Valuation: Accounting For Risk and The Expected Return
Valuation: Accounting For Risk and The Expected Return
Valuation: Accounting For Risk and The Expected Return
Stephen Penman
New York
*Email: [email protected]. Thanks to Matt Lyle, Steven Monahan, Scott Richardson, and
Theodore Sougiannis for comments.
Abstract.
Under accounting principles, the recognition of earnings is path dependent and the path depends
on risk resolution: Under the so-called realization principle, earnings are not booked until
uncertainty is resolved. In asset pricing terms, the principle means that earnings cannot be
recognized until the firm can book a low-beta asset such as cash or a near-cash discounted
receivable. If the risk to which this accounting responds is priced risk, the accounting indicates
the expected return. This paper connects accounting under this principle to risk and return,
summarizes the supporting empirical evidence, and examines the implications for research on the
implied cost of capital, cash-flow betas, asset pricing models that imbed accounting numbers,
and papers that assume an autoregressive model for the earnings path to infer the expected
return. The accounting that captures risk and its resolution also has implications for the unsolved
issue of specifying the appropriate accounting for accounting-based valuation models and,
indeed, for financial accounting standards.
Accounting-based valuation substitutes book values and/or earnings for dividends in equity
valuation. While research in this area has had an impact on text books and, to a lesser extent, on
practice, important issues remain to be resolved.1 These outstanding issues involve both the
For the numerator, the so-called residual income model replaces expected dividends with
book value and expected earnings by assuming clean-surplus accounting. However, clean-
surplus accounting is purely an accounting operation that articulates income statements and
balance sheets, with no prescription for how the accounting numbers are to be measured. Indeed,
an infinite-horizon residual income model―the only version of the model that necessarily
equates calculated value to that given by expected dividends for going concerns―is cynical
about the accounting involved: fair value accounting, historical cost accounting, and even
random numbers are tolerated, with no discrimination between them.2 The Ohlson-Juettner
(2005) model dispenses with book values, but the so-called earnings that remain in the model are
Clearly, something more has to be put on the table before we have a model that can be
embraced with some confidence. As all clean-surplus accounting yields the same value for
infinite horizons, the specification of the accounting must have to do with valuation over finite
1
Demirakos et al. (2004), Hand et al. (2015), and Pinto et al. (2015) survey the use of valuation models in practice.
2
This is understood when it is claimed (correctly) that discounted cash flow valuation (cash accounting) and
accrual-accounting residual income valuation converge with infinite forecasting horizons.
1
forecasting horizons. That satisfies an important requirement: Practical valuation must work with
finite-horizon forecasts. Valuation that requires elusive forecasts for the very-long run—for the
years, 2030, 2040, and even 2020—is hardly practical; in the long run, we are all dead. And
substituting current consumption for consumption at some future (finite) point in time (for
example, at retirement). The investor seeks an accounting where forecasts for finite periods
convey the value and the risk of consumption at a finite point of time in the future.3
The denominator issue has received relatively less attention in accounting research,
though it is the key issue in asset pricing research in finance. In the Ohlson (1995) paper that
spurred much accounting research in the area, the discount rate is assumed to be the risk-free
rate, notifying the reader that the paper has to do with the numerator, not the denominator. There
is some subsequent research on how accounting conveys information about the discount rate but,
for the main part, students in financial statement valuation classes are told to get the “cost of
capital” from finance courses, only to find that, as a practical matter, asset pricing research does
This paper focuses primarily on the denominator: How does accounting convey
information about the discount rate? But, in so doing, a solution for the numerator issue
surfaces. Indeed, the numerator and denominator issues are linked: Accounting for the
3
Penman (1997 and 2015) demonstrates how the accounting affects valuation and its errors with finite-horizon
forecasting.
2
The paper revolves around a key idea. For accountants, the idea is readily appreciated, for
it surfaces in the basic “Accounting Principles” class we all had. In that class, the professor
began by contrasting accrual accounting with cash accounting; you keep the accounts for your
tennis club (and your government) on a cash basis, but businesses use accrual accounting. He or
she then characterized accrual accounting as recognizing periodic earnings that are different from
cash flows; life-time earnings equal life-time cash flows, but the allocation to periods differs.
Then followed a statement of the key principle under which historical cost accounting recognizes
periodic earnings: Under uncertainty, earnings are not recognized until the uncertainty has
largely been resolved. This “realization principle” is typically applied when the firm has a secure
customer and “receipt of cash is reasonably certain”. Accordingly, accrual accounting is driven
by principles based on risk and its resolution (fair value accounting aside); recognized earnings
report the resolution of risk, while anticipated earnings are not recognized because there is risk
that the expectation will not be realized―customers may not materialize. With this as the driving
principle, earnings recognition is not just about conveying news about future cash flows, but also
finance. It is this principle that is central to connecting accounting information to risk and the
expected return. And it is this principle that provides pointers for resolving both the numerator
This paper is a “thought piece”, raising a number of insights but not providing definitive
solutions; you will not get an estimate of the “cost of capital” from this paper. Nevertheless, the
insights provide a commentary and criticism on existing research that strives to that end,
including “implied cost of capital” estimates, “cash-flow betas”, the application of the
Voulteenaho (2002) model, the connection of the discount rate to accounting numbers in
3
empirical asset pricing, and the attribution of “accounting anomalies” to risk or abnormal returns.
d Cov(d , Yt )
Pt
t 1 Rtf
, (1)
where Pt is the current price, dτ is expected dividends τ periods ahead conditional on information
at time t, Ytτ is the time-t conditional discount factor for expected cash flows for period τ, a
random variable common to all assets, and Rtf is the term structure of (one plus) the spot riskless
interest rates from t to τ. (Here and elsewhere, all variables subscripted for periods greater than t
are expected values.) See Rubinstein (1976) and Breeden and Litzenberger (1978).
The risk adjustment in the numerator of equation (1) is given by the infinite sequence of
expected dividends for each τ and their periodic covariance with the economy-wide random
variable, Ytτ. However, under Miller and Modigliani (1961) (M&M) assumptions, the sequencing
of dividends over τ up to any finite future point in time is irrelevant to current value. Further,
with dividends a matter of payout policy and no necessary relation to real activity, there is no
necessary relation with Ytτ. Indeed, a particular payout policy―zero dividends, for example
―could imply Cov(dτ, Ytτ) = 0 for all τ up to the liquidating dividend (and going concerns are not
expected to liquidate).
4
Accounting-based valuation is offered as a way of finessing this issue. Given clean-
surplus accounting such that dτ = Earningsτ – (Bτ – Bτ-1) where B is the book value of common
equity, the corresponding valuation to model (1) is given by Feltham and Ohlson (1999):
RE Cov( RE , Yt )
Pt Bt
t 1 Rtf
. (1a)
Residual earnings, REτ = Earningsτ – iτ-1.Bτ-1, with iτ-1 the riskless spot rate. Price is thus given by
Bτ and the (discounted) sequence of expected earnings and dividends (that imply expected book
values). However, the dividend sequence is irrelevant to this valuation under M&M assumptions
and accounting principles under which dividends do not affect the calculation of earnings but are
paid out of book value (see Ohlson 1995). Christensen and Feltham (2009) elaborate on this
valuation.
These expressions discount for risk in the numerator, with the discount varying overtime.
