Behavioral Development Economics: Michael Kremer, Gautam Rao, Frank Schilbach
Behavioral Development Economics: Michael Kremer, Gautam Rao, Frank Schilbach
Behavioral Development Economics: Michael Kremer, Gautam Rao, Frank Schilbach
Behavioral development
economics✶
5
Michael Kremera,c,∗ , Gautam Raoa,c , Frank Schilbachb,c
a Harvard
University, Cambridge, MA, United States of America
b MIT, Cambridge, MA, United States of America
c National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, United States of America
∗ Corresponding author: e-mail address: [email protected]
Contents
1 Introduction...................................................................................... 346
2 High rates of return without rapid growth .................................................. 354
2.1 The Euler equation puzzle ...................................................... 354
2.2 Present bias....................................................................... 359
2.3 Reference-dependent preferences............................................. 364
2.4 Other behavioral factors......................................................... 368
3 Health ............................................................................................ 368
3.1 Underinvestment in preventive health ........................................ 369
3.2 Present bias....................................................................... 372
3.2.1 Procrastination and health behaviors ...................................... 372
3.2.2 Low willingness to pay and high price sensitivity ........................ 376
3.2.3 Commitment devices.......................................................... 377
3.3 Biased beliefs .................................................................... 380
3.4 Incorrect mental models ........................................................ 385
3.5 Other behavioral factors......................................................... 386
4 Savings........................................................................................... 387
4.1 Commitment savings devices .................................................. 388
4.2 Designing financial products for behavioral agents ......................... 390
5 Risk and insurance............................................................................. 391
5.1 Non-standard preferences affecting insurance demand.................... 393
✶ We thank the editors—Douglas Bernheim, David Laibson, and especially Stefano DellaVigna—for their
detailed comments and helpful suggestions, and their patience and sophistication in the face of our naïve
present focus. We are grateful to Pedro Bessone, Kevin Carney, Joshua Dean, Emily Gallagher, Rachel
Glennerster, Tomoko Harigaya, Karla Hoff, Matt Lowe, Maddie McKelway, David McKenzie, Matthew
Ridley, Mattie Toma, Pierre-Luc Vautrey, and Jack Willis for thoughtful feedback and comments on a draft
version. Audiences at the NBER Development Economics workshop, SITE and ESA conference provided
helpful comments on early versions of this chapter. We thank Fanelesibonge Mashwama, Stephen Nyarko,
and especially Xinyue Lin for excellent research assistance. Michael Kremer discloses that he is a board
member of Precision Agriculture for Development (PAD). PAD is a non-profit organization and Kremer
receives no financial compensation from PAD.
1 Introduction
Modern development economics was born in part as a reaction against a widespread
view among scholars that peasants in poor societies were bound by tradition and
could not be subject to the same type of economic analysis as people in modern
industrialized societies. From the work of Schultz (1964) through the early 1990s,
most development economists instead took it as axiomatic that people in developing
countries were “poor but efficient”.
The field of development economics has been transformed since the 1990s in part
by the growth in experiments. Most of these have focused either on issues of im-
portance to development economics, such as the rate of return to capital for small
enterprises, or policy issues, such as finding ways to increase use of fertilizer to in-
crease agricultural production in Africa. Until recently, only a few were designed to
test behavioral theories or to identify the parameters of behavioral models. Yet, in
the past decade, development economics has increasingly come to incorporate theo-
ries and ideas from behavioral economics into the study of questions in development,
giving birth to the subfield of behavioral development economics.
1 Introduction 347
eter values of present bias alone can explain some failures to invest in high-return
investments. However, explaining failures to invest in very high return investments
(in preventive health or elsewhere) typically requires another ingredient: at least par-
tial naïveté regarding future present bias.
A (partially) naïve individual underestimates the degree of their future present
bias. Such naïveté can magnify the welfare losses associated with present bias since
individuals may delay very high return investments with small short-run utility costs
because they incorrectly anticipate making these investments later. Fully naïve indi-
viduals will not take advantage of commitment devices to overcome their self-control
problems, while partially naïve individuals will mis-predict whether a given commit-
ment device is likely to work for them. Naïveté and uncertainty in the environment
(which increases the value of flexibility) are likely to drive down demand for com-
mitment and may explain why commitment devices are not more widespread.
People in developing countries are often highly exposed to risk, enjoy little social
insurance from governments, and live close to subsistence, giving them little margin
of adjustment. Many also have limited scope for borrowing. Whereas standard the-
ory suggests that risk-averse households without access to borrowing should build up
buffer stocks to insulate themselves from risk, present-biased consumers will have
difficulty saving and maintaining liquid assets and hence will wind up liquidity con-
strained. This will leave them exposed to shocks and unable to self-insure.
A standard finding in development economics is that demand for even actuarially-
fair weather insurance or health insurance is surprisingly low. Present bias, by gener-
ating liquidity constraints, may also reduce demand for standard insurance contracts
which require up-front payment of premia.
Another implication of these endogenous liquidity constraints is that it will be
difficult for present-biased agents to respond to surprise opportunities for investment
without accompanying provisions for credit. This issue makes it difficult to interpret
some standard tests for willingness to pay that are common in the health and envi-
ronmental literatures.
Loss aversion may help explain why many apparently high expected return in-
vestments in developing countries remain unexploited. Just as present bias yields
much larger distortions when combined with naïveté, loss aversion can have much
more negative effects on investment when combined with narrow bracketing, the ten-
dency to consider decisions in isolation from each other. Loss aversion may generate
stickiness of assets, which arguably better matches some of the dynamics of assets
than many poverty-trap models based on increasing returns. In contrast, loss aversion
has ambiguous theoretical effects on the demand for insurance.
Individuals may mis-predict their future preferences in various ways. As dis-
cussed above, naïveté may greatly exacerbate the consequences of present bias.
Projection bias, the tendency to overestimate the degree to which one’s future tastes
will resemble one’s current tastes, may reduce investment in preventive health and
insurance, to the extent that people find it difficult to imagine that they may become
sick in the future and the extent to which they will need resources if they or their
family might be hit by a health shock.
1 Introduction 349
outside of small kin-based groups is rare and key to development. In this view, the
scarcity of large firms in developing societies, and hence the potential role for behav-
ioral factors in firm behavior, is not driven simply by policy mistakes such as state
predation on large firms, but rather reflects fundamental cultural features of societies
that make cooperation difficult outside of the extended family. Similar factors may
interfere with state capacity. We discuss the evidence for differences in social prefer-
ences across societies, and the extent to which these differences may be thought of as
causes or consequences of development, and how they may be shaped by policy.
Finally, we discuss the nascent literature on the psychology of poverty, which
investigates whether poverty itself affects cognitive function and economic decision-
making in meaningful ways. The main argument of this literature is that the con-
ditions associated with poverty, such as the constant worries about money, greater
exposure to factors such as pain, sleep deprivation, noise and malnourishment, and
less access to mental health care, may influence cognitive function (largely nega-
tively). Worse cognitive function may in turn affect decision-making and productivity
in ways that generate a psychological poverty trap. While the literature provides some
evidence of effects on cognitive function, studies evaluating effects on economic out-
comes and behaviors remain scarce.
This chapter complements several existing review articles on behavioral de-
velopment economics. An accessible and thorough review of empirical research in
behavioral development economics is provided in World Bank (2015). While that
report is aimed at policy makers, this chapter is written for researchers and grad-
uate students, and is thus somewhat more technical. Schilbach et al. (2016) and
Dean et al. (2018) cover in detail the relationship between poverty and cognitive
function, which we touch on in Section 10. Datta and Mullainathan (2014) describe
principles of behaviorally-informed design of development policy. Finally, Demeritt
and Hoff (2018) provide a history of the rise of behavioral development economics.
While our chapter concentrates on “universal” behavioral models such as present
bias, reference-dependence and limited attention, Demeritt and Hoff point to a differ-
ent strand of behavioral development economics, which emphasizes the importance
of the “cultural mental models” – categories, concepts, identities and worldviews –
that individuals use to interpret situations and make decisions.
Before proceeding, we discuss a few caveats and critiques of behavioral de-
velopment economics. First, just as behavioral economics seeks to build on and
improve upon existing neoclassical models, behavioral development economics seeks
to augment existing theories of development economics by capturing systematic and
relevant aspects of human behavior, often using parsimonious extensions of existing
models (Rabin, 1998).
Second, behavioral development economics does not deny the importance of insti-
tutions or economic policy in economic development. Instead, it takes local economic
environments seriously, and studies how universal behavioral factors play out in the
context of the choices, markets and institutions common in developing countries.
Rather than diverting attention from the study of important structural issues, behav-
352 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
ioral development may sometimes help better identify and understand these issues
and potential reforms.
Third, a critique of behavioral development is that such work is too quick to
abandon the possibility that apparently irrational actions by people may reflect real
economic incentives and constraints. For example, Rosenzweig and Udry (2014) ar-
gue that it is difficult to generalize about the effectiveness of agricultural inputs even
from several seasons, because agricultural production is highly stochastic and returns
to inputs may vary across seasons. This view implies that one should not too quickly
jump to the conclusion that certain behaviors (such as not using more fertilizer) are
irrational. We see merit in this view. One way that behavioral economists can address
this critique is by designing experiments to more precisely identify specific behav-
ioral mechanisms and to test for those, rather than to simply reject a single rational
model and label any residual as “behavioral”. We believe that the best work in be-
havioral development economics takes precisely such an approach. The solution to
the problem of bad behavioral-development research is more careful and rigorous
behavioral-development research.
Fourth, some see behavioral development economics as blaming the poor for their
poverty. In fact, behavioral development is largely concerned with universal psycho-
logical factors and does not generally attribute poverty to having greater behavioral
biases. Moreover, we do not view having behavioral biases as in any way deserving
blame, since there is no reason whatsoever to believe that they are freely chosen.
Fifth, behavioral economics is often seen as opening the door to paternalistic poli-
cies and restrictions on individual choice. While we believe that understanding the
role of behavioral factors in a scientific way does not automatically translate into any
policy or political implications, we also argue that misunderstanding human behavior
can also lead to bad policy outcomes.
Policymakers are sometimes enthusiastic about behavioral economics due to the
perception that it promises inexpensive but effective interventions, and want to apply
it to policy right away. However, behavioral economics should arguably make policy
makers more cautious for two reasons. One is the subtlety of thinking about welfare
in a behavioral world, a topic which we do not cover, and for which we refer readers
to the chapter by Bernheim and Taubinsky (2018) in this handbook. In addition to
philosophical issues involved in conducting welfare analysis with behavioral agents,
in the case of behavioral development, behavioral biases will often interact with mul-
tiple market failures, potentially leading to second-best issues and making welfare
analysis more challenging. Another reason for humility in policymaking is precisely
because behavioral economics demonstrates that small details can matter for people’s
choices. Consequently, unintended consequences may be more likely in a world with
behavioral agents.
Finally, while we have argued that many behavioral phenomena are relevant for
development economics, it is worth noting that other ideas, which have been found
to be important in laboratory experiments, and in some cases in some real-world
developed-country contexts, have not turned out to play an important role in pop-
ular applications in development. Research provides little support for some views
1 Introduction 353
widely espoused by development practitioners and NGOs regarding the alleged coun-
terproductive behavioral effects of more favorable financial treatment of poor people.
Rather, the growth of scientific behavioral development economics research has led
to the formal testing and rejection of several of these hypotheses, and in some cases,
this has arguably influenced policy debates.
For example, some have conjectured that reducing the cost of preventive health
products such as mosquito nets or distributing them for free would lead people to
value them less and use them less. Rigorous testing by Cohen and Dupas (2010)
and Ashraf et al. (2010) yields no support for this conjecture. Broadly speaking, this
evidence has moved the policy debate towards free distribution of preventive health
goods such as mosquito nets. Similarly, while many practitioners have voiced concern
that financial compensation for community health workers could crowd out intrinsic
motivation or lead to selection of less motivated staff, and indeed in some labora-
tory experiments there is evidence of a tradeoff, most real-world experiments provide
little evidence that extrinsic financial incentives crowd out intrinsic incentives mean-
ingfully, and indeed provide evidence that recruiting community health workers in
ways that emphasize career benefits leads to better selection. To take a final example,
many development practitioners were concerned that unconditional cash transfers to
the poor would be largely dissipated on alcohol and cigarettes, but evidence from
Haushofer and Shapiro (2016) does not support this view.
Roadmap. The remainder of this chapter is organized according to topics in devel-
opment economics, rather than by behavioral biases. Section 2 examines the puzzle
of high rates of return without rapid growth. Section 3 examines behavioral factors
that may contribute to low investment in preventive health. Sections 4 and 5 discuss
how non-standard preferences, beliefs and decision-making can affect savings be-
havior and demand for insurance. Section 6 investigates how technology adoption
decisions may be affected by limited attention and present bias, as well as by failures
in learning.
Section 7 discusses behavioral labor economics in developing economies. We
first consider how some characteristics of labor markets in developing countries may
potentially exacerbate behavioral biases. We then discuss the labor supply and worker
productivity, as well as the role of fairness norms in wage-setting, the selection of
workers, and female labor-force participation. Section 8 discusses behavioral firms,
arguing that firms in developing countries may be more subject to behavioral biases,
since limits on the span of control in developing societies weaken the opportunities
for market forces to eliminate behavioral firms, and imply that a greater proportion
of the population in developing countries acts as managers or owners of firms.
Sections 9 and 10 discuss culture, social preferences, and the psychology of
poverty. We first briefly review the intellectual history of this field and then cover
questions regarding the existence of differences in social preferences across soci-
eties, whether these preferences matter for development, and the potential to change
these attitudes through social contact across groups, or other deliberate policies. We
then review the recent literature on the psychology of poverty, including the effects
of scarcity on cognitive function and economic behaviors, the potential role of other
354 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
deprivations beyond lack of money, and mental health. Finally, we explore question
around aspirations, hope, and religiosity.
derived from consuming Ct in period t. u(C) is increasing and concave and satis-
fies the usual Inada conditions: u (C) > 0 and u (C) < 0, limc→0 u (C) = ∞ and
limc→∞ u (C) = 0.
The budget constraint of the household is xt+1 = f (Kt )(xt − Ct ), where xt is
household assets (“cash on hand”) in period t, with x0 given; f (K) is the production
function denoting the value of the output in the next period including any remain-
ing value of the capital; f (K) is the gross rate of return to capital; f (K) satisfies
f (K) > 0 and f (K) < 0, limK→0 f (K) = ∞, limK→∞ f (K) = 1.
Solving for the optimal consumption path gives the discrete-time Euler equation:
in 20 years, far higher than actual growth rates of consumption.3 Working in reverse,
a consumption growth rate of 5% implies that f (K) = 115%, i.e. net rates of return
of 15%, which is much lower than the rates observed in many contexts.
The finding that many people in developing countries face high rates of return yet
do not have dramatic growth in consumption thus poses a puzzle in the framework
of the neoclassical model. Some would try to resolve this puzzle by arguing that
households face a high implicit tax on the return on capital, for example, due to
predation by corrupt government officials, or due to redistributive pressures from
extended family members.
Allowing for realistic levels of such distortions, it is difficult to reconcile the data
with standard calibrated values for an exponential discount rate. For instance, Jakiela
and Ozier (2015) show with a lab-in-the-field experiment that women (but not men)
face a “kin tax” of 4% when making an observable investment, which would not
dramatically change the above calibration. Moreover, their experiment also includes
men for whom the authors do not find such kin taxes. Further, marginally increasing
inventories for a shopkeeper or marginally increasing fertilizer use by a farmer would
not easily be observable either by the state or by kin outside the nuclear family, and as
such would not be subject to such a tax. Finally, “taxes” by kin or other social groups
are not pure taxes but would likely generate either some reciprocal obligations from
those receiving the transfers or some utility benefits to the household making the
transfers. It thus seems difficult to believe that such taxes would fully resolve the
puzzle.4
It is worth noting that the same households who hold high-interest debt often hold
low-return assets. For instance, Collins et al. (2009) report that every household they
survey has both low-interest savings and high-interest debt at the same time. Anagol
et al. (2017) estimate that cows and buffaloes earn large negative returns in India, and
yet are owned by 45% of rural households. Similarly, the shopkeepers in Kremer et
al. (2013) who leave unexploited inventory-investment returns of over 100% per year
simultaneously deposit money in savings accounts returning a few percentage points.
As discussed below, one interpretation might be that people hold these low return
assets to diversify risk, while another is that they are seeking to manage liquidity.
Poverty traps. Could a non-concave production function help square such high rates
of return with the lack of dramatic growth in consumption? Under the usual concave
production function, poor households will have higher returns to investment, will
accumulate wealth, and thus converge to richer households. With an S-shaped pro-
duction function that is convex for low levels of capital and then concave at higher
levels, there may instead be multiple steady states. Which of these steady states a
household converges to may depend on its initial capital stock, and the long-run dis-
tribution of wealth may depend on the initial distribution. Such a model can feature
poverty traps: households that fall below a certain threshold may be stuck at low
levels of returns and be unable to accumulate wealth. In general, there is limited ev-
4 A given percentage informal “tax” leveled by extended family could potentially be more distortionary if
it was levied on capital itself rather than simply on capital income, especially if they were particularly high
for certain types of investment, for example, on more observable capital goods, but in general there is no
reason to assume that informal taxation systems would be more distortionary than formal taxation systems
used in developed countries, and in any case, even a 4% tax on capital would not be a big deterrent if gross
returns were on the order of 150%.
2 High rates of return without rapid growth 357
idence that such poverty traps are widespread, but they are likely to be present in at
least some situations (Kraay and McKenzie, 2014; Bandiera et al., 2017).5
Yet even in models with poverty traps and non-concave production functions, the
observed initial conditions still need to be consistent with the model. An S-shaped
production function allows for a steady state with a low rate of return (at either low
or high wealth), but it nevertheless also implies that individuals who face a high
marginal rate of return to investment should exhibit fast consumption growth. Thus,
even under a model with a non-concave production function, one would not observe
households with high marginal returns and low growth. Even the presence of assets
with increasing returns would not explain high returns to divisible fertilizer invest-
ments for farmers or inventory for shopkeepers or fruit sellers.
Lumpy investments with high rates of return can remain unexploited in the pres-
ence of credit constraints. Thus, households might not be able to purchase an asset,
like a cow, even if it generated a high return. However, even lumpy investments with
credit constraints are not a sufficient condition for unexploited high returns. For ex-
ample, consider a household that has a discount factor of 0.96, a non-lumpy liquid
investment opportunity offering a 10% return and a lumpy investment opportunity
yielding a 50% rate of return on a discrete investment. The households would ini-
tially save in the liquid non-lumpy investment and then reallocate assets to the lumpy
investment once a sufficient amount was accumulated. Even with a zero rate of return
on the non-lumpy investment, the household would save up for the lumpy investment
unless it required a very large investment.
Moreover, even if certain physical assets are lumpy, the financial returns to in-
vestment could potentially be smoothed with appropriate financial products, informal
institutions, or government programs. Lumpy investments could be exploited using
mechanisms such as ROSCAs, borrowing and lending contracts, or government pro-
grams that would either simply transfer resources to individuals stuck in poverty traps
or would lend them resources and then use the power of the state to collect repay-
ments. Lotteries and ROSCAs are indeed very popular, suggesting that there are ways
to address potential non-concavities in the production function, but they do not seem
to enable the rates of consumption growth one would expect with a gross rate of
return to capital of 150% or more.
In any case, one should not observe high returns to non-lumpy investments with-
out rapid consumption growth. Yet, research has documented high returns to fertilizer
(Duflo et al., 2008) and to small increases in working capital for small firms (Beaman
et al., 2014; Kremer et al., 2013). Moreover, extending credit to poor households does
not result in transformative effects (Banerjee et al., 2015a; Meager, 2019). Credit con-
straints cannot in themselves explain high rates of return.
5 One rarely observes multi-modal distributions of income; there is little evidence that temporary positive
shocks lead to sustained increases in income over time; and unconditional transfers such as Give Directly
and the Georgia land lottery did not provide evidence of poverty traps (Haushofer and Shapiro, 2016;
Bleakley and Ferrie, 2016).
358 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Stochastic returns and risk aversion. If returns are stochastic, risk aversion might
deter individuals from making investments, even if expected returns exceed the dis-
count rate. Can we explain the Euler equation puzzle with stochastic income and risk
aversion? Suppose, for example, income in period t is:
n
Yit = Y0 + εt + μit fi (Kit ) (2)
i=1
where there are n assets or capital goods and capital goods i has stochastic return μit
in period t with an arbitrary pattern of correlation. In this setting, the stochastic Euler
equation is:
u (Ct ) = δEt μit fi (Kit )u (Ct+1 ) , i = 1, 2, . . . , n (3)
Given an initial capital stock, risk aversion will decrease investment in assets that
co-vary positively with consumption and increase investment in assets that co-vary
negatively with consumption. In this framework, it will be optimal for risk-averse
households to build a buffer stock of low-risk savings that they can draw upon when
they experience negative shocks (Deaton, 1991; Carroll, 1997). In the ergodic dis-
tribution, few people will have a low buffer stock. Keeping a high buffer stock will
allow most people to smooth consumption, so that consumption will be largely insen-
sitive to high-frequency income shocks or predictable changes in income. It follows,
for example, that most market traders in the ergodic distribution should be willing to
invest in working capital and most farmers should be willing to invest in fertilizer.
All but those who recently experienced a string of negative shocks would have a
sufficient buffer stock of relatively safe assets to allow them to invest in assets like
fertilizer. Even if the returns to fertilizer investment in a season are highly correlated
with harvest during that season, for example, because they depend on rainfall during
the season, they should only be modestly correlated with lifetime income and thus
consumption. Therefore, risk aversion should only modestly reduce investment, and
cannot fully explain the Euler equation puzzle.
In fact, however, liquid buffer stocks are typically modest (Deaton, 1989). While
consumption is smoother than income, it does still co-vary substantially with income
shocks (Townsend, 1995; Collins et al., 2009). For instance, Jalan and Ravallion
(1999) estimate that the pass-through of income shocks to consumption is 40%
among the poorest decile of households in rural China. Kazianga and Udry (2006),
studying a period of severe drought in Burkina Faso, find little evidence of consump-
tion smoothing.
Moreover, consumption varies not just with shocks to income, but also with pre-
dictable variation in income, contrary to models with patient consumers. Both food
and non-food consumption have been documented to vary seasonally with the har-
vest cycle: consumption is lower before harvest in the lean season, and higher after
harvest, when farmers are cash rich (Mani et al., 2013; Kaminski et al., 2014; Basu
and Wong, 2015). While some of this variation can be explained by seasonal price
2 High rates of return without rapid growth 359
fluctuations and lack of storage opportunities, consumption varies across the pay cy-
cle also among the poor in rich countries, where markets are thick and food prices
do not show similar fluctuations. For instance, Shapiro (2005) shows that caloric in-
take declines by 10–15% over the course of a month after delivery of food stamps.
Stephens (2003) similarly shows that social security recipients in the United States
fail to smooth consumption between checks.
A related finding is that investment decisions of farmers are affected by the timing
of predictable variation in prices and expenditures. For instance, Burke et al. (2018)
show that farmers fail to exploit arbitrage opportunities created by seasonal price
variation in local grain markets. That is, they sell when prices are low, and buy for
personal consumption when prices are high in the lean season. Providing access to
credit reduces this failure to arbitrage and generates returns on investment of 29%.
The question, however, is why farmers are not able to build up liquid buffer stocks to
exploit this investment opportunity themselves, even in the absence of credit markets.
One could further enrich the model, for example, by allowing for illiquid invest-
ments. Households might indeed be more reluctant to invest in fertilizer or inventories
if they might be subject to income shocks and thus require liquidity before the payoff
on those investments was realized. However, the same basic approach of building up
a buffer stock, for example, of cash or grain or other relatively liquid assets such as
jewelry or livestock that could be sold in bad times could help address this problem.
In summary, we have argued that the high rates of return without rapid consump-
tion growth, evident in many parts of the developing world, pose a puzzle that cannot
be explained by the standard neoclassical model, non-concave production functions
or risk aversion. We now discuss theories from behavioral economics that may shed
light on this puzzle.
6 In this chapter, we discuss time preferences and self-control problems through the lens of the present-
bias model, which has emerged as a workhorse model in this literature. However, numerous other models
of limited self-control and intertemporal choice exist, some of which make similar (or even identical) pre-
dictions in the problems we consider. We refer readers to Ericson and Laibson (2018) in this handbook for
a broader perspective on this literature.
7 On estimation of time preferences, see Ericson and Laibson (2018) in this volume and Cohen et al.
(2016) for details as well as a brief discussion further below in this section.
2 High rates of return without rapid growth 361
stantial heterogeneity in present bias itself. Augenblick and Rabin (2018) estimate
that 78% of individuals are present biased, with the rest either acting as exponential
discounters or even exhibiting future bias.8 The mean estimate of β in their sample
is 0.79, with a standard deviation across individuals of 0.29. The extent to which ob-
served heterogeneity in the returns to capital or unexploited investment opportunities
can be explained by heterogeneity in discount factors is an open question for future
research.
The quasi-hyperbolic model can explain another important set of facts about the
poor: low levels of precautionary savings in liquid form, and high covariance of in-
come and consumption. Under standard lifecycle models, individuals will save up
substantial buffer stocks of liquid savings. They will thus be able to self-insure against
shocks, and income and consumption will not co-vary much. In contrast, present-
biased agents will have low levels of liquid savings (e.g. Angeletos et al., 2001).
When such agents are hit with shocks, their lack of buffer-stock savings implies that
they will be unable to self-insure, and consumption will thus co-vary substantially
with transitory income shocks.9 In fact, consumption will also vary with perfectly
predictable changes in income, as is the case with farmers over the harvest cycle.
Standard lifecycle models typically cannot explain the sensitivity of consumption to
predictable falls in income, even in the absence of credit markets (Jappelli and Pista-
ferri, 2010). Note also that these endogenous liquidity constraints generate the high
MPC discussed above, which causes present-biased agents to appear impatient.
In contrast to their failure to build up liquid savings, sophisticated present-biased
agents may build up substantial illiquid assets since they correctly forecast their fu-
ture self-control problems (Angeletos et al., 2001). Such individuals may invest in
education or hold on to land, rather than selling it, since land and human capital
are both illiquid assets that provide valued protection against over-consuming. Thus,
these agents will be willing to save up even in low-return illiquid assets (such as land
or, to a lesser extent, jewelry and cattle), which may partly explain why households
do not appear to equate marginal returns across assets.
In the case of completely naïve present-biased agents, who think they will be
exponential discounters without self-control problems beginning tomorrow, illiquid
assets will only be accumulated if they are perceived to be attractive, high-return in-
vestments. Apart from this feature, the level of naïveté or sophistication has been
found to matter relatively little for quantitative predictions about savings and con-
sumption paths in lifecycle consumption models (Beshears et al., 2015).10,11
in the context of preventive health behavior, another example of apparently under-exploited high-return
investments.
2 High rates of return without rapid growth 363
This widely popular approach rests on shaky theoretical foundations. Cubitt and
Read (2007), for instance, show that choices over money payments at different
time horizons need not reveal anything about time preferences since individuals’
marginal propensity to consume from such payments will likely deviate from one.
Optimizing individuals should smooth consumption over their lifecycle. Thus, re-
ceiving $100 today (say, in experimental payouts) may only increase consumption
today by pennies. Even with reasonable liquidity constraints, one would expect con-
sumption to be smoothed over weeks or more, whereas present bias is thought to
operate over a shorter time horizon of hours or days (e.g. McClure et al., 2007;
Augenblick, 2018). Indeed, choices over money earlier or later may reveal more about
effective interest rates faced by individuals, or about their time-varying liquidity and
financial shocks, even among the poor in developing countries (Dean and Sautmann,
2018; Cassidy, 2018).
A promising recent alternative approach to measuring time preferences is to of-
fer participants choices between actual consumption events or effort. For example,
McClure et al. (2007) offer sips of juice to thirsty individuals, while Augenblick et
al. (2015) ask participants to choose between different amounts of tedious work on
different dates. This approach offers some distinct advantages, since the participant
cannot as easily smooth away the (dis)utility associated with these tasks. Perhaps for
this reason, present bias is more evident in tasks using such real rewards. Augenblick
et al. (2015) estimate a mean β of 0.9 when using an effort task, compared to
β = 0.974, much closer to exponential discounting, when using monetary payments
with a parallel design. However, such approaches come with their own challenges,
particularly the logistical difficulty of implementation, the practical problems of sub-
ject comprehension, and the remaining possibility that consumption or effort outside
the experiment adjusts in response to consumption in the experiment.
