IS-LM Model - 2
IS-LM Model - 2
Economics and mathematics are highly interrelated subjects. Models of economic theories are developed using
integration, differentiation, and probability. In the context of macroeconomics, it is often important to formulate
strategies to combat phenomena like inflation or frame fiscal and monetary policies to stabilize the economy
as well as boost economic growth. The use of mathematics is crucial to the development of these strategies and
policies. The University of Calcutta has combined these two subjects into one paper that is offered in the third
year of the B Com (Hons.) curriculum with the express intention of providing a comprehensive overview of these
subjects, which will help the students grasp and apply the concepts learnt in their overall study of commerce.
s
This book is designed to provide a comprehensive coverage with an easy-to-understand treatment of macroeconomic
es
theory and advanced business mathematics, covering the syllabus for undergraduate honours students of commerce
Pr
in the University of Calcutta.
Macroeconomics examines and analyses the performance of the economy as a whole. The major macroeconomic
y
issues related to national income, inflation, employment, interest rate, and price level are dealt with in a very
sit
articulate manner in terms of verbal logic, graphical illustration, and mathematical proofs. While it contains the
necessary topics completely covering the syllabus of the University of Calcutta, it also captures well the syllabi
er
theory. Keeping in mind that this book is for undergraduate commerce students, the theoretical portions have
Un
Key Features
or
• The contents and sequence of topics in the book have been prepared by following the syllabus given by the
xf
University of Calcutta.
• The extent of each chapter has been decided keeping in mind the number of lectures assigned in the syllabus
O
so that it would be easy for the teachers to frame their lesson plans.
• Practical examples are inserted to make the theoretical concepts easily understandable for the students.
• Numerical problems are provided for easy understanding of the different aspects of macroeconomic theory.
• In the advanced mathematics portion, a large number of problems are solved including those from different
years’ C.U. question papers.
• Solutions to the university questions as well as model questions are provided, which will help the students
prepare for their examinations.
Chapter 2 begins with the national income accounts. The concept and meaning of national income, its
measurement, components, and different methods of computing have been discussed in a very simple way.
Examples with problems and solutions are given for conceptual clarity.
Chapter 3 deals with the determination of national income under the assumption of a fixed price of final
goods and a constant rate of interest in the economy. This chapter presents the basic ideas developed in Keynes’s
theory to explain how effective demand determines national income.
Chapter 4 covers the Keynesian theory of aggregate demand when investment depends on the interest rate. The
Keynesian theory of aggregate demand is constructed on the assumption that two facts are true simultaneously.
First, the quantity of savings supplied equals the quantity of investment demanded; in other words, the product
market is in equilibrium. Second, the quantity of money demanded is equal to the quantity of money supplied.
In the Keynesian theory, we study the determination of equilibrium in these two markets simultaneously.
In Chapter 5, we discuss the concept and functions of money. We also talk about the demand for money,
quantity theory of money, supply of money, credit creation process of commercial banks, and the different
s
components of money supply. In this connection, we also discuss the concept of money multiplier and the process
es
of controlling the supply of money by the central bank of a country.
Chapter 6 deals with inflation. As inflation affects the everyday lives of the citizens of a country and the
Pr
overall situation of an economy, it is essential to discuss the concept, causes, and impacts of inflation. It is also
necessary to differentiate between demand-pull and cost-push inflation. In this connection, it is essential to know
y
the costs of inflation and the relation between inflation and unemployment. Finally, we should be conversant
sit
with the measures to control inflation.
er
The second part of this book deals with advanced business mathematics. This part is divided into nine chapters.
iv
Chapter 1 introduces the basic concepts of number system, function and its classification, properties of
Un
functions, some special functions, and application of function in business and economics.
Chapter 2 explains the concept of limit of a variable and function, limit of some standard functions, and
the concept of continuity and discontinuity with the graphical representation.
d
In Chapter 3, we discuss the differentiability of a function. There are three sections. In the first section,
or
first order differentiability of a function is discussed. Here, differentiation of different types of functions—
differentiation of composite functions, parametric functions, implicit function, logarithmic functions etc.—
xf
are discussed. In the second section, the concept of second order derivative of a function is introduced. The
O
third section expounds on the concept of more than one variable, that is, function of several variables, partial
derivative of a function, and Euler’s theorem on homogeneous function and derivative of a function using
total differential.
After introduction of elementary differential calculus in Chapter 4, the application of calculus is discussed.
The significance of derivatives, their meaning in different aspects such as rate measures and economics
is discussed. In addition, increasing and decreasing functions and maxima and minima of a function are
elucidated here.
Integration is an important concept in calculus. In Chapter 6, a part of indefinite integration is introduced.
In Chapters 6, 7, and 8, important notions in algebra—matrix and determinant—are introduced. Some basic
definitions related to matrix and determinant, their algebras and finally the system of linear equations solved
using matrices and determinants are described.
Lastly, in Chapter 9, we introduce probability theory. Here, the classical definition of probability is introduced.
Important theorems such as total probability theorem, joint probability theorem, and conditional probability
theorem are stated.
Online Resources
The following resources are available to faculty and students using this text:
• Solutions to Chapter-end Exercises
• Solutions to Model Question Papers
Acknowledgements
We thank the people who encouraged us to work on this manuscript. We are deeply indebted to our colleagues
at the Department of Economics of the University of Calcutta, at Hooghly Women’s College, and Goenka
College of Commerce and Business Administration, Kolkata. Their contributions have been of immense value
to us during the preparation of this text. Comments at the early stages, provided by several colleagues while going
through large portions of the manuscript, helped greatly improve the quality of this book.
We express our gratitude to the Head of the Department of Economics of the University of Calcutta and
s
the Principals of Hooghly Women’s College and Goenka College of Commerce and Business Administration
es
for inspiring us at different stages of this project.
Pr
Comments provided by the referees are gratefully acknowledged. We thank the editorial team at Oxford
University Press for their patience and support.
y
Readers are welcome to share their feedback and suggestions with us at [email protected], asengupta15@
sit
yahoo.com, and [email protected].
er
Panchanan Das
Anindita Sengupta
iv
Swapan Samanta
Un
d
or
xf
O
PART I MACROECONOMICS 1
1. Macroeconomics—Scope and Basic Concepts 3
2. National Income Accounting 18
s
3. Theory of Equilibrium Income Determination 40
es
4. Commodity and Money Market Equilibrium 72
Pr
5. Money and Economy 97
6. Inflation and the Economy 124
y
sit
Solved Question Paper (only Group A)—2012 150
Solved Question Paper (only Group A)—2013 154
er
1. Functions 167
xf
PART I MACROECONOMICS 1
1. Macroeconomics—Scope and Basic Concepts 1.7 Aggregate Demand and
3 Aggregate Supply Approach in
s
1.1 Introduction: Different Schools of Macroeconomics11
es
Thought3 1.7.1 Aggregate Demand 11
1.1.1 Classical Macroeconomics 3 1.7.2 Aggregate Supply 12
Pr
1.1.2 Keynesian Macroeconomics 4 1.7.3 Short-run Equilibrium 14
1.1.3 Classical Keynesian Synthesis 4 1.7.4 Long-run Equilibrium 15
1.1.4 Monetarism 4
y
sit
2. National Income Accounting 18
1.1.5 New Classical
2.1 Introduction 18
er
Macroeconomics 5
2.2 Circular Flow of Income 19
1.1.6 Rational Expectations Theory 5
2.3 Concepts and Measurement of
iv
s
Propensities to Consume 46 Money 79
es
3.4.2 Saving Function from 4.3.2 Precautionary Demand for
Pr
Consumption Function 47 Money 80
3.4.3 Determinants of Propensity to 4.3.3 Speculative Demand for
Save 49
y Money 80
sit
3.4.4 Important Features of Keynes’s 4.3.4 Supply of Money 83
Consumption Function 51 4.3.5 Money Market Equilibrium:
er
s
Reserve Bank of India to Control between Rates of Inflation and
es
Money Supply 120 Unemployment 142
6.6 Monetary and Fiscal Policies to
Pr
6. Inflation and the Economy 124
Control Inflation 143
6.1 Introduction 124
6.6.1 Monetary Policy to Control
6.2 Concept of Inflation and
y Inflation 144
sit
Inflationary Gap 125
6.6.2 Fiscal Policy to Control
6.2.1 Inflationary Gap 127
Inflation 145
er
Inflation 146
6.3.1 Demand-pull Theory of
Un
Inflation 128
d
s
Value Function 172
3.1.3 Derivative of a Function 204
es
1.8.4 Greatest Integer Function 173
3.1.4 Differentiation of Functions
1.9 Single-valued and Multiple-valued
Pr
Using First Principle 205
Functions173
3.1.5 Derivative of Some Standard
1.10 Functions in Business and
Economics173
y Functions 207
sit
3.1.6 Fundamental Theorems on
1.10.1 Demand Function 173
Differentiation 207
1.10.2 Supply Function 173
er
s
4.5 Increasing and Decreasing 6.2.12 Singular and Non-singular
es
Functions251 Matrix 287
4.6 Maxima and Minima of Functions 252 6.2.13 Equality of Matrices 287
Pr
4.7 First Derivative Test for Maximum 6.3 Operations on Matrices 288
and Minimum Values 252 6.3.1 Scalar Multiplication 288
4.8 Maximum and Minimum by
y 6.3.2 Matrix Addition and
sit
Second Derivative Method 253 Subtraction 288
4.9 Point of Inflexion 253 6.3.3 Matrix Multiplication 289
er
s
Probability and Conditional
9. Probability Theory 342
es
Probability347
9.1 Introduction 342
9.6.1 Compound Probability
Pr
9.2 Terminology 342
Theorem 348
9.2.1 Random Experiment 342
9.6.2 Extension of Compound
9.2.2 Random Variable 342
y Probability Theorem 348
sit
9.2.3 Trial 342
9.6.3 Dependent and Independent
9.2.4 Sample Space 342
Events 348
er
4
Commodity and Money Market
Equilibrium
This chapter is about the Keynesian theory of aggregate demand when investment depends on the interest rate.
