CFC Rules PDF
CFC Rules PDF
BEPS ACTION 3:
STRENGTHENING
CFC RULES
12 May 2015
WORK IN RELATION TO CONTROLLED FOREIGN COMPANY RULES
In July 2013, the Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting [1] directed the OECD to commence
work on 15 actions designed to ensure the coherence of corporate income taxation at the international
level.
Action 3 of this plan stresses the need to address base erosion and profit shifting using controlled
foreign company (CFC) rules. Many countries already have CFC rules, but these rules do not always
counter BEPS in a comprehensive manner. While CFC rules in principle lead to inclusions in the residence
country of the ultimate parent, they also have positive spillover effects in source countries because
taxpayers have no (or much less of an) incentive to shift profits into a third, low-tax jurisdiction.
Working Party No. 11 (WP11) has considered many options for the design of CFC rules that would
prevent base erosion and profit shifting. This discussion draft considers all the constituent elements of CFC
rules and breaks them down into the “building blocks” that are necessary for effective CFC rules. Most of
these building blocks include draft recommendations. The exception to this is Chapter 5, which deals with
the definition of CFC income and which does not include recommendations but instead discusses several
possible options. The building blocks include:
• Definition of a CFC
• Threshold requirements
• Definition of control
• Definition of CFC income
• Rules for computing income
• Rules for attributing income
• Rules to prevent or eliminate double taxation
The Committee on Fiscal Affairs (CFA) invites interested parties to send written comments on this
consultation document. Comments should be sent by email to [email protected] by no later than 1 May
2015. Please note that all comments received regarding this consultation draft will be made publicly
available. Comments submitted in the name of a collective “grouping” or “coalition”, or by any person
submitting comments on behalf of another person or group of persons, should identify all enterprises or
individuals who are members of that collective, or the person(s) on whose behalf the commentator(s) are
acting.
Persons and organisations who submit comments on this consultation document are invited to indicate
whether they wish to speak in support of their comments at a public consultation meeting on action 3 that
is scheduled to be held in Paris at the OECD Conference Centre on 12 May 2015. Persons selected as
speakers will be informed by email.
This consultation meeting will be open to the public and the press. Persons wishing to attend this
public consultation meeting will be able to register on line. Due to space limitations, priority will be given
to persons and organisations who register first and we reserve the right to limit the number of participants
from the same organisations.
This meeting will also be broadcast live on the internet and can be accessed on line. No advance
registration will be required for this internet access.
[1]
OECD (2013), Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting, OECD Publishing, available at
http://www.oecd.org/ctp/BEPSActionPlan.pdf
2
This document does not necessarily reflect consensus views of either the Committee of Fiscal Affairs
(CFA) or of WP11 regarding the issues it addresses. Rather it reflects preliminary consideration of the
issues since the publication of the Action Plan and seeks to identify issues for public comment. It is
considered that stakeholder comments are essential to advancing this work. Specific issues on which
comments would be appreciated are identified throughout the document as “Questions for Consultation”
and are summarised at the end of the document.
Some countries have proposed that in addition to CFC rules (which for the purposes of the proposal is
described as the “primary rule”), countries could introduce further rules (the “secondary rule”) that applied
to income earned by CFC s that did not give rise to sufficient CFC taxation in the parent jurisdiction. Such
secondary rules would introduce a secondary form of taxation in another jurisdiction (for example the
source country of the income earned by the CFC).
Working Party 6 is currently considering several options for special measures in the area of transfer
pricing as part of Action Items 8-10, which could be implemented as possible secondary rules. Possible
future work on the options to address the tax challenges of the digital economy could also be adapted to be
applied as secondary rules. There is a question as to whether any of these options might form the basis for
a secondary rule.
The CFA has not yet considered whether this high level proposal should be taken forward.