Where does this leave development economists who would like to measure time
preferences or present bias using surveys or experiments in the field? Unfortunately,
there are no easy answers. If measuring time preferences is central to the research,
implementing a real-effort task as in Augenblick et al. (2015) or Augenblick (2018)
may be the best option. If not, utilizing a money-earlier-or-later task may still provide
some signal of patience over monetary payments, even if it does not cleanly isolate
time preferences.
Recent evidence suggests that hypothetical and incentivized choices over money
provide fairly similar results (Ubfal, 2016; Madden et al., 2004; Falk et al., 2016),
making hypothetical choices over money an even lower-cost approach. However, hy-
pothetical choices over money may still fail to pin down present bias precisely for the
reasons described above in the discussion of the incentivized cases. These questions
may be supplemented with qualitative survey questions on self-assessed willingness
to wait for larger rewards, as in Falk et al. (2018).12
12 The Global Preference Survey of Falk et al. (2018) is worth highlighting here. The authors provide
an accessible dataset of unincentivized survey measures of risk, time and social preferences from 80,000
364 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
individuals in 76 countries. Their measure of patience is a function of both answers to quantitative money
earlier or later questions, as well as a qualitative self-assessment of patience. In a paper exploiting these
data, Dohmen et al. (2018) document a positive correlation between patience and income, both within and
across countries.
13 O’Donoghue and Sprenger (2018) in the first volume of this handbook provide a detailed discussion of
reference dependence.
2 High rates of return without rapid growth 365
effect with 50% probability. Then, the expected return of fertilizer is 50%. Given the
relatively small stakes, an expected-utility agent would be approximately risk neu-
tral, and would make the investment, since the expected value is 0.5 · ($6 − $2) +
0.5 · (−$2) = +$1. In contrast, a loss-averse agent with λ = 2.5 who narrowly brack-
ets returns for this investment would not invest, since 0.5 ·($6−$2)+λ·0.5·(−$2) =
−$0.5.
Despite the clear intuition for how loss aversion could cause individuals to forgo
high-return investments, we have relatively limited field evidence of the importance
of loss aversion in developing countries. Kremer et al. (2013) provide correlational
evidence: shopkeepers in Kenya who exhibit greater small-stakes risk aversion in
experimental tasks (presumably due to loss aversion) also maintain lower invento-
ries, thus forgoing bulk-purchase discounts and increasing the probability of creating
stock-outs.
Carney et al. (2018) provide field-experimental evidence on loss aversion, credit
and technology adoption among dairy farmers in Kenya. The authors study the de-
mand for collateralized loans to fund the purchase of durable assets (both domestic
and productive assets). They show that the endowment effect—a canonical implica-
tion of loss aversion—causes borrowers to dislike taking loans in which the collateral
is an asset they already own, since already-owned assets (such as land, jewelry, or
cattle) are already in the borrower’s reference point. The prospect of losing such as-
sets in case of loan default (say, due to a negative income shock) makes such loans
unattractive. In contrast, the authors show that loans collateralized using the new as-
set being financed by the loan itself, as in mortgages or car loans, are more attractive
to borrowers, since the new asset is not yet in the reference point at the time of loan
take-up, and borrowers do not anticipate experiencing as great a sense of loss in case
of default.
To isolate this effect, the experimenters endow potential borrowers with a
randomly-selected durable asset. A week later, individuals are offered a loan to
finance the purchase of a second randomly-selected asset, varying whether the col-
lateral required is the endowed asset, or the new asset itself. The authors find that
borrowers are willing to pay approximately 9 percentage points per month higher
interest rates to collateralize using the new asset. Interestingly, the same-asset collat-
eralized loans do not result in higher default rates, despite the higher take-up. This
suggests that, after taking possession of the new asset, borrowers’ reference points
update such that they come to develop a comparable endowment effect over their new
asset, even before it is paid off. Crucially, individuals systematically under-estimate
their future endowment effect before possessing an asset, an example of naïveté or
projection bias.
Carney et al. illustrate a general theme of this chapter, the interaction between
universal behavioral phenomena and institutions that differ across societies. To the
extent that people are reluctant to use goods they already own as collateral, creditors
operating in markets with institutions that make it easy to repossess collateral will
simply ask them to collateralize loans with the new items they are buying with the
loan. On the other hand, where the institutional environment is weak enough that
366 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
it’s hard to collect certain types of collateral, lenders may accept only the easiest to
collect forms of collateral.
For example, in the environment studied by Carney et al., the financial institution
making the loans, like most of its type, normally required that one-third of each loan
be collateralized with the borrower’s own deposits held in the financial institution,
and the remaining two-thirds be guaranteed by deposits by co-signers. Work by Jack
et al. (2016), suggests that substituting the ability to collateralize loans with newly
purchased assets, rather than with deposits in the financial institution, increased take-
up of loans for rainwater harvesting tanks used by dairy farmers from 2.4% to 44%.
This is thus an example of how in the context of developing country institutions,
loss aversion may prevent individuals from undertaking potentially high return in-
vestments, since financing these investments requires putting existing assets at risk.
The above discussion is all based on either static decisions, or on models with
limited dynamics. Unlike the literature on present bias, we only have a limited un-
derstanding of the implications of reference-dependence in life-cycle models. One
exception is Pagel (2017) who studies life-cycle consumption with expectations-
based reference dependence. We conjecture that dynamic models with reference
dependence may yield more reasonable dynamic predictions, with a fair amount of
stickiness in asset levels, but without the dramatically different dynamic behavior
around a threshold asset level than poverty trap models.
Loss aversion is less directly helpful in understanding the second empirical fact
underlying the Euler equation puzzle: borrowing at high interest rates without a cor-
responding increase in consumption over time. One way in which loss aversion may
increase demand for credit is if credit is used to insure against consumption losses or
losses of assets in case of negative income shocks. Of course, the question remains
why individuals are not able to self-insure by building up liquid buffer stocks, which
could be due to present bias as described in the previous subsection.
Narrow bracketing. The effects of loss aversion on choices involving risk are partic-
ularly likely to be important when individuals engage in narrow bracketing. Narrow
bracketing refers to an individual considering each choice or source of uncertainty
they face in isolation, failing to integrate it with other choices and risk from other
sources (Tversky and Kahneman, 1981). Narrow bracketing is implicitly assumed in
a range of economic models and analyses. It has bite in the case of loss aversion, due
to the importance of the sharp kink in the utility function at the reference point, which
would effectively be smoothed out if individuals were considering many sources of
uncertainty simultaneously.
Narrow bracketing can also reduce dynamic problems to repeated static prob-
lems if individuals bracket, for instance, daily income or annual stock-performance.
Bracketing also helps explain the so-called Samuelson bet problem: an individual
may turn down a single 50–50 gamble of losing $100 or gaining $120 but would be
willing to accept a hundred such gambles if offered together (Haigh and List, 2005;
Bellemare et al., 2005). Such choices are not compatible with expected utility but
are easily explained by the decision-maker bracketing the bets more broadly when a
hundred bets are presented together.
2 High rates of return without rapid growth 367
Lab evidence suggests narrow bracketing is in fact common and leads individuals
to make first-order stochastically dominated choices (Tversky and Kahneman, 1981;
Rabin and Weizsäcker, 2009). Field evidence on reference-dependence also presents
cases of narrow bracketing, from taxi drivers bracketing daily labor supply and earn-
ings (Camerer et al., 1997; Crawford and Meng, 2011; Thakral and Tô, 2018) to
investors bracketing realized financial gains or losses from each asset (Barberis and
Xiong, 2012). Many open research questions remain in this area, including deter-
mining in which cases individuals narrowly bracket, how these brackets are formed,
whether individuals can be taught to bracket more broadly, and whether such inter-
ventions translate into reduced risk aversion in investment decisions in the field.
Narrow bracketing may be particularly relevant in developing countries. Many
households run small firms and face a host of potentially risky decisions. For exam-
ple, a shopkeeper might have to make decisions of how much inventory to buy on
each of many different products and in each case if they are loss averse, they might
be concerned about the potential that some of the types of goods might go unsold,
creating a loss. A farmer makes decisions every growing season about whether to use
each of several different agricultural inputs, as well as whether to invest in livestock,
farm equipment such as irrigation pumps, etc. If the manager of a shop or a farm treats
each of these decisions in isolation, they may wind up turning down gambles that are
very attractive. Loss aversion combined with narrow bracketing could help explain
the high unrealized rate of return on additional inventory investment in Kremer et al.
(2013).
Reference-point formation. Models of reference-dependence come with an impor-
tant degree of freedom: the assumption about what constitutes the reference point.
The literature has taken different approaches to selecting the relevant reference point:
the status-quo level of wealth or assets (e.g. Kahneman and Tversky, 1979) and ra-
tional expectations of consumption (Kőszegi and Rabin, 2006, 2009) are the most
common. Other papers have chosen different reference points, such as the average of
lagged outcomes (DellaVigna et al., 2017) or salient targets such as round-number
finishing times among marathon runners (Allen et al., 2016).
Different assumptions about reference-point formation can generate important
differences in predicted behavior. Assuming a status quo reference point can pre-
dict staying in place, and sticky asset allocations, as well as a high degree of local
risk aversion. With expectations-based reference points, multiple equilibria are possi-
ble (Kőszegi and Rabin, 2006, 2009). If people have a stochastic reference point (and
are already anticipating uncertainty in outcomes), they will often be somewhat more
willing to take risks. We conjecture that both types of reference points are relevant
and important in different contexts. When people face decisions that they have much
experience with (e.g. planting usual crops), expectations will likely determine their
reference points. In contrast, if they face new choices (e.g. trying new technologies),
the status quo may be more likely to determine their reference point. Investigating
this question and the formation of reference points more generally remain important
areas for future research.
368 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
3 Health
Low investment in preventative health is one specific case of apparently underinvest-
ment in high-return opportunities.14 The neoclassical model has difficulties explain-
ing such behavior, especially when paired with the high sensitivity of this investment
to price and convenience. We argue that present bias combined with at least partial
naïveté can help explain some cases of low investment in preventive health due to
procrastination and liquidity constraints. However, other cases remain unexplained
by present bias alone. We argue that biased beliefs could play an important role in
explaining other cases of low investment.
14 Behavioral economists have also studied other aspects of health economics, such as health insurance.
We do not cover those topics here, in part due to less evidence on those topics from poor countries, and
refer readers instead to the chapter by Chandra et al. (2018) in this handbook.
3 Health 369
15 Taking deworming pills is not prevention but treatment. However, from a behavioral perspective, treat-
ment for chronic conditions is more similar to prevention than acute care: (1) acute conditions are salient,
but the worm load builds up over time and people don’t see a sudden worsening of health; (2) there is
a short-run disutility of taking deworming medicine as the worms are expelled. Any nutritional or other
gains take place over time.
370 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
FIGURE 1
Demand for preventative health products. The y-axis plots the share of individuals or
households taking up the product.
From Dupas and Miguel (2017).
change their decision in response to a small change in prices has a clear interpre-
tation: a large share of consumers must be very close to indifferent between taking
up the health investment or not. Therefore, the small incentive could easily tip the
balance between costs and benefits and change their decision. That is, the costs and
benefits associated with investing in their health must have been nearly equal, such
that they were making decisions balanced on a knife’s edge. While possible for a sin-
gle product, it appears extremely unlikely that this situation would occur for so many
different households (at the same price), and across a range of different technologies
and settings.
This reasoning suggests that households which do not adopt these preventive be-
haviors either do not perceive large benefits, or that decisions are not being made in
the way conventionally modeled by economists. Of course, some health investments
(e.g. vaccination against rare diseases) likely indeed have small private benefits. How-
ever, there are also cases of low take-up of health investments with large private ben-
efits. In at least some of these cases, individuals report believing in the effectiveness
of health investments (Kremer et al., 2011). A careful investigation of such beliefs,
including rigorous ways to address social desirability bias, and potential other expla-
nations for low demand would be a highly valuable contribution to this literature.
tinguished from purely financial costs) in the present, with benefits potentially years
in the future.
The degree to which present bias hinders the take-up of such behaviors depends
crucially on two factors: (a) how sophisticated an individual is about their present
bias (O’Donoghue and Rabin, 1999, 2001), and (b) whether the task involves clear
deadlines.
Naïveté and sophistication. A naïve, present-biased individual prefers and expects
to do a painful but worth-doing task tomorrow but fails to account for the fact that
they will also be present-biased then. The naïveté required for present bias is usually
thought of as overconfidence about future self-control.16 Sophistication, on the other
hand, makes the individual realize that if they do procrastinate today, they will also
likely do so tomorrow, increasing the cost of putting off the difficult task today. In
this way, naïveté can greatly amplify the impact of present bias on behavior and lead
to large distortions and welfare consequences (O’Donoghue and Rabin, 2001).
To better understand the extent to which present bias can explain low take-up
of preventive-health behaviors and the extent to which the explanation depends on
naïveté, we distinguish between the following categories of health behaviors:
Case I: Health investments without deadlines
Consider first a health investment good or action without a deadline for take-up.
Theory tells us that a sophisticated present-biased individual might delay taking up
such an investment good for a few time periods (say, days or weeks) due to present
bias. However, she will take up the good eventually, since she will foresee her future
present bias and thus avoid lengthy and costly delays. More generally, sophisticates
have rational expectations, so they anticipate correctly what they will do it if they
wait. For them, delaying from period t to period τ is a single decision to procrastinate.
Therefore, small self-control problems cannot cause severe welfare losses in such
investment decisions for sophisticates (O’Donoghue and Rabin, 2001).
In contrast, (partially) naïve individuals do not (fully) understand their future self-
control problems. Such individuals may think every day that they will incur the cost
investing on the following day, and never actually follow through with their plans.
Naïveté can compound the impact of self-control problems by inducing individuals
to make repeated decisions to procrastinate, each time believing they will do it next
period.17 The welfare costs arising from procrastination can become arbitrarily large
since a naïve individual never compares the immediate costs to future benefits. In-
stead the individual keeps comparing the costs of taking up the good today to the
costs of doing so tomorrow, wrongly anticipating that she will take up the good re-
gardless of the choice of doing it immediately (O’Donoghue and Rabin, 2001).
Many of the lifestyle choices with important health consequences involve habits
that could at least in principle be changed every day. On any given day, a smoker or
drinker may decide to quit. An individual may start improving their food intake, sleep,
or exercising behavior on any day. In such situations, the structure of costs and ben-
efits is the same as for take-up decisions without deadlines. A change in habit often
causes short-run costs for a limited time and yields significant benefits in the often-
distant future. While the short-run costs of such behavioral change can be substantial
(e.g. quitting smoking), they are arguably far outweighed by the long-run benefits in
many cases (e.g. avoiding lung cancer). There is typically no enforced deadline that
determines when to start changing a habit. As discussed above, while a sophisticated
person may delay changing their habits for a few days, present bias cannot lead to
large costs caused by the delay for this person. In contrast, a (partially) naïve person
may procrastinate for a long time, possibly forever telling themselves that they will
start developing virtuous habits soon but never actually following through.
The above discussion highlights the importance of considering naïveté in models
of present bias. For instance, if an individual is observed to never get a flu shot de-
spite being well-informed about the benefits and perhaps even displaying some stated
intention to do so, they may be procrastinating. If a researcher were to attempt to fit
a model of sophisticated present bias to the data, they would conclude that the indi-
vidual has such pathological levels of present bias, that they simply don’t care about
the future. If instead they allowed the individual to be naïve about their present bias,
plausible values of present bias may be able to fit the data quite well. While evidence
of demand for commitment suggest at least some sophistication (Schilbach, 2019;
Casaburi and Macchiavello, 2018), the best direct estimates of individuals’ sophis-
tication suggest that individuals are largely naïve on average (e.g. Augenblick and
Rabin, 2018).
Similarly, it is important to make sensible assumptions about the length of a time
period when modeling choices under present bias. A naïve present-biased individual
deciding whether to get a flu vaccination today or tomorrow may be tempted to wait
until tomorrow, since the expected cost of delay (i.e. the chance that he may get the
flu this evening) will be small compared to the lower discounted cost of getting the
vaccination tomorrow (which is down-weighted by the present bias factor). The cost
of delay might instead appear quite large if the choice is between going now and
going next month. The empirical literature suggests that the “present” in present bias
is a matter of hours or, at most, a day (Augenblick, 2018). Thus, it will often be
appropriate to model daily decision-making, unless the opportunity to take the costly
action truly only occurs once a month.
Impact of small incentives. In the absence of other issues, present bias will not lead
to large distortions for fully sophisticated present-biased individuals (O’Donoghue
and Rabin, 2001). As a result, there is only limited potential for small incentives to
alter take-up behavior of sophisticated agents, nor is there much need for them to do
so. Small incentives might accelerate take-up by sophisticated present-biased indi-
viduals, but they are unlikely to cause large shifts in the extensive margin of demand.
In contrast, small but time-limited discounts can have large effects for naïve present-
3 Health 375
biased individuals facing costly actions without deadlines. The time limit on these
incentives is crucial: on the last day of the incentives (or at some sooner date, in case
of uncertainty), the choice is between making the investment today at a lower price or
in the future at a higher price. The time limit makes acting immediately more attrac-
tive and can thus inhibit procrastination. In contrast, this reasoning does not apply for
permanent incentives. Essentially, time-limited discounts provide a deadline, which
can help overcome procrastination problems, as we discuss below.
Case II: Health investments involving deadlines (but no or small monetary costs)
Consider next a one-shot decision of an investment good that is otherwise not
available. An example could be a one-time visit by an NGO that offers to provide
you with deworming pills free-of-cost, or a vaccination camp at a local health clinic
where age-sensitive vaccines are provided for free. For realistic parameter values
and in the absence of other behavioral biases, present bias cannot explain the lack
of take-up of such high-return, time-limited investment goods. Present bias induces
individuals to put less weight on future benefits relative to current costs. However, re-
alistic estimates of present bias find values of β ≈ 0.7, which implies a 30% reduction
in weight on future periods relative to the present. Even a present-biased individual
with β = 0.5 or β = 0.3 (on the low end of empirical estimates) would take up the de-
worming or vaccination for their child (assuming they care about them sufficiently)
since the associated benefits outweigh costs by orders of magnitude. This insight
does not depend on the level of sophistication about present bias, since individuals
do not need to make predictions about their future behavior to make this one-shot
decision.
The present bias model similarly has difficulty explaining individuals’ lack of
take-up of investment behaviors that are available for a longer but still finite time
with a clear deadline. Essentially, on the day of the deadline, the individual’s choice
problem reduces to the one-shot decision as described in the previous paragraph, and
the present-biased individual will take up on that day if he has not done so already,
regardless of naïveté or sophistication.
The above conclusion is not greatly affected by the presence of shocks to the cost
of taking the action on any given day (subject to the deadline), provided the individual
has accurate beliefs about the distribution of shocks. For example, on any given day,
individuals may find it particularly costly to go to the clinic to get an immunization
since they may be busy or unwell. If they are forward-looking and think through the
optimal stopping problem, they will have in mind a reservation cost below which they
will take the action on each day, with the reservation cost rising over time. Naïve and
sophisticated agents may have different reservation costs on any given day, since the
naïve agent expects to be more patient in the future. But, again, both will do the task
on the last day if not done already, barring an extreme or unlucky shock. The welfare
losses from present bias in this case are thus bounded by the cost of delaying until
the deadline. Naïve individuals are, however, more likely than sophisticates to delay
the task up to the deadline before finally completing it.
If individuals have biased beliefs about the probability of future shocks, even
deadlines may not ensure take-up. For instance, suppose individuals have imperfect
376 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
memory, with a probability of simply forgetting about the task on any given day.
If they are sophisticated about this imperfect memory, they will act similarly to a
sophisticated present-biased individual and will not delay for long, since they realize
they might forget to do the task in the future. If they instead underestimate their
chances of forgetting in the future, they might put off the task until tomorrow, and
then forget to complete it despite the deadline.
While at any given point in time, lack of liquidity may explain why individuals do
not invest in their future health, liquidity itself is endogenous. As described in Sec-
tion 2, risk-averse non-present biased people living in an environment where they are
subject to shocks, should build up buffer stocks over time, even if they are initially
very poor. However, present-biased individuals will find it difficult to build up sub-
stantial buffer stocks and hence will be much more liquidity constrained (Angeletos
et al., 2001). As such, evidence of liquidity constraints preventing individuals from
making investments in their health can be interpreted as evidence in favor of the
importance of present bias rather than evidence against it.
Moreover, once an individual is effectively liquidity-constrained, present bias can
further reduce their demand for an investment good, since the monetary cost of the
investment will reduce immediate consumption more severely in the presence of
liquidity constraints (since consumption smoothing is hampered by liquidity con-
straints). Such a reduction in immediate consumption to finance the health investment
will be particularly unattractive to a present-biased agent.
Demand estimation. An important frontier in this area is how to estimate demand
for health investments or other goods in the presence of liquidity constraints.18 Unan-
nounced visits to study participants, offering to sell a good, will not measure long-run
demand under liquidity constraints. Several approaches have been pursued. One is to
endow people with money first. However, it is unclear how much money is needed
in a buffer stock world. In a model in which people are subject to shocks and hold
buffer stocks, WTP is likely to rise smoothly with the amount of money that people
are given in the experiment. Demand will only level off with a high buffer stock. Sep-
arately from this issue, endowing individuals with cash and then offering them items
for sale is likely to result in experimenter demand effects. A second approach is to
allow individuals time to purchase the good or to allow them to pay with their time
(Dupas, 2009). Offering coupons to purchase the good at a local shop may reduce
demand effects (Duflo et al., 2018). A third approach is to allow individuals to pay
using credit (Devoto et al., 2012).
Present bias and liquidity constraints complicate welfare calculations using
willingness-to-pay estimates. Welfare may be underestimated for at least two rea-
sons. First, present-biased individuals are likely to face liquidity constraints, which
will lower demand estimates. Second, even in the absence of liquidity constraints,
present bias may lower demand estimates for durables and long-run investments if
costs are upfront and not smoothed over the lifetime. Of course, behavioral models
including more generally some challenges to using revealed preference to infer wel-
fare (Kőszegi and Rabin, 2007; Bernheim and Taubinsky, 2018 in this handbook).
18 We refer the reader to Dupas and Miguel (2017) for a detailed discussion of this topic.
378 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Commitment devices are arrangements entered into by an individual with the aim
of helping fulfill a plan for future behavior that would otherwise be difficult owing to
intrapersonal conflict stemming from, for example, a lack of self-control (Bryan et al.,
2010). Demand for such devices is often interpreted as “smoking-gun” evidence of
time-inconsistency and self-control problems. It is difficult to rationalize why some-
one would elect to constrain their future choice set in the absence of time-consistent
preferences. Laibson’s (1997) model of quasi-hyperbolic preferences features time-
inconsistent preferences (induced by present bias) and can thus generate demand
for commitment. Alternative models of self-control are equally consistent with de-
mand for commitment (Thaler and Shefrin, 1981; Gul and Pesendorfer, 2001, 2004;
Fudenberg and Levine, 2006).
Ashraf et al. (2006) provide a proof of concept that offering commitment de-
vices can cause important changes in behaviors, as discussed in Section 4.1. More
recently, development economists have documented demand for commitment to
achieve health-related goals. Giné et al. (2010) offered smokers a voluntary commit-
ment product to support their attempts to quit smoking. Eleven percent of individuals
who were offered the commitment device took it up, with modest but significant im-
pacts on smoking six months later, which persisted in surprise tests at 12 months.
Schilbach (2019) explores the relationship between alcohol consumption and self-
control among rickshaw drivers in Chennai. As part of the experiment, participants
were offered a choice between receiving an unconditional payment of a fixed amount
or a conditional payment that had a high payoff for sobriety (measured using a breath-
alyzer) and a lower payoff otherwise. The amount of the unconditional payment
varied, such that one of the unconditional options weakly dominated the conditional
option and another strictly dominated the conditional option. Schilbach (2019) finds
substantial demand for costly commitment to sobriety: more than half of those of-
fered the choices chose the weakly dominated option that incentivized sobriety over
the unconditional payment, and more than a third chose the strictly dominated con-
ditional incentives over the larger unconditional payment.
Despite this promising evidence, commitment devices have not taken off as a pol-
icy tool or in real-world markets. Two weaknesses are at the heart of this issue. First,
while Schilbach (2019) and Casaburi and Macchiavello (2018) find high take-up for
costly commitment, demand for commitment devices is relatively low in many other
settings (Laibson, 2015).19 Second, many of the individuals who demand commit-
ment fail to follow through with their plans despite the commitment device, such that
they ex post appear to be made worse off by being offered commitment (John, 2018;
Bai et al., 2017).
Does the mixed (at best) success of commitment contracts imply that self-control
problems are not an important driver of preventive health behavior? To answer this
question, it is important to keep in mind determinants of commitment demand. A key
requirement for generating demand for commitment is a sufficient level of sophis-
tication about self-control problems. A completely naïve present-biased individual
19 See Table 1 in Schilbach (2019) and Table 1 in John (2018) for overviews of the existing evidence.
3 Health 379
would never demand commitment, since they believe they have no self-control prob-
lems beginning in the next period. Thus, demand for commitment is a one-sided
test for self-control problems: finding demand for commitment indicates self-control
problems (in the absence of confusion or social pressure to sign up), but absence of
demand does not necessarily mean self-control problems do not exist or are not im-
portant in that domain or in other domains. It could instead be that (a) individuals
are not sufficiently sophisticated to demand commitment, (b) that the commitment
device is perceived as being ineffective, or (c) that uncertainty in the environment
makes commitment unattractive despite self-control problems (Laibson, 2015).
The variation in take-up across settings could partly be explained by variation
in the extent of individuals’ present bias, as well their awareness of such problems.
While standard models of present bias assume that both the level of present bias
β and the level of sophistication about it (β̂) are the same across all dimensions,
it could be that individuals are more aware of their self-control problems in some
dimensions than in others. Of course, it is surely the case that much of the variation
is simply explained by difference in beliefs or long-run preferences: many people
may simply not think the task is worth doing and would not want their future selves
to do it either. People may also have varying beliefs about the likely effectiveness
of the contract, which in turn might be related to individuals’ experience with the
device. Better understanding the role of individuals’ beliefs in commitment decisions
remains an important area for future research.
Individuals’ failure to follow through is a second reason why commitment has
not become a more successful policy tool (John, 2018). If people are only partially
aware of their present bias, there may be systematic failures of commitment, with
plausibly negative effects on welfare. Those who are partially naïve may accept a
commitment contract without realizing the true extent of their present bias, resulting
in them incurring the cost of the commitment device without its intended benefit.
Bai et al. (2017) show how people may be willing to take out commitment con-
tracts that are ultimately welfare harming. They study attendance at “Hypertension
Day” health camps organized by a healthcare provider in rural India. In partnership
with the provider, they offer contracts in which individuals make a large up-front
payment, which reduces future attendance fees or, in the case where the payment ex-
ceeds the visit fee, provides a conditional payment for each future visit to the camp.
The authors find low demand for the commitment contracts, but among those who
do take up a commitment contract, a large proportion do not follow through with
their future visits to the camp. These people lose the paid up-front fee and do not
gain the health benefits that the contracts were intended to facilitate. This behavior is
consistent with partial naïveté, where individuals demand some commitment, but not
enough to overcome their present bias, which they do not fully anticipate.20
20 The authors also design a contract intended to appeal to naïve individuals: they bundle together price
discounts and commitment. The idea is that naïve individuals who expect to attend the health camp in any
case might sign up to take advantage of the discount, but then be helped ex-post by the commitment aspect
of the contract. Yet, even for this contract, follow-through rates are disappointing.
380 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Indeed, this point was made by Arrow (1963) in a paper sometimes considered the
founding work of modern health economics.
In addition to the general difficulty of learning about health, individuals often face
additional challenges to learning, especially in developing countries. For instance,
sometimes they may simply not have access to relevant information, and there may
be few trained experts around to learn from. Once we additionally account for the
fact that human beings systematically depart from the Bayesian learning benchmark
(see Benjamin, 2018 in this volume), the likelihood that individuals have inaccurate
beliefs—and perhaps systematically biased beliefs—becomes even greater.
Below, we discuss how inaccurate beliefs may explain some patterns in health be-
havior in developing countries. We describe reasons for inaccurate beliefs including
simple lack of access to information, as well as specific biases in learning and beliefs
which may be important, including information avoidance and motivated reasoning,
incorrect mental models, and non-Bayesian social learning.