We will show that aggregate demand depends not only on the money supply, as in the classical theory, but also
s
on fiscal policy and on the expectations of households and firms. The Keynesian theory of aggregate demand
es
is constructed on the assumption that two facts are true simultaneously. First, the quantity of savings supplied
equals the quantity of investment demanded; in other words, the product market is in equilibrium. Second, the
Pr
quantity of money demanded is equal to the quantity of money supplied. In other words, the existing stock of
money in circulation is willingly held. In the Keynesian theory, we have to study the determination of equilibrium
in these two markets simultaneously.
y
sit
In Chapter 3, we discussed national income determination and investment multiplier by assuming that
private investment is autonomous. This is the subject matter of product market analysis, where equilibrium
er
national income is determined by equating aggregate demand to aggregate supply of output. We also add the
investment function, where private investment depends on both income and interest rates. In this chapter,
iv
we extend our analysis by taking the interest rate as an important determinant of investment; a reduction
in the interest rate raises investment demand. Now, we have to find out what determines the interest rate.
Un
This search extends our analysis further to include the markets where interest rate is determined. This is the
money market or market for financial assets where interest rate is determined. The interest rate, however,
is not determined from the money market in an isolated manner. This forces us to study the interaction of
d
the product and money markets. National income and interest rates are jointly determined by equilibrium
or
in the product and money markets. The analysis in this chapter qualifies some conclusions we came to in
Chapter 3.
xf
O
4.1 Introduction
Keynes contended that monetary policy was powerless to boost the economy out of a depression because it depended
on reducing interest rates, and in a depression, interest rates were already close to zero. Increased government
spending, on the other hand, would not only boost demand directly, but also set off a chain reaction of increased
demand from workers and suppliers whose incomes had been increased by the government’s expenditure. Similarly,
a tax cut would put more disposable income in the wallets of consumers, and that too would boost demand. The
appropriate fiscal policy during periods of high unemployment was to run a budget deficit. These ideas flew in the
face of the conventional wisdom that budget deficits were always bad. Historical research, however, pioneered
by Milton Friedman has convinced many economists that the Depression was mainly the result of incompetent
monetary policy in both Britain and the United States rather than the inability of monetary policy to influence the
economy. Many economists had expected a resumption of the Great Depression when World War II ended, but
instead the US economy experienced an era of spectacular growth. To the surprise of almost everyone, the most
s
on interest rate. In the money market also, a part of
es
money demand depends on income and another part depends on interest rate. Thus, income and interest rate are
determined jointly by the product market and money market equilibrium. This is the essence of Hicks’s IS-LM
Pr
model. The IS-LM model emphasizes the interaction between the product and money markets. In Chapter 3,
we discussed national income determination by arguing that income affects spending, which in turn determines
y
output and income. In this chapter, we consider the effects of interest rates on investment and aggregate spending,
sit
and ultimately on income. Thus, we need the dependence of the money market on income. Higher income raises
money demand, and thus interest rates. Higher interest rates lower spending, and thus income. Spending, interest
er
rates, and income are determined jointly by equilibrium in the product and money markets. Fiscal policy works
iv
by changing government expenditure or tax rates or both through the product market, but monetary policy
Un
and aggregate demand by analysing the investment function once again in Section 4.2. We extend our analysis
or
from Chapter 3 to include the interest rate as a determinant of aggregate demand and derive the key relationship
between income and interest rates in the form of the IS curve, which explains equilibrium in the product
xf
market. In Section 4.3, we turn to the money market. We show that the demand for money depends on interest
O
rates and income. There are combinations of interest rates and income levels for which the money market is
in equilibrium in the form of the LM curve. In Section 4.4, we deal with the two-sector Keynesian model of
national income determination by combining the IS and LM schedules to study the joint determination of
interest rates and income. Section 4.5 lays out the multiplier process and the effectiveness of monetary and
fiscal policies in this framework.
In the Keynesian model, it is no longer true that there is a unique level of income. The fact that income
may fluctuate over the business cycle will affect the interest rate because households will be willing to save
more if they are rich than if they are poor. If income is high and unemployment is low, there will be a relatively
high supply of savings. Firms will not need to offer a high rate of interest to attract lenders and so a high value
of income will be associated with a low equilibrium interest rate. If instead income is low and unemployment
is high, investors will compete with each other to borrow a small pool of savings and they will bid up the rate
of interest. A low value of income will be associated with a high equilibrium interest rate. In the Keynesian
model, we summarize this idea by deriving a schedule, the IS curve, that plots the nominal interest rate on the
vertical axis and the level of income on the horizontal axis. At every point on the IS curve, the product market
is in equilibrium.
s
closed economy, aggregate demand has three components: consumption expenditure, investment expenditure, and
es
government expenditure. Consumption expenditure depends on disposable income (national income less taxes),
investment expenditure depends on the interest rate, and government expenditure is autonomous. Aggregate
Pr
supply in the product market is gross national product (GNP) at factor cost or national income. Thus, the
equilibrium condition in the product market is given by
y
sit
Y = C (Y − t(Y )) + I ( r ) + G , 0 < C ′ < 1, 0 < t ′ < 1, I ′ < 0 (4.1)
er
dC dT
Here, C ′ = = mpc. The tax function is T = t(Y ) , and t ′ = is the marginal tax rate.
dY dY
iv
dI
Un
dS
or
Here, S ′ = = mps
dY
xf
The alternative form of the equilibrium condition states that investment (I) equals savings (S) under the
O
assumption that government budget is balanced. Thus, the product market equilibrium schedule is popularly
known as the IS curve, the schedule along which investment equals savings. The product market equilibrium,
either in equation 4.1 or 4.2, consists of several combinations of income (Y) and interest rate (r) that keep equality
between aggregate demand and aggregate supply, or between savings and investment.
The geometric representation of product market equilibrium is the IS curve. The IS curve is a locus of several
combinations of income and interest rate that maintain the product market in equilibrium in a sense that aggregate
demand equals aggregate supply, or investment equals savings. The product market equilibrium schedule, the IS
curve, is an extension of national income determination with a 45°-line diagram as shown in Chapter 3. Now
investment is no longer fully exogenous but is also determined by the interest rate.