3
TABLE OF CONTENTS
4
II. Explanation ..................................................................................................................................58
A. Which taxpayers should income be attributed to? ...................................................................58
B. How much income should be attributed? ................................................................................59
C. When should the income be included in tax returns? ..............................................................59
D. How should the income be treated? ........................................................................................60
E. What tax rate should apply to CFC income? ...........................................................................60
CHAPTER 8: RULES TO PREVENT OR ELIMINATE DOUBLE TAXATION .....................................61
I. Recommendations........................................................................................................................61
II. Explanation ..................................................................................................................................61
A. Issues with respect to relief for foreign corporate taxes...........................................................61
B. Issues with respect to relief for CFC taxation in multiple jurisdictions ...................................62
C. Relief for subsequent dividends and capital gains ...................................................................63
ANNEX I – DE MINIMIS THRESHOLDS ...............................................................................................65
ANNEX II - LOW TAXATION THRESHOLDS ......................................................................................66
ANNEX III - DEFINITIONS OF INSURANCE INCOME .......................................................................68
ANNEX IV - QUESTIONS FOR CONSULTATION ................................................................................69
5
INTRODUCTION
1. Action Item 3 of the BEPS Action Plan recognises that groups can create low-taxed non-resident
affiliates to which they shift income and that these affiliates may be established in low-tax countries
wholly or partly for tax reasons rather than for non-tax business reasons. 1 Controlled foreign company
(“CFC”) rules combat this by enabling jurisdictions to tax income earned by foreign subsidiaries where
certain conditions are met. However, some countries do not currently have CFC rules and others have rules
that do not always counter BEPS situations in a comprehensive manner. Action Item 3 mandates Working
Party 11 (WP 11) to “develop recommendations regarding the design of controlled foreign company rules”.
The objective is to develop recommendations for CFC rules that are effective in dealing with base erosion
and profit shifting.
2. CFC rules have existed in the international tax context for over five decades, and dozens of
countries have implemented these rules. This discussion draft considers all the constituent elements of CFC
rules and breaks them down into the “building blocks” that are necessary for effective CFC rules. These
building blocks would allow countries without CFC rules to implement recommended rules directly and
countries with existing CFC rules to modify their rules to align more closely with the recommendations,
and they include:
I. Definition of a CFC
II. Threshold requirements
III. Definition of control
IV. Definition of CFC income
V. Rules for computing income
VI. Rules for attributing income
VII. Rules to prevent or eliminate double taxation
3. Before discussing these seven building blocks, this discussion draft first addresses the policy
considerations to be considered in the context of Action Item 3. These include some fundamental policy
considerations that need to be considered when designing CFC rules such as how to strike a balance
between the need to tax foreign income and the need to maintain competitiveness, how to limit
administrative and compliance burdens while ensuring that CFC rules are effective, and the avoidance of
double taxation. It also considers the role of CFC rules; that is their role as preventative measures, the
scope of base stripping prevented by CFC rules, and the interaction between transfer pricing rules and CFC
rules. These are all briefly considered in Chapter 1. The following chapters then set out the building
blocks. There are also three annexes with tables outlining how existing CFC rules currently address several
of the issues addressed in this discussion draft, including how countries de minimis and low-tax thresholds
work, and how they define attributable income from insurance.
1
Non-tax business reasons could include, for example, the availability of employees, increased resources, or
a more favourable legal environment. CFC rules are not by definition limited to situations where CFCs are
controlled by companies, and jurisdictions may also design CFC rules to apply in situations where
individuals control foreign entities.
6
4. The recommendations discussed in this discussion draft are designed to combat base erosion and
profit shifting. It is recognised that some countries design their CFC rules to achieve wider policy
objectives. Jurisdictions can choose to adopt CFC rules that apply more broadly than the recommendations
as long as these are consistent with other international legal obligations. However, such wider aims are not
within the scope of the BEPS Action Plan for CFCs.
5. The work on CFCs is being co-ordinated with the work on other Action Items. The Action Items
that are most closely associated with CFC rules include Action Item 1 (addressing the tax challenges of the
digital economy – this co-ordination involves working closely with the Task Force on the Digital Economy
Liaison Group.), Action Item 2 (hybrid mismatch arrangements), Action Item 4 (interest deductions),
Action Item 5 (countering harmful tax practices), Action Items 8-10 (transfer pricing), 2 Action Item 11
(methodologies to collect and analyse data), Action Item 14 (dispute resolution mechanisms), and Action
Item 15 (developing a multilateral instrument).
2
The interaction between CFC rules and the outcomes under Action Items 8-10, as well as transfer pricing
rules more generally, will be addressed at the end of the process.