Inaccurate beliefs. Misperceived returns to health investments could help explain
the stylized facts described in Section 3.1. Underestimating returns will drive down
the demand for preventive health investments. Perceived returns close to zero could
also help explain the high demand elasticity for such investments. Surprisingly lit-
tle work directly elicits individuals’ beliefs regarding the returns to different health
investments. While quantitative belief elicitation is challenging, methods have been
developed to elicit even probabilistic beliefs meaningfully in low-literacy popula-
tions in the developing world (see Delavande et al., 2011 and Delavande, 2014 for
reviews).
One example is Delavande and Kohler (2009), who elicit subjective probabilities
of HIV infection in Malawi. Compared to the actual HIV prevalence of 6.9% in Sub-
Saharan Africa at the time, 67% of respondents report that their likelihood of being
currently infected with HIV is 0, while only 1% think the likelihood is 100 percent.
Godlonton et al. (2016) elicit men’s beliefs about male circumcision and HIV trans-
mission risk and find that only 36% correctly believe circumcision is related to lower
HIV transmission risk.
It remains to be seen whether inaccurate beliefs, by themselves, can help explain
under-investment in preventive health. It could even be that eliciting beliefs height-
ens the puzzle in some contexts, if many individuals over-estimate the returns to
healthy behaviors or the risks involved in unhealthy behaviors such as for the risks
associated with smoking in the US (Viscusi, 1990) and the risks of HIV transmis-
sion in Malawi (Anglewicz and Kohler, 2009). However, our lack of understanding
of these beliefs constitutes a glaring gap in the literature at present. More systematic
elicitation of beliefs—including quantitative beliefs—in the health domain will be a
valuable agenda for future research.
Information interventions. A substantial body of work has studied the effects of
information interventions on health behaviors (although often without measuring
beliefs themselves). These have been treated as tests for whether information is a
binding constraint on preventive health behaviors. Put differently, providing informa-
tion and measuring changes in health behaviors is an indirect way of testing for errors
382 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
One compelling example from the developed world is Oster et al. (2013) who
study genetic testing among individuals at risk for Huntington’s Disease (HD). While
Huntington’s is a degenerative neurological disorder without cure, it may still be
very useful to learns one’s HD status as it can inform important life decisions re-
garding childbearing, retirement plans, savings, or education. However, despite the
relatively low economic cost, pre-symptomatic testing is rare. Moreover, actions
among untested individuals are strongly skewed toward the optimal action of those
who do not carry the HD mutation. Finally, individuals often get tested when their
symptoms paired with their genetic disposition predicts a positive result with near
certainty.
The standard neoclassical framework has difficulties explaining this set of results.
Oster et al. (2013) explain the patterns in the data using a model of anticipatory util-
ity. Untested individuals have the option to choose their beliefs about the future, at the
cost of increasing the probability of choosing the wrong action. Avoiding information
may be optimal if the increase in anticipatory utility outweighs the costs associated
with making choices based on wrong beliefs. Oster et al. (2013) explain the patterns
in the data using a model of anticipatory utility. Untested individuals have the op-
tion to choose their beliefs about the future, at the cost of increasing the probability
of choosing the wrong action. Avoiding information may be optimal if the increase
in anticipatory utility outweighs the costs associated with making choices based on
wrong beliefs.
Work on this topic in developing countries is scarce, but there is little reason to
think that a similar psychology might not apply also in poor countries, and with re-
spect to important health conditions ranging from HIV to hypertension and diabetes.
Indeed, Li et al. (2018) provide suggestive evidence on information aversion in the
case of diabetes blood-testing at a rural hospital near Beijing.
Although Oster et al. (2013) and Li et al. (2018) both use the same model of
anticipatory utility to rationalize their results, anticipatory utility alone cannot fully
explain people’s preferences over medical testing. In line with the evidence for other
health products, Li et al. (2018) and Thornton (2008) show that demand for medical
test results can be highly sensitive to small changes in prices, even among relatively
high-risk populations. It is hard for anticipatory utility by itself to drive this result:
it would require individuals to be close to indifferent, once accounting for both the
total expected benefits and costs of getting tested, and the change in anticipatory
utility from being tested. It seems unlikely that this would occur by chance for many
individuals.
Incorporating present bias into models of information preferences might help ex-
plain this behavior. If people are averse to learning medical test results, say due to
news utility or simply because they dislike focusing their attention on their health
status, then a present-biased person could forgo testing because they put dispro-
portionate weight on the immediate welfare costs of learning the test’s result.21
21 News-utility is different than anticipatory utility. In the case of news utility, the utility cost of receiving
news is at the moment that the news is received. By the next period, once the information has been incor-
384 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Especially in the case of naïve present bias, small psychological costs of learning new
information may cause individuals to procrastinate indefinitely on obtaining their test
result, as in Thornton (2008).
Redundancy neglect. Individuals may learn about health choices—such as which
provider to go to—by observing their peers’ decisions and experiences. To interpret
peer behavior, they must employ some theory as to how and why others made their
own decisions. For example, an individual who observes her two neighbors go to a
local witch doctor needs to think through what information their choice reveals. One
possibility is that both those neighbors chose to visit the witch doctor due to indepen-
dent private information. Another is that one of those neighbors simply observed and
imitated the other. In the latter case, the signal in support of visiting the witch doctor
is weaker—despite observing two neighbors, there is effectively just one information
source.
Eyster and Rabin (2010) provide a model of naïve social learning in which people
fail to appreciate the redundancy in their predecessors’ actions by naively interpret-
ing their actions as independent. The authors show that societies which behave in this
way can converge to confident and wrong beliefs, an outcome that is impossible in
standard rational-actor economics. Eyster et al. (2018) run a lab experiment in which
student subjects act in precisely this way: by failing to account for the redundancy in
one another’s actions, subjects do worse than they would do without the possibility
for social learning. While we do not have tests of this from the health domain, so-
cial learning about health behaviors and providers might be a promising domain in
which to study these biases. We discuss applications related to technology adoption
in Section 6.
Sampling and statistical biases. People often generalize from small amounts of
information—they tend to exaggerate the extent to which a small sample of out-
comes represents the distribution of outcomes they will face in the future (Tversky
and Kahneman, 1971; Griffin and Tversky, 1992; Rabin, 2002). For example, an in-
dividual who recovered from an illness after visiting a health provider and following
their instructions may be excessively confident that the provider is highly able.
Furthermore, summary statistics about a health behavior or product might not be
sufficient to correct beliefs: people also display a tendency to under-infer from large
samples (Griffin and Tversky, 1992; Benjamin et al., 2016). Information campaigns
that provide scientific evidence supporting a new treatment may thus have limited
effect, since individuals might continue to overweight individual negative experiences
or anecdotes relative to seemingly conclusive statistical evidence that runs counter.
Countering these statistical biases is potentially critical for more accurate beliefs and
better health behaviors.
porated into the reference point, the past news no longer “hurts”. In contrast, in the case of anticipatory
utility, news once learned will continue to affect one’s anticipatory utility in future time periods.
3 Health 385
22 One might argue even for negative prices, but these create obvious incentives for people to take the
good, accept the subsidy, and then not use it.
4 Savings 387
advocated charging users for preventive health products and services. The main mo-
tivation for this is the pursuit of financial sustainability. However, another reason that
is often cited in support of positive prices is that higher prices may stimulate higher
usage through a sunk-cost effect. The sunk cost effect describes a direct effect that
price has on use: it predicts that paying a price for a good makes an individual more
likely to use it (Thaler, 1980; Eyster, 2002). These effects have been demonstrated in
evidence from the field and the lab in rich countries. For instance, Arkes and Blumer
(1985) experimentally offered discounts to season ticket holders at a theater and show
a positive relationship between the effective price paid for a ticket and performance
attendance.
In the context of preventive health products in the developing world, there is good
evidence that higher prices (or even positive relative to zero prices) do not cause
greater product use. Ashraf et al. (2010) use a field experiment to estimate the impact
of the price of a drinking water disinfectant on its use. Their experimental design uses
a two-stage randomization procedure as in Karlan and Zinman (2009) to distinguish
between a screening effect, through which prices limit take-up to buyers who are
more likely to use the product, and a sunk-cost effect. Conditional on a household’s
willingness to pay, they randomize surprise price-discounts to obtain variation in the
actual price paid by a household. The authors find a strong screening effect, but no
evidence of a sunk-cost effect on ultimate usage of the product. While willingness to
pay sensibly predicts usage, the actual transaction amount paid does not. Those who
paid a positive price were no more likely to use the product at endline than those who
received it for free.
Cohen and Dupas (2010) use a similar two-stage price randomization design to
study the influence of prices on use of insecticide-treated bed nets. Conditional on
purchase of a net at a posted price, they surprise buyers with a randomly determined
discount and estimate the relationship between the discount size and net use. Consis-
tent with the results of Ashraf et al. (2010), they find no significant effect of effective
price on usage, suggesting that the sunk cost effect is not an important determinant
of usage of health products.
Overall, therefore, the evidence suggests that a policy-maker looking to increase
usage of preventive-health products should avoid small positive prices, as they lead
to large reductions in take-up without increasing utilization.
4 Savings
In recent years, an active field-experimental literature has studied savings in devel-
oping countries.23 At the individual level, as described in Section 2, savings are
23 See Karlan et al. (2014b) for an excellent recent review of neoclassical and behavioral constraints on
saving in developing countries.
388 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
24 This evidence raises the question of why the individuals with high returns to savings accounts do not
borrow or save enough to pay the fees (typically a few dollars) associated with opening these accounts.
4 Savings 389
different types of commitment devices of varying strength. They compare the effects,
relative to a control group, of providing participants with either a safe box in which
to store money at home (to which the participants have the key) or instead a lock box
(whose key is held by the research staff). The idea is that the former provides a softer
commitment than the latter treatment. Both treatments were motivated as targeting
saving to cover health expenses. A year later, the authors find high sustained use of
both products, but only the more flexible, softer commitment of the safe box led to
increased spending on preventive care.
The findings of Dupas and Robinson (2013b) connect to a key open question
surrounding the usefulness of commitment devices: the optimal tradeoff between
commitment and flexibility (Beshears et al., 2017). A commitment that is too weak
will not overcome self-control problems, while one which is too restrictive will
drive down take-up due to the real costs of commitment in uncertain environments
(Amador et al., 2006; Laibson, 2015).
The tradeoff between weak and strong commitment is complicated by the ex-
istence of partial naïveté. John (2018) studies savings commitment accounts in the
Philippines (in the same context as Ashraf et al., 2006) and shows that many of
the individuals who demand commitment savings fail to follow through with their
commitment and incur financial penalties. As a result, these individuals are (ex post)
made worse off by being offered the commitment device. Partial naïveté about present
bias can explain this result: partially naïve individuals realize that they have a self-
control problem, so they will have demand for commitment. However, they might
under-estimate the needed strength of the commitment, so they might sign up for
commitment contracts that do not provide sufficient incentives to follow through.
It is worth noting that savings commitments are not restricted to formal sav-
ings accounts. Instead, social networks and savings groups such as ROSCAs may
effectively provide commitment. Kast et al. (2018) show large impacts of public
goal-setting and group monitoring on savings, emphasizing the potential for social
ties to pay a role in motivating individuals to save. Breza and Chandrasekhar (2015)
randomly assign “monitors” to savers within the same village and show that monitors
cause an increase in savings of over 40% a year later, with some evidence of a social
image or reputation channel driving the effects.
We speculate that such socially-provided commitment might also be able to more
flexibly deal with uncertainty and shocks. While it is difficult for a formal provider
to contract on and verify shocks which may affect savings, others in the same social
or economic network may be better placed to do so.
Another potential weakness of commitment savings accounts is that they merely
prevent individuals from withdrawing money that they have already deposited. How-
ever, present-biased individuals might have difficulties depositing money into their
savings account in the first place. Alternative designs that include automatic pay-
ments into savings accounts (e.g. using M-Pesa in Kenya) could prove to be highly
effective.
390 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
individuals in developing countries do not have the option to automatically save for
retirement (such as using 401k savings vehicles) or to have their salary paid into their
bank account monthly. Instead, many workers are paid daily or even hourly, which
may increase individuals’ susceptibility to temptation. For instance, Casaburi and
Macchiavello (2018) argue that farmers may prefer to sell milk to the dairy where
they get paid monthly, rather than to sell it on the spot market for a higher price
because this creates a form of savings since they get paid at the end of the month.
Memory and attention. Limited memory and attention might distort individuals’
decision-making in various ways, ranging from medical adherence to savings be-
havior. Memory constraints might be particularly important for the poor since low
literacy levels make it difficult to effectively use of written reminders or similar tech-
nologies. Karlan et al. (2016) study the impact of reminders in a field experiment
with three different banks in Bolivia, Peru, and the Philippines. Their idea is that,
when making consumption decisions in the moment, individuals may forget or not
attend to their future consumption of investment goals. They find that reminder mes-
sages which increase the salience of the savings goal help individuals follow through
on their weak-commitment savings plan, suggesting important interactions between
memory and self-control (as in Ericson, 2017).
Exponential growth bias. Financial literacy can greatly impact individuals’ savings
choices (Lusardi, 2009). For instance, individuals may also underestimate the returns
to savings due to a systematic under-estimation of the power of compound interest
(Stango and Zinman, 2009). Song (2015) provides evidence consistent with exponen-
tial growth bias using a field experiment in China. A treatment group which is taught
the principles of compound interest contributes substantially more to a government
pension plan.
New technologies. The development of new technologies such as mobile money
creates great opportunities for the financial inclusion and empowerment of the poor
(Jack and Suri, 2014, 2016; Suri, 2017). Such technologies can greatly help indi-
viduals with behavioral biases, for instance, through automatic payment schemes or
reminders (Cadena and Schoar, 2011). A thorough understanding of the above behav-
ioral biases can greatly improve the design of adequate financial products. However,
new technologies also create potential for behavioral agents to be targeted and ex-
ploited, raising important questions of consumer protection (Ru and Schoar, 2016).
For instance, recent increases in sports-betting using mobile phones in East Africa,
and the growth of an industry making small loans at very high interest rates are im-
portant topics for future research.
and even political risk (e.g. civil conflict) (Hazell, 1992; Dercon, 2005). Under most
plausible utility functions, the sharply diminishing marginal utility of income at very
low consumption levels implies a particularly strong need for insurance. Yet, little
social insurance (whether health or income insurance) is provided by governments
in poor countries. Poor countries also have less well-developed markets for dealing
with risk through private insurance.
Instead, societies have developed non-market institutions for coping with risk
(Besley, 1995; Townsend, 1994). A large literature studies informal risk-sharing
in developing countries, and how risk considerations affect crop choice, migration
choice, and marriage, and other decisions. Evidence on the extent of risk shar-
ing within villages (or other networks, such as sub-caste networks in India) is
mixed. In some cases, one cannot reject the hypothesis that consumption moves
only with village-wide income shocks, not idiosyncratic shocks, but in other cases
consumption and even mortality and long-run health outcomes move with idiosyn-
cratic shocks (Paxson, 1992; Townsend, 1995; Yang and Choi, 2007; Rose, 1999;
Maccini and Yang, 2009). There is also evidence that consumption moves with
health shocks, sometimes dramatically (Gertler and Gruber, 2002; Collins et al.,
2009).
Since people in poor countries are often exposed to weather risk, and since such
risk is not generally subject to asymmetric information, it is a puzzle that rainfall in-
surance is not more common. Weather risk is different from other risks (e.g. illness or
death in the family) because it is not idiosyncratic, but correlated within regions, and
therefore cannot be easily insured away within villages or even across villages. These
reasons make rainfall insurance a particularly interesting context to study behavioral
biases, since other reasons for market failures or low take-up may be less relevant
here.
Weather insurance remains uncommon despite subsidies from governments and
NGOs. In India, rainfall-indexed insurance was introduced in 2003, but despite mon-
soons being notoriously unpredictable, and a large share of the population being
dependent on rainfall, take-up has been disappointing (Stein, 2016). Several field ex-
periments have found low levels of take-up, despite heavy subsidies and significant
marketing efforts (Giné et al., 2008; Cole et al., 2013). Some of this low take-up may
be explained by standard reasons, e.g. basis risk (Clarke, 2016) or fear of contractual
non-performance (Doherty and Schlesinger, 1991).25
Below, we focus on potential behavioral reasons that might contribute to in-
efficiently low take-up levels of insurance. We first consider existing evidence of
non-standard preferences affecting the demand for insurance. We then investigate the
role of non-standard beliefs.
25 Lack of trust is more generally correlated with low levels of participation in financial markets (Guiso
et al., 2006). Low social trust may have deep historical roots and be culturally-determined, as discussed in
Section 9.
5 Risk and insurance 393
26 Bad states may also fail to come to mind or be salient when times are good, and vice versa (Bordalo et
al., 2012).
27 Further evidence on recency effects in insurance choices includes a body of work by Slovic et al., 1974;
Kunreuther et al., 1978; and Gallagher, 2014.
6 Technology adoption 395
lower demand for insurance. To the best of our knowledge, no existing evidence con-
siders this hypothesis.
Beliefs in higher powers. Individuals’ beliefs might deviate in more dramatic ways
from standard probability assessments, including beliefs in higher powers, witchcraft,
and magic. In a clever lab-in-the-field study in Ghana, Auriol et al. (2018) find that
enrolling individuals in a commercial funeral-insurance policy lowers individuals’
investment behavior in religious goods, as measured by choices between payments
for themselves and contributions to church. The authors interpret their results as ev-
idence of individuals perceiving the church as a source of insurance, derived from
beliefs in an interventionist god. Such beliefs could be relevant barriers to demand
for formal insurance in other settings as well.
6 Technology adoption
The development literature has identified various instances of seemingly sub-optimal
technology choices. In Pakistan, Atkin et al. (2017) showed that take-up of a new
technology that reduced waste in the production of soccer balls was surprisingly low,
despite its potential to increase profits.28 Other examples of apparently non-optimal
technology choice in the development literature include fertilizer use in Kenya (Duflo
et al., 2008) and textile factories in India (Bloom et al., 2013).
Below, we discuss two behavioral factors that could potentially either interfere
with technology adoption: present bias, and limited attention. We then argue that
behavioral social learning could produce badly distorted social outcomes.
28 The authors point to the role of agency problems within the firm.
396 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
would otherwise lead to revision of beliefs. In such models, inattention can create
significant inefficiencies and lead to large welfare losses.
Hanna et al. (2014) apply this insight to technology adoption among seaweed
farmers in Indonesia. Given the complex production function with many possibly
important dimensions, the authors argue that farmers will only pay attention to the
dimensions of production they think are important. Hanna et al. (2014) track the
relationship between the size of planted seaweed pods and farmers’ output, arguing
that larger pods lead to greater output. Farmers, when asked, did not suggest that pod
size is an important determinant of output. 86% of farmers did not even know the
pod sizes they themselves planted, even though 83% of them were literate and the
average farming experience amongst the sample was 18 years.
Moreover, natural variation in pod size created numerous quasi-experiments that
farmers could have learned from. Hanna et al. (2014) argue that despite large amounts
of data being available for free on their own farms, inattention appears to have pre-
vented farmers from noticing this relationship. Hanna et al.’s (2014) data is based on
only a single season and there is significant cross-sectional variation in optimal pod
size. Since the authors did not collect impacts of their intervention on subsequent
profits, some questions remain whether optimal pod sizes for given farms vary over
time and whether the intervention indeed increased profits. Additional data to shed
light on this issue would be valuable.
If attention is limited, providing simple information with tips about optimizing
production may be more effective than providing full information. In an RCT to test
the above theory of inattention, Hanna et al. (2014) find that presenting farmers with
summaries that draw their attention to the importance of pod sizes changed their
farming techniques and increased output, but simply providing them with data on
initial pod size and eventual yield from each of their pods did not induce learning and
did not change farming behavior.
Similarly, Bennear et al. (2013) find in Bangladesh that a simpler message (pro-
viding red versus green labels) about whether a well has dangerous levels of arsenic
is more effective than providing more continuous information. In the Dominican Re-
public, Drexler et al. (2014) find that a simple “rule-of-thumb” training significantly
improved the financial practices of participating firm relative to a fuller training about
accounting. This evidence suggests that there are cases when limited attention may
lead to sub-optimal decisions and providing well-chosen limited information may be
more effective than providing the full set of available information.
There are also potential downsides of presenting simplified information. First,
there may be heterogeneity in the population and some individuals may benefit from
fuller information. Second, external analysts may not understand the decision prob-
lem as well as the people to whom they are trying to transmit information, or they
may pursue different objectives. They may therefore offer inappropriate advice. For
example, in an agricultural context, agricultural scientists or government departments
may seek to maximize agricultural production rather than profits and thus may not
appropriately value farmer time.
6 Technology adoption 397
these apply to others within the farmers’ social networks. For example, if farmers’
have envious or competitive preferences towards their peers, they may avoid shar-
ing information to remain or become relatively more successful. Farmers might even
choose to share false information to maintain an advantage. In contrast, individu-
als are likely to be altruistic towards others from their own extended families, kin
or ethnic groups, and might therefore be willing to provide advice to such individu-
als.
Existing research from Uganda provides some evidence for such differential ef-
fects: agricultural extension workers target information towards farmers from their
own social group, while withholding information from others (Bandiera et al., 2018).
This evidence suggests that accounting for the structure of social networks and dis-
tributional preferences across those networks may help explain patterns of social
learning and allow for the design of more efficient methods to seed and transmit
information.
Social-image concerns. Social-image concerns may keep farmers from asking oth-
ers for information or advice, since doing so may signal ignorance or low ability on
the part of the asker. An experiment conducted by Chandrasekhar et al. (2018) in ru-
ral India provides some evidence for such an effect. They design a field experiment
in which “seekers” must acquire information from a paired “advisor”. In one arm of
the experiment, the seeker’s need for the information is (artificially) correlated with
their ability from a baseline test, such that choosing to ask for advice may signal low
ability. In the other arm, ability is revealed to the advisor regardless of the seeker’s
choice to ask for information, such that the signaling channel is shut down, although
low-ability seekers may still feel some shame from interacting with an advisor who
has learned of his low ability. The authors find that signaling is the dominant force
overall and that low ability individuals do face large stigma inhibitions: there is a
55% decline in the probability of seeking when the need for information is correlated
with cognitive ability.
If such mechanisms are more broadly relevant—that is, if asking for information
about technology signals low ability even without artificially creating a correla-
tion between low ability and need for information—then interventions to reduce the
stigma of asking for information, for instance by using technology to make accessing
such information private, could increase the demand for social learning.
Social image concerns might also affect the supply of social information. On the
one hand, if acquiring the image of being a helpful community member is valued,
then social-image incentives such as publicly acknowledging those who share in-
formation might increase the supply of information. On the other hand, social-image
motives might instead reduce the supply or quality of information. For instance, farm-
ers may want to selectively share positive experiences that create an image of success,
while suppressing their failures, thus providing biased information. Similarly, farm-
ers may fear unfairly acquiring an image of being either incompetent or malicious, if
accurate information they share leads a peer to make a decision that ends poorly due
to chance.
400 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
29 This has been termed “Belief in the Law of Small Numbers” by Tversky and Kahneman (1971).
7 Labor 401
play a tendency to under–infer from large samples (Griffin and Tversky, 1992;
Benjamin et al., 2016). Information campaigns that provide scientific evidence sup-
porting a new technology may thus have limited effect, since farmers might continue
to overweight individual negative experiences or anecdotes relative to seemingly con-
clusive statistical evidence that runs counter. This bias prevents farmers from growing
confident when they should, meaning that their beliefs are too easily swayed by new
data. Such a bias, along with other statistical errors that give undue weight to recent
outcomes (e.g., base-rate neglect; see Kahneman and Tversky, 1973 and Benjamin
et al., 2018), may therefore underlie why some farmers seem to switch in and out of
using a new technology over time (e.g. Suri, 2011). Countering these statistical biases
is potentially critical for sustained adoption.
Selection neglect. Above, we highlighted several ways that farmers may selectively
transmit information (e.g. due to distributional concerns or for social image motives).
For those who receive this information to properly interpret its content, they must
properly account for the selection process underlying when and why farmers share
information in the first place. Farmers might, for instance, be excited to tell their
neighbors and friends when a newly adopted technology works well but say nothing
when it works poorly. Alternatively, competitive farmers may decide to keep infor-
mation about profitable technologies to themselves.
In each of these scenarios, rational inference requires special attention to the
selection rule: in the first case, taking recommendations at face value would lead
farmers to become overly optimistic about the technology; in the latter, it would
lead them to be overly pessimistic. Enke (2017) provides laboratory evidence that
many individuals completely neglect the fact that the signals they receive are selected,
especially when the environment itself is somewhat complex. However, nudging par-
ticipants by drawing their attention to the bias leads to much better inference.
7 Labor
This section discusses behavioral issues in labor markets in developing countries.
First, we highlight how work patterns in poor countries differ from those in rich
countries. Instead of 9-to-5 work in the formal sector as in rich countries, labor mar-
kets in developing countries are instead characterized by three features that might
potentially increase the importance of behavioral biases: high levels of informality,
casual labor, and self-employment.
We discuss evidence on worker productivity and labor supply in developing coun-
tries, including female labor-force participation; wage-setting and incentives with
behavioral workers; and the selection of workers.
time during those hours being devoted to work, and other time being devoted to do-
mestic responsibilities. We typically assume impersonal employment norms and laws
governing interactions between workers and their managers during the work period.
Such work patterns are far from the historical norm or the current situation in de-
veloping countries, where many individuals work in family firms without a sharp
delineation of work and domestic time; and others are subject to sometimes coer-
cive, multi-stranded relationships, for example, working as domestic servants or for
feudalistic landowners with de facto political authority.
Some historians of the Industrial Revolution argue that it is not at all natural for
people to work regular hours in factories under factory discipline, and that peas-
ants had to be turned into workers through pressures like enclosures and through
devices like factory bells and provisions to lock out workers who showed up late.
Many historians and some economists (e.g., Thompson, 1967; Marglin, 1974) have
argued that the introduction of the new management technology of factory discipline
was as important to the Industrial Revolution as any purely technological innovation.
Such scholars tend to see factory discipline as imposed on workers by capitalists, and
perhaps as made possible only by the dispossession of farmers by enclosure of the
commons.
Clark (1994) turns this interpretation on its head, with a much more benign view
of the role of factory discipline. He argues that workers themselves preferred the
introduction of factory discipline as a commitment device. He notes that under the
older putting-out system, workers “frequently kept irregular hours, often taking off
Monday (‘St. Monday’) and even Tuesday and working long hours on Thursday and
Friday” (Clark, 1994). Clark posits that workers valued the constraints imposed on
their behavior by factory discipline because this helped mitigate their self-control
problems.
Informality and self-employment. Labor markets in developing countries are charac-
terized by high levels of informality and self-employment. Most people in developing
countries are self-employed. The majority of the rural population operates a farm
in most developing countries, while many additionally operate a non-agricultural
business. The poor are highly likely to be self-employed entrepreneurs, potentially
running multiple microenterprises or juggling casual labor and business (Banerjee
and Duflo, 2007). In contrast, only 12% of employment in OECD countries is self-
employment.
Some standard explanations for the lack of large firms, and the prevalence of
self-employment in developing countries, are agency problems, credit constraints and
predation. A potential additional explanation is that regular employment may simply
be costlier for workers in poor countries. First, it may be harder to hold a formal job
simply because of the likelihood of unpredictable demands on one’s time. For exam-
ple, you may have to go to the hospital with family members when they get sick to
ensure they receive quality care, or you may yourself be more likely to get sick. Sec-
ond, preferences for work schedules may feature strategic complementarities, which
make fixed scheduled unattractive when others do not also have them.
7 Labor 403
In the United States, Mas and Pallais (2017) show that workers place little value
on work-hours flexibility, and instead have a strong preference for Monday–Friday
9-to-5 jobs. In contrast, in developing countries, where most others are self-employed
or engaged in casual day-labor, having a fixed schedule may be unattractive. Social
expectations for participation in events like weddings and funerals may be shaped
by the fact that most adults have flexible schedules. This fact may partly explain
why formal-sector jobs in poor countries often come with a wage premium. Such a
premium may in part be a compensating differential and not simply reflect a higher
marginal product of labor in the formal sector. It is also consistent with the doc-
umented high absence rates of employees even in the private sector in developing
countries (Kremer et al., 2005).
In standard models of development such as the Harris and Todaro (1970) model,
factory jobs are highly desirable and provide large rents. Many economists assume
that distortionary unions, or state-owned firms, or labor legislation provide these
rents. An alternative perspective is that these jobs are not particularly desirable.