By following the trick we have applied in Chapter 3 the derivation of the IS curve is shown in Fig. 4.2.
Panel B of Fig. 4.2 shows the investment function, which relates investment to the interest rate. Panel A of
Figure 4.2 locates equilibrium points corresponding to different interest rates, and the IS curve is drawn in
Panel C. The negatively sloped investment curve implies that investment demand rises when the interest rate
falls and vice versa. In Chapter 3, we discussed why investment is inversely related to the interest rate. The level
C, I, G r r
E2 C + I2 + G I
C + I1 + G E1
r1 r1
E1 C
r2 r2 E2
I2 + G
I′ IS
I1 + G
45°
Y1 Y2 Y I1 I2 I Y1 Y2 Y
Panel A Panel B Panel C
s
es
of investment is I1 when the interest rate is r1. This level of investment produces aggregate demand for output
C + I1 + G shown in Panel A. Given this level of aggregate demand, the product market is in equilibrium at
Pr
point E1, where equilibrium national income is determined at Y1 as shown in Panel A of Fig. 4.2. Thus, when
the interest rate is at r1, income will be at Y1, satisfying equilibrium in the product market. Measuring income
y
along the horizontal axis and the interest rate along the vertical axis, this (Y1, r1) combination which maintains
sit
equilibrium in the product market is plotted at point E1 in Panel C of Fig. 4.2. When the interest rate falls to
r2, investment rises to I2 and the equilibrium point shifts to E2, where aggregate demand (C + I2 + G) equals
er
income (Y2). Therefore, income level Y2 corresponds to the interest rate r2, satisfying equilibrium in the product
iv
market. This (Y2, r2) combination point is placed at E2 in Panel C. By joining all points such as E1, and E2, we
can draw the IS curve.
Un
A given reduction in the interest rate, from r1 to r2, raises the intercept of the aggregate demand curves by
the same vertical distance, as shown in Panel A of Fig. 4.2. However, the implied change in income is larger than
d
the change in investment demand because of the multiplier effect. The larger the mpc, the larger the change in
or
Y = a + b (1− t )Y + a1 − b1r + G
or, (4.3)
{1− b (1− t )}Y = a + a1 − b1r + G
From equation 4.3, it is clear that an increase in the interest rate reduces aggregate demand.
Alternatively, by using savings−investment equality, the equation of the IS curve is
S +T = I +G
or,
− a + {1− t − b(1− t )}Y + tY = a1 − b1r + G (4.4)
or,
[1− b(1− t )]Y = a + a1 − b1r + G
s
the linear consumption schedule. In quadrant 3,
es
S, T
a 45º diagonal line is used to find out equilibrium
Fig. 4.3 Derivation of IS curve: investment−savings in the product market. The IS curve is derived in
Pr
approach quadrant 1.
At an interest rate r1, investment plus
y
government expenditure is I1 + G. Point E1 in quadrant 3 determines equilibrium in the product market
sit
by equating I1 + G to S1 + T at income level Y1. Therefore, the combination of Y1 income and r1 interest
rate keeps the product market in equilibrium, which is shown by point E1 in the first quadrant. Points
er
E1 shown in the first and third quadrants represent the same equilibrium. A fall in the interest rate to r2
iv
raises investment to I2, increasing the level of spending at each income level. The new equilibrium point
Un
E2 requires higher savings at S2 corresponding to higher income level Y2. In the first quadrant, point E2
records the new equilibrium in the product market corresponding to (Y2, r2) combination of income and
interest rate. We can apply the same procedure to all conceivable levels of the interest rate and thereby
d
generate all the points that make up the IS curve. Thus, by joining all combination points such as E1 and
or
The IS curve is negatively sloped reflecting the increase in aggregate demand associated with a reduction in the
interest rate. Therefore, the lower the rate of interest, the higher the income by maintaining the product market
in equilibrium. We can calculate the slope of the IS curve from either equation 4.3 or 4.4:
dr 1 − b (1 − t )
= (4.5)
dY −b1
dr
As 0 < b < 1, 0 < t < 1, and b1 > 0, the slope of the IS curve, <0
dY
The steepness of the curve depends on how sensitive investment spending is to changes in the interest
rate. Suppose that investment spending is very sensitive to the interest rate, so that b1 in equation 4.5 is large,
that is, a given change in the interest rate produces a large change in investment demand and also aggregate
demand that produces ultimately a large change in equilibrium income. If investment is very sensitive to the
interest rate, the IS curve is very flat. Conversely, if b1 is small and investment spending is not very sensitive
to the interest rate, the IS curve is relatively steep. If investment is perfectly interest elastic or the investment
schedule is horizontal, the IS curve will be horizontal to the income axis. On the other hand, if investment is
perfectly interest inelastic, that is, the investment schedule is vertical, the IS curve will be vertical.
s
in equilibrium, savings plus tax will I + G1 I + G E1 E11
es
also be more, which corresponds to r1
higher income Y11. Therefore, the new
Pr
E2 E21
combination of income and interest r2 IS1
rate (Y11, r1) produces equilibrium in
y
IS
I2 + G I1 + G G
sit
the product market at the increased
I, G O Y1 Y2 Y11 Y21 Y
level of government expenditure. An
45°
er
increase in aggregate demand due to S1 + T
higher government spending shifts the
iv
expenditure
horizontal shift of the IS schedule is equal
O
We have shown the shifts of the IS schedule owing to an increase in mpc, or a decrease in mps, in Fig. 4.5.
A fall in mps shifts the S + T schedule rightwards. This is because when mps declines, other things remain
the same, people will save less at the
r
given level of income. In other words,
E1 a fall in mps or a rise in mpc means
I+G
r1 a rise in aggregate demand through
E2
more consumption, which produces
r2 more income. Therefore, a given rate
IS1
of interest corresponds to higher
I2 + G I1 + G IS
G income to keep the product market
I, G O Y1 Y2 Y in equilibrium. Thus, a fall in mps shifts
45°
S1 + T
the IS schedule rightwards. However,
in this case, the slope of the IS schedule
s
also changes, implying that the change
S2 + T
es
S+T
in mps or mps does not produce a
parallel shift.
Pr
S, T
4.2.4 Points off the IS Curve
y
Fig. 4.5 Shifts of the IS curve due to an increase in mpc
It is clear that any combination point
sit
of income and interest rate on the
IS curve satisfies the equilibrium condition in a sense that planned
er
r
output is exactly equal to planned demand, and, hence, no unintended
iv
but point E3 lies below the curve, while point E4 is above the curve.
or
E2
At point E3, we have the same level of income, Y1 as at E1, but the
E3
r2 interest rate is lower. Therefore, the demand for investment is higher
xf
IS
than at E3, and the demand for goods is higher than at E1. This means
O
O Y1 Y2 Y
that aggregate demand exceeds the level of output, and so there is
an excess demand for goods generating a fall in inventory. On the
Fig. 4.6 Disequilibrium in the product other hand, at point E4, the interest rate is higher than at E2. Thus,
market investment demand and aggregate demand are lower than at E2. There
is an excess supply of goods at point E4, raising the inventory level.
Therefore, points above the IS schedule correspond to an excess supply of goods, and points below relate to
an excess demand for goods.
Problem 4.1 Find an equation of the IS curve in a closed economy where the consumption, investment, and
government expenditure are
C = 350 + 0.3Y; I = 120 − 40r; G = 120
What value of the real interest rate clears the goods market when Y = 600? Calculate the slope of the IS curve.