However, the evaluation of the discount presents us with a difficult practical problem: the Ytτ
but has no economic content without further structure. Given this difficulty, practical valuation
resorts to the expediency of applying a discount rate in the denominator of a valuation model, with
that discount rate given by the risk-free rate plus a premium for risk (often referred to as the
d
Pt
R
t 1
p
, (2)
t
where Rtp is the discount rate for period τ given by the sequence of (one plus) periodic risk-
5
RE
Pt Bt p
t 1 Rt
. (2a)
Residual earnings is now defined as REτ = Earningsτ – ERτ.Bτ-1, where ERτ is the expected return
for period τ. A further expediency sets the expected return as a constant over time, but at some
cost: If risk varies with the sequencing of earnings and its covariance with Ytτ, as in equation (1a),
this feature is suppressed. Indeed, the notion of a constant discount rate is suspect from first
principles; if the discount rate is time-varying, the assumption of a constant discount rate is
inconsistent with the no-arbitrage assumption on which valuation theory is based, and one
presumes that the discount rate varies with interest rates, risk preferences, the evolution of the firm
(and maybe information in accounting reports). Ang and Liu (2004) demonstrate the valuation
Models (1a) and (2a) are the foundation of accounting-based valuation. However, apart
from the clean-surplus equation, not much has been put on the table. Importantly, the accounting
for earnings and book value in these valuations is unspecified. As mentioned in the introduction,
these models exhibit a value-irrelevance property with respect to the numerator accounting; the
form of the accounting does not matter. However, the accounting also bears on the discount for
risk, as the risk adjustment depends on the sequence of expected earnings and Ytτ. Accrual
accounting generates that sequence, for it involves an allocation of earnings to periods, τ. Thus,
the form of the accrual accounting is pertinent to the risk assessment. To stress the point, random
numbers for earnings, with zero covariance with Ytτ, would have no implication for the risk
discount. Just as the sequence of dividends and their covariance with Ytτ has no necessary bearing
on value or the risk discount, so might the accounting without further specification.
6
A FRAMEWORK TO EVAUATE THE ISSUES
A simple identity that connects the expected return to accounting numbers serves as a starting
point. By the clean-surplus relation (CSR), expected dividends, dτ = Earningsτ – (Bτ – Bτ-1) for
all τ. Substituting for dividends in the expression for the stock return (with firm subscripts
omitted), the sequence of expected stock returns for future periods is given by
P d P 1 Earnings P B ( P 1 B 1 )
ER , (3)
P 1 P 1 P 1
τ = t+1, t+2, t+3, …. . That is, the expected stock return for any year is equal to the expected
forward earnings yield plus the expected change in premium over the year denominated in the
expected beginning-of-period price.4 With the current price, Pt, set to obey the no-arbitrage
condition, Pt+1 + dt+1 = (1+ERt+1)Pt , and so, recursively, for all τ. Thus Pτ-1 (and Pt) discounts
expectations on the right-hand side for the risk surrounding those expectations.
Penman, Reggiani, Richardson, and Tuna (2015) introduce equation (3) as a starting
point for identifying the earnings-to-price ratio and the book-to-price ratio as characteristics that
relate to expected returns. The expression is a tautology, but nevertheless serves to yield some
insights. To gain these insights, we first establish certain properties (see also Penman and Zhang
(2015):
4
This identity has long been recognized for realized returns, for example in Easton, Harris, and Ohlson
(1992). We adapt it here to apply to expected returns.
7
P1. Dividend irrelevance. Under M&M assumptions, dividends reduce price one-to-one,
dividends are not charged to earnings. Condition (ii) is satisfied if dividends reduce book
value one-for-one (as they do price under M&M). Both conditions are satisfied under
ΔBτ + dτ = Earningsτ
Thus, for a given ERτ (and thus a given ΔPτ + dτ), a change is premium is induced by the
measurement of earnings given P1; lower earnings, for example, imply an increase in
premium.
P3. An expected change in the premium implies expected earnings growth. If earnings
Earnings
are measured such that ER and thus Pτ – Bτ – (Pτ-1 – B τ-1) = 0, then,
P 1
Earnings 1 P 1
ER 1 ( . ) ER . Setting dτ = 0,
P Earnings
8
1
Earnings 1 ER 1 (1 ) Earnings
ER
That is, earnings are expected to grow at a rate equal to the (time varying) expected
return.5 It follows that, if earnings are expected to grow at rate different from the
earnings growth at a rate different from the expected return. See also Shroff (1995).
P1 grounds the analysis in no-arbitrage valuation theory. Under M&M, the expected
return that reconciles successive price expectations (with no arbitrage) is insensitive to the timing
of dividends, and P1gives accounting conditions under which ERτ expressed in terms of
accounting numbers exhibit this property. P2 brings the point on accounting measurement to the
fore: The relationship between ERτ and accounting depends on how accounting is measured. P3
establishes a benchmark accounting where expected earnings equal expected returns (with no
expected change in premium) and there can be no expected earnings growth beyond the
“normal” rate equal to the ERτ+1. More generally, earnings below this “normal” earnings implies
expected earnings growth with a corresponding increase in the premium. Put differently, Pτ -1 is
based on the expectation of all subsequent (life-long) earnings, so the lower is the expected
period-τ component of those earnings, the higher must be the subsequent expected earnings
relative to the period-τ earnings. Viewed in terms of P/E ratio, with no expected change in
Earnings 1
premium, ERτ = implies the expected forward P/E = , that is, a “normal” P/E
P 1 ER
5
If Earningsτ = Earningst+1, all τ, the accounting is sometimes referred to as “permanent income accounting”
whereby Earningst+1 is sufficient for forecasting all future earnings. One can show that, if Earningsτ = Earningst+1,
all τ, then ERτ = ERt+1, all τ, that is, the expected return is constant over time. Setting dτ = 0 is for simplicity; dτ ≠ 0
reduces Earningsτ+1, but, with the dividends reinvested at the rate, ERτ+1, cum-dividend earnings are unaffected,
given P1.
9
(without expected earnings growth). According, ERτ can be represented in terms of a sequence
However, if one is seeking information from the accounting that informs about the
expected return, not much has been put on the table. Any measurement of earnings satisfies
equation (3): A lower expected earnings yield, the first term on the right-hand side, merely
implies an offsetting change in premium, with ERτ of the left-hand side unaffected. Indeed,
accrual accounting that determines the earnings in any one period can be arbitrary, without
economic substance. Equation (3) is, after all, a tautology. Just as CSR (alone) gives no
resolution to the numerator issue, nor does it to the denominator issue; CSR just involves a
substitution of earnings and book value for dividends, but “earnings” and “book values” are
nothing more than names without more specification as to the their measurement.
If the sequence of ERτ is to be informed by the accounting, one requires more structure on
the accounting. That structure must communicate risk that results in a discount in the
denominating price, Pτ-1, (and thus the current price, Pt) to yield a higher ERτ that reflects that
risk. That is, the portion of expected life-long earnings to be recognized in period τ must
communicate the ERτ for that period. That, again, is an accounting measurement issue, for
accounting measurement is simply (!) an allocation of earnings to periods under specified accrual
accounting principles.
We consider two alternative prescriptions for accounting for earnings and book values and
A. Mark-to-Market Accounting
10
Earnings
Set Bτ = Pτ, all τ. Then, Pτ – Bτ – (Pτ-1 – B τ-1) = 0, and ERτ = by equation (3). Bt
P 1
(current reported book value) is equal to the present value of expected cash flows, so imbeds
both expected cash flows and the discount rate. Thus, like Pt to which it equates, Bt is not
informative about the discount rate; the investor looks for information that informs about risk in
Pτ, but Bt cannot supply it. Further, realized Earningst (equal to the cum-dividend change in book
value) also conveys no information; earnings and price changes imbed revisions in both expected
cash flows and future ERτ―so-called cash-flow news and discount-rate news―but not ERτ. Just
as price changes convey little information about future ERτ, neither does earnings.6 And, the ERτ
no information about ERτ is supplied by the accounting. In short, there is no accounting for risk
These points are best demonstrated in the case of a marked-to-market bond. That
accounting sets Pτ – Bτ – (Pτ-1 – B τ-1) = 0, and appropriately so, for a bond cannot have expected
Earnings
growth. Accordingly, ERτ = , with the earnings yield determined via the effective
P 1
interest method. However, effective interest is inferred from the bond price and the bond yield it
6
Just as one might infer the expected return from a (long) time series of shocks to prices, so might one do so from
shocks to book values (earnings) under mark-to-market accounting, provided that the expected return were a
constant over that observation period. But this is doubtful with changing discount rates where shocks reflect both
cash-flow news and discount-rate news.
