.X.; writing—review and editing, H.X.
Funding: This research was funded by The Frontier and Innovative Project of Philosophy, Social Science and
Interdisciplinary in Jilin University, grant number 2019QY017.
Acknowledgments: The authors thank the Editor and three anonymous reviewers for their insightful comments
and guidance.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
References
1. Ahuja, G. The duality of collaboration: Inducements and opportunities in the formation of interfirm linkages.
Strateg. Manag. J. 2000, 21, 317–343. [CrossRef]
2. Das, T.K.; Teng, B.-S. Resource and risk management in the strategic alliance making process. J. Manag. 1998,
24, 21–42. [CrossRef]
3. Mahoney, J.T. A resource-based theory of sustainable rents. J. Manag. 2001, 27, 651–660. [CrossRef]
4. Douma, M.U.; Bilderbeek, J.; Idenburg, P.J.; Looise, J.K. Strategic alliances: Managing the dynamics of fit.
Long Range Plan. 2000, 33, 579–598. [CrossRef]
5. Hoffmann, W.H.; Schlosser, R. Success factors of strategic alliances in small and medium-sized enterprises–An
empirical survey. Long Range Plan. 2001, 34, 357–381. [CrossRef]
6. Chan, S.H.; Kensinger, J.W.; Keown, A.J.; Martin, J.D. Do strategic alliances create value? J. Financ. Econ.
1997, 46, 199–221. [CrossRef]
7. Gulati, R.; Nohria, N.; Zaheer, A. Strategic networks. Strateg. Manag. J. 2000, 21, 203–215. [CrossRef]
8. Anand, B.N.; Khanna, T. Do firms learn to create value? The case of alliances. Strateg. Manag. J. 2000, 21,
295–315. [CrossRef]
9. Oxley, J.; Wada, T. Alliance structure and the scope of knowledge transfer: Evidence from US-Japan
agreements. Manag. Sci. 2009, 55, 635–649. [CrossRef]
10. Swaminathan, V.; Moorman, C. Marketing alliances, firm networks, and firm value creation. J. Mark. 2009,
73, 52–69. [CrossRef]
11. Yasuda, H.; Iijima, J. Linkage between strategic alliances and firm’s business strategy: The case of
semiconductor industry. Technovation 2005, 25, 513–521. [CrossRef]
12. Dussauge, P.; Garrette, B.; Mitchell, W. Asymmetric performance: The market share impact of scale and link
alliances in the global auto industry. Strateg. Manag. J. 2004, 25, 701–711. [CrossRef]
13. Barney, J.B. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. J. Manag. 1991, 17, 99–120. [CrossRef]
14. Peteraf, M.A. The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view. Strateg. Manag. J. 1993, 14,
179–191. [CrossRef]
15. Wang, L.; Zajac, E.J. Alliance or acquisition? A dyadic perspective on interfirm resource combinations.
Strateg. Manag. J. 2007, 28, 1291–1317. [CrossRef]
16. Jap, S.D. Pie-expansion efforts: Collaboration processes in buyer-supplier relationships. J. Mark. Res. 1999,
36, 461–475.
17. Das, T.K.; Teng, B.S. A resource-based theory of strategic alliances. J. Manag. 2000, 26, 31–61. [CrossRef]
18. Varadarajan, P.R.; Cunningham, M.H. Strategic alliances: A synthesis of conceptual foundations. J. Acad.
Mark. Sci. 1995, 23, 282–296. [CrossRef]
19. Beamish, P.W.; Banks, J.C. Equity joint ventures and the theory of the multinational enterprise. J. Int. Bus.
Stud. 1987, 18, 1–16. [CrossRef]
20. Yan, A.; Gray, B. Bargaining power, management control, and performance in United States–China joint
ventures: A comparative case study. J. Acad. Manag. J. 1994, 37, 1478–1517.
Sustainability 2019, 11, 6594 13 of 14
21. Harrigan, K.R.; Newman, W.H. Bases of Interorganization Co-operation: Propensity, Power, Persistence.
J. Manag. Stud. 1990, 27, 417–434. [CrossRef]
22. Salancik, G.R.; Pfeffer, J.A. A social information processing approach to job attitudes and task design. Adm. Sci.
Q. 1978, 23, 224–253. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
23. Lambe, C.J.; Spekman, R.E.; Hunt, S.D. Interimistic relational exchange: Conceptualization and propositional
development. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 2000, 28, 212–225. [CrossRef]
24. Dyer, J.H.; Singh, H. The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive
advantage. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1998, 23, 660–679. [CrossRef]
25. Day, G.S. Advantageous alliances. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 1995, 23, 297–300. [CrossRef]
26. Lavie, D. Alliance portfolios and firm performance: A study of value creation and appropriation in the US
software industry. Strateg. Manag. J. 2007, 28, 1187–1212. [CrossRef]
27. Gleason, K.C.; Mathur, I.; Wiggins, R.A., III. Evidence on value creation in the financial services industries
through the use of joint ventures and strategic alliances. Financ. Rev. 2003, 38, 213–234. [CrossRef]
28. Chan, S.H.; Kensinger, J.W.; Keown, A.J.; Martin, J.D. When do strategic alliances create shareholder value?
J. Appl. Corp. Financ. 1999, 11, 82–87. [CrossRef]
29. Kalaignanam, K.; Shankar, V.; Varadarajan, R. Asymmetric new product development alliances: Win-win or
win-lose partnerships? Manag. Sci. 2007, 53, 357–374. [CrossRef]
30. Rindfleisch, A. Organizational trust and interfirm cooperation: An examination of horizontal versus vertical
alliances. Market. Lett. 2000, 11, 81–95. [CrossRef]
31. Rindfleisch, A.; Moorman, C. The acquisition and utilization of information in new product alliances: A
strength-of-ties perspective. J. Mark. 2001, 65, 1–18. [CrossRef]
32. Williams, R.G.; Lilley, M.M. Partner selection for joint-venture agreements. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 1993, 11,
233–237. [CrossRef]
33. Stuart, T.E. Interorganizational alliances and the performance of firms: A study of growth and innovation
rates in a high-technology industry. Strateg. Manag. J. 2000, 21, 791–811. [CrossRef]
34. Pfeffer, J.; Salancik, G. The external con-trol of organizations. In A Resource Dependence Approach; Harper and
Row Publishers: New York, NY, USA, 1978.