Solution The IS curve represents equilibrium in the product market. Therefore, the equation of the IS curve is
Y=C+I+G
or, Y = 350 + 0.3Y + 120 − 40r + 120
or, 0.7Y + 40r = 590
When Y = 600, 40r = 590 − 420 = 170 or, r = 4.25
dr
Slope of the IS curve, = −0.0175
dY
s
demand is equal to the nominal money demand divided by the price level. If the nominal money demand is `500
es
and the price level is `5, then the real money demand is 100. The real money demand is called the demand for real
balances. People create demand for real balances because money has some important functions. We will discuss in
Pr
detail different functions of money in Chapter 5. In the context of demand for money, we are now mentioning two
important functions of money: money functions as a medium of exchange, and money functions as a store of value.
y
sit
Money is the means by which we purchase goods and services. Money facilitates the exchange, because everyone
is willing to accept money as a medium of exchange for whatever it is that one might want to buy or sell. It is also
er
very easily divisible to the scale of what is being exchanged. Money is a store of value because it is a liquid asset. The
liquidity of an asset refers to how quickly the asset can be turned into cash, and since money is already cash, it is
iv
the most liquid asset possible. This is probably the reason that so many people hold onto cash as a store of value.
Un
Given our explanations of the functions of money, it will not be surprising that there are three different types
of demand for money. In Keynes’s theory, money is demanded due to three main motives: transactions motive,
precautionary motive, and speculative motive. The transactions motive gives rise to the transactions demand
d
for money, which refers to the demand for cash by the people for making current transactions of all kinds. The
or
precautionary motive induces the public to hold money to provide for contingencies requiring sudden expenditure
xf
and for unforeseen opportunities of advantageous purchases. This demand arises because of uncertainties. The
speculative motive giving rise to the speculative demand for money is the most important contribution Keynes
O
made to the theory of the demand for money. The transactions and precautionary motives are related to the
medium of exchange function of money. The asset demand for money is connected with the speculative motive.
income. Therefore, the transactions demand for money depends on income. If the volume of income and output
produced in the goods markets increases, then clearly there will be a larger volume of transactions and exchanges
taking place. People will need to hold a larger volume of money to meet all these transactions and make payments.
The transactions demand for money is a demand for active balances because it is used as a means of payments in
national income-generating transactions.
s
demand for money depends on income (Y).
es
As both the transactions demand and precautionary demand for money depend on income, we can express
these demands for money (L1) together:
Pr
dL1
L1 = L1 (Y ) , L1′ = >0 (4.6)
dY
y
sit
Keynes retained the influence of the Cambridge approach to the demand for money under which money
demand is assumed to be a function of income (Y). The transactions demand for money in Keynes’s version is
er
similar to the Cambridge version of the classical money demand function. Thus, Keynes’s transactions demand
iv
L1 = kPY (4.7)
Here, k is constant and similar to income velocity of money, P is price level which is assumed to be constant
in Keynes’s framework. Therefore, the transactions and precautionary demand schedule will be an upward rising
d
There is one other reason why people have a demand for holding money balances. This is called the speculative
O
motive. People hold money as a financial asset just like stocks and
Y bonds. Holding money as a liquid asset is using money as a store
of value. Thus, the speculative demand for money is a demand
L1 = kPY for idle balances. An individual has to decide how to allocate the
financial wealth between alternative types of assets. Decisions
on the form in which to hold assets are portfolio decisions. For
the sake of simplicity, Keynes assumed that perpetual bonds
are the only non-money financial asset in the economy, which
compete with money in the asset portfolio of the people. Bonds
have returns in the form of interest rates, while money has no
return. On the other hand, money has liquidity, but bonds have
O L1
no liquidity. The more bonds held, the more interest received on
Fig. 4.7 Transactions and precautionary total financial wealth. The more money held, the more likely the
demand for money individual is to have liquidity. The portfolio decisions on how
much money to hold and on how many bonds to hold are really the same decision. This is because the sum of
the individual’s demand for money and demand for bonds has to add up to that person’s total financial wealth.
A decision to hold more money means a decision to hold less bonds. The wealth budget constraint implies that
when the money market is in equilibrium, the bond market also is in equilibrium. This implication allows us to
discuss assets markets entirely in terms of the money market.
Money does not earn any interest income. However, money is a certain asset in a sense that its capital value
in terms of itself is always fixed. In other words, the nominal value of a `10 note is always `10. Money is a liquid
asset. People create demand for money only because of its liquidity. Money is the most liquid asset and the cost
of holding money as an asset is the foregone interest rate. Thus, there is an inverse relationship between the
interest rate and the asset demand for money. If the interest rate goes up, the demand for liquidity goes down
and vice versa.
Bonds, on the other hand, yield interest income to their holders adjusted by capital gain or capital loss. It
can be shown algebraically that the price of a (perpetual) bond is given by the reciprocal of the market rate of
s
interest times the coupon rate of interest. Suppose the coupon rate (i.e., interest payable on a bond) is `1 per year
es
and the market rate of interest is 4% per year. Then, the market price of the bond will be `1/0.04 × 1 = `25. If
the market rate of interest rises to 5% per year, the market price of the bond will fall to `1/0.05 × 1 = `20. Thus,
Pr
bond price is seen as an inverse function of the interest rate. Bond prices keep on changing from time to time.
Therefore, they are subject to capital gains or losses. Thus, to a bond-holder, the return from bond-holding per
y
unit period (say a year) per `1 is the rate of interest ± capital gain or loss per year.
sit
er
A bond is a promise by a borrower to pay the lender a certain amount (the principal) at a specified
iv
date (the maturity date of the bond) and to pay a given amount of interest per year in the meantime. A
Un
perpetuity is a bond which promises to pay interest forever, but not to repay the principal on the bond.
Equities or stocks are claims to a share of the profits of an enterprise. The shareholder, or stockholder,
receives the return on equity in two forms: dividends and capital gain. The stockholders may receive a
d
certain amount for each share they own in the form of dividends. Sometimes firms decide not to distribute
profits to the stockholders but retain the profits and reinvest them by adding to the firms’ stocks of
or
machines and structures. In this case, the shares become more valuable, the price of the stock in the
market will rise, and stockholders can make capital gains. A capital gain is an increase in the price of
xf
The speculators are of two kinds: bulls and bears. Bulls are those who expect the bond prices to rise in the
future. Bears expect these prices to fall. In Keynes’s model, these expectations are assumed to be held with certainty.
Bulls, then, are assumed to invest all their idle cash into bonds and bears prefer more liquidity to bonds. To
move to the aggregate speculative demand for money, Keynes assumed that different asset holders have different
interest-rate expectations. Thus, at a very high rate of interest (and very low bond price), investors may behave
like bulls. Then, the speculative demand for money will be equal to zero. However, at a very low rate of interest
(very high bond price), investors will behave like bears and the demand for speculative balances will very high.
Thus, Keynes’s speculative demand for money is inversely related to the interest rate.
If we denote the speculative demand for money as L2 and the interest rate as r, Keynes’s speculative demand
function can be written as
dL
L2 = L2 ( r ) , L2′ = 2 < 0 (4.8)
dr
s
every investor in the asset market behaves like bears. As the interest rate is very low, everybody prefers liquidity
es
and the liquidity preference function becomes perfectly interest elastic. This phase in the speculative demand
function is known as liquidity trap in Keynes’s theory and this trap appeared during the phase of deep depression.
Pr
The liquidity trap refers to a situation when at a certain rate of interest the speculative demand for money becomes
perfectly elastic. This will come about when at that rate all the asset holders turn bears, so that none is willing to hold
y
bonds and everyone wants to move into cash. At the rate of interest r2, expansion of money supply cannot lower the
sit
rate of interest further. The people are willing to hold the entire extra amount of money in the form of cash at r2. The
extra liquidity created by the monetary authority gets trapped in the asset portfolios of the people without lowering r.
er
Keynes’s theory of liquidity preference has been called into question by Tobin (1958).1 In Keynes’s theory,
iv
there is no uncertainty in interest-rate expectations. Unlike Keynes, Tobin assumes that an individual investor does
Un
hold his interest-rate expectations with uncertainty in the form of capital loss. Liquidity preference is analysed
as behaviour towards risk under uncertainty. The degree of risk increases with the increase in the proportion
of bonds in the asset portfolio. Asset holders need higher compensation in the form of rate of interest for
d
undertaking higher risk. Thus, at higher interest rates, more bonds and less money will be held in the portfolio,
or
and at lower interest rates, less bonds and more money will be preferred. The result is a diversified asset portfolio
and a downward sloping asset demand curve for money with respect to the interest rate.
xf
Keynes’s theory of the speculative demand for money has also been criticized on the ground that bonds
O
are taken as representative of all non-money financial assets. In reality, however, a large number of non-money
financial assets are not similar to bonds. Examples of such assets include fixed deposits with commercial banks.