7
Cochrane (2011) makes the same point about fair value accounting.
11
implies via an internal rate-of-return calculation. The accounting does not supply the expected
earnings yield from which the ERτ can be inferred; rather it is the other way around.
While mark-to-market accounting (or fair value accounting) is somewhat hypothetical for
B. Mark-to-Market Accounting for Financing Activities and Historical Cost Accounting for
Operating Activities
Set the accounting for book value such that Pτ – Bτ ≠ 0. Separate price and book value associated
with operating (business) activities and financing (net borrowing) activities while honouring the
P P NOA P ND
B NOA ND
P NOA is the price of the operating activities (enterprise price), NOAτ (net operating assets) is the
book value of operating activities (enterprise book value), and P ND and NDτ are the price and
book value of the net debt, respectively. Marking net debt to market implies the following two
properties:
P4. Financing leverage does not affect the premium or the change in premium if net debt
The ND P ND condition is not precisely met under GAAP, but is approximately so except
when there is a significant change in interest rates or credit risk (and these changes are
12
P5. Financing leverage impacts the expected return via the expected earnings yield. By the
cash conservation equation of accounting, free cash flow (the net cash from operations),
be expressed as
P NOA P ND
ERNOA ERND
P P
ERNOA
P ND
1
P 1
ERNOA ERND
P ND F P ND
1 P ND
ER
ND
is the expected return for net debt, and 1
is the amount of
P ND
1 P 1
leverage. This, of course, is the Modigliani and Miller (1958) leverage equation underlying
the standard weighted-average cost-of-capital calculation.
A similar arithmetic expresses the expected earnings yield as the accounting analog to this
expected return. As Earningsτ = OIτ – Net Interestτ (where OIτ is earnings from operations),
ND
accounting for net debt such that NDτ = P implies
where OINOA
is the forward unlevered earnings yield and Net Interest is the firm’s net
P 1 ND 1
borrowing rate as reported in the financial statements. See Penman, Reggiani, Richardson,
and Tuna (2015). Thus, leverage that increases the expected return to equity on the left-
hand side of equation (3) also increases the expected earnings yield on the right-hand side
13
of that equation. With no effect on the premium under P4, the leverage contribution to the
P4 and P5 describe how the effect of leverage on the expected return is conveyed through
the accounting. It is quite instructive, for it provides an insight in to how the risk in operations
might also be conveyed through the accounting. Property 6 introduces the idea:
P6. Leverage increases expected earnings growth. By the same arithmetic for the
expressions in P5,
gEarnings
OI Net Interest
OI 1 Net Interest 1
gOI
Earnings 1
Net Interest 1 OI
g t gNet Interest
for all τ, where gτ indicates a growth rate in period τ and the respective superscripts indicate
the subject of the growth. Thus leverage increases expected earnings growth provided
expected growth in income from operations is greater than that for net interest (a
Here is the insight: Typically one views expected earnings growth as increasing price and thus
decreasing the earnings-to-price (E/P) ratio (increasing the P/E ratio). However, while leverage
increases expected earnings growth, leverage has no effect on equity price under Modigliani and
Miller (1958) conditions. The growth from leverage that might otherwise add to price is risky
growth so is discounted in the price; expected growth and risk cancel to leave the price
unchanged.8
8
Penman (2013, Chapter 14) provides numerical examples.
14
And so to the question: Could it be that expected earnings growth associated with
operating activities is also discounted in the price to yield a higher ERτ? If, like leverage,
expected earnings growth is discounted because it is risky, that growth does not add to price.
And, if the denominating price, Pτ-1, in equation (3) remains unchanged, ERτ will increase with
Although redundant, the point can be made via a simple valuation model with a constant
expected return and constant growth rate. Given full payout, the valuation,
Earnings t 1
Pt (4)
ER g
yields the same valuation as a discounted dividend valuation (and an equivalent valuation to the
Earnings t 1
ER g . (4a)
Pt
The standard view is that expected growth, g, adds to price and thus decreases the E/P ratio (and
increases the P/E ratio). But, that is only so if ER is held constant while g varies. If ER increases
with g, one for one, in equation (4a), then price does not change. The way this works with
9
The full payout assumption is unimportant. Payout (retention) other than full payout adds to earnings
growth, g, but does not add value under M&M conditions, nor does it affect the premium of price over
book value under P1. The valuation in equation (4) isolates the growth that potentially affects price and
the expected return, r, and at the same time is M&M consistent. Penman, Reggiani, Richardson, and Tuna
(2015) connect growth to the expected return via the Ohlson-Juettner (2005) model that generalizes the
Gordon model by maintaining M&M properties for all payouts.
15
leverage has been demonstrated. With respect to operating activities, further information that
this question would require accounting principles for the measurement of earnings such that two
(a) Earnings are measured such that the expected growth generated by earnings
Condition (a) appears to be satisfied under GAAP and IFRS accounting principles for
recognizing earnings:
P7. The realization principle. Under uncertainty, GAAP and IFRS historical cost
accounting defers the recognition of earnings until the uncertainly has largely been
resolved.
Deferring earnings to the future reduces recognized earnings and, for a given Pτ-1, increases
subsequent expected earnings, that is, it increases expected earnings growth. Further, under the
principle, the earnings that are deferred are at risk, uncertain as to their realization.
Correspondingly, realized earnings represent the outcome of the risk, risk resolved. Pt (current
price) is the expectation of all future earnings but the timing of those earnings to periods, τ, is
dictated by accrual accounting principles and the governing principle is the realization principle
16
Indeed, under this principle, accounting can be seen as a system that tracks the resolution
of uncertainty over time: Earnings is recognized and book value added only when uncertainty is
resolved, while the recognition of earnings still at risk is deferred to the future. Accordingly, the
sequence of future ERτ in equation (3) can be represented as a sequence based on expected
earnings realization but also earnings deferred. The deferral establishes prior probabilities for the
The deferral principle is applied with revenue recognition rules that (usually) require the
firm to have a firm customer, with receipt of cash to be “reasonably certain”: Expected future
sales are not recognized, even though they may be anticipated in the price, because they are at
risk of not being consummated.10 However, the uncertainty principle is also applied in expensing
investments that are particularly risky―R&D, promotion, start-up costs, investment in software,
distribution and supply chain development, employee training, to name a few. This so-called
conservative accounting reduces reported earnings but increases expected future earnings (from
expected sales with no amortization of investment expenditure), that is, earnings growth.11 But
the growth is risky: The payoff to the R&D etc. may not be realized. Feltham and Ohlson (1995)
and Zhang (2000) recognize the property whereby conservative accounting depresses earnings
and creates expected earnings growth, but with a constant discount rate. P7 opens up the prospect
that this accounting may have implications for the discount rate.12 Penman and Zhang (2015)
10
New IASB and FASB proposals for revenue recognition require satisfaction of a contract, and contract resolution
appears to have the feature of removing uncertainty.
11
“Conservative accounting” is characterized in different ways in the literature. It is used here to mean any
accounting that results in price greater than book value which, in turn, implies that expected earnings in price are
recognized (and added to book value) with a delay.
