Determinants of Sovereign Risk: Macroeconomic Fundamentals and The Pricing of Sovereign Debt
Determinants of Sovereign Risk: Macroeconomic Fundamentals and The Pricing of Sovereign Debt
doi: 10.1093/rof/rfq005
Advance Access publication: 6 March 2010
Abstract. This paper investigates the effects of macroeconomic fundamentals on emerging market
sovereign credit spreads. We find that the volatility of terms of trade in particular has a statistically
and economically significant effect on spreads. This is robust to instrumenting terms of trade with
a country-specific commodity price index. Our measures of country fundamentals have substantial
explanatory power, even controlling for global factors and credit ratings. We also estimate default
probabilities in a hazard model and find that model implied spreads capture a significant part of the
variation in observed spreads out-of-sample. The fit is better for lower credit quality borrowers.
1. Introduction
∗
We are grateful to John Campbell, N. Gregory Mankiw, Kenneth Rogoff, and Jeremy Stein for
their advice and suggestions. We thank an anonymous referee, Alberto Alesina, Silvia Ardagna,
Gregory Connor, Darrell Duffie, Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln, Amar Gande, David Hauner, Dirk Jenter,
David Laibson, David Lesmond, Emi Nakamura, Ricardo Reis, Andrei Shleifer, Monica Singhal,
Jón Steinsson, Federico Sturzenegger, Suresh Sundaresan, Glen Taksler, Sam Thompson, Don van
Deventer, and seminar participants at Harvard University, the Federal Reserve Board of Governors,
Warwick Business School, Oxford Saı̈d Business School, the Bank for International Settlements,
Macalester, UC Irvine, Brandeis University, Barclays Global Investors, Oak Hill Platinum Partners,
the 2006 MMF and FMA conferences, the Swiss National Bank, the 2007 Moody’s and Copenhagen
Business School Credit Risk Conference, the 2007 EEA and EFA meetings, the Bank of England,
the 2008 ESRC/WEF Warwick Conference on Incentives and Governance in Global Finance, NUI
Maynooth, Exeter University, and Bristol University for helpful comments and discussions. We also
thank Carmen Reinhart, the IMF, J.P. Morgan, and the World Bank for providing us with data, and
Pavel Bandarchuk and Manjola Tase for research assistance.
C The Authors 2010. Published by Oxford University Press [on behalf of the European Finance Association].
All rights reserved. For Permissions, please email: [email protected]
236 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
exogenous (Chen and Rogoff, 2003) and use it as an instrumental variable for terms
of trade. The instrumentation does not lead to a significant change in the coefficients
on our main variables or the overall regression fit.
We also examine the relative importance of country-specific and global factors.
A number of papers have emphasized the importance of global factors for emerging
markets: Calvo et al. (1993), and more recently Calvo (2002), Herrera and Perry
(2002), Grandes (2003), Diaz Weigel and Gemmill (2006), Garcı́a-Herrero and
Ortiz (2006), Longstaff et al. (2007), and González-Rozada and Levy Yeyati (2008).
the stochastic nature of a country’s debt accumulation equation. This allows them
to infer the probability that debt to GDP exceeds a given threshold. They show that
these model implied probabilities are closely related to EMBI spreads in the case
of Brazil. Calvo and Mendoza (1996) present related evidence in the context of the
Mexican crisis of 1994–95.3
When we group bond spread observations into quintiles by their estimated de-
fault probability we find that predicted spreads are smaller than actual spreads
for all the groups,4 but that the proportion of the spread explained by the default
3
In the literature on corporate default risk, the link between default probabilities and spreads has
been explored by a number of papers, e.g. Anderson and Sundaresan (1996), Huang and Huang
(2003), and Berndt et al. (2005).
4
This is not surprising given that we only model the default component of the spread. We discuss
other spread components in Section 4.
5
Early contributions to this literature include Hajivassiliou (1987, 1994). Berg et al. (2000),
Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999), and Goldstein et al. (2000) have concentrated on constructing what
they refer to as “early warning systems.” Berg et al. (2005) provide an overview of this line of
research.
