An Analytical Framework For The Cross-Country Comparison of Higher Education Governance

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 19

High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

DOI 10.1007/s10734-011-9412-4

An analytical framework for the cross-country


comparison of higher education governance

Michael Dobbins • Christoph Knill • Eva Maria Vögtle

Published online: 1 February 2011


Ó Springer Science+Business Media B.V. 2011

Abstract In this article we provide an integrated framework for the analysis of higher
education governance which allows us to more systematically trace the changes that
European higher education systems are currently undergoing. We argue that, despite highly
insightful previous analyses, there is a need for more specific empirically observable
indicators of policy change and inertia. We therefore propose a systematic classification of
empirical indicators of higher education governance. To do so, we look at three historically
entrenched and still highly relevant European models of higher education—academic self-
governance, the state-centered model and the market-oriented model. Based on these
broader overarching models which reflect the tensions between the state, market and
academia, we develop three ideal-types that take internal university governance as well as
the role of the state and external stakeholders into account. Against this background, we
derive empirical indicators with regard to the institutional balance of power, financial
governance, personnel autonomy and substantive matters. Our analytical contribution shall
enable scholars, and in particular political and social scientists, to trace ongoing patterns of
change and convergence as well as persistence and inertia in higher education governance
arrangements.

Keywords Higher education governance  Marketization  Analytical framework 


Indicators

Introduction

Around the globe higher education (HE) is currently subject to profound changes. The
emergence of the knowledge society (Delanty 2001; Arthur 2006; Gornitzka et al. 2007),
demographic developments, sluggish economic growth and increased competitive pres-
sures from globalization have stimulated an array of reforms to contemporary HE systems.
In view of convergence-promoting processes such as the Bologna Process and the spread of

M. Dobbins (&)  C. Knill  E. M. Vögtle


Department of Politics and Management, University of Konstanz, Konstanz, Germany
e-mail: [email protected]

123
666 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

New Public Management, domestic HE institutions are increasingly subject to competing


visions of how university systems and institutions of higher education should be governed
(see Vaira 2004; Olsen 2007; Krücken et al. 2007). At the same time, individual national
HE systems are still also anchored in country-specific regulatory and coordinative regimes,
which to a great extent reflect national historical and institutional developments (see Neave
2003).
Previous research has shown that, amid demands for universities to ‘‘do more with
less’’, national education policy makers are designing and embracing new models of
governance and frequently transforming individual HE institutions, the role of the state, as
well as the socio-economic role and function of HE (see Gornitzka and Maassen 2000).
Many of the ongoing reforms in Europe, in particular, have been subsumed under the
banner of ‘‘marketization’’, ranging from the partial retreat of the state as a financier, to the
allocation of strategic authority to university management, and to an increasing focus on
the economic utility of teaching and research (see Meek 2000; Phillip 2000; Neave 2003).
In Europe and beyond, the Bologna Process has also played a key role in stoking
national reforms of HE and there are strong reasons to believe that Bologna is likely to
foster changes in national governance structures. Various analyses have shown that the
Bologna Process has enabled domestic actors to shore up support for a range of only
loosely related HE agendas, e.g. tuition, privatization (see Dobbins and Knill 2009; Bieber
2010; Niemann 2010). At the same time, the European Commission has put forward a clear
vision for the governance of European universities, which includes, among other things, a
diversification of funding sources, an intensification of ties between universities and
industries and a closer match between the supply of qualifications and labour market
demands (see European Commission 2003, 2006). As a result of transnational pressures
and domestic exigencies, national systems of HE governance are—to a greater or lesser
degree—being reshaped, transformed, modernized and in many cases ‘‘marketized’’. These
changes have reshaped the role of the state, heralded new paradigms for university man-
agement, and contributed to new forms of university-industrial relations.
In the following we address the current state-of-the-art on the analysis of higher edu-
cation governance by examining the literature on both internal university governance as
well as the state’s involvement in higher education. We then argue that, despite much
progress in the past decade, there still is a need for more specific comparative empirical
indicators to grasp the complexity and diversity of governance arrangements. Against this
background, we propose a systematic classification of governance indicators based on three
historically entrenched models of higher education in Europe. We contend that such
indicators will enable scholars to more systematically trace and compare current system-
and university-level developments, in particular in research-oriented universities in
Europe.1

Higher education governance—the state of the art

In recent years, scholars have aimed to grasp the phenomenon of higher education gov-
ernance and changes within it. One frequent starting point to address the institutional
origins and balance of power in modern higher education systems is Clark’s triangle
(1983), which distinguishes between a state-control model, a Humboldtian model of

1
With regard to governance regimes in polytechnic, non-research higher education, see Kyvik (2009).

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 667

academic self-rule and an Anglo-American market-oriented model (see also Neave 2003).
Drawing on Clark’s work, other authors have more recently provided highly instructive
classifications of various types of HE governance (see van Vught 1995; Braun 2001;
Niklasson 1996; McDaniel 1996), while other scholars have developed typologies for
specific dimensions (see e.g. Jongbloed 2003 for financial governance). For example, Van
Vught (1989) and Goedegebuure et al. (1993) distinguish between ‘‘state control’’ models
and ‘‘state supervising’’ models, the latter of which saw the role of the state not as guardian
and designer of higher education systems, rather as that of a ‘‘referee’’, ‘‘mediator’’, and
‘‘activator’’ of widely autonomous systems. Other authors such as Neave (1998a, b) and De
Boer et al. (2007) have also demonstrated that a shift in the form of state influence from ex
ante to ex post control has taken place, the latter of which involves a stronger focus on
institutional output and comparative performance indicators (see Neave 1998a, b).
Other scholars have addressed the diversity of governance patterns emerging in the
course of the HE reforms in Europe in the last 15–20 years. Sporn (1999), for example,
described the concept of shared governance, which focuses on negotiations, the role of
external stakeholders and the participation and integration of all groups and objectives
relevant to higher education. Braun (2001) discussed the model of corporate governance,
with an emphasis on the entrepreneurial character of HE institutions and their strategic
planning efforts. Here, universities are regarded as highly proactive and reactive organi-
zations with strong academic participation in decision-making bodies. Braun distinguished
the corporation model from a different type of university governance defined as the
‘‘entrepreneurial model’’ (see also Clark 1998), which focuses on the links between uni-
versities, markets and society and emphasizes universities’ efforts to acquire industrial
capital through applied research (ibid. 2001: 256). Braun and Merrien (1999) and Braun
(2001) also assert that New Managerialism has emerged as a key principle for steering the
HE systems of many OECD countries. Among other things, New Managerialism entails
policies based on decentralization, the definition of quantitative and qualitative aims,
institutional autonomy, cooperation with the private sector, while incorporating principles
such as institutional evaluation, continuous learning and performance contracts (ibid. 1999;
2001).2
Such analyses have greatly enhanced our understanding of current phenomena at higher
education institutions and the shift towards more flexible, competitive and managerial
structures. However, we believe that the current discussion on governance patterns could
also greatly benefit from the development of more systematic empirical indicators that
enable us to measure the degree and direction of change, both in individual countries as
well as across different countries. For example, social scientists may be interested in the
degree to which a given country has departed from its historical state-centered model
towards the entrepreneurial or new public management model or to what extent the HE
systems of several countries have become ‘‘marketized’’. However, a critical prerequisite
for doing so—a broad scheme of empirically observable indicators for various sub-
dimensions of HE governance and policy change within them—is still lacking.
In recent years though, various studies have made significant contributions towards
achieving this objective. For example, the recent volume University Governance: Western
European Comparative Perspectives (Paradeise et al. 2009b) renders particularly
instructive comparative accounts of the current changes in HE governance in Europe, while
deriving a series of indicators to reflect them. Similarly to Clark, the authors distinguish

2
See also Gornitzka and Maasen (2000), who distinguish between a sovereign state steering model, an
institutional steering model, a corporate-pluralist steering model and a supermarket steering model.