12
A special case involves conservative accounting for investment with no change in the premium: If there is no
growth in investment, earnings (and the premium) are not affected, even though conservative accounting is applied
to the investment. So, for example, earnings are not affected by the expensing of R&D if there is no growth in R&D;
in steady state, earnings are the same whether R&D is expensed immediately or capitalized and amortized. With
17
elaborate.13 The accounting for earnings is path dependent and the path depends on risk and its
resolution.
It is far less clear whether condition (b) on the pricing of risk is satisfied. However, asset
pricing theory demonstrates that it is satisfied for leverage: Levered betas are higher than
unlevered betas. Accordingly, the increase in expected earnings growth from leverage is at risk
from market-wide shocks. Thus, it is not farfetched to imagine that shocks to expected earnings
(growth) might be sensitive to economy-wide shocks such as shocks to GDP. The realization
principle implies an effect on betas: In asset pricing terms, earnings are not recognized (and
added to book value) until the firm can book a low-beta asset such as cash or a near-cash
receivable; there is a different beta exposure with unrecognized earnings versus realized
earnings.
Asset pricing theory (and valuation theory more generally) is built on the principle of no-
arbitrage, and a no-arbitrage argument further supports the idea that the realization principle ties
to priced risk. In holding stocks, investors bear risk that the expected return may not be realized,
and thus require a return commensurate with the risk. But, when they sell stocks and invest the
cash proceeds in the risk-free asset―they realize the return―the risk is reduced, and so is the
expected return (to the risk-free rate). A stock is a claim on the expected earnings of a firm, so
when the firm realizes those expected earnings into cash or a near-cash asset on shareholders’
behalf, the investors’ risk and expected return are correspondingly reduced. On a consolidated
respect to risk, this steady-state property―the so-called cancelling error property of accounting―occurs when the
reduction of earnings from expensing new risky investment is exactly offset by the realization of earnings from
earlier investments.
13
Penman, Reggiani, Richardson, and Tuna (2015) demonstrate many of the properties in this section with
examples, including a case where expected growth is priced to yield a higher expected return.
18
basis, the firm’s accounts are part of the shareholders’ accounts, so it makes no difference if the
shareholder “realizes” or the firm “realizes” on the shareholder’s behalf― the shareholders (the
100 percent owners) have the claim to the same cash. A no-arbitrage condition so dictates
(frictions aside). The idea of realization as risk resolution also resonates with the economics
(realized) cash that buys consumption. Again, no-arbitrage applies: Cash payout has no effect on
cum-dividend value under M&M, so cash held in the firm has the same consumption value as
These points aside, under asset pricing theory condition (b) would require the risk that is
recognized in the realization principle to be non-diversifiable risk. That is, the expected growth
created under the principle would have to be growth that can be shocked by factors common to
all stocks. (Of course, it remains an open question as to whether idiosyncratic risk is also priced.)
One would love to have a property 8 that links the deferred earnings (growth) to priced risk and
thus the expected return. That is too ambitious (for me) given we do not have a generally
accepted asset pricing model for priced risk and return and, if we did, linking accounting
operations to risk factors and their sensitivities is a challenging task.15 It would involve an
identification of Ytτ and the covariance terms in model (1a) that discounts the sequence of
14
Realization typically results in a receivable rather than cash, but receivables are discounted to a cash equivalent
value for the risk of not receiving the cash, at least in principle.
15
Ohlson (2008) lays out a model where permanent income accounting with a constant expected return (as defined
in P3) is modified to yield a constant growth rate that equates to the risk premium (and, in turn, implies an expected
increase in premiums of price over book value). The paper envisions an allocation of life-long expected earnings to
periods with this feature, but is silent on the transaction analysis and accrual accounting principles that could induce
earnings growth that is tied to risk.
19
However, there is evidence that suggests that this accounting conveys information about
EVIDENCE
Penman and Reggiani (2013) shows that average returns are related to the extent to which
earnings are expected to be recognized in the short term versus the long term. Penman, Reggiani,
Richardson, and Tuna (2015) show that portfolios with higher expected earnings growth are at a
higher risk of that growth not being realized and that higher growth also has higher sensitivity to
market-wide shocks to growth. Ellahie, Katz, and Richardson (2014) reports similar findings at
the aggregate (country) level. Penman and Zhang (2015) find that firms where higher earnings
growth is created by earnings deferrals under conservative accounting yield higher average stock
returns. Correspondingly, expected earnings, so deferred, have higher variance around them and
higher sensitivity to shocks to aggregate earnings. Based on P7, Penman and Yehuda (2015)
extract a measure of the change in ERt from financial statements (“discount-rate news”) and
show that the market indeed prices this information as if it is news about expected returns.
All these results could be attributed to market inefficiency, of course. But that would be
cavalier; the connection to risk via the realization principle cannot be dismissed lightly. The
predicted returns in the papers just cited are not from data dredging with a search for t-statistics;
rather the tests are structured with an understanding of how accounting connects to risk. That
said, condition (b) remains an open question. That qualification must be kept in mind in reading
what follows.
20
This analysis provides a commentary on a number of streams of accounting and finance research
that attempt to connect risk and expected returns to accounting numbers. While the commentary
is negative at points, it is provided in the spirit of improving the research. One requires a sense of
balance: While points of theory should be recognized and implemented if possible, rough-and-
ready approaches should not be dismissed out of hand if fine points are not operational.
A long stream of research has attempted to infer expected returns from forecasts of accounting
numbers. That research reduces model (2a) such that, in the simplest form,
RE1
Pt Bt . (5)
ER g
The expected return, a constant called the “implied cost of capital” (ICC), is then calculated as
the internal rate of return that reconciles forecasts of forward earnings and a constant growth
rate, g, to observed Pt – Bt. Variations include two or more years of forecasted earnings with a
growth rate applied at the longer forecast horizons or (in Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan,
2001) with an assumption that book rates of return will decline to an industry benchmark over
time. Other papers, such as Gode and Mohanram (2003), reverse engineer the Ohlson-Juettner
(2005) model with a constant growth rate. See Easton (2007) and Easton and Monahan (2015,
this issue) for review and commentary. Note that, as this expected return is inferred from price, it
cannot be inserted in model (2a) to calculate price. For that, one needs (accounting) information
Some papers have shown that ICC measures are somewhat related to conjectured risk
measures such as beta, leverage, and industry membership, in Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan
21
(2001) and Botosan and Plumlee (2005), for example. However, the research has been largely
unsuccessful in predicting average returns, a failure in validation. Guay, et al. (2011) and Easton
and Monahan (2005) discuss. This state of affairs is quite remarkable given that many
accounting numbers (with less pretense to being the expected return) readily predict returns (and
robustly so), for example, E/P, book-to-price (B/P), accruals, growth in assets, and a number of
financing variables, to name a few. This predictive ability could be attributed to market
inefficiency, but the ICC is the implied internal rate of return implicit in the current price so
should similarly identify market mispricing. The problem is more likely to be in the approach
and/or the inputs. Much is at stake; a considerable amount of research on disclosure, earnings
quality, audit quality, regulatory institutions, and corporate governance mechanisms rides on the
effect of these features on the “cost of capital” as measured by the ICC. This research seems to
have taken on a life of its own with broad acceptance that ICC measures the cost of capital.
Much of the critique of ICC estimates focuses on using analysts’ forecasts as an input.
