Catastrophe Theory and The Business Cycle
Catastrophe Theory and The Business Cycle
ẋ = f (x, a).
.
x=0
a* a
Here we have depicted a system with one fast variable, x, and one slow
variable a. For any fixed value of a, the fast variable adjusts to a locally
stable equilibrium, This means that the system moves rapidly to either the
upper or the lower leaf of the ẋ = 0 locus, depending on initial conditions.
For definiteness, we imagine that initially a is rather small, so that x adjusts
to a short run equilibrium position on the upper leaf of the ẋ = 0 locus.
We now suppose that a slowly increases. Then the short run equilibrium
will move continuously to the right along the x = 0 locus, until it reaches
the fold point a∗ . Any further increase in a necessitates a jump from the
upper leaf to the lower leaf of the ẋ = 0 locus. This movement is an
example of the fold catastrophe. Note that any sort of return to the upper
leaf of the ẋ = 0 would involve a similar jump when a declined past the
other fold point.
It can be shown that in a system with one state variable and one param-
eter, this is essentially the only kind of catastrophe that can occur—any
sudden jumps in such two-dimensional systems are generally locally topo-
logically equivalent to Figure 1.1
In higher dimensions things get a bit more complicated. Suppose we
have a three dimensional system with one fast variable, x, and two slow
variables, a and b:
ẋ = f (x, a, b).
Then the ẋ = 0 locus will generally be some two dimensional surface
in R3 . This surface locally sits over the plane R2 in one of three possible
ways, which are depicted in Figure 2.
1 More precisely, one should qualify this statement by requiring that the catastrophe
be “stable” in the sense that its geometry is qualitatively unaffected by any small
perturbations. The word “generally” really should be “generically.”
4 CATASTROPHE THEORY AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE
Slow
return
b c
a
Fast
return
2 Again, a rigorous statement of this result would involve the qualification in footnote 1.
A MODEL OF RECESSIONS 5
dynamical systems. In this case Thom has shown that when k ≤ 4, there
are generically only 7 kinds of local catastrophes. For a development of
some of the mathematical ideas involved in this classification theorem the
reader should consult Golubitsky (1978), Wasserman (1974), Lu (1976),
Thom (1975), or Zeeman (1977).
In the economic model that follows we will only utilize the two simplest
catastrophes, the fold and the cusp. In these low dimensional cases, there
are no restrictions on the nature of dynamical systems involved. In some
ways, the material that follows is more closely related to the mathematical
theory of the singularities of maps, rather than catastrophe theory per se.
(For an elementary survey of singularity theory see Callahan (1974); for a
more advanced exposition see Golubitsky and Guillemin (1973)).
3 Some sort of distinction between gross and net investment is necessary if we wish
savings to be positive even when investment is negative The usual formulation is
to make replacement investment proportional to k. But this tends to obscure some
of the calculations in the appendix. The autonomous investment formulation is a
compromise for the purposes of exposition.
6 CATASTROPHE THEORY AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE
S(y)
I(y,k)
I(y,k1)
S(y)
I(y,k2)
I(y,k3)
Figure 3. Savings and investment behavior which generate the fold catas-
trophe.
small for unusually high levels of activity because rising costs of con-
struction, increasing costs and increasing difficulty of borrowing will
dissuade entrepreneurs from expanding still faster—at a time when
they already have large commitments.” Kaldor (l940), p. 81.
.
y k=0
.
y=0
k
In order to describe a model with both fast and slow recoveries, we need
to utilize the cusp catastrophe. The cusp catastrophe requires two slow
variables. One of these must be the capital stock, but what will the other
be? It seems natural to choose the other stock variable of short run macro-
economic theory, namely private wealth. By wealth here, I mean wealth
very broadly construed—including human capital, expectations of future
employment, all types of assets, and in fact any type of stock variable that
affects consumption decisions up to, and including, “consumer sentiment.”
Well, how should changes in wealth affect consumption decisions? It is
generally agreed that an increase in wealth will, other things being equal,
increase consumption. Conversely, a decrease in wealth results in a decrease
in consumption, presumably because consumers wish to save more in order
to rebuild their stocks of wealth.