Blattman and Dercon (2018) randomly assign industrial jobs in Ethiopia and find
that workers quickly quit and move to different sectors.
One implication of self-employment and informal employment is that workers of-
ten set their own work hours and effort, without the structure, commitment and norms
provided by formal employers. This feature makes behavioral phenomena such as
limited self-control and income-targeting potentially more important in labor mar-
kets in developing countries. Consistent with this hypothesis, Fafchamps (1993) and
Baird et al. (2016) find very low hours worked in agriculture in some parts of Africa:
just 9.8 hours per week among young Kenyan adults employed in agriculture. In
contrast, Bick et al. (2018) harmonize survey evidence from 49 countries (although
missing India, China and large parts of Sub-Saharan Africa) and conclude that people
in poor countries work more hours on average than those in rich countries. While we
do not yet have a full understanding of labor supply differences across rich and poor
countries, we discuss direct evidence on self-control problems at work in Section 7.2
below.
Casual labor in agricultural labor markets. The share of the population employed
in agriculture is much higher in poor countries than in rich countries. While most
agricultural production in poor countries occurs on smallholder farms, with family
labor as an input, there is also a highly active agricultural labor market. Most farms
employ outside workers for short spells using informal contracts; providing labor in
such markets is an important source of earnings, especially for the poorest amongst
the poor (Kaur, 2019).
How efficient are these labor markets? At first glance, agricultural labor markets
in poor countries would appear to satisfy many of the conditions for competitive
markets: many small buyers and sellers of labor, without formal unions or enforced
minimum wages. Yet, surprisingly, such markets exhibit several features such as wage
rigidity and limited wage dispersion. We discuss these in Section 7.3 below.
Role of the public sector. Formal employment in developing countries is often dom-
inated by the state. The public sector in poor countries is an attractive employer.
404 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
It provides a large wage premium over the private sector (much more so than in
rich countries), provides job security with few chances of being fired, and rarely uti-
lizes incentives or performance pay (Finan et al., 2017). This public sector typically
does quite poorly at providing public services such as education, health, sanitation
and law-and-order, relative to rich countries. A recent literature in development eco-
nomics has used field experiments to study the personnel economics of the state,
including topics related to behavioral labor: the selection of prosocial workers, and
the response to monetary and non-monetary incentives. We discuss some of these
issues in Section 7.4 below.
While many have seen the high absence rates among government social service
employees like teachers and health workers as evidence of weak incentives and poor
accountability in the public sector, it is worth noting that absence rates of teachers
in private schools are also very high (e.g., 22.8% in Indian private schools, Kremer
et al., 2005). One interpretation of this fact is that high absence rates are in fact part
of an efficient contract because employees find a regular 9-to-5 schedule to be very
costly.
Social norms and networks. Social norms and networks play an important role in
labor markets in developing countries, just as in rich countries. However, the nature
of the norms and social pressures may differ. For instance, many developing countries
have strong norms against female labor force-participation. In India, the caste system
prescribes norms regarding appropriate occupations for individuals based on their
inherited caste (although surprisingly little recent work in economics studies how
this distorts occupational choice). Given the importance of kin or caste networks in
poor countries, job search and referrals often flow along these networks, leading to
potentially inefficient matching of workers with jobs (Beaman and Magruder, 2012).
The barriers to the efficient allocation of workers to jobs—such as due to norms
against women or other disadvantaged groups working—may have large aggregate
effects on growth, as has been studied in the case of the United States (Hsieh et al.,
2018).
In addition, life for workers and even employers in poor countries features many
deprivations: the scarcity of money, the prevalence of environmental factors such as
noise and heat, and health issues such as chronic sleep deprivation among the urban
poor. While we discuss these factors in detail in Section 10 on the psychology of
poverty, they may also have implications for worker productivity.
(2019), who often work while inebriated, are only able to do so because they are
self-employed.
Kaur et al. (2010) study whether workers prefer contracts that help them commit
to working more to overcome self-control problems. Such self-control problems at
work may be different than in other domains because, in addition to reducing the
worker’s welfare, they can hurt profits. The existence of self-control problems fun-
damentally changes the nature of the contracting problem, in that both parties have
interests in incentivizing the worker to exert more effort in the future. Furthermore,
whereas in other contexts commitment mechanisms will only arise if agents are so-
phisticated and demand them, employers may elect to design contracts that mitigate
self-control problems even if the employee is naïve or does not demand them explic-
itly. The authors speculate that this may be the reason why employers often impose
contracts with production minimums, such as the forty-hour work week, where em-
ployees have little authority over how much they work, and instead must elect to
either work the designated amount or risk being fired.
Using evidence from a 13-month field experiment in India, Kaur et al. (2015)
investigate whether commitment contracts can help workers tackle their self-control
problems and increase their productivity. Study participants were hired as full-time
data-entry workers and paid a piece rate for output, without restrictions on their hours,
so that they could largely determine themselves how much they would produce and
be paid. Then, on randomly selected days, the experimenters gave workers the option
to set a target output level for the day. If their realized output fell below the chosen
target, workers received a piece rate that was half of the usual rate; if their output
exceeded the target, they receive the usual piece rate. Choosing a positive target cre-
ates a dominated contract, in that the contract punishes low output but does not reward
high output relative to a contract with no target. Crucially, apart from potential boosts
in productivity and labor supply, there is no reason for workers to choose a positive
target since doing so can only reduce workers’ pay for any given worker effort.
Workers set a positive target 36% of the time when offered the option to choose
a target level, thus selecting a dominated contract that incentivized reaching the tar-
get. Workers also exerted more effort as the randomly assigned payday approached,
suggesting high levels of worker impatience and the existence of self-control prob-
lems.30 The authors argue that workers chose these dominated contracts to overcome
self-control problems and commit themselves to working a certain amount. Indeed,
choosing such a contract increased worker output, with an effect of the same size as
an 18% increase in the piece rate. Those who had greater payday effects were more
likely to choose positive targets when offered and had larger increases in output un-
der these contracts relative to the standard contract. As some workers may be naïve
about their level of self-control, and thus may not choose commitment despite having
self-control problems, these estimates may be a lower bound on the extent of time
inconsistency and the potential of these kinds of contracts to increase productivity.
30 Although note that a standard model of present bias would not imply higher effort closer to the payday,
unless workers are severely liquidity-constrained.
406 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
This result is consistent with the explanation that the workers with the greatest
self-control problems benefited the most from the dominated contracts. However, if
there is heterogeneity among workers in the extent of self-control problems, workers
who do not have strong self-control problems may be made worse off by the fact
that other workers have self-control problems. This insight stands in sharp contrast
to other equilibrium settings in which, for example, the gym membership setting
in which agents with more standard preferences effectively benefit from the firm’s
efforts to exploit the preferences of behavioral agents since firms are subject to a zero-
profit condition in equilibrium. In this context, there is an adverse selection problem
in which firms may be forced to offer contracts with draconian work rules to avoid
selecting undesirable workers, even if those draconian work rules are not appropriate
for most workers.
Reference-dependence and income targeting. Another implication of self-employ-
ment with flexible schedules is that workers may engage in various forms of income
or effort targeting. In his book, The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, We-
ber argued that peasants in traditional societies have what modern economists would
label a backward-bending labor supply curve and contrasted this to what he saw as
the predictions of models of rational economic actors.
In a static labor-supply model, there are opposing income and substitution effects,
so the response to a wage increase is theoretically ambiguous. However, in a dynamic
model in which there are high-frequency wage shocks, and individuals have a con-
stant exponential discount factor, for any plausible parameter values, labor supply
would increase in response to temporary wage increases (e.g., Lucas and Rapping,
1969). Backward bending labor supply could be generated under at least two be-
havioral stories: reference-dependent preferences and present bias. First, we discuss
reference-dependent labor supply, which has received a great deal of attention in the
behavioral literature.
An active literature has studied whether workers such as taxi-drivers, who can set
their own hours, respond to wage shocks as neoclassical models would predict (by in-
crease labor supply when wages are high), or if they instead exhibit income-targeting
due to reference-dependence (such that fewer hours of work are supplied when the
wage is high, since the reference point/income target is attained sooner on high-wage
days).31 While there remains a debate in this literature, most evidence points towards
some role for income targets and reference dependence, with negative daily wage
elasticities (e.g. Thakral and Tô, 2018).
The literature on reference-dependent labor supply has largely been used to pro-
vide sharp tests of reference-dependence in the field, rather than because of the
inherent economic importance of daily labor supply in rich countries (O’Donoghue
and Sprenger, 2018 in Volume 1 of this handbook). In poor countries, given the
high share of self-employment, this phenomenon could be rather more important.
31 See, for instance, Camerer et al. (1997), Farber (2005, 2015), Crawford and Meng (2011), and Thakral
and Tô (2018).
7 Labor 407
Economists studying developing countries have begun to apply this idea to studying
labor supply (Giné et al., 2017; Andersen et al., 2014; Dupas et al., 2018b). Below,
we discuss one such paper in detail.
Dupas et al. (2018b) study the labor supply of Kenya bicycle-taxi drivers. They
depart from the existing literature in two ways. First, instead of estimating the refer-
ence point, or using the typical earnings as the reference point, they collect daily data
on the worker’s “cash needs” for the day—unexpected (until recently) expenses such
as repairs or entirely anticipated needs such as a savings-club payment coming due.
Second, instead of relying on instruments for the wage, they use experimental cash
drops on workers to generate variation in how quickly the cash needs for the day may
be reached.
The authors find evidence of income targeting, in that labor supply responds pos-
itively to cash needs, even entirely anticipated needs. However, a cash drop at the
beginning of the day does not decrease labor supply, implying that the reference
point is over earned income, rather than over total daily income.32 Finally, Dupas et
al. (2018b) develop a model in which being below the reference point reduces effort
costs (rather than the usual assumption that being below the reference point induces
a sense of loss). The authors calibrate this model to conclude that in the absence of
such income targeting, workers would earn 19% less, even in the absence of factors
like present bias. Since their model does not feature the exogenous wage shocks (as
opposed to cash drops) considered by the previous papers, they do not capture a po-
tential opposite effect of income targeting: that income-targeters will earn less for
the same total number of hours supplied, since they will work too long on low-wage
days, and too little on high-wage days.
Dupas et al. (2018b) thus implicitly connect the literature on reference-dependent
labor supply with a potential alternative or complementary explanation: liquidity con-
straints caused by present bias. In a standard model, individuals should not react
sharply to predictable daily expenditure needs, since they would be building up sav-
ings over time. If people are severely present-biased, as discussed in Section 2, then
they may hold no liquid assets and may also be incapable of saving funds from the
period with high wages and using them in periods with lower wages. In this case,
the dynamic labor supply problem approximately reduces to the static problem with
opposing income and substitution effects and the theoretical impact of a temporary
positive wage shock on labor supply is again ambiguous.
Environmental factors. Heat and noise are ubiquitous features of developing coun-
tries, especially in large cities. Dean (2018) conducts an ingenious set of experiments
in Kenya with factory workers who are accustomed to working in a noisy environ-
ment, recruiting them to work in an environment where the experimenter can control
noise levels. The author shows using a randomized intervention that a 10 dB increase
in ambient noise (akin to the increase in noise from running a vacuum cleaner com-
pared to a dishwasher) leads to a 5% decline in output of textile workers. Using lab
32 The literature studying cab-drivers has implicitly made the same assumption, since those papers only
consider a single source of income.
408 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
measures, he shows that the increase in noise also causes a worsening of cognitive
function. Specifically, executive function (also known as cognitive control), a set of
higher-order cognitive functions which direct one’s attention and manipulate working
memory (Diamond, 2013), declines by 0.07 standard deviations. While the decline
in cognitive function cannot be directly linked to the decline in the textile-production
output, some alternative channels such as direct effects on health can be ruled out.
Moreover, noise has no effects on a cognitively unchallenging effort task (the a–b
task of DellaVigna and Pope, 2017).
Importantly, Dean (2018) finds that workers seem unaware of the effect of noise
on their productivity, despite having frequently experienced exposure to such noise.
Stated beliefs about the productive effect of noise were generally inaccurate, and
workers were not willing to pay more for a quiet work environment when pay de-
pended on productivity compared to when pay was fixed (although the latter com-
parison is somewhat under-powered). This evidence suggests that while the amenity
value of quiet was valued to some extent, its productive value was not appreciated.
Workers are thus unlikely to take steps by themselves to sufficiently insulate them-
selves from noise.
Adhvaryu et al. (2018a) show similar effects for the consequences of heat in the
workplace. They work with 26 textile factories in India and show that replacing incan-
descent bulbs with LED lighting reduced temperature on the factory floor, boosting
output substantially, and particularly on hot days. Daily variation in temperature sim-
ilarly affects output. While the authors do not formally elicit workers’ or managers’
beliefs about the effect of heat, they note that the managers were unaware of the
productivity benefits of lowering temperature, and that the change in lighting was
implemented to reduce lighting costs. We return to this point when we discuss be-
havioral firms in Section 8.
duce wages. Moreover, transitory positive shocks lead to persistently higher nominal
wages, even when the marginal product of labor has returned to a lower level. The
asymmetry in response to positive and negative shocks is precisely what is predicted
with nominal rigidity. Such rigidities distort employment: agricultural employment
is 9% lower in the year following a positive shock. Consistent with the importance
of fairness motives, Kaur shows survey evidence that nominal wage cuts are widely
perceived as being unfair, as in the classic findings of Kahneman et al. (1986) and
Bewley (1998).
Breza et al. (2018a) provide field-experimental evidence on how such nominal
wage rigidities persist in the absence of enforced minimum wages or formal insti-
tutions such as unions. The authors partner with small employers to offer jobs to
workers in spot labor markets in India during the lean season, when unemployment
is high. They vary both the wage offered to the worker—either the prevailing market
wage, or 10% below the wage—as well as the observability of the wage offer (ei-
ther inside the worker’s home, or on a public street). Offers below the market wage
are often accepted when made in private (18%, compared to 26% acceptance at the
full market wage). However, acceptance of low offers drops to only 2% when the
low-wage offers are made publicly. In contrast, offers made at the market wage are
equally likely to be accepted in the private and public conditions. Workers thus ap-
pear to be subject to social pressure to prevent them from accepting job offers below
the prevailing market wage. Nearly a quarter of workers are willing to forego a day’s
work to avoid being seen as a “scab”.
The authors provide indirect evidence that the wage floor is enforced through so-
cial sanctions: when playing a costly punishment game in the lab, players impose
large penalties on their partners when they are informed that the partner previously
accepted a job at below-market wages. Interestingly, players impose these punish-
ments even on scabs in other villages, whose labor supply does not affect their own
outcomes, implying that punishing scabs is an internalized social norm. The paper
leaves one puzzle unanswered: why are employers not able to make such offers in
private themselves, especially given the repeated nature of the employment relation-
ships, and the potentially substantial efficiency losses?
Pay equality. An existing literature in behavioral labor studies the consequences of
pay inequality in the workplace. Card et al. (2012) show using a field experiment at a
large employer that disclosing information on peers’ salaries reduces job satisfaction
among workers with below-median salaries in their work unit and makes them more
likely to look for a new job. Breza et al. (2018b) build on this literature by studying
how social preferences over pay inequality affect not just satisfaction and job-search,
but also workers’ labor supply and productivity. The authors set up a manufacturing
workshop, in which 378 workers are randomized into small units of three workers
each, for one month of full-time employment. Workers are paid a flat daily wage for
attendance but select their own effort levels.
Breza et al. (2018b) randomly assigned work units to one of four different pay
structures. In the “pay disparity” treatment condition, each worker in the unit is
assigned to a different wage (wlow , wmedium , whigh ), based on their own baseline pro-
410 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
ductivity levels, with the most productive worker receiving the highest wage. The
pay differences between the three levels are modest (less than 5%). In three control
conditions, all workers in a unit were paid the same—either wlow , wmedium , whigh ,
depending on the group. This design allows the authors to compare two individuals
earning the same daily wage, with one being in a group with pay inequality (the treat-
ment group), and the other in a group with homogeneous pay (the control conditions).
Importantly, the design allows the authors to identify the effects of pay inequality
separately on high earners and on low earners.
The key finding is that when coworker productivity is hard to observe, introduc-
ing pay inequality reduces output by 0.45 standard deviations, driven largely by an
18-percentage point reduction in attendance. Somewhat surprisingly, while the re-
duction is largest for the workers who are paid the least in their group, even those
receiving the high or medium pay reduce their attendance, suggesting that pay in-
equality makes the workplace a less attractive environment. Overall, workers appear
to give up 9% of their earnings to avoid a workplace where they are paid differently
than their peers. Interestingly, these negative effects on worker morale vanish if the
wage inequality is more clearly justified: when output is more observable, or when
coworkers’ baseline productivity levels are further apart, pay disparity does not re-
duce output.
Kaur (2019) and Breza et al. (2018a, 2018b) help explain why even decentralized
informal markets in developing countries have high levels of nominal wage rigidity
and little dispersion in wages across workers.
Incentives in the public and non-profit sectors. Developing countries often have
poor provision of public services such as education and health. An active area of
research in development is thus on how to improve the productivity of workers in the
public and allied non-profit sectors. Recent work has evaluated financial incentives
for performance, with mixed results. Some papers find positive effects: for instance,
financial incentives for teachers can reduce teacher absence (Duflo et al., 2012) and
improve student test scores (Muralidharan and Sundararaman, 2011). However, pro-
viding incentives to multi-tasking agents is well known to be difficult (Holmstrom
and Milgrom, 1991). Indeed, some papers show that incentives are gamed when em-
ployed, and argue they are of limited utility (Glewwe et al., 2010). Perhaps the bottom
line is that such financial incentive programs, whether effective or not, are often po-
litically unpopular and are rarely adopted and scaled up by governments (Finan et al.,
2017).
One alternative, lower-cost strategy is to provide non-monetary incentives such
as social recognition and awards. The idea is to increase and harness prosocial mo-
tivation, to provide social-image or competitive motives to exert effort, and to align
the worker’s identity with the employer’s goals. Despite a great deal of interest in
such interventions, and evidence that social incentives broadly matter in organizations
(Ashraf and Bandiera, 2018), there is relatively little evidence on their effectiveness
in the field in poor countries, especially with the public sector or over an extended
period.
7 Labor 411
An exception is Ashraf et al. (2014), who compare financial and social incen-
tives for the sale of condoms by agents of a non-profit organization in Zambia. The
authors find that a simple non-monetary incentive—providing agents with a publicly-
displayed “thermometer” display and awarding stars based on sales—outperforms
even providing them with a 90% margin on selling condoms. However, in this case,
even the largest financial incentives were modest, given the low cost and demand for
the condoms. It is unclear what role the prosocial nature of the task played in mak-
ing the thermometer display effective. More research remains to be done on whether
such non-monetary incentives are more broadly effective, on which types of such
incentives are most promising, and what the underlying mechanisms are. The same
challenges with providing incentives to multi-tasking agents that apply to financial
incentives will also likely apply to non-monetary incentives.
Crowd-out of intrinsic motivation. One question that has garnered much interest
in both development policymaking and in behavioral research is whether extrinsic
incentives crowd out intrinsic motivations. Influential lab evidence from social psy-
chology has shown that extrinsic rewards can reduce individuals’ intrinsic motivation
to do a task. A famous paper by Deci (1971) shows that after a temporary incentive for
solving puzzles in the lab is withdrawn, effort in a subsequent unincentivized round is
lower than in a group where incentives were never offered to begin with. Several lab
experiments provide similar evidence of crowd-out of intrinsic motivation, and theo-
retical work in economics provides potential explanations for this phenomenon: e.g.
incentives can signal information such as task difficulty and extrinsic rewards can
muddy the self- or social-signaling value of a prosocial task (Bénabou and Tirole,
2003, 2006).
Yet, there is little field evidence that extrinsic incentives crowd out intrinsic mo-
tivation substantially.33 Lacetera et al. (2013) review field studies on incentives for
blood donation—an example of a prosocial task in which policy makers are con-
cerned about potential crowd-out—and conclude that in 18 out of 19 cases, providing
incentives increase donation, without evidence of long-run reductions in donations
if incentives are removed. Some papers also find that more pro-socially motivated
workers respond more to financial incentives, perhaps due to the correlations of pro-
sociality and other omitted variables in the underlying population (e.g. Ashraf et al.,
2014).
Overall, there seems little reason to think that extrinsic incentives systematically
crowd out intrinsic motivation in practice in real-world situations. This result is rel-
evant, for instance, for the ongoing policy debate about whether community health
workers should be paid more. In the following section, we describe evidence that
paying higher wages does not generally lead to increased select of less prosocial
workers.
33 An exception is Gneezy and Rustichini (2000), who find that introducing a small fine for late pickup
of children from day-care centers in Israel increased the incidence of late pick-ups.
412 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
personality traits, and experience. Yet this increase in applicants did not come with a
cost in terms of lower public-service motivation (measured using survey questions).
Ashraf et al. (2018) find similar results with a field experiment in Zambia, where
they vary across locations whether job postings to recruit health workers empha-
sized either career prospects or instead the possibility of helping one’s community.
Emphasizing career prospects led to recruiting applicants with higher high-school
grades, but no lower prosocial motivation. Moreover, those recruited under the career
concerns condition have much better job performance.
In contrast, Deserranno (2018) finds that posting job notices with a higher implied
pay attracts candidates who donate less money in dictator games, and who perceive
lower social benefits to the job at the time of applying. Such candidates subsequently
have higher turnover on the job. However, one important way this experiment differs
from the others is that Deserranno studies applicants to an entirely new position, such
that the advertised wages may communicate a great deal more information about the
position that will typically be the case. This feature makes it perhaps more likely that
the theoretical mechanism of Bénabou and Tirole (2006) applies, but it is not clear
that such an effect would persist once information about the jobs is more widely
diffused.
While paying less and yet recruiting more motivated workers is no doubt an attrac-
tive proposition for governments and non-profits, the bulk of the evidence suggests
that this is unlikely to be the case. This evidence is consistent with the underlying
correlation of cognitive ability and pro-sociality in the population: Falk et al. (2018)
find in their Global Preference Survey that altruism and reciprocity are both strongly
positively correlated with cognitive ability within countries. In addition, the previous
section argued that crowd-out of intrinsic motivation is similarly not typically found
in the field. Clearly, one should not generally expect to find that higher wages will
select out prosocial motives.
and with less female participation in the labor force. Thus, at least to some extent,
FLFP appears to be driven by sticky cultural and preference factors.
8 Firms
Behavioral economics investigates how individual decision-making, preferences, and
beliefs systematically depart from standard economic models. It is thus not surprising
that even behavioral industrial organization (Heidhues and Koszegi, 2018) has mostly
assumed sophisticated, profit-maximizing firms responding to behavioral consumers.
Is it reasonable to assume that firms successfully maximize profits? There are
numerous justifications for this assumption. First, one longstanding argument for
treating firms as neoclassical actors is that market forces should weed out firms that
systematically deviate from profit-maximizing behavior. Therefore, at equilibrium,
surviving firms will be profit-maximizers.
Second, applying the same argument to competition within firms and building
on Lucas’s (1978) span of control model, even if a significant share of individuals
exhibits behavioral biases, individuals without such biases may rise to become the
key managers and decision-makers in firms. In contrast, workers with particularly
severe behavioral biases might get fired. Of course, forms of principal-agent problems
within firms can attenuate this advantageous selection.
Third, many important decisions in large firms are made jointly by several actors
and often under intense scrutiny by stakeholders and the company’s board, potentially
limiting the scope for persistent mistakes, to the extent that groups are more rational
than individuals (Cooper and Kagel, 2005; Charness and Sutter, 2012; Kugler et al.,
2012). Moreover, workers typically receive considerable training and operate within
structures that are designed to limit the impact of behavioral factors.
Indonesia, the corresponding number is close to 100 percent. This firm distribution
is in sharp contrast to rich countries (Tybout, 2000). Thus, firms in poor countries
involve a limited span of control: decisions are often made by one person only, the
owner-operator. There is little scope for within-firm competition that might cause
non-behavioral agents to rise to the top of the firm via an efficient selection process.
Nor are firm owners necessarily highly selected. As described in the previous section,
self-employment rates are much higher in poor than in rich countries: a large share
of individuals operate some sort of firm.
A classic theme in development economics is the lack of separation between
household economics and firm economics for smallholder farmers. Under the condi-
tions for the separation theorem, family labor supply or risk preferences of household
members would not affect the type of agricultural production chosen. In reality, they
seem to have an impact (e.g., Lopez, 1984; Grimard, 2000; Le, 2010). Given this find-
ing in development economics, it is only natural to expect that behavioral factors, like
other household factors, would have important impacts on production in family-run
firms.
Behavioral issues might also be particularly powerful due to limited training and
education, and limited potential to learn from co-workers or to receive on-the-job
training. While new workers in a large firm are thoroughly instructed and trained,
such training does not exist in small firms in developing countries. Few owner-
operators have much business-training or adequate schooling, such that making opti-
mal decisions might be more challenging.
Some factors instead point in the opposite direction. One might argue that be-
havioral issues are less likely to have bite since the stakes are a lot higher for self-
employed individuals and owners of small firms—their consumption is directly tied
to profits. Moreover, within any given marketplace in Kenya or India, one can often
observe many seemingly identical retail shops that offer nearly identical products,
suggesting high levels of local competition. Yet, none of these shops appear to grow
rapidly and few go out of business. Nor do behavioral issues only matter for small
decisions: even high-stakes decisions such as retirement savings choices or decisions
to take one’s potentially life-saving medications seem to involve behavioral biases,
as described in other chapters in this handbook. Moreover, some behavioral factors
such as present bias and loss aversion could have more bite precisely because firm
profits and individual consumption are so intimately linked.
The topic of behavioral firms departs from an emphasis on the classic behavioral
biases such as present bias, loss aversion, etc. By “behavioral firms”, we simply mean
firms that depart from profit-maximization in systematic ways. We do not yet have
enough research on this to be sure if these cases are due to the same psychological
factors studied in consumer behavior or if other biases and behavioral phenomena are
more relevant in the case of firm decision-making. Almost surely, limited attention,
salience, failures of Bayesian learning, and self-control issues can matter for firms
too.
8 Firms 417
Trust, firm structure, and missing firm growth. Behavioral economics may provide
some insights into why firms in developing countries are small and typically run
as a family business with little decentralization in decision-making. Standard ex-
planations for small firms include taxation, regulation (e.g. labor regulation), and
predation. While these factors may well play some role, many firms are even smaller
than these thresholds (e.g. Hsieh and Olken, 2014), suggesting there may be addi-
tional reasons for firms to fail to grow. Credit constraints again likely play some role,
but even with incomplete credit markets, profitable firms should grow over time and
increase their market share.
Low levels of trust may play an important role in keeping firms small is. As de-
scribed in detail in Section 9, developing countries have systematically lower levels
of social trust than rich countries (Falk et al., 2018). Lower levels of trust have been
shown to be associated with smaller firm sizes and less decentralization of decisions
made within firms, both between and within countries (Cingano and Pinotti, 2012;
Algan and Cahuc, 2014). Non-Western countries are also more likely to have moral
values emphasizing the importance loyalty to one’s group and respect for authority
(Haidt, 2012). This in turn might make firm owners less likely to hire or cooperate
with out-group members, and less likely to decentralize decision-making, potentially
inhibiting firm growth. Moreover, these differences are driven at least in part by deep
historical factors (Enke, 2018; Schulz et al., 2018), and might thus causally explain
variation in firm size across countries.
This argument echoes an existing literature on agency issues in firms in devel-
oping countries. Ilias (2006) argues that some managers decide to hire only family
members as an organizational way of dealing with agency costs. Consistent with this
hypothesis, Ilias shows that there is a positive relationship between family size and
firm size in the surgical-instrument industry in Pakistan. Firm founders with more
brothers (and therefore a larger pool of potential managers) end up with larger firms.
Similarly, Bertrand et al. (2008) study 93 large business families in Thailand and find
a positive relationship between family size and family involvement in the company.
When the founder dies, sons play a larger role in the company, and their increased
involvement following the founder’s death is associated with lower firm-level perfor-
mance. The authors’ interpretation of these results is that the sons engage in a “race
to the bottom” to tunnel out company resources.