The Lewellen (2010) critique stresses this issue, among others. Mohanram and Gode (2013) and
Wang (2013) demonstrate some improvement in dealing with it. Other papers such as Hou, van
Dijk, and Zhang (2012) and Li and Monhanram (2014) replace analysts’ forecasts with forecasts
estimated from accounting data, with some success. Lee, So, and Wang (2014) propose a
framework for evaluating alternative ICC estimates. The review below focuses on the approach
First, the assumption of a constant expected return (and estimating the cost of capital)
based on forecasted earnings is doubtful if ERτ varies with the expected time-varying realization
of earnings as uncertainty is resolved. For example, if ERτ is time varying, the ICC estimated
with the input of a long-term earnings growth rate, g, may be a poor predictor of short-term
22
expected returns, perhaps explaining the inability of ICC estimates to forecast year-ahead
returns.16
Second, the typical assumption of the same growth path for all firms is likely to be
violated; indeed, estimating different growth rates over firms, as in Nekrasov and Ogneva
(2011), shows improvement in predicting returns. This point is well recognized, but our analysis
adds a further dimension: If expected growth is connected to risk and the expected return under
the realization principle, ER and g in model (5) are connected; a higher g implies a higher ER.
Failure to distinguish different growth rates across firms may thus fail to distinguish different
risk. And failure to input a growth rate commensurate with the indicated risk confounds the ICC
estimate. Further, the joint estimation of ER and g in Easton, Taylor, Shroff and Sougiannis
(2002) as if they were independent inputs to a valuation is suspect if growth is risk. The
connection of growth, risk, and the expected return in P5 and P6 makes the point: Leverage
increases both expected earnings growth and risk, and also ERτ. The realization principle
Cash-flow Betas
A number of papers have attempted to calculate so-called “cash-flow betas”. See Cohen, Polk,
and Vuolteenaho (2009), Campbell, Polk, and Vuolteenaho (2010), and Nekrasov and Shroff
(2009), for example. The labelling is confusing because these “fundamental betas” are actually
estimated slope coefficients from regressions of firm return on equity (ROE) on market-wide
16
This point complements the criticism of Hughes, Liu, and Liu (2009) that, with time-varying expected returns, the
internal rate of return is not the expected return.
23
ROE, not cash flows. The estimation is an admirable attempt to come to grips with the
However, there are accounting issues that frustrate the endeavor. In the inter-temporal
Merton (1973) asset pricing model, investment opportunities are linked to the state of the
economy.17 Under conservative accounting, earnings in the numerator of ROE are reduced with
growth in risky investment. If firms increase that investment in good times when market-wide
ROE is up, they will reduce the firm ROE, inducing a negative correlation between ROE and
market-wide ROE (and thus will appear to have lower rather than higher risk). Similarly, firms
may reduce investment in bad times, increasing ROE when market-wide ROE is down.
Conservative accounting, with its generation of risky expected growth, signals higher risk, but
induces a lower correlation between ROE and market-wide ROE. There is also the issue of
estimating one covariance over periods where discount rates may vary and the composition of
deferred and realized earnings differs from period to period to indicate those changing discount
rates. With reference to P3, cash-flow beta estimates are appropriate with constant premiums
Earnings
over time (no growth). In that case ERτ = , all τ.18
P 1
A string of papers embrace the Voulteenaho (2002) model to decompose stock returns into
components that are attributed to expected returns, cash-flow news, and expected-return news
17
Also, under Cochrane (1991) Q-theory, firms invest in good states when discount rates are low.
18
Equation (3) Earnings and is covariance with the market earnings yield, rather than ROE, as the way to
P 1
estimate “cash flow betas”.
24
and to connect accounting numbers to each component. The model is implemented in a vector
autoregressive (VAR) scheme to estimate the linear dependencies in the time series evolution of
indicator variables and returns and, in turn, to identify the three return components from
residuals from the modeling. In Lyle, Callen, and Elliott (2013) and Lyle and Wang (2015), the
model has also been applied to estimate the expected return from accounting data as an
alternative to ICC calculations, and with success in predicting returns out of sample. Unlike the
analysis in this paper, the modeling has the appealing feature of explicitly connecting accounting
numbers to the expected return and its variation. The Callen (2015) paper in this issue lays out
the scheme and supplies references to papers that employ it. Easton and Monahan (2005 and
Like equation (3), the clean-surplus relation is evoked to state the Voulteenaho tautology,
tying ROE and book-to-price to the expected return. However, an additional assumption is
autoregressive parameter to equal the expected (stock) return, ERτ in the long run. See Lyle and
Wang (2015) and Lyle, Callen, and Elliott (2013), for example. Chattopadyhay, Lyle, and Wang
(2015) allow for the expectation Pτ - Bτ to be non-zero but constant in the long run. However,
they maintain the autoregressive assumption such that growth in book value and market value
converge linearly to zero over time and ROE is anchored on the long-run expected return.
Modelling the evolution of log premiums is curious for, unlike Pτ – Bτ, log premiums are
affected by dividends, so P1 (and M&M) are violated.19 But, further, P2 demonstrates that the
19
This is more than just a passing comment. Modeling that violates a foundational principle of modern finance is
called into question unless it is justified by a relaxation of one of the assumptions in M&M.
25
evolution of the premium, Pτ – Bτ, is dictated by the accounting for earnings, and the
autoregressive assumption for the evolution of this premium imbeds a specific accounting. If Pτ –
might be modified such that Pτ - Bτ > 0 in the long run, but the path to the long-run is critical. P3
shows that expected earnings growth implies an expansion of premiums: Pτ − Bτ – (Pτ-1 − Bτ-1) >
0. So, for the typical case of Pt – Bt > 0, an autoregressive assumption where the premium
declines (linearly) over all τ, does not admit earnings growth that implies an increase in
premiums, nor does it accommodate the conservative accounting of P7 that yields that growth, so
pervasive in GAAP and IFRS. In short, the modeling does not admit a path-dependent evolution
The Ohlson (1995) paper with unbiased accounting was supplemented with the Feltham
and Ohlson (1995) paper with “biased accounting” under which Pτ – Bτ > 0 in expectation, all τ,
and the (conservative) accounting involved can yield expected growth (and, correspondingly, an
expansion of price premiums over book value). See also Zhang (2000). Under that accounting,
ROE does not correspond to the expected return in expectation. The growth (and increasing
premium) generated by conservative accounting reduces earnings in the numerator of ROE such
that ROE increases (to a level well in excess of the expected return) as the firm matures with
subsequent realization of the deferred earnings (and then only if the risk pays off). Consider
Microsoft, Apple, Google, and Infosys, mature firms with high ROE (and, more so, RNOA),
compared to a new firm, Twitter with a low ROE due to expensing investments but similarly a
low book-to market. The anchoring of expected ROE to the expected return is justified as driven
by “the forces of competition”, but ROE is an accounting measure driven by the realization
principle and conservative accounting. There is nothing in that accounting that anchors ROE to
26
the expected return in expectation. To the contrary: Rather than a high ROE indicating higher
risk and expected return, with both declining over time, the accounting indicates that a lower
ROE affected by conservative accounting, indicates a higher risk, with risk and the expected
Penman and Zhang (2015) elaborate and present supporting evidence based on an
analysis of the actual accounting rather than an assumed parameter for the dynamics. Based on
the realization principle, Penman and Yehuda (2015) extract measures of discount-rate news
directly from financial statements that look quite different from those estimated via the
Vuolteenaho model. The measures satisfy a set of validation tests; in contrast, the discount-rate
news and cash-flow news component of returns estimated with the autoregressive scheme fail
On a more general level, both theory and empirical papers often assume a “process” for
the evolution of earnings―an AR(1) process is common. Papers on the time-series properties of
earnings, earnings persistence, as well as those that connect accounting numbers to prices come
to mind. But an assumed process implies an assumption about accounting principles for
recognizing earnings over time, and that implied assumption may not be appropriate if the model
One might well ask, given the critique here, why estimates of the expected return from
the Voulteenaho model predict actual returns out of sample. That raises another issue.