DETERMINANTS OF SOVEREIGN RISK 239
studies is on level variables, rather than volatility. There are some exceptions: Catão
and Sutton (2002) and Catão and Kapur (2006) predict sovereign default in a hazard
model using a similar setup to the one used in the second part of this paper. They
identify volatility of terms of trade as an important predictor of default.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the
data. Section 3 describes the results from using fundamentals to explain spreads
in a regression framework. In Section 4 we turn to default prediction and compare
out-of-sample predicted spreads to observed spreads. Section 5 concludes.
240
The table presents statistics by country. EMBI refers to J.P. Morgan’s Emerging Market Bond Index Global (EMBI). The spread is measured in basis
points over U.S. Treasuries. We report the first year for which EMBI data is available and the median end-of-year spread between 1998 and 2007.
Volatility of terms of trade is the median standard deviation of the percent change in terms of trade calculated using annual data and a rolling ten year
backward-looking window. Number of defaults is the number of times a country has gone into default over the next year. Debt/GDP is the median
level of external debt divided by GDP. These three colums are for the sample period 1970 to 2007. Export groups are for 2000–2001 (UNCTAD).
Start of Volatility
Country EMBI EMBI of terms Number of Top two exports (SITC group) and their percentage
Country code series spread of trade defaults Debt/GDP of total exports
Latin America Argentina ARG 1994 707 9.2 2 42.4 Crude petroleum (10%), feeding stuff for animals (10%)
Brazil BRA 1994 565 9.5 1 33.1 Aircraft (6%), iron ore and concentrates (5%)
Chile CHI 1999 143 9.6 1 46.4 Copper (27%), base metals ores (13%)
Colombia COL 1997 436 10.0 0 32.7 Crude petroleum (26%), coffee and substitutes (8%)
Dominican Rep. DMR 2001 447 0.9 1 29.4 Men’s outwear non-knit (17%), under garments knitted (13%)
Ecuador EQU 1995 824 12.4 3 60.9 Crude petroleum (41%), fruit, nuts, fresh, dried (18%)
El Salvador ESD 2002 238 13.6 0 30.5 Coffee and substitutes (16%), paper and paperboard, cut (6%)
Mexico MEX 1994 310 7.8 1 31.7 Passenger motor vehicles, exc. bus (10%), crude petroleum (8%)
Panama PAN 1996 346 2.3 1 77.6 Fish, fresh, chilled, frozen (20%), fruit, nuts, fresh, dried (20%)
Peru PER 1997 435 14.5 4 52.3 Gold, non-monetary (17%), feeding stuff for animals (13%)
Uruguay URU 2001 308 8.4 4 34.7 Meat, fresh, chilled, frozen (16%), leather (10%)
Venezuela VEN 1994 601 21.8 3 40.3 Crude petroleum (59%), petroleum products, refined (25%)
Africa Côte d’Ivoire CDI 1998 2666 19.7 2 108.0 Cocoa (28%), petroleum products, refined (18%)
Morocco MOR 1997 429 7.3 2 55.6 Women’s outwear non-knit (11%), men’s outwear non-knit (8%)
1500
2.7
1300
EMBI
EMBI spread (basis points over U.S. Treasuries)
Commodity_Index
1100
500
300
100 2.3
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
date
yield spreads. Since many emerging markets are important commodity exporters,
we expect an improvement in the terms of trade and a resulting decline in spreads
when commodity prices increase. We plot commodity prices as measured by the
Commodity Research Bureau (CRB) commodity index in Figure 1 and find that
commodity prices and spreads in fact exhibit a strong negative correlation of −0.66,
which is apparent from the graph.
A natural interpretation is that when commodity prices are high, commodity
exporters are more likely to repay their external debt, which reduces the yield
spread they face in international capital markets. For example, the substantial
increase in commodity prices from 2002 to 2007 was accompanied by significant
spread narrowing. However, it is important to note that we cannot readily generalize
from this evidence since countries have very different baskets of exports, the top
two of which we report in Table I. For example, Venezuela exports mainly oil, while
Chile exports copper and other metals. In order to capture these differences we
use more detailed country-specific terms of trade data in our subsequent empirical
investigation.
