DDDD
DDDD
For decades, experts have debated the impact of population growth on economic
development. "Population pessimists" have insisted that high fertility and rapid population
growth inhibit development. This view contributed to the rationale for widespread funding of
family planning policies and programs in the 1960s.[1] Conversely, "population optimists" have
argued the opposite position: Rapid population growth and large population size can promote
economic prosperity by furnishing abundant human and intellectual capital and increasing
market size. Proponents of both views can find support in the research record, but overall, the
evidence has been inconclusive.
Proponents of yet a third view, "population neutralism," contend that population growth, in
isolation from other factors, has little impact on economic performance, a position supported
by a sizable body of economic research. This view has become the dominant position in the
current policy environment.
Focusing on population size and growth, the debate has largely ignored a critical demographic
variable: the age structure of the population (that is, the way the population is distributed
across different age groups). Because individual economic behavior varies at different stages
of life, changes in age structure can significantly affect national economic performance.
Nations with a high proportion of young or old dependents tend to devote a relatively high
proportion of resources to these groups, often limiting economic growth. By contrast, nations
in which a relatively large share of the population has reached the prime ages for working and
saving may enjoy a boost to income growth stemming from the higher share of the population
that is working, from the accelerated accumulation of capital, and from reduced spending on
dependents. This phenomenon is known as the "demographic dividend." The combined effect
of this "dividend" and effective policies in other areas can stimulate economic growth.
The relationship between population change and economic growth has taken on added
salience in the last few decades because of demographic trends in the developing world. At
varying rates, developing countries are undergoing a demographic transition to lower rates of
mortality and fertility, producing a boom generation that is gradually working its way through
nations' age structures. Thus, many developing countries face opportunities to translate their
ongoing demographic transitions into economic gains.
The cases of East Asia and sub-Saharan Africa best illustrate the two ends of the spectrum
with respect to the demographic dividend.
East Asia. The East Asian "economic miracle" shows how reduced fertility can help to create
conditions for robust economic growth. Declining mortality, followed by declines in fertility,
resulted in a rapid demographic transition in the region between 1965 and 1990. As a result,
the working-age population grew four times faster than the dependent (youth and elderly)
population. A strong educational system and trade liberalization policies enabled national
economies to absorb this "boom" generation into the workforce. The demographic dividend
fueled the region's spectacular economic boom: Real per capita income growth averaged 6
percent per year between 1965 and 1990. The demographic dividend accounted for
approximately one-fourth to two-fifths of this growth.
As the case studies show, falling fertility rates can create conditions for economic growth.
However, reduced fertility by itself provides no guarantee of prosperity. In order to capitalize
on their demographic dividend, nations need effective policies in key areas.
Catalyzing the Demographic Transition. Improvements in public health are the key to initiating
the demographic transition. Improved sanitation, immunization programs, and antibiotics lead
to declines in mortality that lead in turn to declines in fertility. Furthermore, there are
economic reasons to invest in health: Mounting research indicates that a healthy population
can abet economic growth and lessen poverty,
contrary to the long-standing belief that causation
runs only from wealth to health.
• Economic policy. A larger, better-educated workforce will yield benefits only if the
extra additional workers can find jobs. Government policies that lead to stable
macroeconomic conditions are associated with the growth of productive and rewarding
jobs. Labor- market flexibility and openness to trade are also important, but the
relevant policy reforms must be undertaken gradually and in a manner that protects
those who can lose out in such transitions.
• Good governance. In many countries, necessary steps to reaping the benefits of the
demographic dividend include strengthening the rule of law, improving the efficiency
of government operations, reducing corruption, and guaranteeing contract
enforcement.
The effects of successful policies in all of these areas can be mutually reinforcing, helping to
create a "virtuous cycle" of sustained growth. Conversely, without effective policies, countries
may miss opportunities for economic growth, or worse. They may risk high unemployment,
increased crime rates, and political instability.