Substitution between them and money does not entail Keynes’s speculative motive, because they are not subject
to variation in their nominal capital values. In their case, their rates of return influence as simple opportunity-
cost variables without any element of speculation.
Also, as in Baumol−Tobin theory, the transactions demand for money also is interest elastic. The same can
be argued for the precautionary demand for money too. The explanation of the speculative demand for money
shows that this kind of demand will be an increasing function of total assets or wealth. If income is taken as a
proxy for wealth, the speculative demand also becomes a function of both income and the rate of interest.
Keynes’s money demand function can be specified as
dL1 dL
L = L1 (Y ) + L2 ( r ) , L1′ = > 0, L2′ = 2 < 0 (4.9)
dY dr
1
Tobin, James (1958). Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk, The Review of Economic Studies, 25, 65−86.
Here, L is the total demand for money which is an additive demand function with two separate components.
The first part, L1(Y), represents the transactions and precautionary demand for money. Keynes made both
an increasing function of the level of money income. In the Cambridge tradition, he tended to assume that
L1(Y) had a proportional form of the kind represented in Fig. 4.7. The second component, L2(r), represents the
speculative demand for money, which, as shown earlier, Keynes argued to be a declining function of interest rate.
As shown in Fig. 4.8, this relation was not assumed to be linear.
Keynes’s additive form of the demand function for money has been discarded by Keynesians and other
economists. In addition, we can write the Keynesian money demand function as
∂L ∂L
L = L (Y , r ) , > 0, <0 (4.10)
∂Y ∂r
Here, it is hypothesized that L is an increasing function of Y and a decreasing function of r.
s
4.3.4 Supply of Money
es
In developing the LM curve, we assume that the entire money supply is an exogenous variable that is directly
under the control of the central bank. The assumption that the money supply is exogenous is broadly correct,
Pr
although it is oversimplified, since strictly speaking the central bank (e.g., Reserve Bank of India) can directly
control only a small part of the stock of money. The theory of the demand for money is a theory about how the
y
sit
real value of money depends on income and the interest rate, but the theory of the money supply is a theory
of how the nominal quantity of money is controlled by the central bank. The real supply of money depends
er
not only on the behaviour of the central bank, but also on the price level. To complete our development of the
LM curve, we will assume that the price level is exogenous.
iv
The demand for money is the purchasing power of money (real balances). The supply of money M is determined
by the central bank, and its purchasing power is M/P, where P is the price level. It is assumed that the central
d
bank has full control of the nominal money supply. The money market is in equilibrium when the demand for
or
real balances equals the supply. We can write the equilibrium in the money market as
xf
M
= L (Y , r )
O
P
M
or, = L1 (Y ) + L2 ( r ) (4.11)
P
Here, we have assumed the expected rate of inflation to be zero and therefore the nominal and real rate
of interests are identical. Equation 4.11 shows several pairs of income (Y) and interest rate (r) that satisfy the
equilibrium condition in the money market.
The LM curve represents the pairs of income and interest rate that will keep the money market in equilibrium
with a given level of money supply and a given price level. The locus of all (y, r) combination points satisfying
money market equilibrium as given in equation 4.11 is called the LM curve. In other words, the combinations of
interest rates and income levels on the LM curve are such that the demand for real balances exactly matches the
available supply. The LM schedule, or the money market equilibrium schedule, shows all combinations of interest
rates and income levels such that the demand for real balances is equal to the supply. Along the LM schedule,
the money market is in equilibrium.
s
a decreasing function of interest
es
M
L1(Y)
rate. In the southwest quadrant,
we find out equilibrium in the
Pr
money market by equating the
L1 total demand for money to supply
given real money supply, M/P. At any point on the 45º line, the transactions demand and the speculative demand add
iv
up to the total money supply on each axis. This 45º line directly represents the money market equilibrium condition.
Un
We can now locate several pairs of (r, Y) that maintain the money market in equilibrium in the northeast
quadrant. At a given level of income at Y1, we can find L11 transactions demand for money from the schedule
L1(Y). We subtract this transactions demand from the money supply to find out the level of speculative demand
d
at L21 in maintaining money market equilibrium. This level of speculative demand shows the level of interest
or
rate r1 that will maintain money market equilibrium at income level Y1. Thus, we have a pair (Y1, r1) at point E1
in the northeast quadrant of Fig. 4.9. By repeating this process, we have another point E2. By joining all such
xf
0 = L1′dY + L2′dr
dr L′
or, =− 1 (4.12)
dY L2′
Equation 4.12 provides the slope of the LM curve. Here, L1′ = ∂L1 / ∂Y is the slope of transactions demand
for money and is positive; L2′ = ∂L2 / ∂r measures the slope of the speculative demand curve and is negative.
Therefore, the slope of the LM curve, dr/dY > 0, is positive. A rise in income increases the transactions demand
for money. The LM curve is positively sloped. An increase in the interest rate reduces the demand for real balances.
To maintain the demand for real balances equal to the fixed supply, the level of income has to rise. Accordingly,
money market equilibrium implies that an increase in the interest rate is accompanied by an increase in the level
of income.
It is clear from equation 4.12 that the greater the responsiveness of the demand for money to income ( L1′), and
the lower the responsiveness of the demand for money to the interest rate ( L2′ ) , the steeper the LM curve. If the
demand for money is relatively insensitive to the interest rate, so that L2′ is close to zero, the LM curve is nearly
vertical. If the demand for money is very sensitive to the interest rate, so that L2′ is large, then the LM curve is
close to horizontal. The horizontal part of the LM curve represents liquidity trap.
s
follows equilibrium in the money market in a sense that demand for real
es
balances equals the supply. Points below and to the right correspond to an B
E2
excess demand for real balances. Let us take a point E1 on the LM curve
Pr
where the combination of income and interest rate satisfies the money market
equilibrium condition. Let income level be increased while the rate of interest
y
A
remains the same as at point E1. An increase in income moves the combination E1
sit
point from E1 to A as shown in Fig. 4.10. As income is more at point A, demand
for money is higher than its supply. Thus, at point A, there is an excess demand O Y
er
for money. By a similar argument, we can say that points above and to the left Fig. 4.10 Points off the LM curve
iv
r
money market equilibrium. Now,
or
LM curve to the right (Fig. 4.11). An increase in the stock of real balances shifts the 45º line outwards in the
southwest quadrant from MM to M1M1. At the initial interest rate r1, the equilibrium income will be higher
to keep the money market in equilibrium. The equilibrium pair of income and interest rate shifts to the right
and, as a result, the LM schedule will shift to the right in the northeast quadrant. At each level of the interest
rate, the level of income has to be higher so as to raise the transactions demand for money and thereby absorb
the higher real money supply.
Problem 4.2 Suppose that the real money demand function is
L = 100 + 0.2Y − 200r
Assume that M = 300, P = 2.
Find out the LM curve equation.
What is the value of the interest rate when Y = 600?
Solution The LM curve represents money market equilibrium. Therefore, the equation of the LM curve is
s
es
M
= 100 + 0.2Y − 200r or, 150 = 100 + 0.2Y − 200r
Pr
P
or, 0.2Y − 200r = 50
y
sit
When Y = 600, 120 − 200r = 50 or, r = 0.35
dr
er
We are now ready to put together the two parts of the Keynesian theory of aggregate demand: the IS and LM
d
curves. John Hicks, a Nobel laureate (1974), devised the IS-LM model based on Keynes’s theory. IS stands
or
for investment-savings and LM for liquidity-money. The IS-LM model describes the aggregate demand of
the economy using the relationship between output and interest rates. Hicks allowed investment to be a
xf
function of interest rate. The IS equation shows an equilibrium relationship between the real income and the
O
real rate of interest. The higher the rate of interest, the lower is investment, and consequently income. Hicks
also considered the demand for and supply of liquidity or money, which depend on income and the nominal
rate of interest. An increase in income results in a higher demand for money and an increase in the interest
rate will decrease the demand. The reason is that the more income a nation has, the more transactions will be
made; hence, the more money needed. However, the interest rate is the price of money, and an increase in the
price will cut the demand.