A country’s ability to pay its external debt affects its probability of default and,
therefore, the spread it has to pay in international capital markets. In order to analyze
spread variation across countries and over time we gather annual cross-country data
242 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
9
For the few cases where data on terms of trade start later in the sample, we reduce the window size
to a minimum of six years.
10
There is considerable variation in terms of trade volatility across countries. High terms of trade
volatility is to a large extent driven by oil prices. Petroleum products are among the top two export
categories for the three countries with the highest terms of trade volatilities (Table I). However, our
results are robust to excluding countries with more than 20% of their exports concentrated in oil.
11
If unrestricted, this measure could become very large for countries that continue to stay out
of default. We make these adjustments because we expect additional years out of default to have
incrementally less importance.
DETERMINANTS OF SOVEREIGN RISK 243
CDI
1250
1000
EMBI spread (basis points)
EQU
VEN
750
BUL
500
URU PAK
LEBTUR
COL UKR
PHIMOR
PER
MEX
PAN
DMR RUS
250 ESD
SAFSKO
CRO
MAL PLD
EGY
TUN THA CHI
CHN
HUN
5 10 15 20 25
Volatility of terms of trade (%)
on multiple occasions – Peru and Uruguay each have four defaults – while nine
countries did not go into default during this period.
While many of the countries in our data set are large commodity exporters whose
export prices are determined in world markets, not all of the countries’ exports
are concentrated in commodities. It is therefore possible that our measure of terms
of trade may be influenced by local factors, raising the concern of endogeneity.
In order to address this, we construct country-specific commodity export price
indices which we use to instrument for terms of trade in our empirical investigation
in Section 3.
We gather data on export quantities from COMTRADE and export prices from
Global Financial Data. We then construct an export-weighted price index for each
country using time-varying weights. The commodities included in the basket are
those for which we are able to match export price and quantity data. Specifically, we
include the following commodities (ordered by the mean share in country exports)
in the price indices: oil, coffee, textiles, copper, cotton, cocoa, meat, bananas,
leather, gold, gas, and silver (SITC codes listed in the appendix). We use these price
244 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
indices to construct the change in export prices and the volatility of export price
changes analogous to the change in terms of trade and the volatility of terms of
trade discussed above. In the next section we use the commodity price index to
instrument for terms of trade. Before doing so we check that price index changes
are associated with terms of trade changes. We regress the terms of trade measures
on the price index measures and find that, for both measures, the coefficients are
statistically significant at the 1% level and the R 2 are close to 0.5.
In order to control for global factors such as changes in aggregate risk aversion,
world interest rates, and liquidity, we add four time series variables. We include
the VIX index and the U.S. default yield spread, defined as the spread between
corporate bonds with a Moody’s rating of Baa and Aaa. As a proxy for the world
interest rate we include the 10-year U.S. Treasury rate and to capture changes in
aggregate liquidity we include the TED spread.
We also examine two additional country-specific variables: external debt to GDP
(Debt/GDP) and the ratio of reserves (including gold) to GDP (Reserves/GDP). A
number of papers, particularly in the early literature on this topic (e.g. Edwards,
1986), have found a significant positive coefficient on the ratio of debt to GDP in
spread regressions. There are two main concerns with these variables. First, they
are both potentially endogenous. The dynamics of debt in particular are likely to
be endogenous and non-linear (e.g. Favero and Giavazzi, 2002; 2005). A country’s
GDP may also be affected by its spread (e.g. Uribe and Yue, 2006). Second, neither
variable is an ideal measure of sustainability; reserves to GDP in particular is
likely to reflect liquidity rather than solvency.12 We present specifications with and
without these variables to check that our results are robust to their inclusion and to
make our results more readily comparable to earlier studies.
We now explore how much of the variation in sovereign yield spreads can be
explained by macroeconomic fundamentals by running linear regressions of yield
spreads on explanatory variables. For each country we construct an annual end-of-
year spread series to match the annual frequency of our measures of fundamentals.