123
668 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

between the Napoleonic HE models of France and southern Europe, which are marked by
top-town ministerial law making, and the northern European Humboldtian tradition of a
self-governing community of scholars. The individual country reports highlight shifts at
the national level away from these historical models towards more managerial, competi-
tion-oriented approaches in HE governance. This is reflected by indicators such as
increasing university autonomy amid greater accountability towards stakeholders, a trend
towards strategic planning and university missions, diversification of funding sources,
greater personnel autonomy, lump-sum budgeting and ex post quality audits (Paradeise
et al. 2009a, b). However, the authors point out that each national system bears it own
nuances due to historical peculiarities and path dependencies, often leading to contradic-
tory development patterns and hybrid forms of governance.
In their analysis of the organizational transformation of Dutch universities, De Boer
et al. (2007) also present very specific indicators to grasp the trend towards state steering at
a distance and, in particular, the emergence of universities as corporate actors. The authors
contend that the governance reforms of the past 20 years have led to the construction of
new forms of identity, hierarchy and rationality in universities. The proposed indicators of
this transformation span from financial discretion and setting own employment conditions
(constructing identity), to an authoritative center directing action, managers as chief
executives (constructing hierarchy), on to management by objectives, performance
agreements and monitoring (constructing rationality).
Ferlie et al. (2009) also incorporate the role of the state into their three narratives of
public sector reforming, for which they identify distinct ‘‘signs and systems’’ applicable to
HE systems. For example, according to the network governance narrative, higher education
systems are understood as multi-level self-steering and self-organizing networks between
societal and academic actors, which facilitate joint problem solving and the diffusion of
best practice. Together with regional and local actors, the state thereby plays an indirect
shaping role and ensures that HE institutions operate in accordance with the public interest.
The so-called Neo-Weberian narrative is characterized by the reassertion of Weberian
principles such as administrative law and due process as well as professionalized public
service, which now focuses on meeting citizens’ needs by means of outward-oriented
service planning and quality assurance. In recent years, the state has emerged as a vehicle
of modernization through the legal framework, for example facilitating a shift from ex ante
to ex post control and a strong result orientation (2008: 339). According to the authors, the
new public management narrative is characterized by market-based features such as
competition for students and research funding, for which the state develops a HE market.
Other indicators are student fees, performance-based funding, as well as entrepreneurial
operating rectorates in highly autonomous HE institutions.
In their recent exploratory study, Estermann and Nokkala (2009) deal with one very
crucial aspect of governance, university autonomy, and make the very significant contri-
bution of breaking autonomy down into its component parts (see also Berdahl 1990). Based
on empirical data from 33 countries, they outline a trend towards greater autonomy in the
organizational structures of universities, which covers aspects such as governing bodies,
executive leadership and internal administration, as well as staffing matters, which involves
the recruitment and appointment of staff, setting salary levels, and civil servant status of
academics. This greater autonomy also applies to academic matters, which involves uni-
versities’ ability to define their own institutional strategies and academic profiles and freely
regulate student admissions. The authors also map out various facets of financial autonomy
and determine a trend towards competition-oriented funding policies such as student fees,
block-grant funding, and third-party funding.

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 669

In the present analysis we aim to pull together and further systematize the previous
work on HE governance and university autonomy. In doing so, we develop three ideal-type
models which encompass not only internal university governance, but also the role of the
state and other stakeholders. On the one hand, we wish to move the debate on higher
education governance forward by developing a more systematic set of indicators to
measure the degree and direction of policy change. On the other hand, we believe that
systematic indicators of higher education governance must not only render current trends
(e.g. marketization, universities as corporate actors), but also reflect historical foundations
of (European) universities, and in particular Humboldtian and Napoleonic traditions (see
Clark 1983; Neave 2003). Hence, indicators of HE governance should enable us to better
contrast the status quo ante with present trends and thus identify historically rooted path
dependencies amid recent developments. Our objective is therefore not to refute previously
developed indicators of various forms of governance (see above), rather to further sys-
tematize them and bring them in line with the historical visions of the university in which
European HE systems are still rooted.
To do so, we deliberately seek to build on the recent study by Olsen (2007), who
himself draws on earlier work of Clark (1983) and Neave (2003) to describe different
historical visions on which European HE systems are based. Following Olsen (2007), we
develop three overarching models defined as ‘‘the market-oriented model’’, the ‘‘state
centered-model’’ and the ‘‘academic self-rule model’’. Fully aware of the static nature of
comparative indicators and the peculiarities of national systems, we nevertheless believe
that our broader models and the indicators will be a useful tool for future studies on
changing HE systems. Moreover, they provide an added value for measuring and com-
paring the depth of change and can also be streamlined into more nuanced models of
governance presented above (Sporn 1999; Braun 2001; de Boer et al. 2007).

Proposed ideal-type models

To arrive at an encompassing picture of policy developments over time, we deliberately lay


down a broad and multifaceted definition of contemporary HE governance, which com-
prises patterns of control, coordination and the allocation of autonomy between three
levels—the state, professoriate, and university management—while preserving Clark’s
tripartite distinction between the state, academia and the market, which in turn reflects the
Humboldtian, Napoleonic and British traditions of HE prevalent in Europe. Thus we seek
to integrate into our analytical framework (1) the organizational structure of universities
including personnel and funding issues (2) the state’s regulatory approach, and (3) relations
between universities, external stakeholders and society (McDaniel 1996). Of crucial
importance to our classification is the allocation of autonomy, which accounts for
how order in the academic sphere is attained, i.e. through centralized management,
all-embracing control or through the differentiation of spheres of influence vested with
self-regulatory powers. Similarly to Estermann and Nokkala (2009) and Berdahl (1990),
we break down the notion of autonomy into its major component parts. We restructure
what Berdahl (1990) defined as procedural autonomy, i.e. the means and resources which
universities have to put their goals and programs into practice, into a broader category
which we label ‘the institutional balance of power of the university system’, as well as two
further sub-dimensions of this which we define as ‘personnel autonomy’ and ‘financial
governance’. The category ‘institutional balance of power’ pertains to general state-
university-society relations, decision-making structures, quality control arrangements as

123
670 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

well as the management approach. ‘Financial governance’ addresses the procurement,


allocation and management of funds. For example, does university management have the
autonomy to implement performance-based management and funding and what personnel
matters does the state influence? ‘Personnel autonomy’ pertains to the authority of insti-
tutions to freely set conditions for staff, e.g. appointments, salaries, and even work hours,
and the role and status of rectors and/or university leadership. We also incorporate matters
of substantive autonomy (Berdahl 1990), which comprises the overall possibilities for
academic institutions to regulate programs without state intervention (see van Wageningen
2003). The concept addresses whether decision-making authority over goals, programs, the
research profile and curriculum is delegated to the level of the universities and/or faculties.
Do universities have the means to set their own content of curricula and standards for
granting academic degrees? Substantive autonomy thus comprises the freedom to review
and eliminate academic programs and control institutional and research activities.