The task of the IS−LM model is to determine income and interest rate simultaneously by the interaction
of the product and money markets. When we put together the IS and LM curves, we will be able to describe
the simultaneous determination of the nominal interest rate and income in an IS−LM equilibrium. When we
build the IS−LM model, we will take the price level as fixed. Thus, we may get different equilibrium points, the
points of intersection between the IS and LM curves, corresponding to different price levels. The relationship
between the price level and the equilibrium value of income in the IS−LM model is called the Keynesian aggregate
demand curve.
Figure 4.12 shows that the interest rate and the level of output are determined by the interaction of the money
(LM) and product (IS) markets. In Fig. 4.12, we have combined the LM curve with the IS curve. The IS curve, given
in equation 4.1, represents values of the interest rate and income for which
the product market is in equilibrium. Any point on the IS curve satisfies r LM
the product market equilibrium condition. The LM curve, presented in
equation 4.11, denotes values of the interest rate and income for which
the quantity of money demanded is equal to the quantity supplied. At
any point on the LM curve, the money market is in equilibrium. The rE E
s
The demand for goods is equal to the level of output on the IS curve. O YE Y
es
In addition, on the LM curve, the demand for money is equal to the Fig. 4.12 Equilibrium in the IS−LM
supply of money. Accordingly, at point E, firms produce their planned model
Pr
amount of output (there is no unintended inventory accumulation or
rundown), and individuals have the portfolio compositions they desire.
y
What would happen if the economy were at a point other than point E? The answer is that there are two
sit
forces pulling the economy back to the point of intersection of the IS and LM curves. First, suppose that the
economy is at a point that is below the IS curve. Points below the IS curve are points for which investment exceeds
er
savings. Investors will bid up the interest rate in an attempt to secure funds and the interest rate will rise. A similar
iv
argument establishes that points above the IS curve are points for which savings exceed investment. Investors will
Un
be able to offer lower interest rates since there is an excess of savers in the market and the interest rate will fall.
At any point to the left of the LM curve, income is lower than a point that is on the LM curve but with
the same interest rate. Since income is lower, the quantity of money demanded will also be lower. It follows
d
that points to the left of the LM curve are points for which there is an excess supply of money. Households are
or
holding more money than they need to finance their daily transactions and they will try to spend this money by
demanding more commodities; the aggregate demand for goods and services will increase. As demand increases,
xf
firms will hire more workers and employment and income will rise until the economy is back on the LM curve.
O
A similar argument establishes that if the economy is to the right of the LM curve, there is an excess demand for
money. Households will buy fewer commodities and aggregate demand will fall. As demand falls, firms will lay
off workers and employment and income will fall until the economy is back on the LM curve.
Income and interest rates adjust to the disequilibrium in goods markets and assets markets. Specifically,
interest rates fall when there is an excess supply of money and rise when there is an excess demand. Income rises
when aggregate demand for goods exceeds output and falls when aggregate demand is less than output. The
system converges over time to the equilibrium at E. Thus, there are forces that move the economy towards point
E, the IS−LM equilibrium point.
4.4.1 Derivation of Aggregate Demand Curve
The major assumption in IS−LM equilibrium is that the price level is constant and that firms are willing to
supply whatever amount of output is demanded at that price level. Let us look at how equilibrium income in
the IS−LM model is different for different values of the price level. The aggregate demand curve links the price
level to the aggregate quantity of commodities demanded. In the IS−LM model, the equilibrium output and the
interest rate are determined under the assumption that the price level remains the same. When the price level
changes and other factors remain the same, the position of the LM
r LM1 LM2 curve changes, and accordingly the equilibrium point will change.
Figure 4.13 derives the aggregate demand curve. In Panel A, we plot
the interest rate against income. We will use Panel A to show that
E1 the IS−LM equilibrium is different for different values of the price
r1 E2 level. We must know the price level to construct this diagram since
Panel A
r2 the real value of the supply of money depends on it. Given the price
level P1, the LM curve is LM1. The equilibrium point is determined
IS at E1 where output and interest rate are determined at Y1 and r1,
respectively. Tracing equilibrium income down to Panel B gives a
O Y1 Y2 Y point, E1, corresponding to the equilibrium point, on the Keynesian
s
aggregate demand curve.
es
Let the price level drops from P1 to P2. If price level falls to P2,
the supply of real balances will increase and the LM curve shifts in
Pr
P1 E1
the rightward direction to LM2 as shown in Panel A. Given the IS
P2 E2 curve, the equilibrium point shifts to E2, where output is determined
Panel B
y
at Y2. The price output combination point is plotted at E2 in Panel B.
sit
By joining all such points in Panel B, we have drawn a downward
sloping curve. This curve resembles the aggregate demand curve.
er
Y1 Y2
market and the money market are in equilibrium.
Un
corresponds to a situation in which both the IS and LM equations hold. The same interest rate and income
or
levels ensure equilibrium in both the goods and the money market. In terms of the equations, this means that
we have to solve the IS curve equation (4.1) and LM curve equation (4.11) simultaneously to get equilibrium
xf
values of Y and r. For simultaneous equilibrium, interest rates and income levels have to be such that both the
O
goods market and the money market are in equilibrium. We reproduce here the IS curve equation and the LM
curve equation as shown in equations 4.1 and 4.11, respectively, as
M
Y = C (Y − t(Y )) + I ( r ) + G ; = L1 (Y ) + L2 ( r )
P
By solving these equations, we will get equilibrium income and interest rate in the IS−LM model. To understand
how to calculate equilibrium income and interest rate in the IS−LM framework, let us consider the following
IS and LM curve equations:
Y = b (1 − t )Y − b1r + G (4.13)
M
m=
= l1Y − l2 r (4.14)
P
Here, m denotes real balances, l1 is income sensitivity of money demand, and l2 is interest sensitivity of
money demand.
s
es
m l
− {1 − b(1 − t )} + 1 G
m{1 − b(1 − t )} − l1G l2 l2
r= =
Pr
(4.17)
− l2 {1 − b(1 − t )} + l1b1 l
1 − b(1 − t ) − 1 b1
l2
y
sit
Equation 4.17 shows that the equilibrium interest rate depends on the parameters of fiscal policy captured
in the multiplier and the term G and on the real money stock, m. A higher real money stock implies a lower
er
Equilibrium in both the goods and money markets is simultaneously attained where the IS and LM curves intersect,
that is, at point E in Fig. 4.12. Two points are worth emphasizing. First, the intersection of the two curves in
d
Fig. 4.12 determines the values of the rate of interest and income which are consistent with equilibrium in both
or
markets. Second, if the level of income is below that of full employment, then both fiscal and monetary policies
have a potentially important role to play in stabilizing the economy. We now briefly review what determines the
xf
relative effectiveness of fiscal and monetary policies in influencing aggregate demand and therefore the level of
O
The equilibrium levels of income and the interest rate change when E2
either the IS or the LM curve shifts. The fiscal policy multiplier r2
E1
shows how much an increase in government spending, or a cut r1
E3
in tax rate, changes the equilibrium level of income, holding the IS2
real money supply constant. Figure 4.14 shows the effects of an IS1
increase in government expenditure on equilibrium income and
interest rate. An increase in government spending shifts the IS
schedule out and to the right from IS1 to IS2. The shift of the
O Y1 Y2 Y3 Y
IS curve, given the LM curve at its initial position, results in a
rise in the level of income from Y1 to Y2 and an increase in the Fig. 4.14 Effects of an increase in
interest rate from r1 to r2 by the movement of equilibrium from government expenditure
E1 to E2. Here, the change in income is Y1Y2, which is clearly less than the horizontal shift in the IS curve.
If, somehow the interest rate remains at r1, the increase in income (Y1Y3) equals the length of the horizontal
shift of the IS curve.
