What Affects Long Term Stock Prices?: Aaron Chaum Bryan Price
What Affects Long Term Stock Prices?: Aaron Chaum Bryan Price
Bryan Price
Introduction
capitalization and beta. To varying degrees, these studies have found these variables to
examine the relationship between dividends, interest rates and market capitalization and
their predictive power on capital gains with regression analysis without adjusting for risk.
Our hypothesis is that the recent tax environment has fundamentally changed the
relationship between capital gains and our explanatory variables, and our regression will
The theory of the impact of dividends on future stock prices goes back to the
dividend irrelevance theorem of Miller and Modigliani (1961), which implies that dividends
have no overall effect on stock returns because price appreciation has a compensating effect
on the dividend distribution. Early studies of the dividend irrelevance theorem seemed to
confirm Miller’s and Modigliani’s research. Using data from the period before the
seventies, studies such as Friend and Puckett (1964) and Black and Scholes (1974)
were unable to find any significant relationship between dividend policy and total returns
on a risk-adjusted basis. However, some researchers have continued to look at the effect of
the distribution of cash on investors’ preferences, and recent research has focused on the
effect of dividend yields on future stock returns. Rozeff (1984) finds that the ratio of
the dividend yield to the short-term interest rate explains a significant fraction of
movements in annual stock returns. Fama and French (1988) use a regression
multiple year returns to the NYSE index. They further observe that the
explanatory power of the dividend yield increases in the time horizon of the
returns. Similar results are reported by Flood, Hodrick, and Kaplan (1987) and
Cambell and Shiller (1988). Lewellen (2001) has recently developed an alternative
Many of these forecasting studies use ordinary least squares (OLS) regression.
Fama and French (1988) provide the strongest evidence in support of the dividend yield
effect by using overlapping multiple-year horizon returns. They investigate the ability of
portfolios for intervals between one month and four years. Fama and French use CRSP
monthly data, beginning in 1926, and they construct annualized dividend yields by
summing the previous 12 months of dividends. The OLS specification of Fama and
The error term μt+k,k is an element of the time t+k information set, and Fama and French
define the one-period real return as Rt+1 = (Pt+1 + dt+1)/Pt where Pt is the end of the
month real stock price and dt is real dividends paid during month t and the annualized
dividend yield is Dt/Pt. Fama and French (1988) found that the coefficient of the dividend
yield was positive and significant, and they also observed that the explanatory power of the
dividend yield increases in the time horizon of the returns; over 4-year horizons, R2’s reach
a high value of 64%. However, Fama and French (1988) point out many biases
which will distort the findings of their research. Most notable is the fact that
“dividend yields contain forecasts of future returns and dividend growth, which
may bias downward the regression coefficient in the dividend yield regression.”
discount model and estimate the model in a VAR framework. Their method is to test a
dividend-ratio model relating the dividend-price ratio D/P to the expected future values of
the one-period rates of discount r and one-period growth rates of dividends g over
succeeding periods. The model is based on the Gordon growth model, D/P = r – g, which
was derived under the assumption that dividends will grow at a constant rate forever, and
that the discount rate will never change. The benefit of this assumption is that it permits
analysis of the variation through time in the dividend-price ratio in relation to predictable
changes in discount rates and dividend growth rates. This is different from most previous
studies of the dividend-price ratio that have been concerned with the cross-sectional
relationship between dividend-price ratios and average returns [e.g. Black and Scholes
(1974)], which relies for the most part on the assumption that discount rates are constant.
Campbell and Shiller (1988) use a vector auto-regression to break down movements in the
log dividend-price ratio into components attributable to expected future dividend growth,
expected future discount rates, and other unexplained factors. Campbell and Shiller found
some evidence that the log dividend-price ratio does move with rationally expected future
growth in dividends. Their findings also parallel that of Fama and French (1988) and
Flood, Hodrick, and Kaplan (1986), which all find that stock returns are more highly
predictable when measured over a long period of time. They also find that the moderate
predictability of one-year stock returns can have dramatic implications for the log dividend-
price ratio, and in particular, the log dividend-price ratio has a standard deviation that is at
between dividends and stock prices, which includes the anticipated dividend yields:
where Rit is the total realized return on stock i over period t, βit is the relevant beta
coefficient, δit is the dividend yield anticipated over period t, and εit is a mean-zero
disturbance uncorrelated with βit and δit. The coefficients at, bt, and ct are allowed to vary
randomly from one period to the next and the null hypothesis is that expected returns are
unrelated to anticipated dividend yields (c=o). Blume uses the regression equation to
estimate on a specific cross section and then again on another cross section and so on.