The state-centered model

Drawing on Clark’s (1983) and Olsen’s classifications (2007),3 this model conceives
universities as state-operated institutions. The state directly coordinates all or most aspects
of HE, such as admission requirements, curricula, exams, nomination of academic per-
sonnel, etc. Universities are subject to the formal administrative control of the state and
granted relatively little autonomy. The state plays the role of a ‘‘guardian’’ (see Neave
1996, 2004) and actively influences internal matters, most notably quality assurance,
efficiency and university-business relations (see also Neave and van Vught 1991: xi–xxii).
This notion has profoundly shaped HE in France (Kaiser 2007), Spain, Portugal, and the
Soviet Union and its satellites, albeit within the bounds of the Marxist-Leninist doctrine
(see Dobbins 2011).
According to Olsen (2007), the constitutive logic of a state-centred HE system is the
implementation of pre-determined national objectives. Universities are understood as
rational instruments employed to meet national priorities. Research and education are core
national production factors contributing to industrial and technological competitiveness.
As a consequence, ties between universities and industry and commerce should be med-
iated or filtered though national government (see Neave 2003: 145), while external
stakeholders provide for additional control over academic activities.
The state generally exercises strong oversight over study content, while finances are
allocated by the state in itemized fashion. The strong leverage of the state/ministry is
reflected in the high degree of hierarchy and the fact that administrative staff is often
appointed, not elected. Uniform legislation in combination with nationally standardized
procedures—e.g. conditions of access and employment, pay scales—bonds universities to
the central government. Although not entirely buffered from external forces, HE systems
tend to change as a result of changing government coalitions. Despite trends away from the
state-centered model, very strong traces of its legacy can be identified in France (see Kaiser

3
Olsen (2007) also puts forward a notion of the university as representative democracy, which falls back on
the work of Habermas (1967) and de Boer et al. (1999). Here the university is linked to enhancing
democracy at large in society and bears components of direct democracy and student sovereignty. However,
elements of student sovereignty, egalitarianism, and democracy can also be found in other models in various
ways. Moreover, the concept of the university as a direct democracy has proven to impact the reform efforts
after 1968 and influence other governance systems without fully establishing itself as a broadly practiced
model.

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 671

2007), Turkey (Mizikaci 2006) and post-communist Romania (see Dobbins and Knill
2009) and Russia (see Meister 2007).

University as a self-governing community of scholars (the Humboldt model)

Founded upon Humboldt’s principle of Lern- und Lehrfreiheit (freedom of teaching and
learning), this model has shaped and still shapes HE in Germany,Austria and much of pre-
and post-communist central Europe (Scott 2002: 140–141; Nybom 2003; Dobbins and
Knill 2009). Its guiding organizational principle is described by some as ‘academic self-
governance’ and by more skeptical observers as ‘academic oligarchy’, implying thus weak
university management, strong self-regulation, and collegial control by the professoriate, in
particular as regards study and research profiles (see de Boer and Goedegebuure 2003:
215). In its ideal form, the model is based on a state-university partnership, governed by
principles of corporatism and collective agreement. On the one hand, academic ‘‘oligar-
chy’’ is synonymous with the self-regulation of academic affairs by the academic and
scientific community via academic senates at the institutional level in concert with external
self-governing bodies such as the German or Austrian Hochschulrektorenkonferenz and
Wissenschaftsrat (Clark 1983: 140). On the other hand, the state remains a potent actor
thanks to diverse planning and financial laws limiting the scope of self-governance. Thus,
the supreme degree of autonomy called for by Humboldt is now constricted by universi-
ties’ political affiliation with and financial dependency on the state, which creates a
necessity for collective agreement. However, the protection of academic freedom and
funding by the state enables universities to establish normative and constitutive principles
and rules of their own without being subject to external design (Olsen 2007).
Compared with state-authority models, this understanding of HE is marked by the lack
of institutional coordination between university strategies and industrial and/or political
goals. In other words, there is a lack of anything resembling manpower plans, which would
streamline socio-economic needs into academic activities and student placement. Instead,
the purest and indeed utopian version of the Humboldt model is founded upon free
scholarly enquiry and the inseparable link between research and teaching. Hence, the self-
perception of the university is tantamount to the shared commitment to the search for truth
through intellectual freedom—regardless of the utility, applicability, economic benefit or
political convenience of scientific results (Olsen 2007).
Of paramount importance to the academic self-rule model is the chair system, in which
each professorial chair functions as a core organizational unit vested with a supreme degree
of autonomy (see Schimank 2002: 8). Once appointed, the occupants of professorial chairs
constitute bastions of authority at the micro-level, or as Clark put it ‘‘small monopolies in
thousand parts’’ (1983: 140). When several chairs act in concert or as a ‘‘federation’’ of
chairs (Sadlak 1995), they possess a formidable power to block initiatives of the gov-
ernment. On the one hand, the university still operates in the service of society and science
as a whole. On the other hand, universities and their specialized sub-systems, the pro-
fessorial chairs, are traditionally more in tune with the dynamics of their scientific disci-
plines than socio-economic pressures. Resulting from this, a system of decentralized
collegial organization emerges at the faculty and chair level, in which appointments are
made on a collegial basis and on the basis of scientific merit. Nevertheless, self-governance
takes place within state- defined constraints, as universities remain under the auspices of
the state (or in the German case Länder) and professors hold the status of civil servants.
However, the strong emphasis on scientific demands and detachment from socio-
economic needs is frequently described with catchwords such as the ‘‘Republic of Science’’

123
672 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

or ‘‘Ivory Towers’’ (Olsen 2007; Neave 2003), which are further marked by the frequent
lack of comprehensive performance-based criteria as regards, for example, the quality of
teaching, the selection of students, and pay scales. These circumstances still characterize,
to a large extent, contemporary German higher education, for example (see Schimank
2005; Niemann 2010).