7
CHAPTER 1: POLICY CONSIDERATIONS
6. The design of CFC rules intended to combat base erosion and profit shifting raises a number of
policy considerations: (i) the purpose of CFC rules, (ii) how to strike a balance between taxing foreign
income and maintaining competitiveness, (iii) how to limit administrative and compliance burdens while
not creating opportunities for avoidance, (iv) the role of CFC rules as preventative measures, (v) the scope
of base stripping prevented by CFC rules, (vi) how to ensure that CFC rules do not lead to double taxation,
and (vii) the interaction between CFC rules and transfer pricing rules. These policy issues must be
considered in order to develop recommendations for CFC rules.
7. CFC rules tax the income of controlled foreign subsidiaries in the hands of resident shareholders.
For most countries, they are used to prevent shifting of income either from the parent jurisdiction or from
the parent and other tax jurisdictions. Some countries which give more importance to the principle of
territoriality do not currently apply CFC rules. For those countries CFC rules would have to be limited to
targeting profit shifting. However, where countries have worldwide tax systems, they may also be
concerned about long-term deferral and therefore their rules may have broader policy objectives (for
example, preventing long-term base erosion rather than only preventing profit shifting).
II. Striking a balance between taxing foreign income and maintaining competitiveness
8. In designing CFC rules, a balance must be struck between taxing foreign income and the
competitiveness concerns inherent in rules that tax the income of foreign subsidiaries. CFC rules raise two
primary types of competitiveness concerns. First, jurisdictions with CFC rules that apply broadly may find
themselves at a competitive disadvantage relative to jurisdictions without CFC rules (or with narrower
CFC rules) because foreign subsidiaries owned by resident companies will be taxed more heavily than
locally owned companies in the foreign jurisdiction. This competitive disadvantage may in turn lead to
distortions, for instance it may impact on where groups choose to locate their head office or increase the
risk of inversions, and it may also impact on ownership or capital structures where groups attempt to avoid
the impact of CFC rules. 3 CFC rules can therefore run the risk of restricting or distorting real economic
activity. Second, multinational enterprises resident in countries with robust CFC rules may find themselves
at a competitive disadvantage relative to multinational enterprises resident in countries without such rules
(or with CFC rules that apply to a significantly lower rate or narrower base). This competitiveness concern
arises because the foreign subsidiaries of the first MNEs will be subject to a higher effective tax rate on the
income of those subsidiaries than the foreign subsidiaries of the second MNEs due to the application of
CFC rules, even when both subsidiaries are operating in the same country.
3
There is a perception that robust CFC rules can lead to inversions, that is, that groups will change the
residence of the parent company to escape the effect of CFC rules. However, whilst it is likely that CFC
rules will increase the risk of inversions, they will not be the only factor and other issues such as tax rate
and the general system of taxation (e.g., worldwide or territorial) will also play a role. For this reason
inversions, and the rules that some countries have adopted to combat them, are not covered in this
discussion draft, but countries may want to consider them as a separate matter.
8
9. The balance between taxing foreign income and maintaining competitiveness is often discussed
in the tax policy literature by referring to the impossibility of achieving both capital export neutrality
(CEN) and capital import neutrality (CIN) in the absence of harmonised tax rates. CEN, under which taxes
do not distort a domestic taxpayer’s decision to invest capital domestically or internationally, requires
taxing foreign income at the same rate as domestically earned income. CIN, under which taxes do not
favour domestic over foreign investments of capital, requires that income earned from investments in a
particular country is taxed at the same rate regardless of the investor’s residence.
10. To address these concerns, CFC rules typically exempt so-called “active” income that is, or is
more likely to be, linked to real economic activity in the foreign subsidiary and has not been, or is less
likely to have been, shifted from the parent company. This approach may not be entirely effective in
combatting BEPS, but, in developing recommendations for the design of CFC rules, the balance between
taxing foreign income and maintaining competitiveness needs to be kept in mind. Another way to maintain
competitiveness would be to ensure that more countries implement similar CFC rules. This is therefore a
space where countries working collectively and adopting similar rules could reduce the competitiveness
concerns that individual countries may have when considering whether to implement CFC rules. This
discussion suggests that competitiveness concerns could be reduced either by designing the output under
Action Item 3 as a minimum standard or combining this output with a secondary rule.