Blume is different from previous studies because he calculates an alternative measure of the
dividend yield, as the ratio of the dividends paid over the previous twelve months to the
price at the beginning of these twelve months. This could be more accurate than previous
levels quickly to maintain a fixed payout ratio and the price-earnings ratio was relatively
stable. Blume further adjusts the ratio for what he calls “market-wide changes (general
market movements) in the level of dividend yields over the prior 12 months. He does this
by assuming that the beginning-of-period price had increased or decreased the same
percentage as the market average over these 12 months, and then he uses this adjusted price
in the calculation of the dividend price ratio. The first cross-sectional regression is
estimated using the quarterly total returns for the first calendar quarter of 1936 and he uses
data prior to 1936 to estimate βit and δit. Blume then performs the second cross-sectional
regression using returns for the second calendar quarter of 1936 and this process is
repeated for each and every calendar quarter through the end of 1976 for a total of 164
Blume breaks the securities into groups in order to reduce the magnitude
of βt and δit. The simple averages of the rit’s, βt’s and δit’s within each group are used as
the basic data in estimating the cross-sectional regressions. For the grouping, all NYSE
securities with complete data from 1926 through March of 1936 were ranked from low to
high by their beta coefficients as estimated over the previous 5 years using the S&P
Composite Index. These ranked securities are then partitioned into five groups of an equal
number of securities, and thus the first group contains those securities with the smallest
estimates of beta and the last group those with the largest estimates. Blume further divides
each of the five groups of securities into five subgroups of roughly equal numbers of
securities according to the adjusted 1935 dividend yield. Over the 1936-76 period, Blume
finds that these cross-sectional regressions reveal a positive and significant relationship on
average between the quarterly realized rates of return and both the beta coefficients and the
anticipated quarterly dividend yields. For the portfolios grouped first on beta and then on
dividend yield, the average coefficient on dividend yield for the 164 cross-sectional
regressions estimated over these 41 years was 0.5232 with a t-value of 2.07, and the
average coefficient on beta was 0.0215 with a t-value of 2.34. Taken at face value, these
numbers imply that for a given beta, realized quarterly returns increased an average of
0.52% for each 1% increase in the anticipated quarterly dividend yield. Blume also found
that the significance of the dividend yield variable varies over time. In the two decades
from 1937 through 1946 and from 1957 through 1966, the average coefficients on dividend
yield were positive but not significant at any usual level of significance. But in the decade
from 1947 through 1956, the average coefficient on dividend yield was 0.8743 with a
highly significant t-value of 4.27. In the last decade ending in 1976, the average coefficient
on dividend yield was 1.1272 with a t-value of 1.93, indicating a level of significance
Goetzmann and Jorion (1995) extend the analysis of dividend yield regressions on
monthly U.S. data going back to 1871. They find little evidence of predictability over the
whole sample period. When considering different sample periods, however, they find that
the predictability results do not extend to pre-1926 U.S. data. This is because stock returns
before 1926 were more stable, and in turn means that dividend yields were more stable and
therefore with little variability there is little predictability. The Goetzmann and Jorion study
also points out the survivorship bias inherent in this type of regression analysis because
only those stocks that have long-term “complete” data are used, thus biasing the study in
favor of finding that dividend yields help to predict long-horizon returns. As Fama and
French note, the dividend yields also contain forecasts of future dividend growth, which
Chen, Grundy, and Stambaugh (1986) compare the average “risk-adjusted” returns
for high- and low-yield stocks to determine whether there is a relation between cash
dividends and required rates of return. Their research differs from previous studies
because their main pricing model is a multifactor model that contains two risk measures,
where Rpt is the return on portfolio p in excess of the Treasury-bill rate, RVWt is the return
in excess of the Treasury-bill rate on the value-weighted portfolio of stocks in the NYSE,
and PREMt is the difference between the return on a portfolio of “junk” bonds and the
return on a long-term U.S. government bond. They analyze monthly returns on portfolios
that are formed at the end of each year using a simultaneous two-way classification based
on dividend yield and firm size. The dividend yield for a given stock is computed as the
sum of dividends per share paid during the previous year divided by the share price at the
beginning of the previous year. At the end of each year, beginning in December 1942, each
firm on the NYSE with a complete return data available for the previous 5 years and a
positive dividend yield is classified into one of 20 portfolios. The 20 portfolios are defined
by quintiles of market value and by quartiles of dividend yield. Each year, they estimate the
risk measures βp(M) and δp for each of the 20 portfolios using monthly returns over the
previous 5 years. In the second step, Chen, Grundy and Stambaugh regress the cross-
sectional portfolio returns month by month on the estimated portfolio multiple risk
measures and the dividend yields. This process is repeated for each year from 1943 to
1978, and the estimated risk measures and the dividend yields are updated every year.