Bloom et al. (2013), discussed below, argue that the mid-sized firms they study
were constrained from taking up high-return management practices due to a lack
of management time. They implicate a low level of trust: firm owners do not trust
non-family members to make important decisions or occupy important managerial
418 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
slots. Managerial human capital even in these relatively large firms in India is thus
constrained by the number of male children in the owner’s family.34
Objective function. Standard producer theory assumes that a firm’s goal is to max-
imize expected profits. When firms are instead run as a small (family) business, the
objective function of the firm might be quite different. For instance, the owner’s risk
preferences likely matter, making risk-neutrality and thus expected-profit maximiza-
tion not a safe assumption. Firm owner-operators might not even desire growth, given
the increased effort and lifestyle changes firm growth might entail. Their objectives
may include providing employment to their family or descendants. They may operate
microenterprises as a coping strategy to diversify risk, given the potential for shocks
to other sources of household income such as agricultural output (e.g., Adhvaryu
et al., 2016). Yet, at present, we have a limited understanding of what the actual
objectives of firm-owners in developing countries are and the extent to which the
preferences and skills of household members affect firm decisions.
Pricing. Firms might make suboptimal pricing or product choices. They may have
trouble estimating consumer demand accurately, leading to suboptimal pricing or
product choices. Even if firms perfectly understand demand, they might deviate from
optimal pricing decisions. Recent work has begun to document substantial failures
of profit-maximization among even large and highly sophisticated firms in rich coun-
tries. For instance, DellaVigna and Gentzkow (2017) show that a large grocery-store
chain in the US prices its products uniformly within large geographical zones, despite
substantial variation in the incomes of shoppers across stores. The authors calculate
that the firm gives up 7% of profit by failing to price optimally. Given that such large
firms US chains leave plenty of money on the table by making suboptimal pricing
choices, it seems worth scrutinizing firms’ pricing choices in developing countries.
To the best of our knowledge, no such studies exist.
Inventory management. A recent literature has begun to point to examples of small-
business owners in developing countries leaving profitable investments unexploited.
Kremer et al. (2013) show that many shopkeepers in rural Kenya fail to make small
inventory investments with high expected returns. First, shopkeepers often fail to take
advantage of bulk-purchase discounts from distributors. A considerable mass of in-
ventory purchase orders is for quantities which fall just below thresholds at which
additional discounts kick in. In addition, shops frequently experience stock-outs due
to not maintaining enough inventory, even for relatively low-price goods which can
be purchased in small increments, such as phone cards. The correlation of returns to
inventory across goods is also low, suggesting that shopkeepers may not be equal-
izing marginal returns to inventory across goods. Inventory levels are predicted by
small-stakes risk aversion displayed by the owners in a lab game, as well as by their
math skills, but not by their self-reported credit constraints.
34 This example provides another illustration of the inefficiencies caused by the norms against female
labor-force participation.
8 Firms 419
Beaman et al. (2014) provide another example of small firms failing to maxi-
mize profits. They show that a representative sample of micro-enterprises in two
Kenyan cities lose 5–8% of total profits for a surprisingly simple reason: they fail
to keep enough change on hand to break larger bills, and thus lose potential sales to
customers. The authors study 508 typically small firms, with 60% having just one
worker, the owner. The firms include a variety of businesses, from vegetable vendors
to furniture shops, and service providers such as small restaurants, repair shops, and
barbers.
Simply drawing firms’ attention to the frequency of “change-outs” and lost
sales—through a randomized information intervention, or simply by asking them
questions about it—led to a reduction in change-outs and an increase in sales and
profits. This result parallels Hanna et al.’s (2014) results on inattention and technol-
ogy adoption: firms may not think that change-outs are important, and they thus fail
to attend to them. But once their attention is drawn to the neglected factor, or if they
are directly provided with the summary information, they make the high-return in-
vestment. If the change-outs were instead due to other (rational) factors such as an
aversion to keeping cash on hand due to the risk of theft, providing information on
the frequency and cost of change-outs would not be expected to change behavior.
Labor and capital choices. Firms might also deviate from profit-maximization in
their labor and capital-investment decisions, although we have few direct tests of
this. Adhvaryu et al. (2018b) show that even large firms may under-invest in worker
skills: an experimentally introduced low-cost soft-skills training for workers in a large
textile firm increased worker productivity by 20% without raising turnover, resulting
in a large internal rate of return (over 250% over eight months). How could such
large returns remain unexploited by a large firm? One possibility is that the owners
and managers simply under-estimate the returns to soft skills among workers.
Firms might also manage their staff inadequately, e.g. by providing suboptimal
incentives to workers, by making inefficient hiring choices, or by discriminating cer-
tain types of workers or by hiring their friends and family members. One suggestive
example is from Abebe et al. (2017), who document that firms in Ethiopia do not un-
derstand how skills among workers are correlated with barriers to applying to jobs.
Specifically, they show that a firm that provides a small monetary subsidy for people
to apply to its open jobs attracts a more talented applicant pool than it can achieve by
even doubling the offered wage. The crucial finding from the behavioral perspective
is that firms systematically under-estimate the effect of providing such a subsidy. In
fact, managers on average expect applicant quality to decrease due to the subsidy.
Finally, firms may fail to adopt the highest-return technologies, as discussed with
numerous examples in Section 6, although these focus on agricultural technology
adoption by small-scale farmers. Even larger firms may not adopt appropriate tech-
nologies. For instance, Adhvaryu et al. (2018a) describe how managers of the 28
textile factories in their study largely neglected the effect of heat on worker productiv-
ity, and thus undervalued LED-lighting technology. When LED lighting was adopted
to satisfy environmentally-motivated international buyers, the side-effect of reduc-
ing temperatures led to substantial unanticipated increases in productivity. Similarly,
420 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
tions, however, we describe arguments and recent evidence for systematic differences
in psychology across rich and poor countries, and across rich and poor individuals.
Section 9 describes a literature studying differences in social preferences (such as
trust and reciprocity) and culture across societies and then discusses its possible im-
plications for development. Section 10 describes the new literature on the psychology
of poverty.
These sections are more speculative, in part because the modern economics lit-
erature on these topics is newer. However, some of the ideas in Section 9 echo an
older tradition of thought on economic development, which viewed development as
a process involving important changes in social structure and in ways of thinking.
We begin by briefly sketching a history of the views of human behavior implicit in
thinking about development and growth.
35 In his Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith argued that behavior was determined by the struggle between
what Smith termed the “passions” and the “impartial spectator.” The passions included drives, emotions,
and motivational feeling. Smith viewed behavior as under the direct control of the passions but believed
that people could override passion-driven behavior by viewing their own behavior from the perspective of
an outsider—the impartial spectator (Ashraf et al., 2005).
422 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
36 Modernization theory also fell out of favor in sociology, but for somewhat different reasons: it was
criticized as conflating features of Western society with necessary requirements for development, and was
subject to criticism with the rise of dependency theory.
9 Social preferences, culture, and development 423
37 In surveys, generalized trust is measured with questions such as “Generally speaking, would you say
that most people can be trusted or that you can’t be too careful in dealing with people?”
424 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
body of work shows that such measures of trust (and trustworthiness) are correlated
with per-capita income and institutional features of countries: poorer countries and
regions have lower levels of trust (e.g. LaPorta et al., 1997; Knack and Keefer, 1997;
Tabellini, 2010).
Some economists view survey measures as unreliable and prefer incentivized or
revealed-preference outcomes. An innovative early paper by a team of anthropolo-
gists and behavioral economists ran incentivized social-preference lab experiments
in 15 small-scale societies across the world (Henrich et al., 2001). The authors report
considerable variation across these societies in play in dictator games, ultimatum
games, and public-goods games, although in each case outcomes deviate from self-
interested choices without social preferences or fairness concerns. The author point to
a correlation in their results between the degree of market integration (at the society
level) and greater cooperation in experimental games.
More recently, using the Global Preference Survey (GPS), a dataset covering
80,000 respondents who constitute nationally-representative samples from 76 coun-
tries, Falk et al. (2018) find systematic differences across countries in measures of
social preferences. Specifically, the authors find that developing countries have lower
levels of both trust and reciprocity. However, variation within countries substantially
exceeds variation between countries. Moreover, the measure of patience is more
predictive of per-capita GDP than measures of trust and social preferences, and con-
trolling for patience makes the coefficient on trust non-significant in a regression on
per-capita GDP.38
It is worth noting that there need be nothing irrational about low levels of trust.
To establish some failure of rationality, one would need to show, for example, sys-
tematically biased beliefs about how trustworthy others are, and separate this from
differences in preferences. Differences in societies across trust could, for example, be
driven by differences in history or institutions or could simply reflect multiple equi-
libria (e.g. Aghion et al., 2010, 2011; Alesina and Giuliano, 2015). We are not aware
of systematic evidence on this question.
Moral attitudes. In addition to the standard notions of social preferences in behav-
ioral economics such as altruism, fairness, reciprocity, and social image concerns,
psychologists have in recent years expanded our understanding of moral prefer-
ences. Such authors point out that psychology has focused excessively on WEIRD—
Western, Educated, Industrialized, Rich, Democratic—populations (Henrich et al.,
2010b). In such populations, morality is conceptualized as being primarily about
harm and fairness. Outside of these populations, for example, in developing coun-
tries, and in less-educated and lower-income populations in rich countries, moral
attitudes are broader than these two principles (Haidt, 2012). These conceptions of
morality include not only harm and fairness, but also deeply-held beliefs in moral
ideals of loyalty to one’s group, respect for authority, and purity or sanctity. Haidt
38 As discussed in Section 2, some of the correlation between GDP and measured patience could be due
to liquidity constraints affecting the measures of patience, even for hypothetical choices.
9 Social preferences, culture, and development 425
(2012) argues that these beliefs are extremely important to people and correlate with
important political and social behaviors. The implications of these different moral
frameworks for economic and political behavior are ripe for exploration.
Culture. A recent literature in economics takes an even broader view of cross-society
variation in values, beliefs and social preferences. Guiso et al. (2006) define culture as
“those customary beliefs and values that ethnic, religious, and social groups transmit
fairly unchanged from generation to generation”. Nunn (2012) instead defines culture
as heuristics and rules of thumb that aid in decision making, with a role not just for
values and beliefs, but also for emotions and “gut feelings”.
Nunn (2012) summarizes the evidence on differences in culture across soci-
eties. One empirical strategy has been to compare individuals from different cultures
brought into the same environment. For instance, Fernandez and Fogli (2009) show
that the fertility and labor-force participation of second-generation US women is pos-
itively correlated with historical fertility and labor-force participation in their parents’
country-of-origin. Fisman and Miguel (2007) study national variation in a culture of
corruption by documenting differences in rates of unpaid parking tickets accumulated
by diplomats from different countries who are all stationed in New York City.
Another strategy has been to conduct similar economic lab experiments across
different societies, such as the work of Henrich et al. (2001) or Gneezy et al. (2009).
More commonly, survey evidence has been used to document differences across
countries in the stated importance to the respondent of family, the importance of
children showing obedience and respect, the role of hard work versus luck in suc-
cess, or the degree to which people prefer to be self-reliant versus integrating closely
with a group (Alesina and Giuliano, 2015).
In recent years, some scholars of long-run growth and of cultural economics have
argued that trust and related social attitudes are not only an outcome of development,
but are instead (at least in part) deeper drivers of development themselves.39
One body of work provides evidence that modern-day trust and related concepts
such as trustworthiness have deep historical roots. Nunn and Wantchekon (2011)
show that current differences in trust levels within Africa can be traced back to the
transatlantic and Indian Ocean slave trades, and that individuals who have ancestors
from areas that were heavily raided through the slave trade show lower levels of trust
in survey data. This evidence provides a potential mechanism to explain the large
differences in modern-day development across the same regions of Africa (Nunn,
2008).
Other scholars have pointed to the importance of historical kindship structure in
generating variation in modern-day culture. Enke (2018) shows that historical tight-
ness of kinship structure predicts modern-day moral attitudes and social behaviors.
Enke classifies societies by whether they historically had tighter kinship structures,
in which people were deeply embedded in extended family networks, or conversely
looser kinship structures, in which such extended family networks were less impor-
tant. Groups which historically had tighter kinship have lower levels of trust, more
in-group favoritism, higher willingness to cheat on and distrust outsiders, and more
local rather than broader institutions today.
Schulz et al. (2018) argue that this psychological variation arose as a response
to different institutions governing kinship, descent and marriage. They propose that
the Catholic Church’s policies led to the dissolution of traditional kinship institutions
in Europe, creating the specific modern-day psychology specific to Western coun-
tries, including the increased importance of impartiality, universal moral principles,
generalized trust, cooperation, and fairness.
The above evidence suggests that present-day levels of trust, social preferences
and culture more broadly are not entirely determined by present-day outcomes, mak-
ing a causal role for trust on development more plausible. Other work more directly
attempts to link trust causally to economic outcomes. Algan and Cahuc (2010) use an
ingenious approach to determine historical levels of trust in various countries. They
examine trust levels in present-day individuals in the United States and, using varia-
tion in when the ancestors of those individuals first immigrated to the US, infer the
levels of trust in the sending country at the time of immigration.
Algan and Cahuc (2010) make a key assumption, well-accepted in cultural eco-
nomics, that present-day trust among individuals is correlated with the trust levels
of their ancestors. Moreover, they assume that the nature of selection into migration
by trust does not change substantially over time. The authors then relate the inferred
level of trust in each sender country in a given year to income-per-capita in that coun-
try in that year and estimate substantial causal effects of trust on per-capita income.
39 Recent reviews of this literature include Algan and Cahuc (2014), Spolaore and Wacziarg (2013) and
Nunn (2012).
9 Social preferences, culture, and development 427
In subsequent work, Algan and Cahuc (2014) calculate that Africa would have a 5.5
times higher per-capita income if it had the same trust levels as Sweden (Algan and
Cahuc, 2014).
Discussing the determinants and impact of ethnic diversity on economic, political
and social outcomes is beyond the scope of this chapter, but it is worth noting that
some studies using micro data suggest that, at least in some circumstances, there may
be costs to diversity. Moreover, these costs may be context dependent and subject to
policy influence.
Hjort (2014) examines how inter-group preferences can affect output. He collects
data from a large flower farm in Kenya and shows that workers have strong social
preferences featuring an in-group bias: they act to increase the payoffs of their co-
ethnics relative to members of a rival ethnic group. Workers work in small teams of
three, with one upstream worker and two downstream workers in each team. Hjort
(2014) shows that upstream workers distort their effort and direct more of the inter-
mediate goods they produce towards their co-ethnics downstream, resulting in both
productivity losses of 4 to 8 percent and lower earnings even for themselves. These
distortions worsen when ethnic divisions become more salient after electoral vio-
lence, until the firm finally reacts by adoption a team-pay scheme which eliminates
incentives to discriminate. The paper thus also provides an illustration of how insti-
tutions (in this case, within-firm rules and incentives) can be adapted to reduce the
distortions arising from ethnic preferences.
Ethnic diversity is also associated with worse local public goods. For instance,
higher ethnic diversity is correlated with lower primary school funding and worse
school facilities in Kenya (Miguel and Gugerty, 2005). The authors argue that di-
versity makes it more difficult to impose social sanctions, creating collective action
failures. However, as discussed in Section 9.4 below, such effects are not found in
Tanzania, a country with a history of policies designed to reduce ethnic conflict.
Not all the evidence suggests substantial individual-level ethnic prejudice. For in-
stance, Berge et al. (2015) run lab experiments in a large sample of participants in
Nairobi, Kenya, and find no evidence of ethnic favoritism in dictator games, public-
goods games, and choose-your-dictator games, in which the participant can choose
which other individual must decide how to share some money with them. Intriguingly,
Berge et al. do find evidence of bias among recent movers to Nairobi, suggesting that
living in a more cosmopolitan urban setting, with frequent interaction across eth-
nic groups, may have played some role in reducing ethnic preferences. In contrast
to the overall null effects on behaviors, the authors detect a small amount of ethnic
“bias” in Implicit Association Tests.40 The incongruence in the findings on behaviors
and implicit associations echoes with an ongoing debate in social psychology over
whether IATs meaningfully predict real-world behaviors (Greenwald et al., 2009;
Oswald et al., 2013).
40 The Implicit Associate Test (IAT) is a test developed by social psychologists to measure the extent to
which certain categories (such as race or gender) are associated with stereotypes, or with generally positive
or negative valence (Greenwald et al., 1998).
428 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Low levels of trust and the structure of in-group versus out-group preferences
may also be related to several other important economic and political outcomes.
For instance, some evidence suggests that levels of trust predict the structure of
firms: higher trust in Italian regions predicts larger firm size and more decentral-
ized decision-making (Cingano and Pinotti, 2012). Firms in Asia are substantially
more centralized in terms of decision-making than firms in the United States or Eu-
rope and the extent of centralization is correlated with regional trust. (Bloom et al.,
2012). Similarly, a sense of duty towards family and kin, and a lack of trust towards
strangers may contribute to a culture of corruption and patronage in politics.
national pride and more positive attitudes towards Nigeria, but simultaneously in-
creases the salience of one’s own ethnic identity, resulting in more positive attitudes
towards one’s own group (but not others). These results point to the need for a nu-
anced understanding of national identity and ethnic diversity: it is possible to build
national identity without weakening ethnic identity, even in a diverse developing
country.
Media. Exposure to media has been shown to be a powerful driver of change in
social preferences and attitudes in developing countries. For instance, exposure to
Rwandan government radio propaganda, which focused on post-genocide nation-
building, decreased the salience of ethnicity and increased inter-ethnic trust (Blouin
and Mukand, 2017). Most intriguingly, the authors show that individuals from treated
locations become less likely to use ethnicity (Hutu versus Tutsi) to categorize individ-
uals, suggesting that even the salience of ethnic categories is malleable and could be
influenced by governments or private media. Of course, such effects cut both ways:
the same media tools can effectively be used to worsen social attitudes, stoke distrust,
and even incite violence (Yanagizawa-Drott, 2014).
Exposure to television has also been shown to change attitudes and behaviors.
La Ferrara et al. (2012) find that telenovelas in Brazil reduce fertility for the exposed
cohorts in regions with access to telenovelas. Similarly, Jensen and Oster (2009) show
evidence that the arrival of cable television in villages in India changed stated gender
attitudes and some measures of behavior.
In contrast to the evidence on the effects of radio and television, little rigorous
evidence exists on the effect of the print media on social and economic attitudes.
Similarly, the rapid adoption of social media using internet-enabled cellphones in
developing countries offer another important topic for future research.
Education. Education is generally shown to be positively correlated with trust and
measures of prosocial preferences (e.g. Falk et al., 2018). However, we have rel-
atively little causal evidence on this topic. Miguel (2004) argues that Tanzanian
“nation-building” policies, partly implemented through school curriculum, allowed
ethnically diverse communities in rural Tanzania to achieve considerably better lo-
cal public goods outcomes than diverse communities in the nearby Kenyan region
without similar policies.
School curriculum changes in China have been shown to have substantially af-
fected students’ political attitudes, making them more skeptical of free markets and
more supportive of Chinese governance (Cantoni et al., 2017). Algan et al. (2013)
argued that horizontal teaching practices in school—wherein students work together
in groups—builds social capital. Rao (2018) similarly showed that direct personal in-
teractions between students, caused by quasi-random assignment of students to study
groups, reduced discriminatory behavior towards outgroup-members even outside the
classroom. Further evidence on how education affects in-group preference and moral
and social preferences is a promising area for future research.
This section has described the evidence on cross-society differences in social pref-
erences and other aspect of culture. It has pointed to both evidence that variation in
culture has deep historical roots, but also that social preferences, beliefs and values
430 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
are at least somewhat malleable at the individual level and respond to a variety of
interventions.
10.1 Scarcity
In an influential book, Mullainathan and Shafir (2013) argue that poverty impedes
cognitive function by capturing people’s minds with thoughts of scarcity. At any point
in time, a poor person may worry about paying their rent, their children’s school fees,
cellphone bills, or an adverse health shock with the potential to cause financial ruin.
Everyday events such as seeing the doctor or buying groceries are also more likely to
trigger thoughts about money or cost among the poor (Shah et al., 2018).
One might expect this increased focus to result in better decision-making. Models
of rational inattention would predict that when the stakes are higher, which they often
are for the poor, individuals will pay more attention and thus make better choices.
There is some evidence in support of this theory. The poor have higher awareness of
certain prices (Mullainathan and Shafir, 2013), and they pay more attention than the
rich to sales taxes (Goldin and Homonoff, 2013). They also display more consistent
valuations of goods across contexts, making them less likely to display biases such
as proportional thinking in money (Shah et al., 2015).41
However, according to Mullainathan and Shafir (2013), while some of this at-
tention is intentional and productive, much of it is not. Since cognitive capacity is
limited and money-related thoughts take up some of this valuable capacity, mental
“bandwidth” available for other tasks is reduced. As a result, they argue, poverty itself
impedes cognitive function among the poor, degrading also the quality of decision-
making and lowering productivity.
41 Shah et al. (2015) provide examples in which lower-income individuals hew more closely to a rational
model than the rich do. For instance, the poor appear to engage less in proportional thinking (Tversky
and Kahneman, 1981): they report being equally willing to travel 30 minutes to save $50 off a purchase,
regardless of whether the item they are purchasing costs $300, $500, or $1000. In contrast, high-income
consumers are more willing to spend 30 minutes to save $50 on a $300 purchase than on a $1000 purchase,
a classic finding in behavioral economics (Thaler, 1985). The poor also express the same willingness to
pay for an item across contexts, unlike the rich. Specifically, their WTP for a beer to be consumed on a
beach is the same whether the beer was purchased from a hotel or a store, while higher-income consumers
report being willing to pay more for the same beer from a hotel.
10 The psychology of poverty 431
Mani et al. (2013) provide empirical evidence in support of this hypothesis. Their
study features two complementary designs: a “lab study” in a mall in Trenton, NJ, and
a field study with farmers in India. The lab study induces thoughts about finances by
making individuals consider a financial scenario and then measures cognitive func-
tion using tasks developed by psychologists to measure fluid intelligence (IQ) and
cognitive control. Results from four different trials show a subtle but highly intriguing
picture. Performance by rich individuals, defined as those higher than median income
in the sample, is unaffected by whether the financial scenario concerns involve large
or small amounts of money. In contrast, when asked about the high-amount scenario,
the poor perform significantly worse compared to being asked about the low-amount
scenario, suggesting that induced thoughts about money lowered their cognitive func-
tion.
The complementary field study in Mani et al. (2013) cleverly exploits within-
person variation in financial status before and after harvest among sugarcane farmers
rural India. The harvest cycle for sugarcane, a cash crop, is about 18 months and
farmers have trouble evenly spreading the resources received at harvest over the en-
tire cycle, possibly due to present bias. Consequently, farmers are significantly poorer
in the months before harvest compared to the months after harvest, as reflected in be-
longings pawned, outstanding loans, and reported ability to cope with ordinary bills.
Farmers’ cognitive performance right before harvest is significantly worse compared
to their performance right after harvest. The authors provide evidence against compet-
ing channels such as nutrition or uncertainty and conclude that poverty itself impedes
cognitive function.
The results in Mani et al. are striking and important for several reasons. First,
the estimated effects are enormous. While the effect sizes in the lab study are diffi-
cult to interpret, the authors argue that the differences in the field study correspond
to differences of about 10 IQ points, comparable to the impacts of losing a night of
sleep or being moderately inebriated. Lower cognitive performance is known to be
correlated with lower levels of patience and willingness to accept risk (Dohmen et
al., 2010), worse job performance (Kuncel and Hezlett, 2010) and even higher mor-
tality (Batty et al., 2009). If these effects translate causally into worse real-world
decisions and behaviors, they could help explain puzzling behaviors among the poor,
such as evidence of lower parenting effort, lower medication adherence, and food-
consumption patterns. If such effects indeed exist, they may make an additional case
for the effectiveness of unconditional cash transfers, reducing hassles among the poor,
or subsidizing insurance to facilitate peace of mind.
There is also some, albeit disputed, inconsistently measured and hard-to-interpret
evidence of differences in cognitive ability across the rich and poor, and even across
rich and poor countries (Ervik, 2003; Palairet, 2004). Previous explanations of such
differences include differences in childhood nutrition (such as iodine supplements in
diet), education, and other omitted variables.
In contrast, Mullainathan and Shafir (2013) offer a new perspective: poverty it-
self may lower cognitive function. In fact, in the mall study of Mani et al. (2013),
described above, the cognitive performance of the rich and the poor was indistin-
432 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
guishable from each other in the absence of the financially-stressful question. The
argument is thus not one of fixed differences across individuals, but of the impor-
tance of the situation of poverty. This echoes the long-running debate in psychology
between social psychology, which argues that variation in human behavior is over-
whelmingly driven by variation in the situation or context (Ross and Nisbett, 1991;
Bertrand et al., 2004), and personality psychology, which argues that stable individ-
ual differences in personality traits explain a great deal of variation in behavior (e.g.
Borghans et al., 2008).
However, important gaps and shortcomings in this promising research agenda re-
main. First, the existing studies have understandable methodological limitations. For
instance, the field study of Mani et al. is a simple pre-post comparison without a
control group, which raises the question of potential learning effects or time trends
explaining the results. Second, to the best of our knowledge, neither of the two stud-
ies appears to have been replicated. In a related setting, Carvalho et al. (2016) find
no differences in cognitive function and decision-making around paydays in the US,
though this finding may be in explained by the smaller differences in financial hard-
ship before and after payday in their sample relative to those among farmers in India.
Third, to date, little evidence exists of impacts on economic outcomes such as pro-
ductivity, preferences, or decision-making. Ong et al. (2018) analyze the impacts of a
debt-relief program among low-income individuals in Singapore. While the authors
find intriguing impacts on a range of cognitive and economic outcomes, the study
does not feature a control group, causing identification concerns similar to the ones
regarding Mani et al.’s (2013) field evidence. Bartos et al. (2018) measure the impact
of poverty on time preferences. Experimentally-induced thoughts about poverty in-
creased Ugandan farmers’ impatience, as measured by their preference to consume
entertainment early and instead to delay work effort.
Kaur et al. (2018) consider the impact of poverty on productivity in a field exper-
iment with low-income piece rate workers in rural India. The authors randomly vary
the timing of wage payments to workers—generating variation in the timing of cash
receipt while holding overall income fixed—with the payment amount correspond-
ing to about 2 to 3 weeks’ worth of baseline earnings. Since workers are severely
cash-constrained at baseline, receiving early payments significantly alters workers’
expenditure patterns following the days of the payment. Workers reduce debt over-
hang and increase food purchases.
The authors interpret the early-pay intervention as changing the experienced fi-
nancial constraints among study participants. Upon receiving their early pay, workers
significantly increase their hourly output compared to the control group, with effects
concentrated among poorer workers. Kaur et al. (2018) find evidence of decreased
attentional errors in production, suggesting improved cognition as a contributing
channel for the productivity effects. The authors argue that the impacts are not driven
by gift exchange, trust in the employer, affect, or nutrition. The results provide evi-
dence that the alleviation of experienced financial constraints may have a direct link
with productivity and offer suggestive support for cognition as a channel.
10 The psychology of poverty 433
The effects of scarcity are most likely to translate into important real-world out-
comes if people are not self-aware of such effects. Individuals in both of Mani et al.’s
(2013) studies were not given a choice as to when to perform the cognitive tasks.
Individuals who understand the impacts of scarcity on their decision-making might
choose to make important decisions at times when they are cash-rich and thus to
mitigate the impacts of scarcity. To date, there is no evidence of people’s (lack of)
awareness of the impacts of scarcity on their cognitive function. In an experimental
study on the impact of noise on cognitive function and productivity, Dean (2018)
finds near-complete naïveté regarding impairments of cognitive function and worker
productivity due to noise.
Recently completed and ongoing work has attempted to make inroads into each of
these two lines of research. Studies have found significant impacts of noise, environ-
mental pollution, nutrition on worker learning, productivity, and earnings (Schofield,
2014; Chang et al., 2018; Dean, 2018; Jagnani, 2018). Many of the poor are exposed
to several of these factors, such that impacts on productivity and earning might well
add up to economically large magnitudes. There could also be important interaction
effects between these factors that are yet to be explored.
There is less evidence on the impacts of factors surrounding poverty on prefer-
ences and decision-making. Schofield (2014) finds evidence of increased nutrition
on effort discounting among low-income workers in India. Sleep deprivation ap-
pears to make individuals less altruistic, trusting and trustworthy (Dickinson and
McElroy, 2017). Similarly, Koppel et al. (2017) find that acute pain makes indi-
viduals less patient and more risk-seeking. Finally, Schilbach (2019) finds that in-
centives for sobriety significantly increased savings among low-income drivers in
India, particularly among individuals without access to commitment savings. Addi-
tional evidence linking the above factors to preferences and decision-making would
be valuable.