Our measure of the end-of-year spread is the median daily EMBI spread from J.P.
Morgan for the month of December.13 Since we want to analyze determinants of
12
We thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments on these variables.
13
An alternative would be to use the daily spread on the last trading day of the year which would be
a more noisy measure. Our results are robust to using this alternative measure.
DETERMINANTS OF SOVEREIGN RISK 245
the risk of sovereign default and its impact on debt prices, we focus on spread
observations while the country is not in default.
For an observation to be included in the regression we require that the full set of
explanatory variables is available. This leaves us with a regression sample consist-
ing of 276 country-year observations covering 31 countries from 1994 to 2007. We
restrict the sample to be the same for different specifications to facilitate compar-
ison of point estimates, significance levels, and adjusted R2 across specifications.
Table II reports summary statistics for the spread regression sample. It is apparent
that there is substantial variation in spreads and all of our explanatory variables.
Table III reports results from regressions of spreads on different sets of explana-
tory variables. We group the explanatory variables into three categories: our main
country-specific variables, global time series variables, and control variables. In col-
umn (1), we run a baseline regression with country-specific and global variables.
Volatility of terms of trade and changes in the terms of trade have the expected sign
and are significant at the 1% level: countries with higher terms of trade volatilities
and countries which have experienced a deterioration in their terms of trade tend
to have higher spreads. The coefficient on the years since last default variable is
negative and significant at the 1% level: the closer a country is to its most recent
default episode, the higher its spread tends to be. This latter result is consistent
Table III. Regressions of sovereign spreads on fundamentals
246
This table reports results from regressions of end-of-year (median December) EMBI spreads (31 countries, 1994–2007) on a set of explanatory
variables: macroeconomic variables, time series variables, control variables, and time and regional dummy variables. We only include observations
for which a country is not in default. In specifications (2) and (4) we use the volatility and change in the commodity price index to instrument for
the volatility and change of terms of trade. Credit ratings are from S&P; we include dummy variables corresponding to letter ratings in columns (8)
to (10). t-statistics (reported in parentheses) are calculated using standard errors which are robust and clustered by year. ∗∗ denotes significant at
1%; ∗ significant at 5%; + significant at 10%.
Regression equation:
spread = α + β1 vol tot + β2 chg tot + β3 ytd + β4 VIX + β5 DEF + β6 r 10year + β7 TED + β8 GDP debt + β reserves + dummies + ε
9
GDP
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
COUNTRY VARIABLES
Volatility of terms of trade (vol tot) 37.18 47.78 36.61 47.02 32.36 33.64 20.21 21.93
(9.79)∗∗ (7.76)∗∗ (9.90)∗∗ (8.65)∗∗ (8.75)∗∗ (8.81)∗∗ (2.76)∗ (3.25)∗∗
Change in terms of trade (chg tot) −5.04 −6.26 −4.33 −5.54 −3.86 −3.81 −2.43 −2.28
(5.54)∗∗ (4.63)∗∗ (5.44)∗∗ (4.52)∗∗ (4.98)∗∗ (4.88)∗∗ (2.21)∗ (2.22)∗
Years since last default (ytd) −35.22 −29.62 −25.19 −19.79 −29.34 −17.73 −23.20 −17.95
(5.71)∗∗ (4.32)∗∗ (3.43)∗∗ (2.50)∗ (3.87)∗∗ (3.43)∗∗ (3.65)∗∗ (2.46)∗
GLOBAL VARIABLES
VIX index (VIX) 9.33 9.92 7.66 8.27 7.46 15.24 15.07 11.49 10.31
(3.12)∗∗ (3.08)∗∗ (2.31)∗ (2.37)∗ (2.12)+ (3.67)∗∗ (3.63)∗∗ (3.52)∗∗ (3.08)∗∗
Default yield spread (DEF) 0.73 0.58 1.05 0.90 1.07 1.57 1.38 0.95 1.06
with the findings of Reinhart et al. (2003).14 The coefficient on the VIX index is
positive and significant at the 1% level; the coefficients on the other time series vari-
ables we include are not significant. The regression of spreads on country-specific
fundamentals and global factors delivers an adjusted R2 of 0.53. In contrast, the
regression in column (7) which only includes global factors, delivers a substantially
lower adjusted R2 of 0.13. We return to a discussion of global factors in the next
subsection.