Their approach is different from previous studies because this method allows the risk
premium to change every month, which may reduce the distorting effects of changing risk.
In each case, Chen, Grundy, and Stambaugh (1986) find that if the value-weighted market
beta is the only risk-adjustment, the estimated dividend coefficient is reliably positive.
However, when they include a second risk measure “PREM” (measures changing
Researchers on the dividend yield give a number of reasons why these results
should be regarded with caution. Stambaugh (1986) pointed out that the
explanatory variable, the dividend yield, “is not properly exogenous because it
contains a price level that also appears in the regressand.” Fama and French
(1988) also point out the fact that “yields contain forecasts of future returns and
dividend growth, which may bias downward the regression coefficient in the
dividend yield regression.”
Theoretical Framework
The reason that dividends and interest rates have become increasingly important is
that they have been more volatile in the modern era. Moreover, recent tax law changes have
narrowed the gap in tax rates on capital gains and dividends, implying that, theoretically,
investors should be indifferent between a dividend distribution and a capital gain. But the
problem is that traditional stock valuation models such as the dividend-discount model and
CAPM fail to distinguish between the dividend and capital gain components of a stock’s
return. Given the uncertainty of future monetary policy, investors who are more concerned
with capital risk than income risk may prefer high-dividend stocks to low-dividend stocks.
Especially in times of great economic uncertainty, stocks with low or high dividend-price
ratios may exhibit greater price appreciation than can be explained by company financials
alone. One possible explanation for this dividend preference is that, battered by the poor
market of recent years, some investors have reached the conclusion that retained earnings
bear only a tenuous relationship to subsequent capital gains and that high dividend-yielding
stocks offer, on a risk-adjusted basis, greater expected returns than low dividend-yielding
stocks. Also, dividend policy affects market risk because stocks that pay high dividends
have a shorter duration than do stocks that pay low dividends. Theoretically, stocks with a
greater duration should be priced low enough to compensate investors for the added risk,
which implies that low-dividend yielding stocks should outperform high-dividend yielding
stocks. We propose that in a market with rising interest rates and an increased emphasis the
value of paying dividends goes beyond their nominal amount, especially in “defensive”
market situations where growth prospects are low, and that the effect of dividend
Interest rates have also become increasingly important as most stock valuation
calculations include a discount rate that is relative to general interest rates. According the
common present value calculation, as the discount rate rises the present value of future cash
flows should fall. Typically, most people tend to associate increases in interest rates with
decreases in bond prices, but as our theory would predict a rise in interest rates should
INCLUDEPICTURE "http://www.agecon.purdue.edu/academic/agec217/deboer/graphs/
intratels.JPG" \* MERGEFORMATINET
The economic theory would also predict that small capitalization stocks should
garner a risk premium and that this will lead to above-market average returns over time.
the company’s price per share, and this calculation gives an impression of how large the
company is. Using market capitalization as an explanatory variable for capital gains allows
our regression to test whether a readily available piece of data can have predictive power.
Market capitalization is important because large companies are easier to follow in the
marketplace, and more information is readily available about them relative to small
companies. Therefore, it is often thought that because of the lack of information about
small companies, and their relatively riskier nature, investors should be compensated for the
added risk in investing in small capitalization stocks. According to this theory, we should
find a statistically significant relationship between market capitalization and stock prices.
When determining how best to incorporate market capitalization into the model we
determined that market capitalization is only relevant in relation to the capitalization of the
Data Set
For our data set, we used the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) which
maintains the most comprehensive collection of security price, return, and volume data for
the NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ stock markets spanning from 1925 to the present.