We are going to assume such a positive relationship between consumption
and wealth and a bit more; namely that there is a positive relationship
between wealth and the marginal propensity to consume. That is, not only
does an increase in wealth increase the level of the consumption function,
it also increases the slope of the consumption function.
In the linear consumption function case that we have been using, this
assumption means that we can write C(y, w) = c(w)y + D(w) with c0 (w) >
0 and D0 (w) > 0. Again this assumption seems quite plausible, but I know
of no theoretical or empirical evidence to support it.
10 CATASTROPHE THEORY AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE
S(y,w)
I(y,k)
I(y,k1)
S(y,w)
I(y,k2)
I(y,k3)
Figure 5. Savings and investment behavior which generate the cusp catas-
trophe.
Putting these facts together, we see that the ẏ = 0 locus will be three
sheeted for some values of k and w, but will be one sheeted for sufficiently
low values of w. This characterizes the geometry of the cusp catastrophe. 4
It remains to describe the movements of the slow variables k and w. We
will suppose that there is some long run equilibrium (y ∗ .k ∗ , w∗ ) located
on the top sheet of the ẏ = 0 surface. We will also suppose that this
equilibrium is locally stable: when k is greater than k ∗ , k is negative; when
w is less than w∗ , w is positive and so on. An interesting configuration
consistent with these assumptions is illustrated in Figure 6. In this figure
the flow lines illustrating the ẏ movement and the flow lines hidden beneath
the fold have been omitted for clarity.
4 Zeeman has referred to the a and b parameters as representing “normal” and “split-
ting” factors involved in some underlying dynamical system. The method of generat-
ing the cusp catastrophe described in the text seems perfectly general and suggests
that a more descriptive terminology for a and b would be to call them the the “shift”
and the “tilt” factors.
REVIEW AND SUMMARY 11
Here is the interesting feature of the model. Suppose as before, that there
is some kind of perturbation in one of the stock variables. For definiteness
let us suppose that some kind of shock (a stock market crash?) affects
w. If the shock is relatively small, we have much the same story as with
the inventory recession: a gradual decline in k, then a jump return to
the upper sheet, and an eventual return to the long run equilibrium. If
on the other hand the shock is relatively large, wealth may decrease so
much as to significantly affect the propensity to save. In this case, when k
declines, national income will remain at a relatively low level rather than
experience a jump return. Eventually the gradual increase in wealth due
to the increased savings will move the system slowly back towards the long
run equilibrium. (See Figure 6.)
According to this story the major difference between a recession and a
depression is in the effect on consumption. If a shock affects wealth so much
as to change savings propensities, recovery may take a very long time, and
differ quite substantially from the recovery pattern of a recession. This
explanation does not seem to be in contradiction with observed behavior,
but as I have mentioned earlier, it rests on unproven (but not implausible)
assumptions about savings and investment behavior.
ẏ = s[C(y) + I(y, k) − y]
k̇ = I(y, k) − I0 .
We shall make the following maintained assumptions:
The last part of this assumption simply states that the system is even-
tually self-correcting: for large enough k, k̇ is negative, for large y, ẏ is
negative and so on,
We will use two results from the mathematical theory of dynamical sys-
tems, (For a survey of dynamical systems which describes these and other
useful theorems, see Varian (1978)).
The first theorem gives a criterion for the existence and uniqueness of
equilibria.
+1 if det(−Df (x∗i )) > 0
index(x∗i ) =
−1 if det(−Df (x∗i )) < 0
and these indices have the property that
n
X
index(x∗i ) = +1.
i=1
APPENDIX: THE EXISTENCE OF BUSINESS CYCLE 13
We can apply this theorem directly to the problem at hand. The Jacobian
matrix referred to in the Poincare-Hopf theorem takes the form:
" h i
s 1 − ∂C(y) ∂I(y,k)
−s ∂I(y,k)
#
∂y − ∂y ∂k
−Df (x) =
− ∂I(y,k)
∂y − ∂I(y,k)
∂k
References