Slave Society in Ancient Greece
Slave Society in Ancient Greece
Slave Society in Ancient Greece
(Greek history is conventionally divided into three major epochs. They are: Archaic—from
750 BC to 500 BC; Classical—the fifth and fourth centuries; and Hellenistic—from the time
of Alexander the Great to the Roman conquest of the eastern Mediterranean)
1
Perry Anderson, Passages From Antiquity to Feudalism, London, New Left Books, 1977. Pg 21
2
Ibid
unimportant. To sum up then, we may say that if we put aside the
question of the rise and decline of slavery and concentrate on the
great classical periods in Greece and Rome, then we are faced with
the first genuine slave societies in history, surrounded by societies
which continued to rely on other forms of dependent labour.
According to Finley, slaves were an inherent aspect of the ancient
economy in the classical period being a fundamental part of the
social structure because of the reliance placed on them and their
labour by the upper strata3. Further slavery was the archetypal form
of unfree labour throughout Graeco-Roman antiquity with the result
that much of the terminology of unfree labour was derived from
slave terminology. In fact, slavery was ever present in the psychology
of all classes in the Graeco-Roman society and slavery was seen as a
superior means of extracting surplus in comparison with other
methods of exploitation. This is clear from the sources which
repeatedly indicate that those who did not possess slaves were
working towards a situation when they could also own them.
The totality of the slave owner’s rights over the slave was facilitated
by the fact that the slave was always an outsider who was denied the
most elementary of bonds such as kinship. Complete and brutal
withdrawal of kinship privilege took the form of dispersing the
slaves’ kin through sale. These three components of slavery—the
slave’s status as property, the totality of power over him and his
kinlessness provided powerful advantages to the slave owner as
against other forms of involuntary labour. The slave owner had
greater flexibility in the employment of his labour force and far more
freedom in disposing of unwanted labour. It is not surprising
therefore that in his utopian dreams the small and humbly placed
men also looked to a time when he too could live off his slaves—it
was to be preferred to every other form of labour for the purpose of
extracting a surplus.
During the great classical periods in Athens and other Greek cities
(from the 6th to the 4th century BC) and in Rome (from the early 3rd
century BC to the 3rd century AD) slavery effectively came to replace
other forms of dependent labour. One stimulus for Chattel slavery
came from the growth of urban production for which the traditional
forms of dependent labour were unsuitable. On the land, slavery
made significant inroads wherever Helotage and comparable labour
systems failed to survive on a sufficient scale to meet the needs of
landowners.
While slave labour may not have completely substituted free labour
in Greece which continued to exist alongside it, the use of slave
labour specially in the countryside had important consequences for
Greek society. It freed the land-owning classes from their rural
background and made it possible for them to become urban citizens
while continuing to draw their wealth from the land. There was also
a close link between status and the possession of land in which the
law played its part. The Greek fully preserved for its citizens a
monopoly of the right to own land: in the more oligarchic
communities, full political rights were restricted to the land owners
among its members specially in Sparta. In Athens, people were
divided into citizens, metics (foreign residents in Athens) and slaves.
Only the citizens could own land and participate in the assembly.
Although Greek agriculture used slaves to work the farms, the farms
themselves were usually of very modest size unlike the latter Roman
Latifundia. However, there were a few land owners even in Greece
who possessed 3-6 estates in different parts of Attica. The most
valuable known to us were two farms, one in Eleusis and another in
Thria, which were included among the property of a family founded
by Bucelas and can be traced through the 5th and 6th centuries. It
included a considerable number of men in some prominence in the
military and political affairs of Athens who drew their wealth from
the land which was worked for them by the slaves. Whether in the
case of large landholdings or modest sized farms, slaves were an
important component on the land. According to recent research, a
great deal of slave labour was used on the land in many city states
including Athens and this was a most vital sector of the ancient
economy. It was this fairly pervasive existence of slave labour that
lead to Aristotle to express the social ideology of classical Greece
with the statement: “those who cultivate the land should ideally be
slaves, not recruited from one people nor spirited in temperament”.
This was to ensure that they would be industrious and immune to
rebellion.
Since the Greek sources are somewhat partial to Athens the picture
that emerges of Greek slavery and also of other Greek institutions
such as the city state tends to be a picture of Athens. However, it is
important to take note of another aspect of Greece which was
represented by Sparta. Sparta presents a somewhat complex
problem partly because very little writing on Sparta was the work of
Spartans. Sparta has therefore been presented by others and this
image probably conceals the reality. In the archaic period there is
nothing to suggest that Sparta was very different from the rest of
Greece. But its decisive turning point appears to have come around
600 BC with the second Messenian War which produced persistently
revolutionary potentiates and threats. The army was in disorder and
the community was in a state of stasis to which the Greeks had very
negative reaction. Once the war was won a number of profound
changes were introduced, political, economic and ideological,
resulting in the unique structure which Sparta came to represent in
the ancient Greek world5.
The population of Sparta did not rank with the bigger states. By
conquest Sparta held the districts of Laconia and Messenia which
were quite fertile by Greek standards and which gave her access to
the sea. It also provided her with the rare and invaluable natural
resources of iron as a counterpart to Athenian silver. Apart from the
Spartans this territory supported a subject people of two kinds: the
helots who were in outright servitude functioned as a compulsory
labour force and worked the land for the Spartans; and the others
known as perioeci, who retained their own personal freedom and
their own community organization in return for surrendering all right
of action to Sparta in the military and foreign fields. The perioeci
managed the trade and industrial production for Spartan needs. The
helots had been reduced to helotage by conquest. In contrast to the
common practice in most of antiquity whereby members of a
5
M.I. Finley, “Sparta” in Uses and Abuses of History, New York, The Viking Press, 1975. pp. 161-177; p. 161.
conquered area were enslaved and sold resulting in their dispersal,
the Spartans adopted the alternative of keeping them in subjugation
at home, in their native territory. What kept the helots enslaved
although they were discontented and prone to frequent rebellion
was the emergence of Sparta as an armed camp. After the second
Messenian War the Spartan citizen body became a professional
soldiery, bred from childhood for two qualities, military skill and
absolute obedience, free from all other activities living a barrack life
with their training being provided by the state.