CRSP is a research center at the University of Chicago Graduate School of Business, and
access to the database is located on the Wharton Research Data Services (WRDS) site. To
narrow the range of our data set, we used the Standard & Poor’s 500 stock index, which is
often cited as a good measure of the overall stock market. We examined the period from
1965 to 2005. In the data set, past research has tended to focus on a broad index of
companies that have various characteristics, ranging from small to large market
Examining only the S&P 500 does have its limitations, considering the fact that the
companies in the S&P 500 are closely followed and there is probably not a risk premium
with those S&P 500 stocks with the smallest market capitalization but we would argue that
in looking at the effects of dividends we will be better able to see the impact on large, more
well-established companies such as those in the S&P 500. For our regression we use
monthly stock market data from 1965 – 2005. Although the primary reason we are using
this time period is due to the availability of price and dividend data, we also believe that the
modern period of stock valuation is significantly different than the previous period, as to
render the previous period irrelevant for our analysis. This is based on the fact that the
industrial composition of the index has changed substantially over time, from mostly
past these companies were much more stable investments, as reflected in their lower
standard deviation, and they paid much higher dividends and their annual total return was
Model Specification
Therefore, we used the double-log functional form with the natural log on both the left-
hand side and right-hand side of the equation. We chose capital gains (or price appreciation
or depreciation) as our dependent variable, and interest rates, dividends and market
variables that are known to have a significant impact on stock prices. Numerous studies
have shown that the most important indicator of future market returns is the level of risk,
and that investors who are willing to bear greater risk are usually compensated with higher
stock returns. GDP and earnings per share are also other variables that have been shown to
have some impact on share prices, but there are several reasons why not to include all of
these variables in our regression equation. The first problem is that many of these variables
are significantly correlated with one another, resulting in the violation of Classical
Assumption VI, which specifies that no explanatory variable is a perfect linear function of
any other explanatory variables. While we would always expect some level of correlation
as ours because of the time-series nature of the data to constantly increase over time. The
second problem is that, while certain variables have a well-known impact on stock prices,
we are unable to predict with any certainty the future course of movements in these
variables and so using them as a barometer to invest in the stock market would be useless.
In our regression analysis, we limited our research to information that is readily to known
at the time of the investment decision, such as the interest rate level, dividend yield
(dividends paid last year over the average stock price last year) and market capitalization. .
Another problem with our time-series data set is that the independent variables can
appear to be more significant than they actually are if they have the same underlying trend
as the dependent variable. This is an especially difficult problem with stock prices,
dividends, and market capitalization because they tend to increase over time and this may
regression analysis of these two variables might result in a spurious regression, probably
caused by the fact that our independent variable is non-stationary and has a mean and
variance that change over time. Often times, because financial variables tend to increase
over time the regression estimators will falsely attribute to the wrong independent variable
Regression Results
Number of obs = 213,566
R-squared = 0.3787
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
lncapgain | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
lndividend| 1.129363 .239779 4.71 0.000 .6593961 1.599329
lnrate | -.7880864 .1921628 -4.10 0.000 -1.164725 -.4114473
lnmktcap | .8309234 .0958389 8.67 0.000 .6430791 1.018767
_cons | 6.463215 1.071843 6.03 0.000 4.324027 8.564027
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
As expected, our coefficient on lndividend is positive, indicating that an increase in
dividends will tend to increase stock prices. The coefficient 1.129 means that a 1% increase
in dividends will increase the price by 1.129%, meaning that an increase in dividends has a
more than one-for-one impact on capital gains. This is an interesting result, but it seems
quite normal considering a dividend represents a positive outflow of cash from the
company. Accordingly, a cash outflow should decrease the value of the company as assets
fall in order to pay the dividend, so we would expect that the stock price should fall by the
per share value of the dividend. Given our theory, we would have expected to see a larger
decline in share price, and so there is the possibility that the company will benefit from
paying dividends because the cash outflow signals to investors that the company is strong.
Also, as a proxy for interest rates we used the yield on long-term corporate bonds. We
predicted the coefficient on lnrate to be negative, meaning that an increase in interest rates
will decrease stock prices. This is nicely correlated with our economic theory of how
stocks are valued by using a discount rate. As interest rates rise, the discount rate used to
value future cash flows should also rise, which will have the effect of decreasing the
present value of a stock. The meaning of the coefficient on lnrate is that a 1% increase in
interest rates will decrease stock prices by .788%. Our third variable, lnmktcap, had a
positive coefficient as expected, and a large t-statistic. As expected, the R2 for our
regression equation is somewhat low, at 0.3787, meaning that our dividend, interest, and
market capitalization variables only explain 37.87% of the variation in stock prices. This is
significant, however, when we consider the importance of other measures of company
performance such as EPS that are heavily relied on to value a company’s shares.