The increase in government spending does tend to increase the level of income. However, an increase in
income increases the demand for money. With the supply of money fixed, the interest rate has to rise to ensure
that the demand for money stays equal to the fixed supply. When the interest rate rises, investment spending
is reduced because investment is negatively related to the interest rate. Accordingly, the change in equilibrium
income is less than the change in the simple Keynesian model.
The government expenditure multiplier in the IS−LM framework can be obtained directly from the
expression of equilibrium income shown in equation 4.16. We allow Y to change when G changes with
fixed money supply and other parameters. Thus, by taking the total differential of equation 4.16 and keeping
dm = 0, we have
− l 2 dG dG
s
dY = =
−l2 {1 − b(1 − t )} + l1b1 1 − b(1 − t ) − l1 b
es
1
l2
Pr
dY 1
y
or, = (4.18)
dG 1 − b(1 − t ) − l1 b
sit
1
l2
er
Similarly, the change in interest rate due to change in government spending is obtained from equation 4.17:
iv
l1
dG
Un
−l1dG l2
dr = =
−l2 {1 − b(1 − t )} + l1b1 1 − b(1 − t ) − l1 b
d
1
l2
or
l1
xf
dr l2
or, = (4.19)
O
dG 1 − b(1 − t ) − l1 b
1
l2
Equations 4.18 and 4.19 provide the rate of change of income and interest rate due to the change in government
expenditure. The expression given in 4.18 is known as the government expenditure multiplier in the IS−LM
model. If we compare the IS−LM multiplier with the simple Keynesian multiplier, it would be clear that the
value of the multiplier in the IS−LM model is less than the value of multiplier in the simple Keynesian model.
This is because of the additional term in the denominator, − (l1/l2) b1, in equation 4.18. Here, l1/l2 is the slope of
the LM curve given in equation 4.14. It gives the increase in r that is needed for money market equilibrium with
the increase in Y. Since b1, the slope of the linear investment function, gives the change in investment that comes
from change in r, the expression − l1/l2 b1 then gives the decrease in investment that comes from the interest rate
increase as Y and r rise along the LM curve.
The tax rate is another important fiscal instrument by which the government can control aggregate demand.
To find out the tax cut multiplier, let us take the equilibrium condition in the product market as shown in
the IS curve equation (4.13) and the money market equilibrium condition is given in the LM curve equation
shown in (4.14):
Y = b (1 − t )Y − b1r + G
M
m= = l1Y − l2 r
P
To calculate the tax cut multiplier, we have to keep government expenditure and real money supply constant,
and we can allow the tax rate (t) to change. Taking the total differential of equations 4.13 and 4.14, we have the
following expressions:
dY = b ( dY − tdY − Ydt ) + b1dr
or, (4.20)
{1 − b(1 − t )} dy − b1dr = −bYdt
s
es
l1 (4.21)
l1dy − l2 dr = 0 or, dr =
Pr
dy
l2
y
sit
Substituting the value of dr from (4.21) into (4.20) gives us
er
l
{1 − b(1 − t )} dY − b1 1 dY = −bYdt
l2 (4.22)
iv
−bYdt
or, dY =
Un
l1
1 − b(1 − t ) − b1
l2
d
The numerator of equation 4.22 simply converts the tax change into the policy-induced change in consumer
or
expenditure. The term Ydt is the change in disposable income that comes directly from the change in tax rate.
Thus, the term bYdt is the change in consumption spending that comes from the change in disposable income.
xf
The negative sign implies that when tax rates go down, the policy-induced consumption expenditure goes up.
O
By comparing equations 4.18 and 4.22, we can say that the tax cut multiplier is similar to the government
expenditure multiplier.
when the more interest-elastic is the demand for money (the flatter is the LM curve), and the less interest-elastic
is investment (the steeper is the IS curve). In the limiting cases of a vertical LM curve (classical range), fiscal
expansion will have no effect on income. In this phase, the rise in the rate of interest will reduce private investment
by an amount identical to the increase in government expenditure producing full crowding out. At the other
extreme, a horizontal LM curve (liquidity trap) provides the full multiplier effect of the simple Keynesian model.
How effective the fiscal policy is depends on the rate of fall of private investment owing to the rise in interest
rate induced by the fall in speculative demand for money. The fall in investment due to the rise in interest rate along
the LM curve induced by the increase in autonomous spending is known as the crowding out effect. The government
expenditure multiplier is reduced by this crowding out effect. The effect depends on the slope of the LM curve.
Given the slope of the IS curve, the crowding out is higher the more inelastic the LM curve. Given the slope of the
LM curve, the crowding out is higher the more elastic the IS curve. An expansionary fiscal policy (increasing in G
or decreasing in T) is more effective in affecting the level of real income, and the lower is the crowding out effect.
If the LM curve is horizontal, there will be no crowding out effect and full expansionary effect will be obtained
s
(Fig. 4.15). The increase in government expenditure causes the level
es
of income to rise by Y1Y2. This amounts to the full multiplier times LM
the increase in G. If the increase in G is not tax financed and the r
Pr
money supply is fixed, the funds are obtained by borrowing from the IS6
non-bank private sector of the economy. This type of fiscal policy is a r IS5
y
pure fiscal policy. As the interest elasticity of the demand for money
6
sit
is infinite, a very small increase in interest rate resulting from deficit
financing will decrease the liquidity preference. Thus, a larger level r5
er
IS3 IS4
of transactions has to be financed by a fixed money supply. In the
iv
IS2
new equilibrium, the rate of interest will be the same as before. As a IS1
Un
O Y1 Y2 Y3 Y4 Y5 Y
the multiplier effect will be full. If the LM curve is horizontal, then
the interest rate will not change when the IS curve shifts. This is the Fig. 4.15 Expansionary effects at different
xf
pure Keynesian situation where the fiscal policy will be fully effective. cyclical positions
O
The orthodox Keynesian faith in the effectiveness of fiscal policy has been challenged by, among others,
monetarists who typically argue that in the long run ‘pure’ fiscal expansion (i.e., expansion without any
accommodating changes in the money supply) will result in the crowding out or replacement of components of
private expenditure with relatively minor effects on aggregate demand, the level of income, and employment.
A number of reasons as to why crowding out can occur in the IS−LM framework have been put forward in the
literature, which do not rely on the demand for money being perfectly interest inelastic (a vertically sloped LM
curve), including expectations and wealth effects (Carlson and Spencer).2
dY = b ( dY − tdY ) + b1dr
s
or, (4.23)
es
{1 − b(1 − t )} dY − b1dr = 0
Pr
l1 1
l1dy − l2 dr = dm or, dr = dy − dm (4.24)
l2 l2
y
sit
By substituting dr from (4.24) into (4.23), we have
er
l 1
{1 − b(1 − t )}dY − b1 1 dY − dm = 0
iv
l l
Un
2 2
b1
dm
d
l2
or, dY = (4.25)
or
l
1 − b(1 − t ) − 1 b1
l2
xf
O
Equation 4.25 provides the monetary policy multiplier. The smaller l2 and l1 and the larger b1, the more
expansionary the effect of an increase in real balances on the equilibrium level of income. Large b1 corresponds
to a very flat IS schedule. The monetary policy multiplier is illustrated in Fig. 4.16. An increase in M will shift
the LM curve to the right, by an amount given by the change in M. Let the initial LM curve be LM1. After the
increase in M, the new LM curve is LM2. As we can see the effect is an increase in income from Y1 to Y2 and a
reduction in interest rate from r1 to r2. Thus, an increase in money supply (everything else constant) will increase
the equilibrium level of income and decrease the equilibrium interest rate. The idea is that an increase in the
money supply, given the money demand, will create an excess of money in the money market. To eliminate
this excess of money, the theory of liquidity preference says that the interest rate must decrease. However, if
the interest rate decreases, investment will increase and therefore income will increase. As income increases,
money demand increases, helping to restore the equilibrium in the money market. The process ends at the new
equilibrium E2 determining new income and interest rate at Y2 and r2, respectively. It should be evident that a
2
Keith M. Carlson and Roger W. Spencer, “Crowding Out and Its Critics,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, December 1975, pp. 2−17.
s
and the degree to which investment responds to a fall in
es
the rate of interest. We can verify that monetary policy will be more effective in influencing aggregate demand
and therefore the level of output and employment when the demand for money is more interest inelastic (the
Pr
steeper is the LM curve), and the investment is more interest elastic (the flatter is the IS curve). In the extreme
Keynesian cases of either a horizontal LM curve (liquidity trap) or a vertical IS curve (investment is completely
y
interest inelastic), the transmission mechanism breaks down and monetary policy will have no effect on the
sit
level of income. In the case of the liquidity trap, the interest rate is at the lowest possible level and the additional
liquidity would not have any effect on the interest rate and on investment.
er
Figure 4.17 shows how the monetary policy affects the level of income and the interest rate. If the IS schedule
iv
(IS1) cuts the LM curve in the Keynesian liquidity trap region, the increase in the money supply will not affect the
Un
level of income and the interest rate at all. A very little fall in the interest rate produces an unlimited preference
for liquidity so that all the added money balances move into idle holdings and none move into added transaction
balances. In equilibrium, therefore, the rate of interest remains the same. Investment is not stimulated and the
d
level of income remains unchanged. Thus, if liquidity trap prevails as in deep depression, monetary policy is
or
in increasing the level of income along with the rise in interest rate.