In an ongoing study, Bessone et al. (2018) study the impacts of improving sleep-
ing conditions among the urban poor in Chennai, India. They find that study par-
ticipants sleep on average under 5.5 hours per night, implying severe chronic sleep
deprivation, in part due to environmental irritants such as heat, noise, mosquitoes, and
physical discomfort. The authors evaluate different randomized interventions (such
as improving individuals’ home sleep environment and offering them a place to nap
at the workplace) to investigate the impacts of improved sleep on labor market out-
comes as well as behavioral biases and preferences (time, risk, and social preferences,
susceptibility to defaults, and inattention).
42 One approach is provided by de Quidt and Haushofer (2016), who model depression essentially as
having low beliefs about returns to effort. They show how this simple assumption can rationalize several
behaviors associated with depression.
43 For excellent discussions of the recent literature, see La Ferrara (2018) and Duflo (2012a).
10 The psychology of poverty 437
as endogenously set references point, useful to motivate one’s effort when facing
self-control problems (Hsiaw, 2013).
Dalton et al. (2015) propose a model of aspirations as reference points, wherein
aspirations influence effort choices, and effort produces future wealth. Future wealth
in turn causes aspirations to adjust, potentially producing a virtuous cycle. A key as-
sumption is that individuals do not realize how their future aspirations will be affected
by their current effort levels. That is, they do not internalize the future motivating or
demotivating effects of their present effort choice. Since the authors additionally (rea-
sonably) assume that poor individuals need to exert greater effort to reach the same
final wealth level, the model can generate poverty traps: even if they start with the
same aspirations, poor individuals will exert less effort, which will cause their future
aspirations to become lower, further reducing effort, and so on.
Genicot and Ray (2017) provide another model of aspirations as reference points.
In their model, parents have aspirations for children’s future wealth levels. Parents
receive a utility boost proportional to the extent to which their children exceed their
parents’ aspirations, creating a kink in the utility function akin to models of reference
dependence. Aspirations in their model are not (necessarily) rational expectations or
status-quo levels, but instead may depend upon the distribution of outcomes in soci-
ety. Aspirations moderately above the individual’s present level provide incentives to
invest, while avoiding frustration.
A key empirical question in this literature is whether aspirations are malleable and
how different policies might be able to affect them. Bernard et al. (2014) consider the
impact of exposing individuals to documentaries showing similar individuals from
their community who managed to escape poverty through their own efforts in agricul-
ture or business. The authors find remarkably large five-year impacts on aspirations
as well as investments in education, livestock, and agricultural inputs. More research
in this area is underway, with the goal to confirm and expand upon these striking and
surprising impacts from such a light-touch intervention.
Aspirations for one’s children could be particularly important for economic de-
velopment and poverty alleviation. Beaman et al. (2012) show that role models are
an important aspect in shaping individuals’ aspirations. The authors find that Indian
parents are less ambitious for the education and careers of their daughters than their
sons. However, random exposure to female politicians at the local level (due to a
reservation policy in India) sharply reduced this gender gap in aspirations as well as
actual educational achievement among teenage girls.
An open question is whether improving economic outcomes via cash transfers or
broader programs such as the ultra-poor program fosters higher aspirations. While
Banerjee et al. (2015b) do not report findings regarding aspirations in their six-
country evaluation of the multi-faceted “graduation program”, Sulaiman and Barua
(2013) report that changing aspirations is often cited by the implementers as the
438 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
44 Related evidence is provided by Laajaj (2017), who shows that an intervention providing input subsi-
dies and a savings match to farmers in Mozambique increases their self-reported planning horizons. The
author provides a model in which the agent’s planning horizon is endogeneously determined by how bright
their future prospects appear. The idea is that a gloomy future causes distress due to anticipatory utility,
and the agent responds by avoiding thinking about the future, worsening planning and reducing long-term
investments.
45 Bryan et al. (2018) provide a more thorough review of this literature.
11 Conclusion 439
could also foster individuals’ hopes and aspirations, and even boost mental health, as
argued in a contentious literature going back as far as Freud (Levin, 2010).
Cooley Fruehwirth et al. (2019) consider the possibility that religiosity directly
impacts depression. To address endogeneity concerns, the authors exploit across-
cohort variation in the religiosity of students’ peers at school. They report that in-
creased exposure to religious peers among US adolescents increased own religiosity
and lowered depression. The authors provide evidence that the mechanism through
which religiosity protects against depression is not by strengthening friendships or
increasing social activities. Instead, they argue, religiosity increases psychological
resilience and ability to deal with stressors. While this evidence is intriguing and im-
portant, identification concerns remain, and more work along these lines would be
valuable.
11 Conclusion
In this chapter, we discussed canonical topics in development economics through the
lens of behavioral economics. We argued that models and ideas from behavioral eco-
nomics can help explain important puzzles in development, and have applications to
understanding preventive health behavior, savings, demand for insurance, technology
adoption, labor markets and firms. We also discussed evidence of variation in social
preferences and culture across societies, and of the relationship between poverty and
psychology.
We have not discussed several important topics in development, due to limited
existing work on these topics in behavioral development. One such topic is educa-
tion. As an investment good, education may be particularly subject to behavioral
biases if children and youth themselves have substantial agency over educational in-
vestments (Bursztyn and Coffman, 2012). Existing evidence suggests that the time
preferences of students may be malleable and important (Alan and Ertac, 2018; Alan
et al., 2018) and that students may have systematically biased beliefs about the returns
to education (Jensen, 2010). Another under-explored topic for behavioral develop-
ment could be the economics of the family. Social preferences and norms within the
household could matter for consumption and investment decisions, as could biased
beliefs. For instance, Dizon-Ross (2018) shows that parents do not fully understand
their children’s (relative) ability and returns to education. Another topic we have only
touched on in passing is the political economy of development, where social prefer-
ences, biased beliefs and norms may all be important (e.g. Finan and Schechter, 2012;
Chen and Yang, 2018). We believe that these are equally important areas for future
work in behavioral development economics as those we have covered in this chapter.
While policy design is not the focus of our paper, we have discussed some cases of
success of behaviorally-informed solutions, for instance, the use of small incentives
to encourage desirable health behaviors, and the use of mental accounts to direct sav-
ings. In other cases, the solutions proposed by behavioral economics are yet to show
reliable impacts on outcomes, for instance, in the case of commitment devices to ad-
440 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
dress self-control problems. Yet other interventions show promising initial evidence,
but with much more investigation warranted, as in the case of psychotherapies to
improve mental health and economic outcomes.
We close by encouraging researchers in behavioral development economics to
take behavioral theory seriously and ideally quantitatively, providing calibrations or
estimations where possible (DellaVigna, 2018). This approach entails designing ex-
periments to more precisely identify specific behavioral mechanisms and to test for
them (Ludwig et al., 2011).
References
Abebe, G., Caria, S., Ortiz-Ospina, E., 2017. The Selection of Talent: Experimental and Structural Evi-
dence from Ethiopia. Technical report. Mimeo.
Acemoglu, Daron, Robinson, James A., 2013. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and
Poverty. Broadway Business, New York.
Adhvaryu, Achyuta, Kala, Namrata, Nyshadham, Anant, 2016. Management and Shocks to Worker Pro-
ductivity. Mimeograph. University of Michigan Working Paper.
Adhvaryu, Achyuta, Kala, Namrata, Nyshadham, Anant, 2018a. The Light and the Heat: Productivity
Co-Benefits of Energy-Saving Technology. NBER Working Paper No. 24314.
Adhvaryu, Achyuta, Kala, Namrata, Nyshadham, Anant, 2018b. The Skills to Pay the Bills: Returns to
On-the-Job Soft Skills Training. Technical report. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Aghion, Philippe, Algan, Yann, Cahuc, Pierre, et al., 2011. Can policy affect culture? Minimum wage and
the quality of labor relations. Journal of the European Economic Association 9 (1), 3–42.
Aghion, Philippe, Algan, Yann, Cahuc, Pierre, Shleifer, Andrei, 2010. Regulation and distrust. The Quar-
terly Journal of Economics 125 (3), 1015–1049.
Akerlof, George A., 1982. Labor contracts as partial gift exchange. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 97
(4), 543–569.
Akerlof, George A., Kranton, Rachel E., 2005. Identity and the economics of organizations. The Journal
of Economic Perspectives 19 (1), 9–32.
Alan, Sule, Boneva, Teodora, Ertac, Seda, 2018. Ever failed, try again, succeed better: results from a
randomized educational intervention on grit. Mimeograph.
Alan, Sule, Ertac, Seda, 2018. Fostering patience in the classroom: results from a randomized educational
intervention. Journal of Political Economy 126 (5), 1865–1911.
Aleem, Irfan, 1990. Imperfect information, screening, and the costs of informal lending: a study of a rural
credit market in Pakistan. World Bank Economic Review 4 (3), 329–349.
Alesina, Alberto, Giuliano, Paola, 2015. Culture and institutions. Journal of Economic Literature 53 (4),
898–944.
Alesina, Alberto, Giuliano, Paola, Nunn, Nathan, 2011. Fertility and the plough. The American Economic
Review 101 (3), 499–503.
Algan, Yann, Cahuc, Pierre, 2010. Inherited trust and growth. The American Economic Review 100 (5),
2060–2092.
Algan, Yann, Cahuc, Pierre, 2014. Trust, growth, and well-being: new evidence and policy implications.
In: Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 2. Elsevier, pp. 49–120.
Algan, Yann, Cahuc, Pierre, Shleifer, Andrei, 2013. Teaching practices and social capital. American Eco-
nomic Journal: Applied Economics 5 (3), 189–210.
Allen, Eric J., Dechow, Patricia M., Pope, Devin G., Wu, George, 2016. Reference-dependent preferences:
evidence from marathon runners. Management Science 63 (6), 1657–1672.
Allport, Gordon Willard, 1954. The Nature of Prejudice. Doubleday.
Amador, Manuel, Werning, Iván, Angeletos, George-Marios, 2006. Commitment vs. flexibility. Econo-
metrica 74 (2), 365–396.
References 441
Anagol, Santosh, Etang, Alvin, Karlan, Dean, 2017. Continued existence of cows disproves central tenets
of capitalism? Economic Development and Cultural Change 65 (4), 583–618.
Andersen, Steffen, Brandon, Alec, Gneezy, Uri, List, John A., 2014. Toward an Understanding of
Reference-Dependent Labor Supply: Theory and Evidence from a Field Experiment. NBER Work-
ing Paper No. 20695.
Andersen, Steffen, Harrison, Glenn W., Lau, Morten I., Rutström, E. Elisabet, 2008. Eliciting risk and time
preferences. Econometrica 76 (3), 583–618.
Anderson, Peter, Chisholm, Dan, Fuhr, Daniela C., 2009. Effectiveness and cost-effectiveness of policies
and programmes to reduce the harm caused by alcohol. The Lancet 373 (9682), 2234–2246.
Andreoni, James, Sprenger, Charles, 2012. Estimating time preferences from convex budgets. The Amer-
ican Economic Review 102 (7), 3333–3356.
Angeletos, George-Marios, Laibson, David, Repetto, Andrea, Tobacman, Jeremy, Weinberg, Stephen,
2001. The hyperbolic consumption model: calibration, simulation, and empirical evaluation. The Jour-
nal of Economic Perspectives 15 (3), 47–68.
Anglewicz, Philip, Kohler, Hans-Peter, 2009. Overestimating HIV infection: the construction and accuracy
of subjective probabilities of HIV infection in rural Malawi. Demographic Research 20 (6), 65.
Appadurai, Arjun, 2004. The capacity to aspire: culture and the terms of recognition. In: Rao, Vijayendra,
Walton, Michael (Eds.), Culture and Public Action. Stanford University Press, Stanford.
Arkes, Hal R., Blumer, Catherine, 1985. The psychology of sunk cost. Organizational Behavior and Human
Decision Processes 35 (1), 124–140.
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1963. Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. The American Economic
Review 53 (5), 941–973.
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1972. Gifts and exchanges. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 343–362.
Ashraf, Nava, Bandiera, Oriana, 2018. Social incentives in organizations. Annual Review of Eco-
nomics 10, 439–463.
Ashraf, Nava, Bandiera, Oriana, Jack, B. Kelsey, 2014. No margin, no mission? A field experiment on
incentives for public service delivery. Journal of Public Economics 120, 1–17.
Ashraf, Nava, Bandiera, Oriana, Lee, Scott, 2018. Losing Prosociality in the Quest for Talent? Sorting,
Selection, and Productivity in the Delivery of Public Services. London School of Economics and
Political Science Working Paper.
Ashraf, Nava, Berry, James, Shapiro, Jesse M., 2010. Can higher prices stimulate product use? Evidence
from a field experiment in Zambia. The American Economic Review 100 (5), 2383–2413.
Ashraf, Nava, Camerer, Colin F., Loewenstein, George, 2005. Adam Smith, behavioral economist. The
Journal of Economic Perspectives 19 (3), 131–145.
Ashraf, Nava, Field, Erica, Rusconi, Giuditta, Voena, Alessandra, Ziparo, Roberta, 2017. Traditional be-
liefs and learning about maternal risk in Zambia. The American Economic Review 107 (5), 511–515.
Ashraf, Nava, Karlan, Dean, Yin, Wesley, 2006. Tying Odysseus to the mast: evidence from a commitment
savings product in the Philippines. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (2), 635–672.
Atkin, David, Chaudhry, Azam, Chaudry, Shamyla, Khandelwal, Amit K., Verhoogen, Eric, 2017. Or-
ganizational barriers to technology adoption: evidence from soccer-ball producers in Pakistan. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 132 (3), 1101–1164.
Augenblick, Ned, 2018. Short-term time discounting in unpleasant tasks. Mimeograph.
Augenblick, Ned, Niederle, Muriel, Sprenger, Charles, 2015. Working over time: dynamic inconsistency
in real effort tasks. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 130 (3), 1067–1115.
Augenblick, Ned, Rabin, Matthew, 2018. An experiment on time preference and misprediction in unpleas-
ant tasks. The Review of Economic Studies, rdy019.
Auriol, Emmanuelle, Lassebie, Julie, Panin, Amma, Raiber, Eva, Seabright, Paul, 2018. God Insures Those
Who Pay? Formal Insurance and Religious Offerings in Ghana. Toulouse School of Economics Work-
ing Paper.
Bai, Liang, Handel, Benjamin, Miguel, Edward, Rao, Gautam, 2017. Self-Control and Demand for Pre-
ventive Health: Evidence from Hypertension in India. NBER Working Paper No. 23727.
Baird, Sarah, Hamory Hicks, Joan, Kremer, Michael, Miguel, Edward, 2016. Worms at work: long-run
impacts of a child health investment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 (4), 1637–1680.
442 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Bandiera, Oriana, Burgess, Robin, Das, Narayan, Gulesci, Selim, Rasul, Imran, Sulaiman, Munshi, 2017.
Labor markets and poverty in village economies. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132 (2),
811–870.
Bandiera, Oriana, Burgess, Robin, Deserranno, Erika, Rasulk, Imran, Sulaiman, Munshi. 2018. Social ties
and the delivery of development programs. Mimeograph.
Bandiera, Oriana, Rasul, Imran, 2006. Social networks and technology adoption in Northern Mozambique.
The Economic Journal 116 (514), 869–902.
Banerjee, Abhijit, Duflo, Esther, Glennerster, Rachel, Kinnan, Cynthia, 2015a. The miracle of microfi-
nance? Evidence from a randomized evaluation. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 7
(1), 22–53.
Banerjee, Abhijit, Duflo, Esther, Goldberg, Nathanael, Karlan, Dean, Osei, Robert, Parienté, William,
Shapiro, Jeremy, Thuysbaert, Bram, Udry, Christopher, 2015b. A multifaceted program causes lasting
progress for the very poor: evidence from six countries. Science 348 (6236), 1260799.
Banerjee, Abhijit, Mullainathan, Sendhil, 2010. The Shape of Temptation: Implications for the Economic
Lives of the Poor. NBER Working Paper No. 15973.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., Duflo, Esther, 2005. Growth theory through the lens of development economics. In:
Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 473–552.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., Duflo, Esther, 2007. The economic lives of the poor. The Journal of Economic Per-
spectives 21 (1), 141–168.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., Duflo, Esther, 2014. Do firms want to borrow more? Testing credit constraints using
a directed lending program. The Review of Economic Studies 81 (2), 572–607.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., Duflo, Esther, Glennerster, Rachel, Kothari, Dhruva, 2010. Improving immunisation
coverage in rural India: clustered randomised controlled evaluation of immunisation campaigns with
and without incentives. BMJ British Medical Journal 340, c2220.
Banfield, Edward C., 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. Free Press, Glencoe, IL.
Baranov, Victoria, Bhalotra, Sonia R., Biroli, Pietro, Maselko, Joanna, 2017. Maternal Depression,
Women’s Empowerment, and Parental Investment: Evidence from a Large Randomized Control Trial.
IZA Discussion Papers.
Barberis, Nicholas, Xiong, Wei, 2012. Realization utility. Journal of Financial Economics 104 (2),
251–271.
Bartos, Vojtech, Bauer, Michal, Chytilová, Julie, Levely, Ian, 2018. Effects of poverty on impatience:
preferences or inattention? Mimeograph
Basu, Karna, Wong, Maisy, 2015. Evaluating seasonal food storage and credit programs in East Indonesia.
Journal of Development Economics 115, 200–216.
Batty, G. David, Wennerstad, Karin Modig, Smith, George Davey, Gunnell, David, Deary, Ian J., Tynelius,
Per, Rasmussen, Finn, 2009. IQ in early adulthood and mortality by middle age: cohort study of
1 million Swedish men. Epidemiology 20 (1), 100–109.
Beaman, Lori, Duflo, Esther, Pande, Rohini, Topalova, Petia, 2012. Female leadership raises aspirations
and educational attainment for girls: a policy experiment in India. Science 335 (6068), 582–586.
Beaman, Lori, Magruder, Jeremy, 2012. Who gets the job referral? Evidence from a social networks ex-
periment. The American Economic Review 102 (7), 3574–3593.
Beaman, Lori, Magruder, Jeremy, Robinson, Jonathan, 2014. Minding small change among small firms in
Kenya. Journal of Development Economics 108, 69–86.
Bellemare, Charles, Krause, Michaela, Kröger, Sabine, Zhang, Chendi, 2005. Myopic loss aversion: infor-
mation feedback vs. investment flexibility. Economics Letters 87 (3), 319–324.
Bénabou, Roland, Tirole, Jean, 2003. Intrinsic and extrinsic motivation. The Review of Economic Stud-
ies 70 (3), 489–520.
Bénabou, Roland, Tirole, Jean, 2006. Incentives and prosocial behavior. The American Economic Re-
view 96 (5), 1652–1678.
Benjamin, Dan, Bodoh-Creed, Aaron, Rabin, Matthew, 2018. Base-rate neglect: foundations and implica-
tions. Mimeograph.
Benjamin, Daniel J., 2018. Errors in Probabilistic Reasoning and Judgment Biases. NBER Working Paper
No. 25200.
References 443
Benjamin, Daniel J., Rabin, Matthew, Raymond, Collin, 2016. A model of nonbelief in the law of large
numbers. Journal of the European Economic Association 14 (2), 515–544.
Bennear, Lori, Tarozzi, Alessandro, Pfaff, Alexander, Balasubramanya, Soumya, Ahmed, Kazi Matin, Van
Geen, Alexander, 2013. Impact of a randomized controlled trial in arsenic risk communication on
household water-source choices in Bangladesh. Journal of Environmental Economics and Manage-
ment 65 (2), 225–240.
Berge, Lars Ivar Oppedal, Bjorvatn, Kjetil, Galle, Simon, Miguel, Edward, Posner, Daniel N., Tungodden,
Bertil, Zhang, Kelly, 2015. How Strong are Ethnic Preferences? NBER Working Paper No. w21715.
Bernard, Tanguy, Dercon, Stefan, Orkin, Kate, Taffesse, Alemayehu, 2014. The future in mind: aspirations
and forward-looking behaviour in rural Ethiopia. Mimeograph.
Bernheim, B. Douglas, Taubinsky, Dmitry, 2018. Behavioral public economics. In: Handbook of Behav-
ioral Economics, vol. 1.
Berry, James, Fischer, Greg, Guiteras, Raymond P., 2018. Eliciting and utilizing willingness to pay: evi-
dence from field trials in Northern Ghana.
Bertrand, Marianne, Johnson, Simon, Samphantharak, Krislert, Schoar, Antoinette, 2008. Mixing family
with business: a study of Thai business groups and the families behind them. Journal of Financial
Economics 88 (3), 466–498.
Bertrand, Marianne, Mullainathan, Sendhil, Shafir, Eldar, 2004. A behavioral-economics view of poverty.
The American Economic Review 94 (2), 419–423.
Beshears, John, Choi, James J., Harris, Christopher, Laibson, David, Madrian, Brigitte C., Sakong, Jung,
2015. Self Control and Commitment: Can Decreasing the Liquidity of a Savings Account Increase
Deposits? NBER Working Paper No. 21474.
Beshears, John, Choi, James J., Harris, Christopher, Laibson, David, Madrian, Brigitte C., Sakong, Jung,
2017. Which early withdrawal penalty attracts the most deposits to a commitment savings account?
Mimeograph
Besley, Timothy, 1995. Savings, credit and insurance. In: Behrman, Jere, Srinivasan, T.N. (Eds.), Hand-
book of Development Economics, vol. 3 (Part A). Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 2123–2207.
Besley, Timothy, Ghatak, Maitreesh, 2005. Competition and incentives with motivated agents. The Amer-
ican Economic Review 95 (3), 616–636.
Bessone, Pedro, Rao, Gautam, Schilbach, Frank, Schofield, Heather, Toma, Mattie, 2018. Sleepless in
Chennai: The Economic Effects of Sleep Deprivation Among the Poor. Working paper. MIT.
Bewley, Truman F., 1998. Why not cut pay? European Economic Review 42 (3–5), 459–490.
Bick, Alexander, Fuchs-Schündeln, Nicola, Lagakos, David, 2018. How do hours worked vary with in-
come? Cross-country evidence and implications. The American Economic Review 108 (1), 170–199.
Blattman, Christopher, Dercon, Stefan, 2018. The impacts of industrial and entrepreneurial work on
income and health: experimental evidence from Ethiopia. American Economic Journal: Applied Eco-
nomics 10 (3), 1–38.
Blattman, Christopher, Jamison, Julian C., Sheridan, Margaret, 2017. Reducing crime and violence: exper-
imental evidence from cognitive behavioral therapy in Liberia. The American Economic Review 107
(4), 1165–1206.
Bleakley, Hoyt, Ferrie, Joseph, 2016. Shocking behavior: random wealth in Antebellum Georgia and hu-
man capital across generations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 (3), 1455–1495.
Bloom, David E., Cafiero, Elizabeth, Jané-Llopis, Eva, Abrahams-Gessel, Shafika, Reddy Bloom, Lak-
shmi, Fathima, Sana, Feigl, Andrea B., Gaziano, Tom, Hamandi, Ali, Mowafi, Mona, O’Farrell,
Danny, Ozaltin, Emre, Pandya, Ankur, Prettner, Klaus, Rosenberg, Larry, Seligman, Benjamin, Stein,
Adam Z., Weinstein, Cara, Weiss, Jonathan, 2011. The Global Economic Burden of Noncommunica-
ble Diseases. World Economic Forum.
Bloom, Nicholas, Eifert, Benn, Mahajan, Aprajit, McKenzie, David, Roberts, John, 2013. Does manage-
ment matter? Evidence from India. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128 (1), 1–51.
Bloom, Nicholas, Sadun, Raffaella, Van Reenen, John, 2012. The organization of firms across countries.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (4), 1663–1705.
Blouin, Arthur Thomas, Mukand, Sharun W., 2017. Erasing ethnicity? Propaganda, nation building and
identity in Rwanda. Mimeograph.
444 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Blumenstock, Joshua, Callen, Michael, Ghani, Tarek, 2018. Why do defaults affect behavior? Experimen-
tal evidence from Afghanistan. The American Economic Review 108 (10), 2868–2901.
Boisjoly, Johanne, Duncan, Greg J., Kremer, Michael, Levy, Dan M., Eccles, Jacque, 2006. Empathy or
antipathy? The impact of diversity. The American Economic Review 96 (5), 1890–1905.
Boldrini, Maura, Mann, J. John, 2015. Depression and suicide. In: Zigmond, Michael J., Rowland, Lewis
P., Coyle, Joseph T. (Eds.), Neurobiology of Brain Disorders. Academic Press, London, pp. 709–729.
Bolton, Paul, Bass, Judith, Neugebauer, Richard, Verdeli, Helen, Clougherty, Kathleen F., Wickrama-
ratne, Priya, Speelman, Liesbeth, Ndogoni, Lincoln, Weissman, Myrna, 2003. Group interpersonal
psychotherapy for depression in rural Uganda: a randomized controlled trial. Journal of the American
Medical Association 289 (23), 3117–3124.
Bordalo, Pedro, Gennaioli, Nicola, Shleifer, Andrei, 2012. Salience theory of choice under risk. The Quar-
terly Journal of Economics 127 (3), 1243–1285.
Borghans, Lex, Lee Duckworth, Angela, Heckman, James J., Ter Weel, Bas, 2008. The economics and
psychology of personality traits. The Journal of Human Resources 43 (4), 972–1059.
Borland, Ron, Wilson, Nick, Fong, Geoffrey T., Hammond, David, Cummings, K. Michael, Yong, Hua
H., Hosking, Warwick, Hastings, Gerard B., Thrasher, James, McNeill, Ann, 2009. Impact of graphic
and text warnings on cigarette packs: findings from four countries over five years. Tobacco Control,
358–364.
Breza, Emily, Chandrasekhar, Arun G., 2015. Social Networks, Reputation and Commitment: Evidence
from a Savings Monitors Experiment. NBER Working Paper No. 21169.
Breza, Emily, Kaur, Supreet, Krishnaswamy, Nandita, 2018a. Scabs: the social suppression of labor supply.
Mimeograph.
Breza, Emily, Kaur, Supreet, Shamdasani, Yogita, 2018b. The morale effects of pay inequality. The Quar-
terly Journal of Economics 133 (2), 611–663.
Bruhn, Miriam, Karlan, Dean, Schoar, Antoinette, 2018. The impact of consulting services on small and
medium enterprises: evidence from a randomized trial in Mexico. Journal of Political Economy 126
(2), 635–687.
Brunnermeier, Markus K., Parker, Jonathan A., 2005. Optimal expectations. The American Economic
Review 95 (4), 1092–1118.
Bryan, Gharad, Karlan, Dean, Nelson, Scott, 2010. Commitment devices. Annual Review of Economics 2,
671–698.
Bryan, Gharad T., Choi, James J., Karlan, Dean, 2018. Randomizing Religion: The Impact of Protestant
Evangelism on Economic Outcomes. London School of Economics and Political Science Working
Paper.
Burke, Marshall, Falcao Bergquist, Lauren, Miguel, Edward, 2018. Sell Low and Buy High: Arbitrage and
Local Price Effects in Kenyan Markets. NBER Working Paper No. 24476.
Bursztyn, Leonardo, Coffman, Lucas C., 2012. The schooling decision: family preferences, intergener-
ational conflict, and moral hazard in the Brazilian favelas. Journal of Political Economy 120 (3),
359–397.
Bursztyn, Leonardo, González, Alessandra L., Yanagizawa-Drott, David, 2018. Misperceived Social
Norms: Female Labor Force Participation in Saudi Arabia. NBER Working Paper No. 24736.
Cadena, Ximena, Schoar, Antoinette, 2011. Remembering to pay? Reminders vs. Financial Incentives for
Loan Payments. NBER Working Paper No. 17020.
Camerer, Colin, Babcock, Linda, Loewenstein, George, Thaler, Richard, 1997. Labor supply of New York
City cabdrivers: one day at a time. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (2), 407–441.
Cantoni, Davide, Chen, Yuyu, Yang, David Y., Yuchtman, Noam, Zhang, Y. Jane, 2017. Curriculum and
ideology. Journal of Political Economy 125 (2), 338–392.
Caplin, Andrew, Leahy, John, 2001. Psychological expected utility theory and anticipatory feelings. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (1), 55–79.
Caplin, Andrew, Leahy, John, 2004. The supply of information by a concerned expert. The Economic
Journal 114 (497), 487–505.
Card, David, Mas, Alexandre, Moretti, Enrico, Saez, Emmanuel, 2012. Inequality at work: the effect of
peer salaries on job satisfaction. The American Economic Review 102 (6), 2981–3003.