The market-oriented model

Instead of Humboldt’s ideals of unfettered scholarly enquiry, academic self-governing


models have frequently become synonymous with the deterioration of teaching, mass
bureaucratization, and mistrust between the state, universities, and society. Market-
oriented models, by contrast, contend that universities function more effectively when
operating as economic enterprises within and for regional or global markets (see Marg-
inson and Considine 2000), while entrepreneurial tactics are regarded as legitimate orga-
nizational principles (see Clark 1998). Jongbloed (2003: 113), for instance, defines
marketization policies as ‘‘policies that are aimed at strengthening student choice and
liberalizing markets in order to increase quality and variety of services offered.’’ In this
framework, universities compete for students and financial resources. University man-
agement sees itself in the role of a producer and entrepreneur, which offers academic
services to students. Thus, the institutional leadership demonstrated by HE institutions is a
core feature. Subsequently, the ‘‘entrepreneurial’’ university and related notions of cor-
porate governance have come to dominate current discourse (Clark 1998; Felt 2003). Ideas
based on New Public Management and private enterprises (e.g. performance-based fund-
ing) enjoy a high status as governance mechanisms at the university level, while the forces
of competition are intended to enable rapid adaptation to new constraints and opportunities
(see Ferlie et al. 1996, 2009). This is reflected, for example, by the alleged capacity to add
and subtract fields of knowledge. Thus, unlike in Humboldt systems, information and
knowledge are not an end in themselves. Nor are they a public good. HE is instead viewed
as a commodity, investment, and strategic resource (see Olsen 2007).
Instead of shaping and designing the system, the state tends to promote competition,
while ensuring quality and transparency (Phillip 2000: 78; Ferlie et al. 2009). Accordingly,
competition among buyers (students) and sellers (HE institutions) is assumed to assure
greater discipline in institutional decisions regarding expenditures and the ‘education
product’, as it is believed to facilitate institutional adaptation and innovation. HE mark-
etization may include privatization, although this is not invariably the case.
At the same time, market-oriented systems may offer governments an array of policy
instruments to enhance competition such as regulations on subsidies and instruments
affecting pricing structure and enrolment (e.g. competitive admissions, price ceilings). The
American system, in particular, is known for taxation incentives for families who invest in
children’s education or for corporations who make donations to HE institutions. Hence,
government involvement entails regulation and incentives for competition and quality,
rather than directives, legislative decrees, or manpower-based planning (Olsen 2007;
Niklasson 1995). However, institutions remain financially dependent on external stake-
holders such as private and business donors as well as students, the ultimate beneficiaries
of HE. As a result, research and teaching are ‘‘sold’’ for competitive prices on the market
(Marginson and Considine 2000).
Along the same lines, universities are likely to be more susceptible to special interests as
they find themselves in a delicate position of dual accountability towards the state/public
sector and market demands. In other words, public authorities penetrate vertically into HE

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 673

systems to assert leverage over the structure of academic markets, while market forces
horizontally ‘‘inject’’ consumer demands into the system (see t’Veld et al. 1996: 32),
leading to increased conflict potential.

Empirically observable dimensions

Following these distinctions, we break down systems of university governance into


empirically observable dimensions. The classification of governance types is aimed at
integrating key insights and categorizations from the abovementioned studies, most
notably Clark (1983), Neave (1998a, 2003), Olsen (2007), Estermann and Nokkala (2009)
and Jongbloed (2003) for financial governance. However, it must be first emphasized that
all higher education systems mix elements of hierarchical state control, market competition
and academic self-rule (see Niklasson 1995). Therefore none of the ideal-types outlined
above is likely to be observed in its purest form. Nevertheless, they bear significant
tangible differences with respect to the degree and scope of autonomy granted to institu-
tions and the nature of governance.

Institutional balance of power of the university system

Our classification begins by addressing the institutional balance of power, which is based
to a great extent on the allocation of procedural autonomy (Berdahl 1990), relations to the
state and society as well as controlling functions (Table 1).
In view of the division of authority, it would be faulty to assume that the rejection of
state control automatically implies the unconditional acceptance of the principles of market
regulation. Patterns of mutual peer control among the community of scholars can com-
pensate for the lack of state authority over quality evaluation, for example. The predom-
inance of market principles also by no means implies the complete absence of the state, as
quasi-governmental accreditation or evaluation bodies generally have a stronger hand in
quality evaluation of teaching and research in market-based constellations (see Johnson
and Anderson 1998: 17; Neave 1998a, b; Dill 1997). Hence, the state can be regarded as a
stimulator of competition and quality in market-like systems (Dill 1997).
This is best reflected by the distinction between process control inherent to state-based
models, which concentrates on shaping or regulating the disciplinary profile, duration of
studies, accession conditions, and expended resources, and product control in market-
driven models which entails the development of a more sophisticated system of evaluation
and quality surveillance (see Neave and van Vught 1991: 251–252). And while peer review
rests on the notion that only academic peers are qualified to judge the quality of perfor-
mance and most notably research and publication output (de Boer and Goedegebuure 2003:
216), increased ‘product’ or quality controlling mechanisms imply greater involvement of
(state or quasi-governmental) evaluation bodies in monitoring teaching and research output
as well as student satisfaction.
When examining ties to business and industry, clearly different perceptions are also
evident. In market-based models, business and commerce directly penetrate into HE,
frequently manifested by the existence of technology centers, knowledge networks with
industry/commerce, and other multi-faceted forms of joint cooperation generally coordi-
nated by university management. In state-centered models, such forms of regional and
economic cooperation also exist, but tend to be designed, promoted or coordinated by the
state (Neave 2003: 145). Such is the case, for example, with Finland and the state’s efforts

123
674 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

Table 1 The institutional balance of power of the university system


State-centered Market-oriented model Academic self-governance
model

Institutional structures of the university


Dominant State University management Community of scholars/professional
decision-making chairs
actors
Organizational State agency Enterprise (Corporatist) state-university
structure partnership
Dominant Bureaucratic Entrepreneurial Collegial, federation of chairs
management
approach
Primary mission Satisfying state Provision of services to Academic freedom and long-term
of the university socio- ‘‘academic consumers’’ and commitment to the production
economic satisfying market demands of knowledge
objectives
Patterns of control and quality evaluation
Who controls/ Ministry (State or quasi- governmental) Self-evaluation by university,
evaluates? accreditation/evaluation academic peers (within broad
bodies regulatory framework set by the
state)
What is Academic Quality of academic products Quality of research output,
controlled? processes publications
When does Ex ante Ex post Not systematized; university-
evaluation take dependent
place?
Focus of quality National/state Local, regional, global Meeting scientific/research
evaluation objectives economic demands; objectives
efficiency, flexibility
Relations to the state and society
State control Manpower Incentives for competition, Financial, legal framework
instruments planning quality improvements
system design
Orientation and State defined Market demands Scientific advancement
utility of
teaching and
research
Economic and employer stakeholders
Function Control Marketing Limited (potentially: external
defenders of the institution)
Appointed by State University management Academia

to intertwine university activities with regional economic activity (see Vartiainen and Viiri
2002) as well as state piloted programs in France such as U3M (universite´ du troisie`me
millenaire) and universite´ 2002, which elevated the universities to decisive actors in
regional economic development (see Aust 2007). In Humboldt-oriented models, univer-
sities are relatively insulated from external pressures and business and commerce have
only established themselves as stakeholders during the more recent reforms (see Herrschel
1999; Neave 2003; Trow 1990). If consulted at all, external stakeholders (employer,
industrial representatives) are usually approached by individual academics for the sake
of non-binding advice and small-scale joint cooperation initiatives. Hence, the role of

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 675

socio-economic stakeholders is relatively restricted, although they at times may emerge as


external defenders of higher education institutions. This pattern is also reflected in the
overall orientation and utility of teaching and research. Although the provided distinction
is admittedly highly generalized, in entrepreneurial models there is a stronger orientation
towards market needs and professional interests of students—and away from the Hum-
boldtian ‘‘ivory towers’’.