We draw two main conclusions from these results. First, country-specific funda-
14
An important question which we do not address in this paper is what factors aside from macroeco-
nomic fundamentals may cause some countries to be “serial defaulters.” The evidence in Kohlscheen
(2007) suggests that constitutions are important, in particular whether a country is a parliamentary
or presidential democracy.
248 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
Both variables are significant at the 1% confidence level and including them leads
to an increase in the adjusted R2 of around 0.06. However, as noted in Section
2.3, these variables may be endogenous and should therefore be interpreted with
caution.
In column (5) of Table III, we investigate regional effects by including regional
dummy variables corresponding to the regions in Table I. We find that spread
levels are significantly higher in Latin America than in the other regions. Including
regional dummies increases the adjusted R2 by around 0.03; it does not lead to a
We next examine the global time series variables (VIX index, U.S. default yield
spread, 10-year U.S. Treasury yield, TED spread) in more detail. Our first main
finding is that global factors are indeed important. In column (7) of Table III, we
report results from a regression that only includes our four time series variables.
Overall, these four variables alone give an adjusted R2 of 0.13. González-Rozada
and Levy Yeyati (2008) show that at higher (monthly or weekly) frequencies, the
explanatory power of the U.S. high yield corporate spread and Treasury rate is
even higher. Other papers demonstrating the importance of global factors include
Eichengreen and Mody (1998), Herrera and Perry (2002), Grandes (2003), Diaz
Weigel and Gemmill (2006) and Garcı́a-Herrero and Ortiz (2006).
The finding that the coefficient on the VIX index is positive and significant at
the 1% level is consistent with two recent studies using higher frequency emerging
market CDS spread data: Longstaff et al. (2007) find that at higher frequencies
there is evidence of comovement in sovereign CDS spreads while Pan and Singleton
DETERMINANTS OF SOVEREIGN RISK 249
(2008) find that the VIX is statistically significant in explaining CDS spreads of
Mexico, Turkey, and Korea.15
The finding of a positive coefficient on the 10-year U.S. Treasury yield is con-
sistent with the findings of Arora and Cerisola (2001) and Dailami et al. (2005),
among others. Other evidence on the effect of U.S. interest rates in this literature is
mixed. For instance, Kamin and von Kleist (1999) could not identify a robust rela-
tionship between a number of industrial country interest rates and emerging market
spreads. Min (1998) finds a positive but insignificant effect of U.S. interest rates on
15
In related work, Berndt et al. (2005) find that the VIX has substantial explanatory power in a high
frequency data set of U.S. corporate CDS spreads.
250 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
3.3 ROBUSTNESS
We perform several robustness checks. First, we drop large oil exporting countries
from the regression. In particular we drop countries with more than 20% of exports
concentrated in crude petroleum and petroleum products. The results are largely
unaffected indicating that fluctuations in oil prices are only part of the reason why
terms of trade fluctuations impact sovereign spreads. In order to make sure that out-
liers are not driving some of our results we re-estimate the reduced form regressions
16
One issue in this context highlighted by González-Rozada and Levy Yeyati (2008) is the potential
endogeneity of credit ratings.
17
The question we are interested in here is to what extent credit ratings explain market prices.
A different question is whether credit ratings contain information about future fundamentals not
captured by market prices. Cavallo et al. (2008) find that they do.
18
In addition, Mora (2006) provides evidence of inertia in ratings.