In the Vuolteenaho model, ROE surfaces as an indicator of expected returns, with a higher ROE
indicating higher returns, ceteris paribus. More generally, ROE and similar measures of
27
profitability have been shown to be positively related to returns, in Novy-Marx (2012) and Ball,
Linnainmaa, and Nikolaev (2015), for example. The explanation offered rests on the standard
risk return tradeoff: Higher risk requires higher returns, so the positive association between ROE
and returns is because higher ROE is the reward for taking on risk. The applications of the
Vuolteenaho model formalize this intuition by anchoring ROE to the expected return. Apparently
in response to these observations, Fama and French (2015) have developed a “five-factor model”
condition, so the positive relationship between ROE and returns is conditional on B/P. But, E/P =
E/B × B/P = ROE × B/P, so adding ROE to a predictive regression that also includes B/P
recovers E/P, and E/P is the first term that connects accounting numbers to the expected return in
equation (3). Indeed, in the no-growth case (with no change in premiums), ERτ is equal to the
forward earnings yield, so one would expect ROE and B/P to predict returns (jointly) in this case
if current ROE is a good indicator of forward ROE (which it is). But this is not because ROE is
an indicator of risk and return but because ROE, in combination with B/P, yields E/P that
However, the no-growth case is not typically for equities so the specification is not
complete without an indicator of growth that connects to risk. Equation (3) indicates that the
appropriate specification is to include E/P and then add variables that indicate risky expected
earnings growth. B/P is identified as such a variable, in Penman, Reggiani, Richardson, and Tuna
(2015). If ROE were positively related to expected returns, it would have to be that, conditional
on E/P, ROE also indicates risky growth. However, under the accounting principles in P7,
growth is induced with lower current earnings due to earnings deferrals and lower earnings imply
28
lower ROE (via the numerator). Thus a lower ROE, rather than a higher ROE, indicates risk and
a higher expected return if the risk indicted by the accounting is priced risk. The tests in Penman
and Zhang (2015) provide support: Unconditionally, there is no relation between ROE and
returns but, conditional on E/P, ROE robustly predicts returns negatively, with the relationship
considerably stronger for ROE that are affected by conservative accounting. Further, the
(deferred) earnings predicted by ROE are at higher risk of not being realized and are particularly
Fama and French (2006) connect expected returns to accounting numbers via the following
equation, derived by applying the clean-surplus relation to substitute for dividends in the
Pt
E ( Earnings ( B B 1 ) /(1 r ) t
t 1
,
Bt Bt
E (Earnings )
t 1
where r is the expected return, a constant. They refer to the term, , as
Bt
B B 1
profitability (rate of return on book value), and the change in book value, , as growth
Bt
holding the expected book rate of return and expected investment growth constant, increasing in
the expected book rate of return holding B/P and expected investment growth constant, and
decreasing in expected investment growth holding B/P and expected book rate of return constant.
These comparative statics motivate the five-factor model in Fama and French (2015).
29
However, the comparative statics are inconsistent with how accounting works. One
cannot vary B/P while holding book rate of return (profitability) constant, because both reflect
the accounting for book value. High book rate of return means low B/P, ceteris paribus, by
construction of the accounting. As indicated immediately above, this is strictly so in the case of
no growth: r = E/P, by equation (3) and E/P = E/B ×B/P (where E/B is profitability). Thus, the
expected return is given by E/P rather than B/P and E/B as separate inputs. Indeed, B/P and E/B
can be any value (but the mirror image of each other because of the common effect of the
accounting for book value), yet still yield the same E/P. The same critique applies to the claim
that r is increasing in profitability holding B/P constant (as discussed above). On the connection
of “investment” to the expected return, there is a mislabeling that voids the interpretation:
Growth in book value in the formula is not investment. Rather, Bτ – Bτ-1 = Earningsτ + dτ. Thus,
as dividends are not relevant under P1, growth in book value is driven by earnings and the
profitability that involves those earnings. So, profitability cannot be held constant while looking
The Fama and French comparative statics appear to support the view, standard in asset
pricing, that expected returns are negatively related to growth―as in the standard “value” versus
“growth” spread where “growth” yields lower returns than “value”. In contrast, P7 suggests that
the expected return is positively related to growth. The Fama and French formulation does not
admit the period-to-period growth envisioned in P7. With the infinite summation over expected
future earnings in their model, the earnings expectation relative to current book value is for life-
long earnings, with no allocation to periods. In contrast, P7 focuses on the allocation of earnings
to the short-term versus the long-term that introduces expected earnings growth. The “value” and
“growth” labels do not stand up to scrutiny, as explained in Penman and Reggiani (2014).
30
A RE-THINK OFANOMALIES RESEARCH
Considerable empirical research connects accounting numbers to average stock returns, among
them earnings-to-price (E/P), book-to-price (B/P), accruals, investment, growth in assets, and a
number of financing variables. In asset pricing research, the tendency has been to attribute these
“anomalies” to risk and expected return, while accounting research tends to attribute them to
mispricing. In the absence of a validated, generally accepted asset pricing model, the attribution
will not be resolved, but the introduction of the realization principle as the driver behind
accounting numbers requires a re-think on the part of those who ascribe returns that are predicted
Consider three very popular “anomalies”: accruals, investment, and growth in net
operating assets (ΔNOA).20 Under P4, a change in premium is explained by ΔNOAτ, the
accounting for operating activities: If ND P ND , Δ(Pτ – Bτ) = Δ P NOA – ΔNOAτ. Accordingly,
expected earnings growth that induces the change in premium is determined by the accounting
for NOA.21 If that growth is connected to priced risk, then the ΔNOA anomaly is explained:
higher (lower) ΔNOA implies lower (higher) expected growth and correspondingly lower
(higher) risk and average returns, as observed. And, as ΔNOA = Investment + Other Accruals (a
fixed accounting relation), then the investment and accrual anomalies are similarly explained.
High accruals are associated with lower returns, but high accrued earnings come from realized
earnings (driven by the sales-account receivable accrual and expense matching), and realized
20
The original papers appear to be Sloan (1996), Titman, Wei, and Xie (2004), Fairfield, Whisenant, and Yohn
(2003), respectively.
21
P2 ascribes the premium to the measurement of earnings. As financing does not affect premiums, that
measurement pertains to operating income (OI). As OI = Free Cash Flow + ΔNOA by the clean-surplus relation for
operating activities, the measurement of earnings is determined by ΔNOA. (Correspondingly, it can be shown that
free cash flow does not affect premiums.)
31
earnings imply the resolution of risk and lower expected returns. Investment opportunities are at
risk, and that risk is priced under a Merton inter-temporal asset pricing model. Realization of
investment and booking it to the balance sheet is the resolution of that risk, so yields lower
deemed too risky, the investment is expensed immediately, yielding lower ΔNOA ceteris paribus
and expected earnings growth. If that growth is risky, the conservative accounting (that is a
response to risk) should be associated with higher average returns, as observed in Penman and
Zhang (2015).
In short, these anomalies are consistent with rational pricing if the realization principle
aligns with the evolution of risk and the expected return. The evidence in Penman and Zhu
As indicated in the introduction to the paper, practical valuation requires not only information
about the discount rate, the denominator issue, but also the specification of the accounting for the
numerator. The residual income model, based solely on the clean-surplus relation, is agnostic
about the numerator issue. However, the analysis that deals with the denominator issue also
directs the accounting for the numerator; a discount rate for any period, τ, must refer to the risk
The residual income models in equations (1a) and (2a) require (1) a division of the value
in Pt between Bt and expected earnings not yet recognized and (2) the allocation of those total
earnings not yet recognized to each future period, τ. Both issues concern the allocation of
32
earnings to periods―the present versus the future and inter-temporally (in expectation) in the
future.