Financial governance

Funding issues also are part of the overall institutional balance of power, but are worthy of a
separate classification due to their broad ramifications for the overall functioning of insti-
tutions. Funding is a core component of planning and control cycle and directly impacts
matters of quality and access. According to Jongbloed (2003), funding has an immediate
impact on the quality of services offered while the number of student places impacts the
opportunities available for prospective students. In the same vein, quality determines the
ability of institutions to generate additional funding from non-governmental sources.
The analysis by Jongbloed (2003) is a useful starting point. He makes distinctions
between centralized (regulated) and decentralized (market) systems and between input and
output orientation (2003: 123). Input-based systems generally link funding to indicators
such as staff and student numbers. Output-based systems pursue a more incentive-oriented
approach by adjusting funding according to institutional performance, accreditation, and
rankings, etc. At the same time, marketization is synonymous not only with greater
competition over funding, but also with the fragmentation of the funding base, in which the
government’s share of system funding is reduced and funding sources diversified (de Boer
and Goedegebuure 2003: 212). Systems of academic self-rule generally are state funded
and to a large extent input-based (e.g. student numbers), but grant universities broader
discretion in the allocation of funds. In most cases, some funds are for specific purposes,
and others are left to the discretion of institutions.4
In state-managed systems the state maintains control over funds and allocates itemized
or earmarked funding at its discretion. In other words, in state-driven systems institutions
have little freedom to use funds according to preferences. Hence, funds are used for state-
specified objectives. However, it would be faulty to assume that funding is entirely input-
based, i.e. based exclusively on figures such as student numbers or predetermined for-
mulas. More recently, there has been a trend towards output-oriented, contract-based
funding in various traditionally state-centered higher education systems. The most prom-
inent example is the development and implementation of 4-year negotiated contracts
(contrats quadriennaux) in France, which are strategic development plans funded by the
state aimed at performance optimization at the university level (Musselin 2001; Musselin
and Paradeise 2009). Such contracts have also become wide-spread in Scandinavia
(Gornitzka et al. 2004; Hölttä and Rekilä 2003), revealing that the central government has
increasingly become the promoter and guarantor of performance-based funding arrange-
ments in state-centered systems.
In market models institutions decide for themselves how to finance operations and
generate desired outcomes (Jongbloed 2003: 122). Moreover, greater discretion over funds
is vested at the university management level, which may allocate funds on the basis of the

4
In the German case, this generally consists of input-based overhead funds allocated to professorial chairs
combined with third-party funds allocated through research proposals by individual chairs or conglomerates
of chairs.

123
676 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

Table 2 Higher education funding mechanisms


State-centered model Market-oriented model Academic self-governance

Main funding State budget Competitive and diversified State budget (with own
base (university budget (tuition/donations/research university budget)
integral part of state grants/private entities/state)
budget)
State funding Itemized (low Lump sum (high budgetary Mixed-type (high
approach budgetary discretion discretion for university budgetary discretion
for universities) management) for university)
Allocation Input-based ? Output- Output-based (objectives Input-based (objectives
within based (objectives defined by university) negotiated by the state
university defined by the state) and universities)
Strategic State defined Multi-faceted (undertaken by Occasional, chair-based
investments university management, (occasionally undertaken
faculties, via spin-off by chairs and
companies, technology centers) departments)

productive output of individual departments. Thus, an archetypical market-oriented funding


model would involve a strong output-orientation, competitive funding schemes as well as a
concentration of allocation authority in the university management level. In academic self-
control models, universities generally also operate their own budgets. However, unlike in
market-oriented systems, the professoriate often enjoys greater control over allocated
resources as well as third-party funds and grants allocated directly to individual chairs. As a
result, entrepreneurial models are frequently resisted by academic staff, as financial
autonomy is often shifted towards university management (Schimank 2002: 8).
To address changes in funding, we must therefore ask: who pays, how are funds made
available (state, tuition, grants, third-party funds) and allocated (itemized/lump sum), and
who has discretion? And subsequently, do universities engage in strategic investment in
technology and knowledge transfer to expand their funding base? (Table 2).
Hence, market-based financial governance entails a shift in financial autonomy towards
the managerial level and an increase in output-based criteria, while in state-centered
systems we are also witnessing such as shift by means of multi-annual negotiated contracts
(i.e. input-based ? output-based state funding). Also common to both market-based and to
some extent Humboldt-oriented systems is lump-sum funding. Contrary to itemized or
earmarked state funding, this increases the budgetary discretion of universities, and in
particular the management level in market-oriented systems. Marketization also implies
less reliance on state funding and thus the diversification of funding. Student tuition is only
one potential source of funding. Market-based funding also entails the clustering of
activities with private sector institutions by way of strategic investments undertaken
directly by the university, e.g. start-up firms, spin-offs, knowledge transfer (see Sporn
2006: 142). In essence, market-based systems integrate entrepreneurial and investment
culture into funding measures (see Gumport 2000; Clark 1998; Estermann and Nokkala
2009). In Humboldt-based and state models, income and expenditures are much more the
result of incremental annual calculations and state steering measures than entrepreneurial
activities (see Herrschel 1999; Burnham 1999: 75).5

5
Differences exist to a certain degree in Germany between universities and Fachhochschulen (polytech-
nics), with approximately 60% of university professors receiving additional external funding for research
activities, compared to 33% of professors at polytechnics (Enders and Teichler 1995). Private-sector funding
is more prevalent in polytechnics.

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 677

Personnel autonomy

Personnel or staffing autonomy grasps the delegation of authority between the state and
institutions as well as the overall status of rectors, university leadership and academic staff
and their capacity to participate in strategic decision-making processes (see Estermann and
Nokkala 2009). In the state-centered model, the governments define bureaucratic and
academic norms, as academic and administrative positions are based on state appointment.
This falls in line with the original French model in which flexibility in resource management
is substantially limited by state control over recruitment, rules, rewards and sanctions (see
Burnham 1999: 75). In Humboldt-oriented models, the notion of a ‘‘community of scholars’’
is much more apparent as researching academics are highly involved in management affairs
and the recruitment of high and lower-level personnel (see Herrschel 1999: 108), for whom
tenure privileges are frequent. This is reflected in the position of the rector, who is appointed
by the academic electorate, to whom he or she owes his/her loyalty. Hence, his/her selection
is not based on management skills (World Bank 2005: 7), as is generally the case in market-
oriented systems, while in state-centered systems rectors generally can be regarded as civil
servants with an academic or administrative background. Market-oriented approaches see
for greater participation of administrative staff in the selection of academic and high-level
personnel, but also greater autonomy of university management to dismiss academics, e.g.
for unproductiveness. The strong position of the management level can also be bolstered by
performance-based remuneration of academic staff (see segment on financial governance).
The greater leverage of central management in market-based systems goes hand in hand
with fewer tenure options,6 while universities—unlike in state-centered or Humboldtian
systems—also tend to have autonomy to dismiss staff for lack of productivity without state
intervention. Targeted recruitment and professional hiring by university management are
additional indicators of marketization (Table 3).