The characteristic feature of the Spartan system was the fact that in
Sparta the citizens were not the direct producers: inversely the direct
producers could not be citizens. The body of citizens constituted an
exclusive group ruling over a subject population of the helots who
were the direct producers and other subject communities or the
perioeci. The perioeci were allowed no part in the government of the
state or in the determination of foreign policy. They were obliged to
render military and other services to the Spartan state. The helots on
the other hand were subjects of the state with no political community
of their own. The Spartan peer or the homoiors devoted himself to the
noble profession of arms and in order that he might be able to pursue
this career was granted a certain amount of land by the state. A
number of helots were tied to this land and were obliged to cultivate
it and to provide the Spartan peer to whom they were assigned a
certain fixed amount of the products of the land, sufficient to maintain
him and his family. This land and its proceeds were his by right of
citizenship and was assigned to him from the public land. The citizen
was not the owner of the land assigned to him and he was not free to
dispose of it by sale or by will. He could however mortgage it. The
helots were bound to the land, they had no political rights and no
freedom of movement. Individual Spartans had no rights of possession
in them and so long as they remained quiet and paid their annual dues
they were left alone. The distinctive feature of the system was that
surplus labour was extracted from a section of the people by a class of
non labourers by means of the coercive political apparatus of the
state. In Athens on the other hand we have a situation in which the
body of citizens is first and foremost a body of individual private
landowners.
The helots in Sparta were a numerous group, far more numerous than
the Spartans whose estates they worked in Laconia and Messenia.
Although the Greeks referred to the helots as “slaves” they are easily
and significantly distinguished from the chattel slaves of the other
Greek city states such as Athens. They were not the property of
individual Spartans; they could not be bought or sold; they could not
be freed except by the state and most importantly they were self-
perpetuating in contrast to chattel slaves whose ranks were constantly
being replenished by stocks from outside. The helots probably had
their own limited possessions transmitted from generation to
generation and their own institutions apart from their freedom. One
consequences of these distinctions from chattel slavery was that
unlike most other slaves they often revolted. According to Finley the
helots revolted while chattel slaves in Greece by and large did not
because the helot possessed certain rights and privileges and
demanded more.
The Greek word polis, from which we have derived words like
political, in its classical sense meant ‘a self-governing state’.
However, because polis was small in area and population it is
conventionally translated as ‘city-state’. The world polis also did not
distinguish the structure of government and did not imply anything
about democracy, or oligarchy or even tyranny. Athens was the most
well-known polis in Greece and the Athenian polis was a democracy.
All citizens7 who were not expressly disqualified for some offence
such as an unpaid debt to the treasury had equal political rights and
all could speak and vote in the assembly. There was an age
qualification for 30 years for all magistracies, membership in the
council and serving on the juries. For some of the offices there was
an additional qualification of property but by the late 4th century BC
they were being ignored in practice. To make the system work more
effectively it was considered necessary that in order than every
citizen, however poor, should be able to afford the time for
exercising his political rights and pay was provided for this purpose
from the time of Pericles. Magistrates, members of the council and
the juries were all given varying subsistence allowances.
Subsequently this facility was extended to all citizens who
constituted the quorum by arriving first to attend the sessions of the
assembly.
The council took numerous decisions and did a good deal of the
important work itself either through committees or in full sessions. It
was in fact the coordinating body which held the administrative
machine together. But it had a second and more important function,
that of being a steering committee of the assembly. The council
placed on agenda in the assembly motions which had already been
debated and voted by the council. The council consisting of 500
representatives was itself chosen annually by lot and contained 50
members from each tribe. From the elaborately representative
structure of the council it may be inferred that originally the council
7
It is important to note that Athens distinguished between three categories of people within Athens, citizens,
metics and slaves. Only citizens could hold property and participate in the Athenian assembly. For the metics
and slaves there were no political rights whatsoever.
was intended to be the effective governing body of the state, only
referring major and controversial issues to the people. In course of
time however the practice changed. Although in the 5th century
many important decrees were drafted in detail in the council and
passed with minor modifications by the people many of the later
motions were proposed by the people in the assembly and vital
decisions were left entirely to the assembly. The general conclusion
that emerges from the inscriptions is that the council was not a
policy making body. On uncontroversial matters it drafted decrees
sometimes leaving minor difficulties to be settles by the people but
on any major issue it merely put the question on the agenda of the
assembly. In sum the control of the council over the assembly
amounted to very little. It was probably the intention of the
Athenians that the council, consisting of mature men and in theory
at least of some substance, should act as some check on possible
irresponsible conduct by the assembly. It was their duty to refuse to
put to vote illegal proposals and they saw to it that no motion was
proposed without due notice and publicity. But policy was clearly
decided in the assembly and not in the council.
8
M.I. Finley, Ancient Slavery, Modern Ideology, p.112
9
G.E.M Coix, Class Struggles in the Ancient World, p.146
state first to create slaves and then to keep them where they were:
as laboring masses denied of any rights whatsoever.
________________________________________________________