11. A particular competitiveness concern may arise in the context of the European Union. Since
2006,4 it is generally acknowledged that the European Court of Justice’s case law imposes limitations on
CFC rules that apply within the EU. Therefore, whilst recommendations developed under this Action Item
need to be broad enough to be effective in combatting BEPS they also need to be adaptable, where
necessary, to enable EU members to comply with EU law. This policy consideration affects all
jurisdictions, including those that are not Member States of the EU, because recommendations that are
inconsistent with EU law would mean that Member States could not adopt those recommendations to apply
within the European Union. This in turn would mean that multinational groups that are based in
jurisdictions that are not EU Member States could be at a competitive disadvantage compared to
multinational groups that are based in Member States since the latter groups would not be subject to
equally robust CFC rules.
12. In Cadbury Schweppes5 and subsequent cases, the European Court of Justice has stated that CFC
rules and other tax provisions that apply to cross-border transactions and that are justified by the
prevention of tax avoidance must “specifically target wholly artificial arrangements which do not reflect
4
In 2006, the European Court of Justice issued its opinion in Cadbury Schweppes plc and Cadbury
Schweppes Overseas Ltd v. Commissioners of Inland Revenue, C-196/04. This case considered the
compatibility of Member State CFC rules with the EU treaty freedoms.
5
Cadbury Schweppes plc and Cadbury Schweppes Overseas Ltd v. Commissioners of Inland Revenue, C-
196/04. More recent cases have echoed the decision in Cadbury Schweppes. In Itelcar – Automóveis de
Aluguer Lda. v. Fazenda Pública, Case C-282/12 (3 October 2013), the ECJ made it clear that a national
measure restricting the fundamental EU freedoms may be justified where it specifically targets wholly
artificial arrangements which do not reflect economic reality and the sole purpose of which is to avoid the
tax normally payable on the profits generated by activities carried out on the national territory. In Itelcar
the ECJ went on to say that it is apparent from the case-law of the Court that, where rules are predicated on
an assessment of objective and verifiable elements for the purposes of determining whether a transaction
represents a wholly artificial arrangement entered into for tax reasons alone, they may be regarded as not
going beyond what is necessary to prevent tax evasion and avoidance, if, on each occasion on which the
existence of such an arrangement cannot be ruled out, those rules give the taxpayer an opportunity, without
subjecting him to undue administrative constraints, to provide evidence of any commercial justification
that there may have been for that transaction.
9
economic reality and whose only purpose would be to obtain a tax advantage”.6 The ECJ’s jurisprudence
applies to all Member States of the EU and the EEA, 7 and it applies when the parent jurisdiction and the
CFC jurisdiction are both within the EEA.
13. The purpose of this discussion draft is to set out recommendations for effective CFC rules that
can be implemented in all jurisdictions. These recommendations will ideally be the same for EU Member
States and non-EU Member States, but this discussion draft acknowledges that, depending on the agreed
recommendations, EU Member States may need to modify these recommendations to comply with EU
law. 8 Modifications to comply with EU law should only change how CFC rules that apply to other Member
States are implemented by Member States of the EU, and they should not change whether they comply
with the recommendations outlined in the discussion draft.
14. Although the determination of how to comply with EU treaty freedoms is the decision of each
individual EU Member State, in designing CFC rules, EU Member States could potentially consider the
following when implementing adaptable and durable CFC rules:
• Including a substance analysis that would only subject taxpayers to CFC rules if the CFCs did not
engage in genuine economic activities. Some Member States have already modified their CFC
rules so that they do not apply to genuine economic activities and are therefore consistent with
their understanding of the ECJ’s “wholly artificial arrangements” limitation.