Substantive autonomy

Substantive autonomy essentially comprises what should be taught and researched as well
as the size, core specializations, and accession conditions of the institution (see Berdahl
1990; see also Estermann and Nokkala 2009). Hence, the central question is whether
teaching and research should focus on what the academic faculty or state deems most
important or what students wish to learn and what the market demands. Thus, the con-
ceptualization of substantive autonomy also moves beyond more elementary classifica-
tions, e.g. full state administration vs. market linkages, and reflects the tripartite forces
tugging over HE (Clark 1983). The extent to which institutions are autonomous as regards
research and teaching is also directly linked to the institutional balance of power addressed
above as well as issues of quality control. Changes in substance, i.e. new departments/units
and areas of knowledge, lead to changes in the size and shape of the institution, which are
in turn directly reflected in the institutional framework. Distinct differences can be iden-
tified here with regard to the academic self-governance model prevalent in Germany and
areas historically influenced by it. According to Trow (1990), aside from the freedom to
teach and to learn, the (European) university rarely has much authority to manage its own
size and shape, its entry or exit requirements, or its broader character and functions (see
also McDaniel 1997: 82). In other words, in academic self-governance models, the state

6
For example, in the US in 2001 only one-fourth of newly hired faculty members had the opportunity for
tenure (see Keller 2006: 230 for the US; Dill 1997 for Great Britain).

123
678 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

Table 3 Personnel autonomy


State-centered model Market-oriented Academic self-
model governance

Recruitment of high- Appointed by state Elected by faculty/ Elected by


level academic staff university professoriate
management
Recruitment of high- Appointed by state Elected by university Elected by
ranking administrative management professoriate
staff
University autonomy to No—state competence; Yes (for lack of No—frequent tenure
dismiss high-ranking frequent tenure (dismissal productivity; limited (dismissal only for
academics for ideological non- tenure privileges) severe misconduct)
compliance in
undemocratic states)
Professional background Public administration Management Scholar/chair holder
of rectors/deans
Participation of Limited Moderate High
academic staff in
administrative
management

functions as a ‘‘gatekeeper’’ (Herrschel 1999: 999) that sets the institutional framework
conditions (size, institution requirements). Decisions over academic matters are, on the
other hand, entirely left up to the professoriate with little intervention by university
management or by the state, except for a very broad state framework in some cases.
Market-based university institutions determine admission requirements, core academic
specializations and institutional parameters without state intervention, while conducting
cost-benefit analyses in devising strategic plans (Jongbloed 2003: 114) (Table 4).
Market models, for example, delegate greater autonomy over substance and content
away from the ‘‘academic oligarchy’’ to university management, which frequently seeks to
reduce the gap between research and teaching and economic demands (de Boer and
Goedegebuure 2003: 215).7 In state-centered systems, academic content is generally the
result of co-administrative arrangements between the state and academics (see Musselin
2001; Friedberg and Musselin 1993 for the French case). Humboldt-inspired systems, by
contrast, thrive on heavy faculty control and academic freedom, placing greater decision-
making weight on senior academic staff, e.g. in boards. Collegial self-governance models
allegedly grant academics the highest degree of substantive autonomy, unrestricted by
socio-economic pressures (see Schimank 2005: 7). Entrepreneurial models, which shift
some substantive autonomy to the managerial level, are generally not welcomed by aca-
demics, as they tend to chip away at collegial decision-making structures and in some cases
academic freedom (see de Boer and Goedegebuure 2003: 213; Felt 2003: 18). In the same
vein, Olsen (2007) cites the overemphasis on individual and disciplinary freedom as a
potential hindrance to good performance and timely decision-making.

7
Market-based academic cultures (e.g. the United States) are often marked by the co-existence of public
colleges and university with private institutions. In public institutions, the state assumes a greater role in the
development of higher education policy. Personnel policy and funding are generally set down by the state
executive and authorized by the legislature. Nevertheless, institutions maintain a considerable degree of
substantial, procedural and financial autonomy with regard to the allocation of funds (see Horton 1999: 269).

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 679

Table 4 Substantive autonomy


State-centered model Market-oriented model Academic self-
governance

Setting academic profiles/ State/academia University management/ Academia


curriculum design academia
Setting strategic goals State University management Academia
Determining the State/academia University management/ Academia
research profile academia
Setting accession conditions, State University management State/university
size of institution, and core (negotiated)
specializations

Conclusions

Our proposed scheme for analysing HE governance structures built on various previous
analyses on higher education governance and aimed to break down three historical ideal-
types in Europe into empirically observable indicators. Despite their somewhat simplified
and static character, the presented indicators may be used to trace and operationalize the
extent and direction of policy change or persistence in European higher education systems.
By doing so, we also aimed to demonstrate how university autonomy can manifest itself
differently and that marketization is not necessarily synomynous with the retreat of the
state. Countries may be confronted with more market and government influence at the
same time (see Theisens 2003). Decisive is not necessarily the mere amount of influence,
rather the nature of influence (i.e. product vs. process control; more state steering via
performance-based funding) that is crucial. It is also often the government which has the
power to decide how much ‘‘market’’ may penetrate into higher education, making clear
distinctions difficult. Moreover, some measure of university autonomy is compatible with
all three models, but this autonomy presents itself in different manners and different facets.
Fully aware that the typology is by no means complete, we contend that individual
indicators may be fine-tuned, supplemented and realigned, for example to accommodate
more recent notions such as corporate governance, flexible governance and participative
governance (see Braun and Merrien 1999; Sporn 1999). In particular, the classification of
financial governance could be fine-tuned to accommodate the recent trend towards con-
tract-based funding arrangements in Scandinavia (Gornitzka et al. 2004) and France
(Musselin 2001; Musselin and Paradeise 2009). However, the scheme does offer an array
of advantages for assessing domestic or comparative cross-country changes in higher
education governance. Firstly, the classifications allow for the existence of mixed-types,
i.e. national systems which have evolved into hybrid forms of Humboldt or state-centered
and market-oriented governance (see Dobbins and Knill 2009 for several such examples in
central and eastern Europe). The classification also enables us to ‘‘mix and match’’ dif-
ferent characteristics of the ideal-types and allows for variation between different sub-
dimensions of governance. For example institutions in one country might display great
financial autonomy, but limited personnel autonomy, or strong procedural autonomy
restricted by stringent state financial oversight. Or, interestingly, two ideal-types may be in
practice in one single country. Such is the case with Poland, whose public higher education
system remains strongly aligned with the academic self-rule model, while its private HE
system reflects the market-oriented model in all its facets (see Dobbins and Knill 2009).

123
680 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

Despite difficulties in accommodating the entire complexity of contemporary HE


governance (e.g. co-decision authority of governments and academics), our contribution to
the contemporary debate about HE reforms can be used for both large cross-country
comparative studies as well as a few comparable countries. Single case studies may also
provide crucial insights into the nuances and peculiarities of individual national approaches
to HE governance, which can only be partially reflected by our indicators. Moreover, the
framework can be used to compare the status quo of different timeframes and thus identify
what events (e.g. domestic political transmission or external forces of globalization, the
Bologna Process) were important for HE policy change.
Although the scheme is unable to identify the forces of change or inertia, it also
provides a systematic framework to analyze developments in various sub-dimensions of
governance. For example, we can now measure the correspondence of a particular Euro-
pean country to a certain model in various different aspects of governance (e.g. role of the
state, internal university governance, funding issues). Future empirical analyses could also
demonstrate, for example, whether changes are more easily implemented in financial
governance than in personnel issues, or whether quality assurance or the incorporation of
external stakeholders, for instance, are particularly change-resistant areas requiring more
focussed reform strategies. In any case, it is our hope that the true value and limitations of
such a framework will become more apparent in future research.