References 445
Carney, Kevin, Kremer, Michael, Lin, Xinyue, Rao, Gautam, 2018. The endowment effect and collateral-
ized loans.
Carroll, Christopher D., 1997. Buffer-stock saving and the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (1), 1–55.
Carter, Emily, Bryce, Jennifer, Perin, Jamie, Newby, Holly, 2015. Harmful practices in the management of
childhood diarrhea in low- and middle-income countries: a systematic review. BMC Public Health 15
(1), 788.
Carvalho, Leandro S., Meier, Stephan, Wang, Stephanie W., 2016. Poverty and economic decisionmaking:
evidence from changes in financial resources at payday. The American Economic Review 106 (2),
260–284.
Casaburi, Lorenzo, Macchiavello, Rocco, 2018. Demand and supply of infrequent payments as a commit-
ment device: evidence from Kenya. The American Economic Review. Forthcoming.
Casaburi, Lorenzo, Willis, Jack, 2018. Time vs. state in insurance: experimental evidence from contract
farming in Kenya.
Case, Anne, Deaton, Angus, 2015. Suicide, Age, and Wellbeing: An Empirical Investigation. NBER Work-
ing Paper No. 21279.
Cassidy, Rachel, 2018. Are the Poor so Present-Biased? Institute for Fiscal Studies Working Paper
No. 18/24.
Chabris, Christopher F., Laibson, David, Morris, Carrie L., Schuldt, Jonathon P., Taubinsky, Dmitry,
2008. Individual laboratory-measured discount rates predict field behavior. Journal of Risk and Un-
certainty 37 (2–3), 237–269.
Chandra, Amitabh, Handel, Benjamin, Schwartzstein, Joshua, 2018. Behavioral economics and health-care
markets.
Chandrasekhar, Arun G., Golub, Benjamin, Yang, He, 2018. Signaling, Shame, and Silence in Social
Learning. NBER Working Paper No. 25169.
Chang, Tom Y., Huang, Wei, Wang, Yongxiang, 2018. Something in the air: projection bias and the demand
for health insurance. The Review of Economic Studies 85 (3), 1609–1634.
Charness, Gary, Sutter, Matthias, 2012. Groups make better self-interested decisions. The Journal of Eco-
nomic Perspectives 26 (3), 157–176.
Chen, Yuyu, Yang, David Y., 2018. The impact of media censorship: 1984 or brave new world? Mimeo-
graph
Chetty, Raj, 2015. Behavioral economics and public policy: a pragmatic perspective. The American Eco-
nomic Review 105 (5), 1–33.
Chetty, Raj, Friedman, John N., Leth-Petersen, Søren, Heien Nielsen, Torben, Olsen, Tore, 2014. Active
vs. passive decisions and crowd-out in retirement savings accounts: evidence from Denmark. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (3), 1141–1219.
Choi, J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B., Metrick, A., 2002. Defined contribution pensions: plan rules, participant
decisions, and the path of least resistance. Tax Policy and the Economy 16, 67–114.
Christian, Cornelius, Hensel, Lukas, Roth, Christopher, 2018. Income shocks and suicides: causal evidence
from Indonesia. Available at SSRN 2716684.
Cingano, Federico, Pinotti, Paolo, 2012. Trust, firm organization and the structure of production. Carlo F.
Dondena Centre for Research on Social Dynamics Working Paper No. 053.
Clark, Gregory, 1994. Factory discipline. The Journal of Economic History 54 (1), 128–163.
Clarke, Daniel J., 2016. A theory of rational demand for index insurance. American Economic Journal:
Microeconomics 8 (1), 283–306.
Clingingsmith, David, Khwaja, Asim Ijaz, Kremer, Michael, 2009. Estimating the impact of the hajj:
religion and tolerance in Islam’s global gathering. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (3),
1133–1170.
Cohen, Jessica, Dupas, Pascaline, 2010. Free distribution or cost-sharing? Evidence from a randomized
malaria prevention experiment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (1), 1–45.
Cohen, Jessica, Dupas, Pascaline, Schaner, Simone, 2015. Price subsidies, diagnostic tests, and targeting of
malaria treatment: evidence from a randomized controlled trial. The American Economic Review 105
(2), 609–645.
446 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Cohen, Jonathan D., Ericson, Keith Marzilli, Laibson, David, Myles White, John, 2016. Measuring Time
Preferences. NBER Working Paper No. 22455.
Cole, Shawn, Giné, Xavier, Tobacman, Jeremy, Topalova, Petia, Townsend, Robert, Vickery, James, 2013.
Barriers to household risk management: evidence from India. American Economic Journal: Applied
Economics 5 (1), 104–135.
Coleman, James, 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Collins, D., Morduch, J., Rutherford, S., Ruthven, O., 2009. Portfolios of the Poor: How the World’s Poor
Live on $2 a Day. Princeton University Press.
Conley, Timothy G., Udry, Christopher R., 2010. Learning about a new technology: pineapple in Ghana.
The American Economic Review 100 (1), 35–69.
Cooley Fruehwirth, Jane, Iyer, Sriya, Zhang, Anwen, 2019. Religion and depression in adolescence. Jour-
nal of Political Economy. Forthcoming.
Cooper, David J., Kagel, John H., 2005. Are two heads better than one? Team versus individual play in
signaling games. The American Economic Review 95 (3), 477–509.
Corno, Lucia, La Ferrara, Eliana, Burns, Justine, 2018. Interaction, Prejudice and Performance. Evidence
from South Africa. Mimeo.
Crawford, Vincent P., Meng, Juanjuan, 2011. New York City cab drivers’ labor supply revisited: reference-
dependent preferences with rational-expectations targets for hours and income. The American Eco-
nomic Review 101 (5), 1912–1932.
Cubitt, Robin P., Read, Daniel, 2007. Can intertemporal choice experiments elicit time preferences for
consumption? Experimental Economics 10 (4), 369–389.
Dal Bó, Ernesto, Finan, Frederico, Rossi, Martín A., 2013. Strengthening state capabilities: the role
of financial incentives in the call to public service. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128 (3),
1169–1218.
Dalton, Patricio S., Ghosal, Sayantan, Mani, Anandi, 2015. Poverty and aspirations failure. The Economic
Journal 126 (590), 165–188.
Das, Jishnu, Do, Quy-Toan, Friedman, Jed, McKenzie, David, Scott, Kinnon, 2007. Mental health and
poverty in developing countries: revisiting the relationship. Social Science & Medicine 65 (3),
467–480.
Das, Jishnu, Hammer, Jeffrey, 2007. Money for nothing: the dire straits of medical practice in Delhi, India.
Journal of Development Economics 83 (1), 1–36.
Datta, Saugato, Mullainathan, Sendhil, 2014. Behavioral design: a new approach to development policy.
The Review of Income and Wealth 60 (1), 7–35.
Dean, Emma Boswell, Schilbach, Frank, Schofield, Heather, 2018. Poverty and cognitive function. In:
Barrett, Christopher B., Carter, Michael R., Chavas, Jean-Paul (Eds.), The Economics of Poverty
Traps. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Dean, Joshua T., 2018. Noise, cognitive function, and worker productivity. Mimeo.
Dean, Mark, Sautmann, Anja, 2018. Credit constraints and the measurement of time preferences. Mimeo.
Deaton, Angus, 1989. Saving and Liquidity Constraints. Technical Report w3196. National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Deaton, Angus S., 1991. Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica 59 (5), 221–248.
Deci, Edward L., 1971. Effects of externally mediated rewards on intrinsic motivation. Journal of Person-
ality and Social Psychology 18 (1), 105.
Delavande, Adeline, 2014. Probabilistic expectations in developing countries. Annual Review in Eco-
nomics 6 (1), 1–20.
Delavande, Adeline, Giné, Xavier, McKenzie, David, 2011. Measuring subjective expectations in develop-
ing countries: a critical review and new evidence. Journal of Development Economics 94 (2), 151–163.
Delavande, Adeline, Kohler, Hans-Peter, 2009. Subjective expectations in the context of HIV/aids in
Malawi. Demographic Research 20, 817–874.
DellaVigna, Stefano, 2009. Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. Journal of Economic
Literature 47 (2), 315–372.
DellaVigna, Stefano, 2018. Structural Behavioral Economics. NBER Working Paper No. 24797.
References 447
DellaVigna, Stefano, Gentzkow, Matthew, 2017. Uniform Pricing in US Retail Chains. NBER Working
Paper No. 23996.
DellaVigna, Stefano, Lindner, Attila, Reizer, Balázs, Schmieder, Johannes F., 2017. Reference-dependent
job search: evidence from Hungary. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132 (4), 1969–2018.
DellaVigna, Stefano, List, John A., Malmendier, Ulrike, Rao, Gautam, 2016. Voting to tell others. The
Review of Economic Studies 84 (1), 143–181.
DellaVigna, Stefano, Pope, Devin, 2017. What motivates effort? Evidence and expert forecasts. The Re-
view of Economic Studies 85 (2), 1029–1069.
DellaVigna, Stefano, Pope, Devin, 2018. Stability of experimental results: forecasts and evidence. Mimeo.
De Mel, Suresh, McKenzie, David, Woodruff, Christopher, 2008. Returns to capital in micro enterprises:
evidence from a field experiment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (4), 1329–1372.
Demeritt, Allison Davis, Hoff, Karla, 2018. The making of behavioral development economics. History of
Political Economy 50, 303–322.
de Quidt, Jonathan, Haushofer, Johannes, 2016. Depression for Economists. NBER Working Paper No.
22973.
de Quidt, Jonathan, Haushofer, Johannes, Rao, Gautam, Schilbach, Frank, Vautrey, Pierre-Luc, 2018. The
economics consequences of depression. Mimeograph.
Dercon, Stefan, 2005. Insurance Against Poverty. Oxford University Press.
de Ree, Joppe, Muralidharan, Karthik, Pradhan, Menno, Rogers, Halsey, 2018. Double for nothing? The
effects of unconditional teacher salary increases in Indonesia. Quarterly Journal of Economics 133
(2), 923–1039.
Deserranno, Erika, 2018. Financial incentives as signals: experimental evidence from the recruitment of
village promoters in Uganda. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. Forthcoming.
Devoto, Florencia, Duflo, Esther, Dupas, Pascaline, Parienté, William, Pons, Vincent, 2012. Happiness on
tap: piped water adoption in urban Morocco. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (4),
68–99.
Diamond, Adele, 2013. Executive functions. Annual Review of Psychology 64, 135–168.
Dickinson, David L., McElroy, Todd, 2017. Sleep restriction and circadian effects on social decisions.
European Economic Review 97, 57–71.
Dizon-Ross, Rebecca, 2018. Parents’ Beliefs About Their Children’s Academic Ability: Implications for
Educational Investments. NBER Working Paper No. 24610.
Doherty, Neil A., Schlesinger, Harris, 1991. Rational insurance purchasing: consideration of contract non-
performance. In: Cummins, J. David, Derrig, Richard A. (Eds.), Managing the Insolvency Risk of
Insurance Companies. Springer, Dordrecht, pp. 283–294.
Dohmen, Thomas, Enke, Benjamin, Falk, Armin, Huffman, David, Sunde, Uwe, 2018. Patience and com-
parative development. Mimeograph.
Dohmen, Thomas, Falk, Armin, Huffman, David, Sunde, Uwe, 2010. Are risk aversion and impatience
related to cognitive ability? The American Economic Review 100 (3), 1238–1260.
Drexler, Alejandro, Fischer, Greg, Schoar, Antoinette, 2014. Keeping it simple: financial literacy and rules
of thumb. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 6 (2), 1–31.
Duflo, Esther, 2012a. Human values and the design of the fight against poverty. Tanner Lectures, 1–55.
Duflo, Esther, 2012b. Women empowerment and economic development. Journal of Economic Litera-
ture 50 (4), 1051–1079.
Duflo, Esther, Hanna, Rema, Ryan, Stephen P., 2012. Incentives work: getting teachers to come to school.
The American Economic Review 102 (4), 1241–1278.
Duflo, Esther, Kremer, Michael, Robinson, Jonathan, 2008. How high are rates of return to fertilizer?
Evidence from field experiments in Kenya. The American Economic Review 98 (2), 482–488.
Duflo, Esther, Kremer, Michael, Robinson, Jonathan, 2011. Nudging farmers to use fertilizer: theory and
experimental evidence from Kenya. The American Economic Review 101 (6), 2350–2390.
Duflo, Esther, Kremer, Michael, Robinson, Jonathan, Schilbach, Frank, 2018. Technology diffusion and
appropriate use: evidence from western Kenya. Mimeograph.
Dupas, Pascaline, 2009. What matters (and what does not) in households’ decision to invest in malaria
prevention? The American Economic Review 99 (2), 224–230.
448 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Dupas, Pascaline, 2011a. Health behavior in developing countries. Annual Review of Economics 3 (1),
425–449.
Dupas, Pascaline, 2011b. Do teenagers respond to HIV risk information? Evidence from a field experiment
in Kenya. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 3 (1), 1–34.
Dupas, Pascaline, Karlan, Dean, Robinson, Jonathan, Ubfal, Diego, 2018a. Banking the unbanked? Evi-
dence from three countries. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 10 (2), 257–297.
Dupas, Pascaline, Miguel, Edward, 2017. Impacts and determinants of health levels in low-income coun-
tries. In: Banerjee, Abhijit V., Duflo, Esther (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Field Experiments, vol. 2.
Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 3–93.
Dupas, Pascaline, Robinson, Jonathan, 2013a. Savings constraints and microenterprise development: ev-
idence from a field experiment in Kenya. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 5 (1),
163–192.
Dupas, Pascaline, Robinson, Jonathan, 2013b. Why don’t the poor save more? Evidence from health sav-
ings experiments. The American Economic Review 103 (4), 1138–1171.
Dupas, Pascaline, Robinson, Jonathan, Saavedra, Santiago, 2018b. The daily grind: cash needs and labor
supply.
Eckles, David L., Wise, J. Volkman, 2011. Prospect Theory and the Demand for Insurance. The Risk
Theory Society, American Risk and Insurance Association (ARIA), Philadelphia, PA, USA. Available
at: http://www.aria.org/rts/proceedings/2012/default.htm. (Accessed 18 September 2013).
Ellison, Christopher G., 1991. Religious involvement and subjective well-being. Journal of Health and
Social Behavior, 80–99.
Enke, Benjamin, 2017. Complexity, mental frames, and neglect.
Enke, Benjamin, 2018. Kinship, Cooperation, and the Evolution of Moral Systems. NBER Working Paper
No. 23499.
Enke, Benjamin, Zimmermann, Florian, 2019. Correlation neglect in belief formation. Review of Eco-
nomic Studies. Forthcoming.
Ericson, Keith Marzilli, 2017. On the interaction of memory and procrastination: implications for re-
minders, deadlines, and empirical estimation. Journal of the European Economic Association 15 (3),
692–719.
Ericson, Keith Marzilli, Laibson, David, 2018. Intertemporal choice. NBER Working Paper No. 25358.
Ervik, Astrid Oline, 2003. IQ and the wealth of nations. The Economic Journal 113 (488), F406–F408.
Esteves-Sorenson, Constanca, 2017. Gift exchange in the workplace: addressing the conflicting evidence
with a careful test. Management Science 64 (9), 4365–4388.
Eyster, Erik, 2002. Rationalizing the past: a taste for consistency. Mimeograph.
Eyster, Erik, Rabin, Matthew, 2010. Naive herding in rich-information settings. American Economic Jour-
nal: Microeconomics 2 (4), 221–243.
Eyster, Erik, Rabin, Matthew, 2014. Extensive imitation is irrational and harmful. The Quarterly Journal
of Economics 129 (4), 1861–1898.
Eyster, Erik, Rabin, Matthew, Weizsäcker, Georg, 2018. An experiment on social mislearning. Mimeo-
graph.
Fafchamps, Marcel, 1993. Sequential labor decisions under uncertainty: an estimable household model of
West-African farmers. Econometrica 61 (5), 1173–1197.
Fafchamps, Marcel, 2000. Ethnicity and credit in African manufacturing. Journal of Development Eco-
nomics 61 (1), 205–235.
Fairburn, Christopher G., Patel, Vikram, 2017. The impact of digital technology on psychological treat-
ments and their dissemination. Behaviour Research and Therapy 88, 19–25.
Falk, Armin, Becker, Anke, Dohmen, Thomas, Enke, Benjamin, Huffman, David, Sunde, Uwe, 2018.
Global evidence on economic preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 133 (4), 1645–1692.
Falk, Armin, Becker, Anke, Dohmen, Thomas, Huffman, David B., Uwe, Sunde, 2016. The Preference
Survey Module: A Validated Instrument for Measuring Risk, Time, and Social Preferences. IZA In-
stitute of Labor Economics Discussion Paper 9674.
Farber, Henry S., 2005. Is tomorrow another day? The labor supply of New York City cabdrivers. Journal
of Political Economy 113 (1), 46–82.
References 449
Farber, Henry S., 2015. Why you can’t find a taxi in the rain and other labor supply lessons from cab
drivers. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 130 (4), 1975–2026.
Fernandez, Raquel, Fogli, Alessandra, 2009. Culture: an empirical investigation of beliefs, work, and fer-
tility. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (1), 146–177.
Finan, Frederico, Olken, Benjamin A., Pande, Rohini, 2017. The personnel economics of the developing
state. In: Banerjee, Abhijit V., Duflo, Esther (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Field Experiments, vol. 2.
Elsevier/North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 467–514.
Finan, Frederico, Schechter, Laura, 2012. Vote-buying and reciprocity. Econometrica 80 (2), 863–881.
Fisman, Raymond, Miguel, Edward, 2007. Corruption, norms, and legal enforcement: evidence from
diplomatic parking tickets. Journal of Political economy 115 (6), 1020–1048.
Fletcher, Erin, Pande, Rohini, Troyer Moore, Charity Maria, 2017. Women and work in India: descriptive
evidence and a review of potential policies.
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO), 2018. The State of Food Security and
Nutrition in the World 2018: Building Climate Resilience for Food Security and Nutrition.
Frederick, Shane, Loewenstein, George, O’Donoghue, Ted, 2002. Time discounting and time preference:
a critical review. Journal of Economic Literature 40 (2), 351–401.
Freeman, Richard B., 1986. Who escapes? The relationship of churchgoing and other background fac-
tors to the socioeconomic performance of black male youths from inner-city tracts. In: Freeman,
Richard B., Holzer, Harry J. (Eds.), The Black Youth Employment Crisis. University of Chicago Press,
Chicago.
Friedrich, M.J., 2017. Depression is the leading cause of disability around the world. Jama 317 (15), 1517.
Fudenberg, Drew, Levine, David K., 2006. A dual-self model of impulse control. The American Economic
Review 96 (5), 1449–1476.
Fuster, Andreas, Laibson, David, Mendel, Brock, 2010. Natural expectations and macroeconomic fluctua-
tions. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (4), 67–84.
Gagnon-Bartsch, Tristan, Rabin, Matthew, Schwartzstein, Joshua, 2018. Channeled attention and stable
errors. Mimeo.
Gallagher, Justin, 2014. Learning about an infrequent event: evidence from flood insurance take-up in the
United States. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 206–233.
Genicot, Garance, Ray, Debraj, 2017. Aspirations and inequality. Econometrica 85 (2), 489–519.
Gertler, Paul, Gruber, Jonathan, 2002. Insuring consumption against illness. The American Economic
Review 92 (1), 51–70.
Ghosal, Sayantan, Jana, Smarajit, Mani, Anandi, Mitra, Sandip, Roy, Sanchari, 2017. Stigma, discrimina-
tion and self-image: evidence from Kolkata brothels. Mimeograph.
Giné, Xavier, Karlan, Dean, Zinman, Jonathan, 2010. Put your money where your butt is: a commitment
contract for smoking cessation. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 2 (4), 213–235.
Giné, Xavier, Martinez-Bravo, Monica, Vidal-Fernández, Marian, 2017. Are labor supply decisions consis-
tent with neoclassical preferences? Evidence from Indian boat owners. Journal of Economic Behavior
& Organization 142, 331–347.
Giné, Xavier, Townsend, Robert, Vickery, James, 2008. Patterns of rainfall insurance participation in rural
India. World Bank Economic Review 22 (3), 539–566.
Glewwe, Paul, Ilias, Nauman, Kremer, Michael, 2010. Teacher incentives. American Economic Journal:
Applied Economics 2 (3), 205–227.
Gneezy, Uri, Leonard, Kenneth L., List, John A., 2009. Gender differences in competition: evidence from
a matrilineal and a patriarchal society. Econometrica 77 (5), 1637–1664.
Gneezy, Uri, List, John A., 2006. Putting behavioral economics to work: testing for gift exchange in labor
markets using field experiments. Econometrica 74 (5), 1365–1384.
Gneezy, Uri, Rustichini, Aldo, 2000. A fine is a price. The Journal of Legal Studies 29 (1), 1–17.
Godlonton, Susan, Munthali, Alister, Thornton, Rebecca, 2016. Responding to risk: circumcision, infor-
mation, and HIV prevention. Review of Economics and Statistics 98 (2), 333–349.
Goldin, Jacob, Homonoff, Tatiana, 2013. Smoke gets in your eyes: cigarette tax salience and regressivity.
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 5 (1), 302–336.
450 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Grandner, Michael A., Patel, Nirav P., Gehrman, Philip R., Xie, Dawei, Sha, Daohang, Weaver, Terri,
Gooneratne, Nalaka, 2010. Who gets the best sleep? Ethnic and socioeconomic factors related to
sleep complaints. Sleep Medicine 11 (5), 470–478.
Greenwald, Anthony G., McGhee, Debbie E., Schwartz, Jordan L.K., 1998. Measuring individual differ-
ences in implicit cognition: the implicit association test. Journal of Personality and Social Psychol-
ogy 74 (6), 1464.
Greenwald, Anthony G., Poehlman, T. Andrew, Uhlmann, Eric Luis, Banaji, Mahzarin R., 2009. Under-
standing and using the implicit association test: III. Meta-analysis of predictive validity. Journal of
Personality and Social Psychology 97 (1), 17.
Griffin, Dale, Tversky, Amos, 1992. The weighing of evidence and the determinants of confidence. Cog-
nitive Psychology 24 (3), 411–435.
Grimard, Franque, 2000. Rural labor markets, household composition, and rainfall in Côte d’Ivoire. Re-
view of Development Economics 4 (1), 70–86.
Gruber, Jonathan, Hungerman, Daniel M., 2008. The church versus the mall: what happens when religion
faces increased secular competition? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (2), 831–862.
Gruber, Jonathan H., 2005. Religious market structure, religious participation, and outcomes: is religion
good for you? The BE Journal in Economic Analysis & Policy 5 (1).
Guiso, Luigi, Sapienza, Paola, Zingales, Luigi, 2006. Does culture affect economic outcomes? The Journal
of Economic Perspectives 20 (2), 23–48.
Gul, Faruk, Pesendorfer, Wolfgang, 2001. Temptation and self-control. Econometrica 69 (6), 1403–1435.
Gul, Faruk, Pesendorfer, Wolfgang, 2004. Self-control and the theory of consumption. Econometrica 72
(1), 119–158.
Haidt, Jonathan, 2012. The Righteous Mind: Why Good People Are Divided by Politics and Religion.
Vintage Books, New York.
Haigh, Michael S., List, John A., 2005. Do professional traders exhibit myopic loss aversion? An experi-
mental analysis. Journal of Finance 60 (1), 523–534.
Hall, Crystal C., Zhao, Jiaying, Shafir, Eldar, 2014. Self-affirmation among the poor: cognitive and behav-
ioral implications. Psychological Science 25 (2), 619–625.
Hall, Robert E., 2009. Reconciling cyclical movements in the marginal value of time and the marginal
product of labor. Journal of Political Economy 117 (2), 281–323.
Hall, Robert E., 2016. Macroeconomics of persistent slumps. In: Taylor, John B., Uhlig, Harald (Eds.),
Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 2131–2181.
Hanna, Rema, Mullainathan, Sendhil, Schwartzstein, Joshua, 2014. Learning through noticing: theory and
evidence from a field experiment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (3), 1311–1353.
Harlan, Sharon L., Brazel, Anthony J., Prashad, Lela, Stefanov, William L., Larsen, Larissa, 2006.
Neighborhood microclimates and vulnerability to heat stress. Social Science & Medicine 63 (11),
2847–2863.
Harris, Christopher, Laibson, David, 2001. Dynamic choices of hyperbolic consumers. Econometrica 69
(4), 935–957.
Harris, John R., Todaro, Michael P., 1970. Migration, unemployment and development: a two-sector anal-
ysis. The American Economic Review 60 (1), 126–142.
Hastings, Justine S., Shapiro, Jesse M., 2013. Fungibility and consumer choice: evidence from commodity
price shocks. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128 (4), 1449–1498.
Haushofer, Johannes, Fehr, Ernst, 2014. On the psychology of poverty. Science 344 (6186), 862–867.
Haushofer, Johannes, Jang, Chaning, Lynham, John, Abraham, Justin, 2018. Stress and temporal discount-
ing: Do domains matter? Mimeo.
Haushofer, Johannes, Shapiro, Jeremy, 2016. The short-term impact of unconditional cash transfers to the
poor: experimental evidence from Kenya. Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 (4), 1973–2042.
Havránek, Tomáš, 2015. Measuring intertemporal substitution: the importance of method choices and
selective reporting. Journal of the European Economic Association 13 (6), 1180–1204.
Hawton, Keith, Casañas i Comabella, Carolina, Haw, Camilla, Saunders, Kate, 2013. Risk factors for
suicide in individuals with depression: a systematic review. Journal of Affective Disorders 147 (1–3),
17–28.
References 451
Hazell, Peter B.R., 1992. The appropriate role of agricultural insurance in developing countries. Journal
of International Development 4 (6), 567–581.
Heath, Rachel, Jayachandran, Seema, 2016. The Causes and Consequences of Increased Female Education
and Labor Force Participation in Developing Countries. NBER Working Paper No. 22766.
Heidhues, Paul, Köszegi, Botond, 2018. Behavioral industrial organization. In: Bernheim, B. Douglas,
DellaVigna, Stefano, Laibson, David (Eds.), Handbook of Behavioral Economics: Foundations and
Applications 1, vol. 1. Elsevier/North-Holland, Amsterdam.
Henrich, Joseph, Boyd, Robert, Bowles, Samuel, Camerer, Colin, Fehr, Ernst, Gintis, Herbert, McElreath,
Richard, 2001. In search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies.
The American Economic Review 91 (2), 73–78.
Henrich, Joseph, Ensminger, Jean, McElreath, Richard, Barr, Abigail, Barrett, Clark, Bolyanatz, Alexan-
der, Cardenas, Camilo Juan, Gurven, Michael, Gwako, Edwins, Henrich, Natalie, Lesorogol, Carolyn,
Marlowe, Frank, Tracer, David, Ziker, John, 2010a. Markets, religion, community size, and the evo-
lution of fairness and punishment. Science 327 (5972), 1480–1484.
Henrich, Joseph, Heine, Steven J., Norenzayan, Ara, 2010b. The weirdest people in the world? Behavioral
and Brain Sciences 33 (2–3), 61–83.
Hjort, Jonas, 2014. Ethnic divisions and production in firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (4),
1899–1946.
Hogarth, Robin M., Einhorn, Hillel J., 1992. Order effects in belief updating: the belief-adjustment model.
Cognitive Psychology 24 (1), 1–55.
Holmstrom, Bengt, Milgrom, Paul, 1991. Multitask principal-agent analyses: incentive contracts, asset
ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 7 (24).
Hsiaw, Alice, 2013. Goal-setting and self-control. Journal of Economic Theory 148 (2), 601–626.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, Hurst, Erik, Jones, Charles I., Klenow, Peter J., 2018. The Allocation of Talent and US
Economic Growth. NBER Working Paper No. 18693.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, Olken, Benjamin A., 2014. The missing “missing middle”. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives 28 (3), 89–108.
Iannaccone, Laurence R., 1998. Introduction to the economics of religion. Journal of Economic Litera-
ture 36 (3), 1465–1495.
Ilias, Nauman, 2006. Families and firms: agency costs and labor market imperfections in Sialkot’s surgical
industry. Journal of Development Economics 80 (2), 329–349.
Inkeles, Alex, Smith, David H., 1974. Becoming modem. In: Seligson, Mitchell A., Passe-Smith, John
T. (Eds.), Development and Underdevelopment: The Political Economy of Global Inequality (Lynne
Rienner Publishers, 1998, Boulder).