35. Drees, J.M.; Heugens, P.P. Synthesizing and extending resource dependence theory a meta-analysis. J. Manag.
2013, 39, 1666–1698.
36. Day, G.S. Closing the marketing capabilities gap. J. Mark. 2011, 75, 183–195. [CrossRef]
37. Uzzi, B. The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations:
The network effect. Am. Sociol. Rev. 1996, 61, 674–698. [CrossRef]
38. Zaheer, A.; McEvily, B.; Perrone, V. Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and
interpersonal trust on performance. Organ. Sci. 1998, 9, 141–159. [CrossRef]
39. Fang, E. Customer participation and the trade-off between new product innovativeness and speed to market.
J. Mark. 2008, 72, 90–104. [CrossRef]
40. Prahalad, C.K.; Ramaswamy, V. Co-opting customer competence. Harv. Bus. Rev. 2000, 78, 79–90.
41. Wheelwright, S.C.; Clark, K.B. Competing through development capability in a manufacturing-based
organization. Bus. Horiz. 1992, 35, 29–43. [CrossRef]
42. Garcia-Pont, C.; Nohria, N. Global versus local mimetism: How strategic networks get built. In Strategic
Management Journal’s Special Issue Conference on Strategic Networks; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany,
1999.
43. Zaheer, A.; Zaheer, S. The structure of global competition: A network approach. In Strategic Management
Journal’s Special Issue Conference on Strategic Networks; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1999.
44. Morris, M.H.; Koçak, A.; Özer, A. Coopetition as a small business strategy: Implications for performance.
J. Small Bus. Strategy 2007, 18, 35–55.
45. Oke, A.; Idiagbon-Oke, M.; Walumbwa, F. RETRACTED: The relationship between brokers’ influence,
strength of ties and NPD project outcomes in innovation-driven horizontal networks. J. Oper. Manag. 2008,
26, 571–589. [CrossRef]
46. Oke, A.; Idiagbon-Oke, M. Communication channels, innovation tasks and NPD project outcomes in
innovation-driven horizontal networks. J. Oper. Manag. 2010, 28, 442–453. [CrossRef]
47. Luo, Y. A coopetition perspective of global competition. J. World Bus. 2007, 42, 129–144. [CrossRef]
Sustainability 2019, 11, 6594 14 of 14
48. Amaldoss, W.; Meyer, R.J.; Raju, J.S.; Rapoport, A. Collaborating to compete. Mark. Sci. 2000, 19, 105–126.
[CrossRef]
49. Luo, X.; Rindfleisch, A.; Tse, D.K. Working with rivals: The impact of competitor alliances on financial
performance. J. Mark. Res. 2007, 44, 73–83. [CrossRef]
50. Sheth, J.N.; Sisodia, R.S. Revisiting marketing’s lawlike generalizations. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 1999, 27, 71–87.
[CrossRef]
51. Gulati, R.; Wohlgezogen, F.; Zhelyazkov, P. The two facets of collaboration: Cooperation and coordination in
strategic alliances. Acad. Manag. Ann. 2012, 6, 531–583. [CrossRef]
52. Burgers, W.P.; Hill, C.W.; Kim, W.C. A theory of global strategic alliances: The case of the global auto industry.
Strateg. Manag. J. 1993, 14, 419–432. [CrossRef]
53. Gomes-Casseres, B. Alliance strategies of small firms. Small Bus. Econ. 1997, 9, 33–44. [CrossRef]
54. Sampson, R.C. R&D alliances and firm performance: The impact of technological diversity and alliance
organization on innovation. J. Acad. Manag. J. 2007, 50, 364–386.
55. Wassmer, U.; Dussauge, P. Network resource stocks and flows: How do alliance portfolios affect the value of
new alliance formations? Strateg. Manag. J. 2012, 33, 871–883. [CrossRef]
56. Park, N.K. A guide to using event study methods in multi-country settings. Strateg. Manag. J. 2004, 25,
655–668. [CrossRef]
57. Giroud, X.; Mueller, H.M. Corporate governance, product market competition, and equity prices. J. Financ.
2011, 66, 563–600. [CrossRef]
58. Xu, H.; Guo, H.; Zhang, J.; Dang, A. Facilitating dynamic marketing capabilities development for domestic
and foreign firms in an emerging economy. J. Bus. Res. 2018, 86, 141–152. [CrossRef]
59. Guo, H.; Xu, H.; Tang, C.; Liu-Thompkins, Y.; Guo, Z.; Dong, B. Comparing the impact of different marketing
capabilities: Empirical evidence from B2B firms in China. J. Bus. Res. 2018, 93, 79–89. [CrossRef]
60. Gnyawali, D.R.; Park, B.J.R. Co-opetition between giants: Collaboration with competitors for technological
innovation. Res. Policy 2011, 40, 650–663. [CrossRef]
© 2019 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).