References

Arthur, L. (2006). Higher education and the knowledge society: Issues, challenges and responses in Norway
and Germany. Research in Comparative and International Education, 1(3), 241–252.
Aust, J. (2007). Le sacre des présidents d’université. Une analyse de l’application des plans Université 2000
et Université du 3ème millénaire en Rhône-Alpes. Sociologie du Travail, 49(2), 220–236.
Berdahl, R. (1990). Academic freedom, autonomy, and accountability in British Universities. Studies in
Higher Education, 19(2), 151–164.
Bieber, T. (2010). Playing the multilevel game in education—The PISA study and the bologna process
triggering swiss harmonization. In K. Martens, N. Alexander-Kenneth, W. Michael, & W. Ansgar
(Eds.), Transformation of education policy—The impact of the bologna process and the PISA study in
comparative perspective (pp. 105–131). Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Braun, D. (2001). Regulierungsmodelle und Machtstrukturen an Universitäten. Die Krise der Universitäten.
Leviathan Sonderheft, 20, 243–264.
Braun, D., & Merrien, F.-X. (1999). Governance of Universities and modernisation of the state: Analytical
aspects. In D. Braun & F. X. Merrien (Eds.), Towards a new model of Governance for Universities? A
comparative view (pp. 9–33). London: Jessica Kingsley Publishers.
Burnham, J. (1999). France: A centrally-driven profession. In D. Farnham (Ed.), Managing academic staff in
changing university systems (pp. 74–93). Buckingham: Society for Research into Higher Education and
Open Univ. Press.
Clark, B. (1983). The higher education system. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Clark, B. (1998). Creating entrepreneurial universities: Organizational pathways of transformation.
Oxford: Pergamon-Elsevier Science.
De Boer, H., Enders, J., & Leisyte, L. (2007). Public sector reform in Dutch higher education: The
organizational transformation of the university. Public Administration, 85(1), 27–46.
de Boer, H., & Goedegebuure, L. (2003). New rules of the game? Reflections on governance, management,
and systems change. In J. File & L. Goedegebuure (Eds.), Real-time systems—Reflections on higher
education in the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and Slovenia (pp. 207–234). Enschede: Logo
CHEPS Centre for Higher Education Policy Studies, University of Twente.
de Boer, H., Maassen, P., & de Weert, E. (1999). The troublesome Dutch university and its Route 66
towards a new governance structure. Higher Education Policy, 12, 329–342.
Delanty, G. (2001). Challenging knowledge: The university in the knowledge society. Buckingham: Open
University Press.

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 681

Dill, D. (1997). Higher education markets and public policy. Higher Education Policy, 10(3–4), 167–185.
Dobbins, M. (2011). Higher education policies in Central and Eastern Europe: Convergence towards a
common model? Basingstoke: Palgrave (forthcoming).
Dobbins, M., & Knill, C. (2009). Higher education policies in Central and Eastern Europe: Convergence
towards a common model? Governance, 22(3), 397–430.
Enders, J., & Teichler, U. (1995). Der Hochschullehrerberuf im internationalen Vergleich: Ergebnisse einer
Befragung über die wissenschaftliche Profession. Bonn: Bundesministerium für Bildung, Wissen-
schaft, Forschung und Technologie.
Estermann, T., & Nokkala, T. (2009). University autonomy in Europe. Exploratory study. Brussels: Euro-
pean University Association.
European Commission. (2003). Higher education in Europe. http://europa.eu.int/comm/education/higher.
html (consulted 15 June 2008).
European Commission. (2006). Delivering on the modernisation agenda for Universities: Education,
research and innovation—Communication from the commission to the council and the European
Parliament, 12.09.2009. http://ec.europa.eu/education/higher-education/doc1320_en.
Felt, U. (2003). University autonomy in Europe: Changing paradigms in higher education policy. Paper
presented at the EAU convention of European Higher Education Institutions, Graz 39-31 May, 2003.
http://eua.uni-graz.at/Ulrike_Felt.pdf (consulted 12 May 2006).
Ferlie, E., Ashburner, L., Fitzgerald, L., & Pettigrew, A. (1996). The new public management in action.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ferlie, E., Musselin, C., & Andresani, G. (2009). The steering of higher education systems: A public
management perspective. Higher Education, 56(3), 325–348.
Friedberg, E., & Musselin, C. (1993). L’Etat face aux universite´s. Paris: Anthropos.
Goedegebuure, L., Kaiser, F., Maassen, P., Meek, L., van Vught, F., & de Weert, E. (1993). Hochschul-
politik im internationalen Vergleich: Eine länderübergreifende Untersuchung im Auftrag der Ber-
telsmann Stiftung. Gütersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung.
Gornitzka, Å., & Maassen, P. (2000). National policies concerning the economic role of higher education.
Higher Education Policy, 13(3), 225–230.
Gornitzka, Å., Maassen, P., Olsen, J., & Stensaker, B. (2007). Europe of knowledge: Search for a new pact.
In P. Maassen & J. P. Olsen (Eds.), University dynamics and European integration (pp. 181–214).
Dordrecht: Springer.
Gornitzka, Å., Stensaker, B., Smeby, J. C., & de Boer, H. (2004). Contract arrangements in the Nordic
countries: Solving the efficiency/effectiveness dilemma. Higher Education in Europe, 29(1), 87–101.
Gumport, P. (2000). Academic restructuring: Organizational change and institutional imperatives. Higher
Education, 39(1), 67–91.
Habermas, J. (1967). Universität in der Demokratie—Demokratisierung der Universität. Merkur, XXI(5),
416–433.
Herrschel, T. (1999). Germany: A dual academy. In D. Farnham (Ed.), Managing academic staff in
changing university systems. Buckingham: Society for Research into Higher Education and Open Univ.
Press.
Hölttä, S., & Rekilä, E. (2003). Ministerial steering and institutional responses: Recent developments of the
finnish higher education system. Higher Education Management and Policy, 15(1), 57–70.
Horton, S. (1999). The United States: Self-governed profession or managed occupation. In D. Farnham
(Ed.), Managing academic staff in changing university systems (pp. 260–289). Buckingham: Society
for Research into Higher Education and Open Univ. Press.
Johnson, R., & Anderson, D. (1998). University Autonomy in Twenty Countries, Centre for Continuing
Education. The Australian National University. April 1998, 98/3. www.dest.gov.au/archive/highered/
eippubs/eip98-3/eip98-3.pdf (consulted 28 Feb 2006).
Jongbloed, B. (2003). Marketization in higher education, Clark’s triangle and the essential ingredients of
markets. Higher Education Quarterly, 57(2), 110–135.
Kaiser, F. (2007). Higher education in France: Country report, CHEPS—Twente.
Keller, G. (2006). Higher education management: Challenges and strategies. In P. Altbach & J. Forest
(Eds.), International handbook of higher education: Part one (pp. 229–242). Dordrecht: Springer.
Krücken, G., Kosmützky, A., & Torka, M. (2007). Towards a multiversity? Universities between global
trends and national traditions (pp. 108–131). Bielefeld: Transcript.
Kyvik, S. (2009). The dynamics of change in higher education. Dordrecht: Springer.
Marginson, S., & Considine, M. (2000). The enterprise university: Governance and reinvention in Aus-
tralian higher education. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
McDaniel, O. (1996). The paradigms of governance in higher education systems. Higher Education Policy,
9(2), 137–158.