DETERMINANTS OF SOVEREIGN RISK 251
on winsorized data where we winsorize the explanatory variables at the 5th and 95th
percentile levels, replacing values above the 95th percentile of the distribution with
the 95th percentile and values below the 5th percentile with the 5th percentile of the
distribution. Our main results are unaffected by these changes. Third, we replace the
volatility of terms of trade with its one year lag. We also drop observations in years
preceding a default. Our results are robust to these changes. Finally, we run our
main specification (3) in Table III in first differences as an additional specification
check. We find that the magnitudes of the coefficients on country fundamentals are
21
These results are consistent with independent work by Catão and Sutton (2002) and Catão and
Kapur (2006) who also investigate empirical determinants of default in a reduced form hazard
model setting that is similar to the specification reported in Table V. These authors do not, however,
instrument for terms of trade.
DETERMINANTS OF SOVEREIGN RISK 253
22
In principle, we could consider additional explanatory variables that predict default in the sample
we consider. However, because of the sample size and the rather small number of default observations,
we choose only the country variables and control variables included in our main spread regression
specification.
254 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
2500
1000
500
50
10
EMBI_spread Fitted_values
We next calculate predicted spreads using fitted default probabilities from the hazard
model and compare these to observed EMBI spreads. We assume that recovery rates
are fixed, i.e. that creditors receive a constant fraction of face value in the event
of default. We set the fractional recovery rate equal to 0.6 which is broadly in line
with the average historical experience (Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer, 2005).23 We
compute the default component of the spread by discounting the expected payoff at
the riskfree rate and calculate predicted spreads using fitted probabilities from our
main specification in column (3) of Table V. We estimate the model using data up
to 1993 and then calculate fitted default probabilities for the period 1994 to 2007.
We compare out-of-sample predicted spreads to actual spreads and ask how much
of the level and variation in EMBI spreads is due to country default probabilities.
Figure 3 plots actual against predicted spreads. We notice a strong positive relation
which is reflected in a correlation of 0.65.
23
Panizza et al. (2008) provide a comprehensive discussion of the legal aspects of sovereign debt
and default.
DETERMINANTS OF SOVEREIGN RISK 255
Table VI Panel A reports summary statistics for EMBI spreads and predicted
spreads. The sample contains spread observations from 31 countries over the period
1994 to 2007 and corresponds to the regression sample used in Table III. Predicted
spreads are smaller than actual spreads: the median predicted spread is equal to
256 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
87 basis points, compared to a median EMBI spread of 265 basis points. This
difference reflects non-default spread components, to which we return later in this
section.
We check more formally how much of the variation in spreads is explained by
variation in default risk by regressing EMBI spreads on predicted spreads and
global variables. Predicted spreads have some extreme values. In order to control
for outliers we winsorize predicted spreads. As a result of this winsorization the
in-sample standard deviation is reduced from 426 to 307 and the kurtosis is reduced
800
Average spread (basis points)
600
200
0
.6 1.1 2.1 4.5 11.9
(2007) provide evidence that a significant part of the spread on emerging market
corporate and sovereign debt may be explained by liquidity. Borri and Verdelhan
(2008), Martell (2008), Remolana et al. (2008), and Andrade (2009) also investigate
non-default risk determinants of spreads in the sovereign bond market.24
To summarize, we find that predicted spreads have significant explanatory power
for observed sovereign spreads. The default component of spreads explains variation
in observed spreads surprisingly well and the fraction of the spread due to default
risk is much larger for borrowers of lower credit quality.
24
For risky corporate bonds, Huang and Huang (2003) find that default risk accounts for only part
of the spread. Elton et al. (2001) document important spread components related to liquidity, risk
aversion, and taxes. Chen et al. (2007) present evidence that liquidity is priced in U.S. corporate
bonds. Longstaff et al. (2005) find that the majority of the U.S. corporate default swap spread is
explained by default risk and that the non-default component is time-varying and closely related to
measures of liquidity.
258 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
5. Conclusion
Appendix
J.P. Morgan’s EMBI includes U.S. dollar denominated Brady bonds, loans, and
Eurobonds issued or guaranteed by emerging market governments. Countries need
to be classified as low or middle income by the World Bank for the last two years,
have restructured debt in the past 10 years, or have restructured debt outstanding.