• Applying CFC rules equally to both domestic subsidiaries and cross-border subsidiaries. A CFC
rule will only be found inconsistent with the freedom of establishment if the rule itself
discriminates against non-residents. This was made clear in Cadbury Schweppes, where the ECJ
focused on the difference in treatment under UK CFC rules between a UK controlled company
and a non-resident controlled company. The Court explained this focus by stating:
“That difference in treatment creates a tax disadvantage for the resident company
to which the legislation on CFCs is applicable. Even taking into account […] the
fact referred to by the national court that such a resident company does not pay, on
the profits of a CFC within the scope of application of that legislation, more tax
than that which would have been payable on those profits if they had been made by
a subsidiary established in the United Kingdom, the fact remains that under such
legislation the resident company is taxed on profits of another legal person. That is
not the case for a resident company with a subsidiary taxed in the United Kingdom
or a subsidiary established outside that Member State which is not subject to a
lower level of taxation”.9
Therefore, if a CFC rule treats domestic subsidiaries the same as cross-border subsidiaries, it
arguably should not be treated as discriminatory under the case law of the ECJ, and no
6
Haribo Lakritzen Hans Riegel BetriebsgmbH and Österreichische Salinen AG v. Finanzamt Linz, Joined
Cases C‑436/08 and C‑437/08, paragraph 165.
7
The ECJ’s jurisprudence applies to countries that are not Member States of the European Union to the
extent that it interprets the fundamental freedoms protected by the Agreement on the European Economic
Area.
8
Countries that are not Member States of the European Union could also implement the modifications
adopted by EU Member States.
9
Cadbury Schweppes, paragraph 45.
10
justification is needed. Such an approach would attribute the allocable income of any controlled
company – whether foreign or domestic – to its resident shareholders. 10
• Applying CFC rules to transactions that are “partly wholly artificial”. Even if a direct tax rule in a
EU Member State is found to implicate the freedom of establishment and to discriminate, it may
still be upheld if it is justified and proportionate. Although earlier CFC cases found CFC rules in
EU Member States to be justified and proportionate only if they were limited to wholly artificial
arrangements, two more recent developments in the ECJ’s analysis suggest that CFC rules may
now be justified and proportionate even if they apply beyond wholly artificial arrangements. The
first development is that cases have suggested that rules may be justified by the need to prevent
tax avoidance if they are targeted at arrangements that are not wholly artificial. In Thin Cap
Group Litigation, for example, the ECJ stated that, in determining whether thin cap legislation
was justified by the need to prevent abusive practices, the Court should determine “whether the
transaction in question represents, in whole or in part, a purely artificial arrangement, the
essential purpose of which is to circumvent the tax legislation of that Member State”.11 This
wording suggests that a CFC rule in a EU Member State that targets income earned by a CFC that
is not itself wholly artificial may be justified so long as the transaction giving rise to the income
is at least partly artificial.
• Designing CFC rules to explicitly ensure a balanced allocation of taxing power. The ECJ has
suggested that Member State tax provisions may not be restricted to wholly artificial
arrangements if they are justified by a reason other than the need to prevent tax avoidance. In
both SGI 12 and Oy AA, 13 for example, the ECJ stated that the rules in question could be justified
notwithstanding the fact that they were not restricted to wholly artificial arrangements because
they were justified by the need to maintain a balanced allocation of taxing rights. In SGI, the ECJ
clarified that this “justification may be accepted, in particular, where the system in question is
designed to prevent conduct capable of jeopardising the right of a Member State to exercise its
tax jurisdiction in relation to activities carried out in its territory”. 14 Although the Court has not
yet found that CFC rules are justified by the need to maintain a balanced allocation of taxing
rights, these cases suggest that CFC rules could be permitted to apply more broadly if they could
be explained by the need for a Member State to tax profits arising from activities carried out in its
territory.
III. Limiting administrative and compliance burdens while not creating opportunities for
avoidance
15. A third policy consideration is how to achieve effective rules that do not unduly increase
compliance costs and administrative burdens. Although one of the benefits of CFC rules can be their
10
At least one jurisdiction already applies such an approach. Denmark’s legislation has the effect that there is
no different treatment, no matter whether the parent company owns a subsidiary resident in Denmark, a
foreign subsidiary resident in the EU/EEA or a foreign subsidiary resident outside the EU/EEA.
11
Test Claimants in the Thin Cap Group Litigation v. Commissioners of Inland Revenue, C-524/04,
paragraph 81 (emphasis added).
12
Société de Gestion Industrielle (SGI) v. Belgian State, C-311/08 (21 January 2010) (holding that the
freedom of establishment did not prevent Member States from requiring profit adjustments in the case of
non-arm’s length transactions involving non-resident parties).