123
682 High Educ (2011) 62:665–683

McDaniel, O. (1997). The effects of government politics on higher education: In search of alternative
steering methods. S’Gravenhage: VUGA Uitgeverij B.V.
Meek, V. L. (2000). Diversity and Marketisation of higher education: Incompatible concepts? Higher
Education Policy, 13(1), 23–39.
Meister, S. (2007). Russlands Hochschulpolitik zwischen Wettbewerb und staatlicher Kontrolle. Russ-
landanalysen, 132, 4–12.
Mizikaci, F. (2006). Higher education in Turkey. UNESCO-CEPES. Monographs on higher education.
http://www.cepes.ro/publications/pdf/turkey.pdf.
Musselin, C. (2001). La longue marche des universite´s françaises. Paris: PUF.
Musselin, C., & Paradeise, C. (2009). France: From incremental transitions to institutional change. In
C. Paradeise, E. Reale, I. Bleiklie, & E. Ferlie (Eds.), University governance: Western European
perspectives. Dordrecht: Springer.
Neave, G. (1996). Homogenization, integration, and convergence: The chershire cats of higher education
analysis. In L. Meek, L. Goedegebuure, O. Kivinen, & R. Rinne (Eds.), The mockers and the mocked:
Comparative perspectives on differentiation, convergence and diversity in higher education. Oxford:
Pergamon.
Neave, G. (1998a). Quatre modèles pour l’Université. Courrier de l’UNESCO, 33(3), 7–25.
Neave, G. (1998b). The evaluative state reconsidered. European Journal of Education, 33(3), 265–284.
Neave, G. (2003). The bologna declaration: Some of the historic dilemmas posed by the reconstruction of
the community in Europe’s system of higher education. Educational Policy, 17(1), 141–164.
Neave, G. (2004). Mr Prometheus—unbound, shackled or released on parole? Being certain adumbrations on
the marvellously changing relationship between government and higher education in Western Europe.
Paper presented at the Fulbright Brainstorms 2004—New Trends in Higher Education. Lisbon, 24–25
Sep 2004. http://www.ccla.pt/brainstorms/release1.0/pdf/09_GuyNeave.pdf (consulted 15 Apr 2005).
Neave, G., & van Vught, F. (1991). Prometheus bound: The changing relationship between government and
higher education in Western Europe. Oxford: Pergamon Press.
Niemann, D. (2010). Turn of the tide—New horizons in German education policymaking through IO
influence. In K. Martens, N. Alexander-Kenneth, W. Michael, & W. Ansgar (Eds.), Transformation of
education policy—The impact of the bologna process and the PISA study in comparative perspective
(pp. 77–104). Houndmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Niklasson, L. (1995). State, market, hierarchy in higher education—A typology and an outline of the debate.
Higher Education Management, 7(3), 345–353.
Niklasson, L. (1996). Quasi-markets in higher education a comparative analysis. Journal of Higher Edu-
cation Policy and Management, 18(1), 7–22.
Nybom, T. (2003). The Humboldt legacy: Reflections on the past, present and future of the European
university. Higher Education Policy, 16, 141–159.
Olsen, J. (2007). The institutional dynamics of the European University. In M. Peter & O. Johan (Eds.),
University Dynamics and European Integration. Dordrecht: Springer.
Paradeise, C., Reale, E., Bleikle, I., & Ferlie, E. (2009a). University governance: Western European
perspectives. Dordrecht: Springer.
Paradeise, C., Reale, E., & Goastellec, G. (2009b). A comparative approach to higher education reforms in
Western European countries. In E. Reale, I. Bleikle, E. Ferlie, & C. Paradeise (Eds.), University
governance: Western European perspectives. Dordrecht: Springer.
Phillip, C. (2000). Auf dem Wege zum europäischen Bildungsmarkt: Supranationale Hochschulpolitik oder
Wettbewerb der Hochschulsysteme? Dissertation, Universität Köln. Josef Eul Verlag, Köln.
Sadlak, J. (1995). In search of the ‘‘post-communist’’ university—the background and scenario of the
transformation of higher education in Central and Eastern Europe. In K. Hüfner (Ed.), Higher edu-
cation reform processes in Central and Eastern Europe (pp. 43–62). Frankfurt: Peter Lang.
Schimank, U. (2002). Governance in Hochschulen, Vortrag zur Veranstaltung ,,Professionelles
Wissenschaftsmanagement als Aufgabe’’ des Zentrums für Wissenschaftsmanagement, 22.10.2002.
Wissenschaftszentrum Bonn. www.zwm-speyer.de/VortragSchimank.pdf (consulted 16 March 2006).
Schimank, U. (2005). Die akademische Profession und die Universitäten: ,,New Public Management’’ und
eine drohende Entprofessionalisierung. In T. Klatetzki & V. Tacke (Eds.), Organisation und profession
(pp. 143–164). Wiesbaden: VS.
Scott, P. (2002). Reflections on the reform of higher education in Central and Eastern Europe. Higher
Education in Europe, 27(1–2), 137–152.
Sporn, B. (1999). Responsive university structures: An analysis of adaptation to socioeconomic environ-
ments of US and European universities. London: Jessica Kingsley Publishers.
Sporn, B. (2006). Governance and administration. In P. Altbach & J. Forest (Eds.), International handbook
of higher education. Part one (pp. 141–157). Dordrecht: Springer.

123
High Educ (2011) 62:665–683 683

t’Veld, R., Füssel, H.-P., & Neave, G. (1996). Relations between state and higher education. The Hague:
Kluwer.
Theisens, H. (2003). Statism by stealth? Market orientation in British higher education. In: B. Denters,
O. van Heffen, J. Huisman, & P. J. Klok (Eds.). The rise of interactive governance and quasi-markets
(pp. 203–216). Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Trow, M. (1990). American higher education: Exceptional or just different? In B. E. Schafer (Ed.), Still
different? A new look at American exceptionalism (pp. 138–186). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Vaira, M. (2004). Globalization and higher education organizational change: A framework for analysis.
Higher Education, 48, 483–510.
van Vught, F. (1989). Governmental strategies and innovation in higher education. London: Jessica
Kingsley.
van Vught, F. (1995). Policy models and policy instruments in higher education. The effects of governmental
policy-making on the innovative behaviour of higher education institutions. Institut für Höhere Studien
(HIS), Wien.
van Wageningen, A. C. (2003). De Staat van de Universiteit: Een rechtsvergelijkende studie naar de
institutionalisering van de universiteit in Nederland, Frankrijk en Nordrhein-Westfalen. PhD thesis at
the University of Twente.
Vartiainen, P., & Viiri, A. (2002). Universities and their local partners: The case of the University of
Joensuu, Finland. Industry and Higher Education, 16(2), 83–89.
World Bank (2005). Bulgaria—Education and skills for the knowledge economy—A policy note executive
summary. http://www.siteresources.worldbank.org/INTBULGARIA/Resources/EducationPolicyNote_
EN.pdf (consulted 5 March 2007).

123

You might also like