The minimum issue size for a debt instrument is U.S. dollar 500 million, it needs to
DETERMINANTS OF SOVEREIGN RISK 259
have a maturity greater than 2.5 years, verifiable daily prices and cash flows, and it
has to fall under G7 legal jurisdiction.25
The Commodity Research Bureau (CRB) commodity index series is from Global
Financial Data. According to the CRB, the index includes energy (crude oil, heating
oil, natural gas), grains and oilseed (corn, soybeans, wheat), industrials (copper,
cotton), livestock (live cattle, live hogs), precious metals (gold, platinum, silver),
softs (cocoa, coffee, orange juice, sugar).26
We use annual terms of trade data provided by the Development Data Group at the
References
Afonso, A., Gomes, P., and Rother, P. (2006) What “Hides” Behind Sovereign Debt Ratings? unpub-
lished working paper, European Central Bank.
Anderson, R. and Sundaresan, S. (2000) A Comparative Study of Structural Models of Corporate
Bond Yields: An Exploratory Investigation, Journal of Banking and Finance 24, 255–269.
Andrade, S. (2009) A Model of Asset Pricing Under Country Risk, Journal of International Money
and Finance 28, 671–695.
Arora, V. B. and Cerisola, M. B. (2001) How Does U.S. Monetary Policy Influence Economic
Conditions in Emerging Markets? IMF Staff Papers 48, 474–498.
Beck, R. (2001) Do Country Fundamentals Explain Emerging Market Bond Spreads? CFS Working
Paper, No. 2001/02, Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität.
25
Source: Emerging Markets External Debt Handbook for 2002–2003, J.P. Morgan.
26
Source: documentation describing CRB Commodity Index in Global Financial Data.
260 JENS HILSCHER AND YVES NOSBUSCH
Berg, A., Borensztein, E., Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., and Pattillo, C. (2000) Anticipating Balance of
Payments Crises–The Role of Early Warning Systems, IMF Occasional Papers 186, International
Monetary Fund.
Berg, A., Borensztein, E., and Pattillo, C. (2005) Assessing Early Warning Systems: How Have They
Worked in Practice? IMF Staff Papers 52, 462–502.
Berndt, A., Douglas, R., Duffie, D., Ferguson, M., and Schranz, D. (2005) Measuring
Default-Risk Premia from Default Swap Rates and EDFs, unpublished working paper, Tep-
per School of Business, Carnegie Mellon University, and Stanford Graduate School of
Business.
Duffie, D., Pedersen, L. H., and Singleton, K. J. (2003) Modeling Sovereign Yield Spreads: A Case
Study of Russian Debt, Journal of Finance 58, 119–159.
Edwards, S. (1984) LDC Foreign Borrowing and Default Risk: An Empirical Investigation, 1976–80,
American Economic Review 74, 726–734.
Edwards, S. (1986) The Pricing of Bonds and Bank Loans in International Markets, An Empirical
Analysis of Developing Countries’ Foreign Borrowing, European Economic Review 30, 565–589.
Eichengreen, B. and Mody, A. (2000) What Explains Changing Spreads on Emerging-Market
Debt: Fundamentals or Market Sentiment?, in: S. Edwards (ed.), Capital Flows and the Emerg-
ing Economies: Theory, Evidence and Controversies, University of Chicago Press.
Kaminsky, G. L. and Reinhart, C. M. (1999) The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-
of-Payments Problems, American Economic Review 89, 473–500.
Kohlscheen, E. (2007) Why are there Serial Defaulters? Evidence from Constitutions, The Journal
of Law and Economics 50, 713–30.
Longstaff, F. A., Mithal, S., and Neis, E. (2005) Corporate Yield Spreads: Default Risk or Liquidity?
New Evidence from the Credit Default Swap Market, Journal of Finance 60, 2213–2253.
Longstaff, F. A., Pan, J., Pedersen, L. H., and Singleton, K. J. (2007) How Sovereign is Sovereign
Credit Risk? unpublished working paper, UCLA Anderson School, MIT Sloan School, NYU Stern
School, and Stanford Graduate School of Business.