LM
O
r LM1 Thus, there will be crowding out effect due to the fall in investment
IS3 because of the rise in interest rate induced by the increasing money
supply. In this case, part of the increase in money supply is absorbed
into active balance in the form of transactions demand for money
and the rest into liquidity preference. The interest rate declines
IS2 and investment will increase, but not to the full extent. The level of
IS1 income will rise only partially as shown in equation 4.25. Therefore,
if the LM curve is upward rising, known as the general Keynesian
range, the monetary policy is partially effective.
If the IS curve (IS3) cuts the LM curve in the vertical part
of the LM curve representing the cyclical phase as described by
O Y classical economists, the monetary policy will be fully effective.
Fig. 4.17 Expansionary effects of monetary In this phase, the prices of government bonds would be bid
policy up enough that other assets are relatively more attractive than
government bonds. There will be no liquidity preference because of high interest rates and wealth holders will
use added money balances to purchase other earning assets. In other words, the added money supply will move
into investment in other earning assets such as new securities or new investment in physical capital in the real
sector. New capital investment will raise the level of income, raising the transactions demand for money. Wealth
holders will continue to compete for earning assets, bond prices continue to rise, and interest rates continue to
fall until the point is reached where new investment raises the level of income exactly enough to absorb added
money balances into transactions.
From the earlier discussion, it should be evident that, while both fiscal and monetary policies can, in normal
circumstances, be used to influence the level of output and employment, the relative effectiveness of these two
policy instruments depends on the structural parameters of the model, that is, the relative slopes of the IS and LM
curves. Within the orthodox Keynesian approach, the demand for money has traditionally been viewed as being
highly responsive to changes in the rate of interest (generating a relatively flat LM curve), while investment has
been taken as being fairly unresponsive to changes in the rate of interest (generating a relatively steep IS curve).
s
es
Pr
SUMMARY
• The IS curve is the locus of combinations of the interest
y
of which the value is fixed in terms of money to meet
rate and level of income such that the product market
sit
a subsequent liability in terms of money.
is in equilibrium. • People hold money as a financial asset just like stocks
• The
er
IS curve is negatively sloped, implying that and bonds. Holding money as a liquid asset is using
an increase in the interest rate reduces planned money as a store of value. This is called the speculative
iv
investment spending and therefore reduces aggregate motive. The speculative demand for money is a demand
demand, reducing the equilibrium level of income. for idle balances. Keynes’s speculative demand for
Un
• The less sensitive investment spending is to changes money is inversely related to the interest rate.
in the interest rate, the steeper the IS curve. • The liquidity trap refers to a situation when at a certain
• The IS curve is shifted by changes in autonomous rate of interest the speculative demand for money
d
including an increase in government purchases, shifts • Money market equilibrium implies that an increase
the IS curve out to the right. in the interest rate is accompanied by an increase in
xf
• At points to the right of the curve, there is excess the level of income.
• The
O
supply in the goods market; at points to the left of LM curve is the schedule of combinations of
the curve, there is excess demand for goods. income and interest rates such that the money market
• In Keynes’s theory, money is demanded due to three is in equilibrium.
main motives: transactions motive, precautionary • The LM curve is positively sloped. Given the fixed
motive, and speculative motive. money supply, an increase in the level of income, which
• The transactions demand for money is using money as increases the quantity of money demanded, has to
a medium of exchange. People want to hold money for be accompanied by an increase in the interest rate.
transactions purposes to bridge the gap between the This reduces the quantity of money demanded and
earning point and the spending point. The transactions thereby maintains money market equilibrium.
demand for money is a demand for active balance • TheLM curve is shifted by changes in the money
because it is used as a means of payments in national supply. An increase in the money supply shifts the
income-generating transactions. LM curve to the right.
• Precautionary demands for money are those that are • Atpoints to the right of the LM curve, there is an
held to provide for contingencies requiring sudden excess demand for money, and at points to its left,
expenditure and for unforeseen opportunities of there is an excess supply of money.
advantageous purchases, and also to hold an asset
• The interest rate and level of output are jointly LM curve is upward rising as in the case of a general
determined by the simultaneous equilibrium of the Keynesian model, the fiscal policy effect is partial. If
goods and money markets. This occurs at the point the LM schedule is vertical, the expansionary effect
of intersection of the IS and LM curves. will be fully crowded out and the value of the fiscal
• The fiscal policy multiplier shows how much an increase policy multiplier is zero.
in government spending, or a cut in tax rate, changes • The effectiveness of monetary policy depends on the
the equilibrium level of income, holding the real money degree to which the rate of interest falls following an
supply constant. increase in the money supply, and the degree to which
• The fall in investment due to the rise in interest investment responds to a fall in the rate of interest. If
rate along the LM curve induced by the increase in liquidity trap prevails as in deep depression, monetary
autonomous spending is known as the crowding out policy is totally ineffective in expanding the economy, or
effect. The effect depends on the slope of the LM curve. in controlling inflation. If the LM curve is upward rising,
• The monetary policy multiplier shows how much an known as the general Keynesian range, the monetary
increase in the real money supply increases the equilibrium policy is partially effective. If the IS curve cuts the LM
level of income, keeping fiscal policy unchanged. curve in the vertical part of the LM curve representing
s
the cyclical phase as described by classical economists,
• If the LM curve is horizontal, there will be no crowding
es
the monetary policy will be fully effective.
out effect and fiscal policy will be fully effective. If the
y Pr
sit
EXERCISES
er
4.1 What is an IS curve? 4.15 Explain graphically how the LM curve shifts with a
4.2 Why is the IS curve negatively sloped? change in money supply. [C.U., 2013]
iv
4.3 What is an LM curve? 4.16 Discuss Keynes’s theory of demand for money.
Un
4.8 Show how equilibrium level of income and interest rate 4.18 Suppose that the government adopts an expansionary
are simultaneously determined in the IS−LM model. fiscal policy by way of increasing autonomous
xf
4.9 The relative effectiveness of the fiscal and monetary government expenditure. Show that the resulting
O
policies depends on the slopes of IS and LM curves. expansionary impact on the equilibrium income will
Explain. be less in the IS−LM model than that in the simple
4.10 Show with the help of a diagram that the extent of Keynesian model. [C.U., 2015]
change in national income arising from an increase in 4.19 Consider the following economy:
government expenditure depends on the elasticity of
C = 200 + 0.5Y
demand for money. [C.U., 2012]
4.11 How are interest rate and national income affected by a I = 200 − 500r
rise in the supply of money? [C.U., 2012] G = 150
4.12 Indicate briefly the aspects of effectiveness and L = 0.5Y − 250r
limitations of fiscal policy. M = 4900
4.13 Discuss with the help of the IS−LM model the
P = 10
effectiveness of fiscal policy in increasing national
income. [C.U., 2013] (a) Find out the equation of the IS curve.
4.14 Derive graphically the IS curve. [C.U., 2013] (b) Find out the equation of the LM curve.
(c) Find out the equilibrium values of Y and r.