Book value is not discounted in the model, so must involve numbers that do not have to
be discounted for risk. As Bt is accumulated earnings recognized to date net of accumulated net
dividends (that include net share isues), our analysis suggests that those earnings in book value
are realized earnings where the uncertainty about outcomes has been resolved. Assets are added
to the balance sheet only at cost (with no added value for the expected earnings that might
accrue). If, ex post, expected earnings imply carrying values higher than the value in those
earnings, the balance sheet is written down. Further, if the outcome to the investment is highly
uncertain, conservatism applies such that the asset is expensed and not put on the balance sheet.
This accounting, along with the recognition of operating liabilities, yields a balance sheet that
will only be affected if earnings are realized in the future, and a balance sheet that has low
probability (ex ante) of being written down. On point (2), the identification of expected earnings
to each τ, is based on the timing of their expected realization such that they are sequenced with
the τ indexed covariance term in model (1a) that discounts for the risk that earnings realization
With this accounting, the residual income model is now really an “accounting-based
valuation model”. It has the feature of accommodating risk. It has the feature of anchoring a
valuation on a book value that contains little risk apart from leverage transparently reported on
the balance sheet; there is nothing in the balance sheet that can come back and hit you later― no
“water in the balance sheet” as a fundamentalist would say. And it has the feature of identifying
where the risk of the business lies―the risk of earnings not being realized.
33
ACCOUNTING POLICY
If accounting is to serve the investor, these points have implications for accounting policy, a
topic in which Abacus has shown a keen interest over the years. There are also implications for
the current debate about fair value accounting versus historical cost accounting. Fair value
accounting is said to be more timely, for it projects the future cash flows, while historical cost
recognizes the information in price with a lag. However, in the comparison of the two accounting
measurements earlier, historical cost accounting conveys the risk in investing while fair value
accounting fails to do so. In fact, fair value accounting (even if ideally implemented) does not
project future cash flows but rather the (discounted) present value of expected cash flow. As
anyone carrying out practical valuations knows, the identification of the discount rate is
problematical, but the information about risk that might supply this aspect of fair value
accounting would be lost with fair value accounting. While other issues enter the debate, this is
one to consider.
This raises the prospect that “good accounting” is less timely accounting, in contrast to
the standard view that accounting is deficient for not being timely. Accounting that recognizes
the earnings expectations in price with a lag informs the investor if that delay it tied to risk and
its resolution. Research has typically seen accounting as providing information about expected
cash flows―cash-flow news―but the investor also requires discount-rate news. After all, equity
value is based, not only on expected cash flows but also the rate at which the cash flow are to be
discounted. Indeed, the objectives in the Conceptual Framework of the IASB ad FASB state that
accounting information should provide investors with information to assess “the amount, timing,
and uncertainty of future net cash flows.” Historical cost accounting with a realization principle
34
Earnings recognition under historical cost accounting is often presented as a matter of
recognizing revenue under the realization principle and then matching associated expenses
against the revenue to determine the earnings. That matching involves holding costs on the
balance sheet then taking them to the income statement under an amortization rule. Conservative
accounting that expenses investment costs immediately violates matching, bringing calls for the
“intangible assets” so expensed to be capitalized and amortized. However, the analysis here
suggests that the mismatching with conservative accounting conveys information about risk and
its resolution that would be lost with such capitalization of risky investments. This accounting
accords with the FASB’s Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts No. 2 (1975) which
immediate expensing of R&D under FASB Statement No. 2, the FASB focused on the
“uncertainty of future benefits.” In IAS 38, the IASB applied the criterion of “probable future
“matching principle” should not be embraced as matter of accounting principle if one wishes to
convey information about the amount and uncertainty of future cash flows.
In fact, mismatching is inevitable and the policy question in how to design the
mismatching. Matching is a principle that can only be implemented under certainty: If one
knows both the amount and timing of future revenues, one can match expenses with those
revenues perfectly, but even then only if the association of expenses with revenues can be
identified. Under uncertainty, the accountant is faced with a choice between capitalizing risky
22
The 2010 and 2015 IASB Discussion Papers on the Conceptual Framework dispense with the notion of
conservatism in favor of “neutrality” and define prudence as “caution when making judgments under conditions of
uncertainty”.
35
investment with an uncertain amortization rate to achieve the matching or expensing it
immediately. In both cases, the settling up against the accounting comes with the resolution of
post with write-offs of carrying values against revenues to which the impairment does not apply.
Implicitly, the write-offs recognize that, on an ex post basis, assets have been inappropriately
recognized on the balance sheet. With the expensing of risky investments, mismatching is
implemented immediately but with the risk now communicated ex ante. So the policy question is
whether the accounting should communicate risk ex ante or ex post. Prudent (conservative)
accounting would suggest that former. Fair value accounting is a third alternative, again with risk
communicated (too late) ex post as fair values are shocked when it is recognized that expected
DISCOUNTED EARNINGS
The task of identifying the economy-wide Ytτ variable and the covariance term in model (1a) is
challenging, as research in asset pricing has found. Enhanced valuation models add further
thus the recourse to the practical expedient of model (2a). However, calculating a risk premium
for the discount rate remains a challenge, one that has been pursued relentlessly in asset pricing.
But a tantalizing idea surfaces: What if accounting could be designed with an earnings
calculation, RE* = REτ – Cov(REτ, Ytτ)? That is, the discount for risk in the numerator of model
(1a) is built into the earnings measurement (such that expected earnings require no discount for
36
risk). The realization principle and conservative accounting appear to imbed this feature: In the
presence of risk, earnings are reduced―discounted for the risk―and deferred contingently to the
future. If the deferred earnings are realized with risk resolution, the recognized earnings indicate
lower risk. It is not clear whether an accounting could be calibrated that captures the risk but,
given the difficulty of the alternative―identifying Ytτ and covariances―the idea is worthy of
consideration.
In any case, the following conjecture is on the table: If GAAP or IFRS already discounts
earnings for risk, the covariance discount that is directed by model (1a) may be redundant, at
least to some extent. If we see a company with earnings prospects but with current earnings
depressed by conservative accounting, is that not a risky company? Amazon and Twitter look
like that sort of firm. They presumably have high earnings expectations but have low or negative
earnings and low ROE from the expensing of investments (as of the date of writing). That is
information that the expected earnings are at risk, they may not materialize. On the other hand,
Coca-Cola reports a high ROE in the order of 25 percent because the investment in promoting its
brand has paid off with realized earnings; it has a beta of 0.4.
REFERENCES
Ang, A., and J. Liu. 2004. How to Discount Cash Flows with Time-varying Expected Returns.
Journal of Finance 59, 2745-2783.
Ball, R., J. Linnainmaa, and V. Nikolaev. 2015. Deflating Profitability. Journal of Financial
Economics 117, 225-248.
Botosan, C., and M. Plumlee. 2005. Assessing Alternative Proxies for the Expected risk
Premium. The Accounting Review 80, 21-53.
Breeden, D., and R. Litzenberger. 1978. Prices of State-contingent Claims Implicit in Option
Prices. Journal of Business 51, 621-651.
37
Campbell, J., C. Polk, and T. Vuolteenaho. 2010. Growth or Glamour? Fundamentals and
Systematic Risk in Stock Returns. Review of Financial Studies 23, 305-344.
Chattopadyhay, A., M. Lyle, and C. Wang. 2015. Accounting Data, Market Values, and the
Cross Section of Expected Returns Worldwide. Unpublished paper, Harvard University and
Northwestern University.
Cochrane, J. 1991. Production-based Asset Pricing and the Link Between Stock Returns and
Economic Fluctuations. Journal of Finance 46, 209-237
Cochrane. J. 2011. Presidential Address: Discount Rates. Journal of Finance 66, 1047-1108.
Christensen, P., and G. Feltham. 2009. Equity valuation. Foundations and Trends in Accounting
4, 1-112.
Cohen, R., C. Polk, and T. Vuolteenaho. 2009. The Price is (Almost) Right. Journal of Finance
64, 2739-2782.