We tested for serial correlation by first plotting our data set on a time-series graph,
.975074 +
| *
| *
| * *
|
| * *
*
R | *
*
e | *
s | **
i |
d | *
u | * ** *
a | * * *
l | ** *
s | ** * *
| ** * *
| * *
| * *
| * *
| * *
-.753042 + * ** *
+----------------------------------------------------------------+
1965 year
2005
It seems from the graph that the expected value of our error term observations does not
equal zero, and it appears that this is evidence of serial correlation in our data. On our
graph, the error term tends to have the same sign from one period to the next, implying
positive serial correlation. This is probably due to the lingering effect of some major
economy-wide shocks, such as the rise and fall in GDP growth in the 1960s and 1970s and
the dynamic change of in the interest rate during the 1970s through the 1980s. Examining
our Durbin-Watson statistic, with DL = 1.44 and DU = 1.54, we would reject the null
. estat dwatson
have omitted several variables that have strong effects on stock prices—such as GDP—that
will cause our equation to have specification bias. However, as we have noted before,
including such variables will have negative consequences on the rest of our regression and
this is why we have chosen to leave them out. As the best remedy for serial correlation is
to find the omitted variables, then there is nothing further we can do.
Besides the formal regression biases that plagued our regression analysis, we
believe that there is a natural bias in using market capitalization as an independent variable.
Because market capitalization reflects the current market price of company shares, there is
going to exist a direct relationship between market capitalization and capital gains. As
prices rise, market capitalizations will rise as well and so it becomes difficult to predict
whether one variable causes the other to change. We believe then that this caused a
spurious correlation in our regression, which cripples any explanatory power that we could
have derived from the coefficient on market capitalization. Another reason that market
capitalization was a poorly conceived independent variable on our part has to do with the
selection of our data set. Because we limited our data to the S&P 500, our observations
estimator tries to attribute the change in capital gains as a result of differences in market
capitalizations, but the market capitalizations of the S&P 500 are all relatively large.
Conclusion
Despite the fact that our data set has generated statistically significant coefficients
for our independent variables, it is likely that our regression equation suffers from omitted
variable bias and does not explain enough of the variation in stock prices to warrant
investing according to our explanatory variables. This is the inevitable result of most
financial time-series regressions, but it does not mean that certain factors do not affect stock
prices, but rather it means that it is difficult to prove the exact relationship between them.
We still believe that in certain time periods, especially when there are many accounting
errors and earnings estimates cannot be trusted, some investors will prefer high-dividend
paying stocks and such stocks will deliver above market average returns over that time
period. But the serial correlation in our time-series data set has rendered our OLS estimator
to bias our standard errors and make unreliable any subsequent hypothesis tests.
cannot reinvest its cash at a higher rate than the investors’ required rate of return. But we
could also make the argument that dividends may very well be influenced just as much by
past prices as current prices are influenced by past dividends (Granger causality).
Another reason why our regression analysis will not pick up some of the variation in the
capital gains as an effect of dividends is because, while companies are willing to increase
dividends to signal company profitability to investors, they often do not cut dividends.
Therefore, dividends will tend to increase over time and as stock prices increase as well the
OLS estimator will falsely attribute to dividends the increase in stock prices that is probably
caused by some underlying macroeconomic variable such as inflation. While our market
relationship between interest rates and stock appreciation. This has serious implications in
our current market environment in which the Federal Reserve uses interest rates to stabilize
the economy, and this has the side effect of causing greater fluctuations in interest rates
during our modern era than in the past. If one believes that interest rates will rise in the
future, our regression results will certainly indicate that any positive company earnings will
be tempered by declines in the present value calculation as an effect of the rising discount
rate.
PAGE
PAGE 18
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. "Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pricing Anomalies." The
Journal of Finance 51.1 (1996): 55-84.
Campbell and Shiller. “The Dividend-Price Ratio and Expectations of Future Dividends.” Review of
Financial Studies, 195-228.
Hodrick, R., 1992, “Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns: Alternative Procedures for Inference
and Measurement,” Review of Financial Studies 5, 357-386.
Blume, Marshall E. "Stock Returns and Dividend Yields: Some More Evidence." The Journal of Finance
62.4 (1980): 567-577.
Goetzmann, William N., and Philippe Jorion. "A Longer Look at Dividend Yields." The Journal of
Business 68.4 (1995): 438-508.
Chen, Grundy, and Stambaugh. “Changing Risk, Changing Risk Premiums, and Dividend Yield Effects”
Table 1 in (fill in info)
Given that the company’s rate of return on capital is equal to the investor’s rate of return on other
investments