International Labour Office (ILO). 2018. Ilostat database.
Islam, Sheikh Mohammed Shariful, Dannemann Purnat, Tina, Phuong, Nguyen Thi Anh, Mwingira, Up-
endo, Schacht, Karsten, Fröschl, Günter, 2014. Non-communicable diseases (NCDS) in developing
countries: a symposium report. Globalization and Health 10 (1), 81.
Iyer, Sriya, 2016. The new economics of religion. Journal of Economic Literature 54 (2), 395–441.
Jack, William, Kremer, Michael, De Laat, Joost, Suri, Tavneet, 2016. Borrowing Requirements, Credit
Access, and Adverse Selection: Evidence from Kenya. NBER Working Paper No. 22686.
Jack, William, Suri, Tavneet, 2014. Risk sharing and transactions costs: evidence from Kenya’s mobile
money revolution. The American Economic Review 104 (1), 183–223.
Jack, William, Suri, Tavneet, 2016. The long-run poverty and gender impacts of mobile money. Sci-
ence 354 (6317), 1288–1292.
Jagnani, Maulik, 2018. Poor sleep: sunset time and human capital production. Mimeograph.
Jakiela, Pamela, Ozier, Owen, 2015. Does Africa need a rotten kin theorem? Experimental evidence from
village economies. The Review of Economic Studies 83 (1), 231–268.
Jalan, Jyotsna, Ravallion, Martin, 1999. Are the poor less well insured? Evidence on vulnerability to
income risk in rural China. Journal of Development Economics 58 (1), 61–81.
Jappelli, Tullio, Pistaferri, Luigi, 2010. The consumption response to income changes. Annual Review of
Economics 2, 479–506.
452 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Jayaraman, Rajshri, Ray, Debraj, de Véricourt, Francis, 2016. Anatomy of a contract change. The Ameri-
can Economic Review 106 (2), 316–358.
Jensen, Robert, 2010. The (perceived) returns to education and the demand for schooling. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 125 (2), 515–548.
Jensen, Robert, Oster, Emily, 2009. The power of TV: cable television and women’s status in India. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (3), 1057–1094.
John, Anett, 2018. When commitment fails—evidence from a field experiment. Management Science.
Forthcoming.
Johnson, Eric J., Goldstein, Daniel G., 2004. Defaults and donation decisions. Transplantation 78 (12),
1713–1716.
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack L., Thaler, Richard, 1986. Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking:
entitlements in the market. The American Economic Review 76 (4), 728–741.
Kahneman, Daniel, Tversky, Amos, 1973. On the psychology of prediction. Psychological Review 80,
237–251.
Kahneman, Daniel, Tversky, Amos, 1979. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Economet-
rica 47 (2), 263–292.
Kaminski, Jonathan, Christiaensen, Luc, Gilbert, Christopher L., 2014. The End of Seasonality? New
Insights from Sub-Saharan Africa. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 6907.
Karing, Anne, 2018. Social Signaling and Childhood Immunization: A Field Experiment in Sierra Leone.
Innovations for Poverty Action (IPA) Working Paper.
Karlan, Dean, McConnell, Margaret, Mullainathan, Sendhil, Zinman, Jonathan, 2016. Getting to the top
of mind: how reminders increase saving. Management Science 62 (12), 3393–3411.
Karlan, Dean, Mullainathan, Sendhil, Roth, Benjamin N., 2018. Debt Traps? Market Vendors and Mon-
eylender Debt in India and the Philippines. NBER Working Paper No. 24272.
Karlan, Dean, Osei, Robert, Osei-Akoto, Isaac, Udry, Christopher, 2014a. Agricultural decisions after
relaxing credit and risk constraints. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (2), 597–652.
Karlan, Dean, Lakshmi Ratan, Aishwarya, Zinman, Jonathan, 2014b. Savings by and for the poor: a re-
search review and agenda. The Review of Income and Wealth 60 (1), 36–78.
Karlan, Dean, Zinman, Jonathan, 2009. Observing unobservables: identifying information asymmetries
with a consumer credit field experiment. Econometrica 77 (6), 1993–2008.
Karlan, Dean S., Linden, Leigh, 2018. Loose knots: strong versus weak commitments to save for education
in Uganda.
Kast, Felipe, Meier, Stephan, Pomeranz, Dina, 2018. Saving more in groups: field experimental evidence
from Chile. Journal of Development Economics 133, 275–294.
Kaur, Supreet, 2019. Nominal wage rigidity in village labor markets. American Economic Review. Forth-
coming.
Kaur, Supreet, Kremer, Michael, Mullainathan, Sendhil, 2010. Self-control and the development of work
arrangements. The American Economic Review 100 (2), 624–628.
Kaur, Supreet, Kremer, Michael, Mullainathan, Sendhil, 2015. Self-control at work. Journal of Political
Economy 123 (6), 1227–1277.
Kaur, Supreet, Mullainathan, Sendhil, Oh, Suanna, Schilbach, Frank, 2018. Does poverty lower produc-
tivity?
Kazianga, Harounan, Udry, Christopher, 2006. Consumption smoothing? Livestock, insurance and drought
in rural Burkina Faso. Journal of Development Economics 79 (2), 413–446.
Knack, Stephen, Keefer, Philip, 1997. Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country
investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4), 1251–1288.
Knetsch, Jack, 1989. The endowment effect and evidence of nonreversible indifference curves. The Amer-
ican Economic Review 79 (5), 1277–1284.
Koppel, Lina, Andersson, David, Posadzy, Kinga, Västfjäll, Daniel, Tinghög, Gustav, 2017. The effect of
acute pain on risky and intertemporal choice. Experimental Economics 20 (4), 878–893.
Kőszegi, Botond, 2003. Health anxiety and patient behavior. Journal of Health Economics 22 (6),
1073–1084.
References 453
Kőszegi, Botond, Rabin, Matthew, 2006. A model of reference-dependent preferences. The Quarterly Jour-
nal of Economics 121 (4), 1133–1165.
Kőszegi, Botond, Rabin, Matthew, 2007. Reference-dependent risk attitudes. The American Economic
Review 97 (4), 1047–1073.
Kőszegi, Botond, Rabin, Matthew, 2009. Reference-dependent consumption plans. The American Eco-
nomic Review 99 (3), 909–936.
Kraay, Aart, McKenzie, David, 2014. Do poverty traps exist? Assessing the evidence. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 28 (3), 127–148.
Kremer, Michael, Chaudhury, Nazmul, Halsey Rogers, F., Muralidharan, Karthik, Hammer, Jeffrey, 2005.
Teacher absence in India: a snapshot. Journal of the European Economic Association 3 (2–3),
658–667.
Kremer, Michael, Glennerster, Rachel, 2011. Improving health in developing countries: evidence from
randomized evaluations. In: Pauly, Mark V., Mcguire, Thomas G., Barros, Pedro P. (Eds.), Handbook
of Health Economics, vol. 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 201–315.
Kremer, Michael, Lee, Jean, Robinson, Jonathan, Rostapshova, Olga, 2013. Behavioral biases and firm
behavior: evidence from Kenyan retail shops. The American Economic Review 103 (3), 362–368.
Kremer, Michael, Leino, Jessica, Miguel, Edward, Peterson Zwane, Alix, 2011. Spring cleaning: rural
water impacts, valuation, and property rights institutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126
(1), 145–205.
Kremer, Michael, Miguel, Edward, 2007. The illusion of sustainability. The Quarterly Journal of Eco-
nomics 122 (3), 1007–1065.
Krueger, Alan B., Stone, Arthur A., 2008. Assessment of pain: a community-based diary survey in the
USA. The Lancet 371 (9623), 1519–1525.
Kugler, Tamar, Kausel, Edgar E., Kocher, Martin G., 2012. Are groups more rational than individuals?
A review of interactive decision making in groups. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Cognitive Sci-
ence 3 (4), 471–482.
Kuncel, Nathan R., Hezlett, Sarah A., 2010. Fact and fiction in cognitive ability testing for admissions and
hiring decisions. Current Directions in Psychological Science 19 (6), 339–345.
Kunreuther, Howard, Ginsberg, Ralph, Miller, Louis, Sagi, Philip, Slovic, Paul, Borkan, Bradley, Katz,
Norman, 1978. Disaster Insurance Protection: Public Policy Lessons. Wiley, New York.
Laajaj, Rachid, 2017. Endogenous time horizon and behavioral poverty trap: theory and evidence from
Mozambique. Journal of Development Economics 127, 187–208.
Lacetera, Nicola, Macis, Mario, Slonim, Robert, 2013. Economic rewards to motivate blood donations.
Science 340 (6135), 927–928.
La Ferrara, Eliana, 2018. Aspirations, Social Norms and Development. European Economic Association
Presidential Address – Cologne.
La Ferrara, Eliana, Chong, Alberto, Duryea, Suzanne, 2012. Soap operas and fertility: evidence from
Brazil. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 4 (4), 1–31.
Laibson, David, 1997. Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112
(2), 443–478.
Laibson, David, 2015. Why don’t present-biased agents make commitments? The American Economic
Review 105 (5), 267–272.
LaPorta, Rafael, Lopez-De-Silanes, Florencio, Shleifer, Andrei, Vishny, Robert W., 1997. Trust in large
organizations. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 87 (2), 333–338.
Le, Kien T., 2010. Separation hypothesis tests in the agricultural household model. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 92 (5), 1420–1431.
Lee, Kenneth, Miguel, Edward, Wolfram, Catherine, 2016. Experimental Evidence on the Demand for and
Costs of Rural Electrification. NBER Working Paper No. 22292.
Lerner, Jennifer S., Li, Ye, Valdesolo, Piercarlo, Kassam, Karim S., 2015. Emotion and decision making.
Annual Review of Psychology 66.
Levin, Jeff, 2010. Religion and mental health: theory and research. International Journal of Applied Psy-
choanalytic Studies 7 (2), 102–115.
454 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Levine, Ruth, Kinder, Molly, 2004. Millions Saved: Proven Successes in Global Health, vol. 3. Center for
Global Development, Washington, DC.
Li, Yufei, Meng, Juanjuan, Song, Changcheng, Zheng, Kai, 2018. Information avoidance and medical
screening: a field experiment in China.
Loewenstein, George, Lerner, Jennifer S., 2003. The role of affect in decision making. In: Davidson,
Richard J., Scherer, Klaus R., Goldsmith, H. Hill (Eds.), Handbook of Affective Science. Oxford
University Press, Oxford and New York.
Loewenstein, George, O’Donoghue, Ted, Rabin, Matthew, 2003. Projection bias in predicting future utility.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (4), 1209–1248.
Lopez, Ramon E., 1984. Estimating labor supply and production decisions of self-employed farm produc-
ers. European Economic Review 24 (1), 61–82.
Lowe, Matt, 2018. Types of contact: a field experiment on collaborative and adversarial caste integration.
Mimeo.
Lucas Jr., Robert E., 1978. On the size distribution of business firms. Bell Journal of Economics, 508–523.
Lucas Jr., Robert E., Rapping, Leonard A., 1969. Real wages, employment, and inflation. Journal of Polit-
ical Economy 77 (5), 721–754.
Ludwig, Jens, Kling, Jeffrey R., Mullainathan, Sendhil, 2011. Mechanism experiments and policy evalua-
tions. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 (3), 17–38.
Lund, Crick, Breen, Alison, Flisher, Alan J., Kakuma, Ritsuko, Corrigall, Joanne, Joska, John A., Swartz,
Leslie, Patel, Vikram, 2010. Poverty and common mental disorders in low and middle income coun-
tries: a systematic review. Social Science & Medicine 71 (3), 517–528.
Lusardi, Annamaria, 2009. Overcoming the Saving Slump: How to Increase the Effectiveness of Financial
Education and Saving Programs. University of Chicago Press.
Lybbert, Travis J., Wydick, Bruce, 2018. Poverty, aspirations, and the economics of hope. Economic De-
velopment and Cultural Change 66 (4), 709–753.
Maccini, Sharon, Yang, Dean, 2009. Under the weather: health, schooling, and economic consequences of
early-life rainfall. The American Economic Review 99 (3), 1006–1026.
Madajewicz, Malgosia, Pfaff, Alexander, Van Geen, Alexander, Graziano, Joseph, Hussein, Iftikhar, Mo-
motaj, Hasina, Sylvi, Roksana, Ahsan, Habibul, 2007. Can information alone change behavior?
Response to arsenic contamination of groundwater in Bangladesh. Journal of Development Eco-
nomics 84 (2), 731–754.
Madden, Gregory J., Raiff, Bethany R., Lagorio, Carla H., Begotka, Andrea M., Mueller, Angela M., Hehli,
Daniel J., Wegener, Ashley A., 2004. Delay discounting of potentially real and hypothetical rewards:
II. Between- and within-subject comparisons. Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology 12 (4),
251.
Madrian, Brigitte C., Shea, Dennis F., 2001. The power of suggestion: inertia in 401(k) participation and
savings behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (4), 1149–1187.
Mahajan, Aprajit, Tarozzi, Alessandro, 2011. Time inconsistency, expectations and technology adoption:
the case of insecticide treated nets.
Malmendier, Ulrike, Tate, Geoffrey, 2005. CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. Journal of Fi-
nance 60 (6), 2661–2700.
Mani, Anandi, Mullainathan, Sendhil, Shafir, Eldar, Zhao, Jiaying, 2013. Poverty impedes cognitive func-
tion. Science 341 (6149), 976–980.
Mann, J. John, Waternaux, Christine, Haas, Gretchen L., Malone, Kevin M., 1999. Toward a clinical model
of suicidal behavior in psychiatric patients. The American Journal of Psychiatry 156 (2), 181–189.
Marglin, Stephen A., 1974. What do bosses do? The origins and functions of hierarchy in capitalist pro-
duction. Review of Radical Political Economics 6 (2), 60–112.
Markowitz, Harry, 1952. The utility of wealth. Journal of Political Economy 60 (2), 151–158.
Marx, Karl, Engels, Friedrich, 1848. The Communist Manifesto.
Mas, Alexandre, Pallais, Amanda, 2017. Valuing alternative work arrangements. The American Economic
Review 107 (12), 3722–3759.
Mayraz, Guy, 2011. Wishful thinking.
McClelland, David C., 1961. The Achievement Society. Von Nostrand, Princeton, NJ.
References 455
McClure, Samuel M., Ericson, Keith M., Laibson, David I., Loewenstein, George, Cohen, Jonathan D.,
2007. Time discounting for primary rewards. The Journal of Neuroscience 27 (21), 5796–5804.
McKelway, Madeline, 2018. Women’s self-efficacy and women’s employment: experimental evidence
from India.
Meager, Rachael, 2019. Understanding the average impact of microcredit expansions: a bayesian hierar-
chical analysis of seven randomized experiments. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics.
Forthcoming.
Meier, Stephan, Sprenger, Charles D., 2011. Time discounting predicts creditworthiness. Psychological
Science 23 (1), 56–58.
Meredith, Jennifer, Robinson, Jonathan, Walker, Sarah, Wydick, Bruce, 2013. Keeping the doctor away:
experimental evidence on investment in preventative health products. Journal of Development Eco-
nomics 105, 196–210.
Miguel, Edward, 2004. Tribe or nation? Nation building and public goods in Kenya versus Tanzania. World
Politics 56 (3), 327–362.
Miguel, Edward, Gugerty, Mary Kay, 2005. Ethnic diversity, social sanctions, and public goods in Kenya.
Journal of Public Economics 89 (11–12), 2325–2368.
Mullainathan, Sendhil, Shafir, Eldar, 2013. Scarcity: Why Having Too Little Means So Much. Macmillan.
Munshi, Kaivan, 2004. Social learning in a heterogeneous population: technology diffusion in the Indian
green revolution. Journal of Development Economics 73 (1), 185–213.
Muralidharan, Karthik, Sundararaman, Venkatesh, 2011. Teacher performance pay: experimental evidence
from India. Journal of Political Economy 119 (1), 39–77.
Murfin, Justin, Pratt, Ryan, 2019. Comparables pricing. The Review of Financial Studies 32 (2), 688–737.
Neufeld, K.J., Peters, D.H., Rani, M., Bonu, S., Brooner, R.K., 2005. Regular use of alcohol and tobacco
in India and its association with age, gender, and poverty. Drug and Alcohol Dependence 77 (3),
283–291.
Nunn, Nathan, 2008. The long-term effects of Africa’s slave trades. The Quarterly Journal of Eco-
nomics 123 (1), 139–176.
Nunn, Nathan, 2012. Culture and the historical process. Economic History of Developing Regions 27 (1),
S108–S126.
Nunn, Nathan, Wantchekon, Leonard, 2011. The slave trade and the origins of mistrust in Africa. The
American Economic Review 101 (7), 3221–3252.
O’Donoghue, Ted, Rabin, Matthew, 1999. Doing it now or later. The American Economic Review 89 (1),
103–124.
O’Donoghue, Ted, Rabin, Matthew, 2001. Choice and procrastination. The Quarterly Journal of Eco-
nomics 116 (1), 121–160.
O’Donoghue, Ted, Sprenger, Charles, 2018. Reference-dependent preferences. In: Bernheim, B. Douglas,
DellaVigna, Stefano, Laibson, David (Eds.), Handbook of Behavioral Economics: Foundations and
Applications 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam.
Okunogbe, Oyebola, 2018. Does exposure to other ethnic regions promote national integration? Evidence
from Nigeria.
Ong, Qiyan, Theseira, Walter, Ng, Irene Y.H., 2018. Reducing debt improves psychological functioning
and changes decision making in the poor.
Oster, Emily, Shoulson, Ira, Dorsey, E., 2013. Optimal expectations and limited medical testing: evidence
from Huntington disease. The American Economic Review 103 (2), 804–830.
Oswald, Frederick L., Mitchell, Gregory, Blanton, Hart, Jaccard, James, Tetlock, Philip E., 2013. Predict-
ing ethnic and racial discrimination: a meta-analysis of IAT criterion studies. Journal of Personality
and Social Psychology 105 (2), 171.
Pagel, Michaela, 2017. Expectations-based reference-dependent life-cycle consumption. The Review of
Economic Studies 84 (2), 885–934.
Palairet, M.R., 2004. IQ and the wealth of nations.
Patel, Nirav P., Grandner, Michael A., Xie, Dawei, Branas, Charles C., Gooneratne, Nalaka, 2010. “Sleep
disparity” in the population: poor sleep quality is strongly associated with poverty and ethnicity. BMC
Public Health 10 (1), 475.
456 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Patel, Vikram, 2007. Alcohol use and mental health in developing countries. Annals of Epidemiology 17
(5), S87–S92.
Patel, Vikram, Kleinman, Arthur, 2003. Poverty and common mental disorders in developing countries.
Bulletin of the World Health Organization 81, 609–615.
Patel, Vikram, Weobong, Benedict, Weiss, Helen A., Anand, Arpita, Bhat, Bhargav, Katti, Basavraj,
Dimidjian, Sona, Araya, Ricardo, Hollon, Steve D., King, Michael, Vijayakumar, Lakshmi, Park,
A-La, McDaid, David, Wilson, Terry, Velleman, Richard, Kirkwood, Betty R., Fairburn, Christopher
G., 2017. The healthy activity program (HAP), a lay counsellor-delivered brief psychological treat-
ment for severe depression, in primary care in India: a randomised controlled trial. The Lancet 389
(10065), 176–185.
Paxson, Christina H., 1992. Using weather variability to estimate the response of savings to transitory
income in Thailand. The American Economic Review, 15–33.
Poleshuck, Ellen L., Green, Carmen R., 2008. Socioeconomic disadvantage and pain. Pain 136 (3), 235.
Prina, Silvia, 2015. Banking the poor via savings accounts: evidence from a field experiment. Journal of
Development Economics 115, 16–31.
Putnam, Robert D., 2000. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. Simon and
Schuster, New York.
Rabin, Matthew, 1998. Psychology and economics. Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1), 11–46.
Rabin, Matthew, 2000. Risk aversion and expected-utility theory: a calibration theorem. Econometrica 68
(5), 1281–1292.
Rabin, Matthew, 2002. Inference by believers in the law of small numbers. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 117 (3), 775–816.
Rabin, Matthew, Weizsäcker, Georg, 2009. Narrow bracketing and dominated choices. The American Eco-
nomic Review 99 (4), 1508–1543.
Rao, Gautam, 2018. Familiarity does not breed contempt: diversity, discrimination and generosity in Delhi
schools. The American Economic Review. Forthcoming.
Rao, K.V., Mishra, Vinod K., Retherford, Robert D., 1998. Effects of Exposure to Mass Media on Knowl-
edge and Use of Oral Rehydration Therapy for Childhood Diarrhea in India. National Family Health
Survey Subject Report (10).
Ray, Debraj, 2006. Aspirations, Poverty, and Economic Change. In: Banerjee, Abhijit V., Benabou, Roland,
Mookherjee, Dilip (Eds.), Understanding Poverty. Oxford University Press, New York.
Reuben, Ernesto, Sapienza, Paola, Zingales, Luigi, 2015. Procrastination and impatience. Journal of Be-
havioral and Experimental Economics 58, 63–76.
Rose, Elaina, 1999. Consumption smoothing and excess female mortality in rural India. Review of Eco-
nomics and Statistics 81 (1), 41–49.
Rosenzweig, Mark R., Udry, Christopher, 2014. Rainfall forecasts, weather, and wages over the agricul-
tural production cycle. The American Economic Review 104 (5), 278–283.
Ross, Lee, Nisbett, Richard E., 1991. The Person and the Situation: Perspectives of Social Psychology.
Pinter & Martin Publishers.
Ru, Hong, Schoar, Antoinette, 2016. Do Credit Card Companies Screen for Behavioral Biases? NBER
Working Paper No. 22360.
Schaner, Simone, 2018. The persistent power of behavioral change: long-run impacts of temporary savings
subsidies for the poor. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 10 (3), 67–100.
Schilbach, Frank, 2019. Alcohol and self-control: a field experiment in India. The American Economic
Review. Forthcoming.
Schilbach, Frank, Schofield, Heather, Mullainathan, Sendhil, 2016. The psychological lives of the poor.
The American Economic Review 106 (5), 435–440.
Schilbach, Frank N., 2015. Essays in Development and Behavioral Economics. PhD thesis.
Schofield, Heather, 2014. The economic costs of low caloric intake: evidence from India. Unpublished
Manuscript.
Schultz, Theodore W., 1964. Transforming Traditional Agriculture. Studies in Comparative Economics.
Economics 37 (1), 47–61.
References 457
Schulz, Jonathan, Bahrami-Rad, Duman, Beauchamp, Jonathan, Henrich, Joseph, 2018. The origins of
WEIRD psychology.
Schwartzstein, Joshua, 2014. Selective attention and learning. Journal of the European Economic Associ-
ation 12 (6), 1423–1452.
Sen, Amartya, 1985. Commodities and capabilities.
Sen, Amartya, 1999. Freedom as development.
Shah, Anuj K., Shafir, Eldar, Mullainathan, Sendhil, 2015. Scarcity frames value. Psychological Science 26
(4), 402–412.
Shah, Anuj K., Zhao, Jiaying, Mullainathan, Sendhil, Shafir, Eldar, 2018. Money in the mental lives of the
poor. Social Cognition 36 (1), 4–19.
Shapiro, Jesse M., 2005. Is there a daily discount rate? Evidence from the food stamp nutrition cycle.
Journal of Public Economics 89 (2–3), 303–325.
Shefrin, Hersh M., Thaler, Richard H., 2004. Mental accounting, saving, and self-control. In: Camerer,
Colin F., Loewenstein, George, Rabin, Matthew (Eds.), Advances in Behavioral Economics. Russell
Sage Foundation/Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford, pp. 395–428.
Sims, Christopher A., 2003. Implications of rational inattention. Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (3),
665–690.
Sims, Christopher A., 2010. Rational inattention and monetary economics. In: Friedman, Benjamin
M., Woodford, Michael (Eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 3. Elsevier, Amsterdam,
pp. 155–181.
Slovic, Paul, Kunreuther, Howard, White, Gilbert F., 1974. Decision processes, rationality and adjustment
to natural hazards. In: White, Gilbert F. (Ed.), Natural Hazards: Local, National, Global. Oxford Uni-
versity Press, New York, pp. 187–205.
Song, Changcheng, 2015. Financial illiteracy and pension contributions: a field experiment on compound
interest in China.
Spolaore, Enrico, Wacziarg, Romain, 2013. How deep are the roots of economic development? Journal of
Economic Literature 51 (2), 325–369.
Stango, Victor, Zinman, Jonathan, 2009. Exponential growth bias and household finance. The Journal of
Finance 64 (6), 2807–2849.
Stein, Daniel, 2016. Dynamics of demand for rainfall index insurance: evidence from a commercial prod-
uct in India. World Bank Economic Review 32 (3), 692–708.
Stephens, Melvin Jr., 2003. “3rd of tha month”: do social security recipients smooth consumption between
checks? The American Economic Review 93 (1), 406–422.
Subramanian, S.V., Nandy, Shailen, Irving, Michelle, Gordon, David, Smith, George Davey, 2005. Role
of socioeconomic markers and state prohibition policy in predicting alcohol consumption among men
and women in India: a multilevel statistical analysis. Bulletin of the World Health Organization 83,
829–836.
Sulaiman, Munshi, Barua, Proloy. 2013 Improving livelihood using livestock: impact evaluation of ‘tar-
geting ultra-poor’ programme in Afghanistan.
Suri, Tavneet, 2011. Selection and comparative advantage in technology adoption. Econometrica 79 (1),
159–209.
Suri, Tavneet, 2017. Mobile money. Annual Review of Economics 9 (1), 497–520.
Sydnor, Justin, 2010. (Over) insuring modest risks. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 2
(4), 177–199.
Tabellini, Guido, 2010. Culture and institutions: economic development in the regions of Europe. Journal
of the European Economic Association 8 (4), 677–716.
Tanaka, Tomomi, Camerer, Colin F., Nguyen, Quang, 2010. Risk and time preferences: linking experi-
mental and household survey data from Vietnam. The American Economic Review 100 (1), 557–571.
Tarozzi, Alessandro, Mahajan, Aprajit, Blackburn, Brian, Kopf, Dan, Krishnan, Lakshmi, Yoong, Joanne,
2014. Micro-loans, insecticide-treated bednets, and malaria: evidence from a randomized controlled
trial in Orissa, India. The American Economic Review 104 (7), 1909–1941.
Thakral, Neil Tô, Linh T., 2018. Daily labor supply and adaptive reference points. Mimeo.
458 CHAPTER 5 Behavioral development economics
Thaler, Richard, 1980. Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic Behavior &
Organization 1 (1), 39–60.
Thaler, Richard, 1985. Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science 4 (3), 199–214.
Thaler, Richard H., Shefrin, Hersh M., 1981. An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political
Economy 89 (2), 392–406.
Thompson, Edward P., 1967. Time, work-discipline, and industrial capitalism. Past & Present 38, 56–97.
Thornton, Rebecca L., 2008. The demand for, and impact of, learning HIV status. The American Economic
Review 98 (5), 1829–1863.
Townsend, Robert M., 1994. Risk and insurance in village India. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric
Society, 539–591.
Townsend, Robert M., 1995. Consumption insurance: an evaluation of risk-bearing systems in low-income
economies. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (3), 83–102.
Tversky, Amos, Kahneman, Daniel, 1971. Belief in the law of small numbers. Psychological Bulletin 76
(2), 105.
Tversky, Amos, Kahneman, Daniel, 1981. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Sci-
ence 211 (4481), 453–458.
Tybout, James R., 2000. Manufacturing firms in developing countries: how well do they do, and why?
Journal of Economic Literature 38 (1), 11–44.
Ubfal, Diego, 2016. How general are time preferences? Eliciting good-specific discount rates. Journal of
Development Economics 118, 150–170.
Viscusi, W. Kip, 1990. Do smokers underestimate risks? Journal of Political Economy 98 (6), 1253–1269.
Weber, Max, 1905. The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism.
World Bank, 2015. World Development Report 2015: Mind, Society, and Behavior. World Bank Group.
World Health Organization, 2015. Noncommunicable Diseases Progress Monitor 2015. Technical report.
World Health Organization.
Yanagizawa-Drott, David, 2014. Propaganda and conflict: evidence from the Rwandan genocide. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (4), 1947–1994.
Yang, Dean, Choi, HwaJung, 2007. Are remittances insurance? Evidence from rainfall shocks in the Philip-
pines. World Bank Economic Review 21 (2), 219–248.