Demirakos, E., N. Strong, and M. Walker. 2004. What Valuation Models Do Analysts Use?
Accounting Horizons 18, 221-240.
Easton, P. 2007. Estimating the Cost of Capital Implied by Market Prices and Accounting
Data. Foundations and Trends in Accounting 2, 241-364.
Easton, P., T. Harris, and J. Ohlson. 1992. Aggregate Accounting Earnings Can Explain Most of
Security Returns: The Case of Long Event Windows. Journal of Accounting and Economics 15
(June-September), 119-142.
Easton, P., and S. Monahan. 2015. Review of Recent Research on Improving Earnings Forecasts
and Evaluating Accounting-based Estimates of the Expected Rate of Return on Equity Capital.
Abacus, this issue.
Easton. P., G. Taylor, P. Shroff, and T. Sougiannis. 2002. Using Forecasts of Earnings to
Simultaneously Estimate Growth and the Rate of Return on Equity Investment. Journal of
Accounting Research 40, 657-676.
Ellahie, A., M. Katz, and S. Richardson. 2014. Risky Value. Unpublished paper, London usiness
School and AQR Capital Management LLC.
Fama, E., and K. French. 1992. The Cross-section of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of
Finance 47, 427-465.
Fama, E., and K. French. 1993. Common Risk Factors in the Returns of Stocks and Bonds.
Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56.
38
Fama, E., and K. French. 2006. Profitability, Investment and Average Returns. Journal of
Financial Economics 82, 491-518.
Fama, E., and K. French. 2015. A Five-Factor Asset Pricing Model. Journal of Financial
Economics 116, 1-22.
Fairfield, P., J. Whisenant, and T. Yohn. 2003. Accrued Earnings and Growth: Implications for
Future Profitability and Market Mispricing. The Accounting Review 78, 353-371.
Feltham, G., and J. Ohlson. 1995. Valuation and Clean Surplus Accounting for Operating and
Financial Activities. Contemporary Accounting Research 12, 689-731.
Feltham, G., and J. Ohlson. 1999. Residual Income Valuation with Risk and Stochastic Interest
Rates. The Accounting Review 74, 165-183.
Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB). 1975. Statement of Concepts No.2: Qualitative
Characteristics of Accounting Information. Stamford, CT: FASB.
Gebhardt, W., C. Lee, and B. Swaminathan, 2001. Toward an Implied Cost of Capital.
Journal of Accounting Research 39, 135-176.
Gode, D., and P. Mohanram, 2003. Inferring the Cost of Capital Using the Ohlson-Juettner
Model. Review of Accounting Studies 8, 399-431.
Guay, W., S. Kothari, and S. Shu. 2011. Properties of Implied Cost of Capital Using Analysts’
Forecasts. Australian Journal of Management 36, 125-149.
Hand, J., J. Coyne, J. Green, and X. Zhang. 2015. The Dual Use of Residual Income and
Discounted Cash Flow Valuation Methods by U.S. Sell-side Equity Analysts. Unpublished
paper, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill.
Hou, K., A. M. van Dijk, and Y. Zhang. 2012. The Implied Cost of Capital: A New Approach.
Journal of Accounting and Economics 53, 504-526.
Hughes, J., J. Liu, and J. Liu. 2009. On the Relation Between Expected Returns and Implied Cost
of Capital. Review of Accounting Studies 14, 246-259.
Lee, C., E. So, and C. Wang. 2014. Evaluating Firm-level Expected-Return Proxies. Working paper 15-
022, Harvard Business School.
Li, K., and P. Mohanram. 2014. Evaluating Cross-sectional Forecasting Models for Implied Cost
of Capital. Review of Accounting Studies 19, 1152-1185.
39
Lyle, M., J. Callen, and R. Elliott. 2013. Dynamic Risk, Accounting-Based Valuation and Firm
Fundamentals. Review of Accounting Studies 18, 899-929.
Lyle, M. and C. Wang. 2015. The Cross Section of Expected Holding Period Returns and their
Dynamics: A Present Value Approach. Journal of Financial Economics 116, 505-525.
Miller, M., and F. Modigilani. 1961. Dividend Policy, Growth and the Valuation of Shares.
Journal of Business 34, 411-433.
Modigliani F., and M. Miller. 1958. The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of
Investment. American Economic Review 48, 261-297.
Mohanram, P., and D. Gode. 2013. Removing Predictable Analyst Forecast Errors to Improve
Implied Cost of Capital Estimates. Review of Accounting Studies 18, 443-478.
Nekrasov, A., and M. Ogneva. 2011. Using Earnings Forecasts to Simultaneously Estimate Firm-
Specific Cost of Equity and Long-term Growth. Review of Accounting Studies 16, 414-457.
Nekrasov, A., and P. Shroff. 2009. Fundamentals-based Risk Management in Valuation. The
Accounting Review 84, 1983-2011.
Novy-Marx, R. 2012. The other side of value: The Gross Profitability Premium. Journal of
Financial Economics 108, 1-28.
Ohlson, J. 1995. Earnings, Book Values, and Dividends in Equity Valuation. Contemporary
Accounting Research 12, 661-687.
Ohlson, J. 2008. Risk, Growth, and Permanent Earnings. Unpublished paper, New York
University Stern School of Business.
Ohlson, J., and B. Juettner-Nauroth. 2005. Expected EPS and EPS Growth as Determinants of
Value. Review of Accounting Studies 10, 349-365.
Penman, S. 1997. A Synthesis of Equity Valuation Techniques and the Terminal Valuation
Calculation for the Dividend Discount Model. Review of Accounting Studies 2, 303-323.
Penman, S. 2013. Financial Statement Analysis and Security Valuation, 5th ed. New York: The
McGraw-Hill Companies.
Penman, S., and F. Reggiani. 2014. The value Trap: Value buys risky growth. Unpublished
paper, Columbia University and Bocconi University.
40
Penman, S., F. Reggiani, S. Richardson, and İ Tuna. 2015. An Accounting-based Characteristic
Model for Asset Pricing. Unpublished paper, Columbia University, Bocconi Univeraity, and
London Business School.
Penman, S., and N. Yehuda. 2015. A Matter of Principle: Accounting Reports Convey both
Cash-Flow News and Discount Rate News. Unpublished paper, Columbia University and
University of Texas at Dallas.
Penman, S., and X. Zhang. 2015. Connecting Book Rate of Return to Risk and Return: The
Information Conveyed by Conservative Accounting. Unpublished paper, Columbia University
and University of California, Berkeley.
Penman, S., and J. Zhu. 2014. Accounting Anomalies, Risk and Return. The Accounting Review
89, 1835-1866.
Pinto, J., T. Robinson, and J. Stowe. 2015. Equity Valuation: A Survey of Professional Practice.
Unpublished paper, CFA Institute, Charlottesville VA.
Rubinstein, M. 1976. The Valuation of Uncertain Income Streams and the Pricing of Options.
The Bell Journal of Economics 7, 407-425.
Shroff, P. 1995. Determinants of the Returns-earnings Correlation. Contemporary Accounting
Research 12 (Fall), 41-55.
Sloan, R. 1996. Do Stock Prices Fully Reflect Information in Accruals and Cash Flows about
Future Earnings? The Accounting Review 71, 289-315.
Titman, S., K. Wei, and F. Xie. 2004. Capital Investment and Stock Returns. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 39, 677-700.
Vuolteenaho, T. 2002. What Drives Firm Level Stock Returns? Journal of Finance 57, 233–64.
Wang, C. 2013. Measurement Errors of Expected Return Proxies and the Implied Cost of
Capital. Unpublished paper, Harvard University.
Zhang, X. 2000. Conservative Accounting and Equity Valuation. Journal of Accounting and
Economics 29, 125-149.
41