13
Oy AA, C-231/05 (18 July 2007) (holding that the freedom of establishment did not prevent Member
States from limiting interest deductions for intra-group transfers to payments made to resident companies).
14
SGI, paragraph 60.
11
relatively mechanical application, CFC rules that are entirely mechanical may not be as effective as rules
that allow more flexibility, and they may not be compatible with EU law for the reasons set out above.
However, flexibility can also create uncertainty, which may impact both on the costs of applying and
complying with CFC rules. CFC rules must strike a balance between the reduced complexity inherent in
mechanical rules and the effectiveness of more subjective rules. This policy consideration is reflected most
clearly in rules on defining income. In that context, although an approach that attributes income based
purely on its formal classification may reduce administrative and compliance burdens, such an approach
may be less effective, and countries with existing CFC rules have generally opted to combine this approach
with less mechanical substance analyses to ensure that the income that is attributed in fact arises from base
erosion and profit shifting. Concerns about the administrative burden of substance-based rules can,
however, be reduced by including suitably targeted entity-level exemptions.
16. CFC rules are designed to act as a deterrent. In other words, CFC rules are not designed to raise
significant revenue in the form of additional corporate taxation. Instead, they are designed to prevent
taxpayers from shifting income into CFCs in the first place, and they therefore protect revenue by
preventing tax avoidance rather than subjecting parent companies to tax on their CFCs. CFC rules will, of
course, raise some revenue by taxing the income of CFCs, but there is likely to be a reduction in the
income shifted to CFCs after the implementation of CFC rules.
17. Because CFC rules are designed to change taxpayer behaviour, they may not have the effect that
their design suggests. For example, the design of CFC rules suggests that they grant secondary taxing
rights to the residence jurisdiction. In reality, however, if CFC rules effectively tax profits at a sufficiently
high rate, they may also increase taxing opportunities in source jurisdictions by reducing or eliminating the
tax incentives for MNEs to shift income into subsidiaries in low-tax jurisdictions.
18. CFC rules are intended to prevent group companies from shifting income to CFCs, but this does
not necessarily mean that CFC rules only protect the base of the parent jurisdiction. Some existing CFC
rules do focus only on protecting the parent jurisdiction’s base, but others protect against both stripping of
the parent jurisdiction’s base and stripping of third countries’ bases (or “foreign-to-foreign stripping”).
Rules that focus on stripping of the parent jurisdiction define CFC income to include only that income that
has been diverted or shifted from the parent jurisdiction, 15 while those that focus on foreign-to-foreign
stripping include any income that could have been earned in any jurisdiction other than the CFC
jurisdiction.
19. Foreign-to-foreign stripping may raise different concerns from stripping of the parent jurisdiction
as third countries may have tax rates that are still lower than the parent jurisdiction. Despite this possible
difference, however, CFC rules that focus only on parent jurisdiction stripping may not be as effective
against BEPS arrangements for two reasons. First, it may not be possible to determine which country’s
base has been stripped (for example, in the case of stateless income). Second, even if it were possible to
15
Another way to narrow the focus of CFC rules, with the result that they do not prevent foreign-to-foreign
stripping, is to implement rules that allow companies to elect whether their subsidiaries are treated as
partnerships or corporations. The rules discussed in Chapter 2, however, are designed to eliminate the
effect of such an election for CFC rules and may therefore reduce the availability of this option.
12
determine which country’s base was stripped, the BEPS Action Plan aims to prevent erosion of all tax
bases, including those of third countries. This issue is of particular relevance for developing countries. 16
20. An additional consideration is how to avoid double taxation. Since CFC rules subject the income
of a foreign subsidiary to taxation in the parent jurisdiction, they can lead to double taxation if the
subsidiary is also subject to taxation in the CFC jurisdiction. Double taxation concerns can be limited by
incorporating low-tax thresholds, which are discussed in the next section, into CFC rules. Existing CFC
rules also seek to prevent double taxation through provisions such as foreign tax credits. These provisions
are outlined in the discussion of the seventh building block in Chapter 8.
21. Transfer pricing rules are intended to adjust the taxable profits of associated enterprises to
eliminate distortions arising whenever the prices or other conditions of transactions between those
enterprises differ from what they would have been if the enterprises had been unrelated. If transfer pricing
rules were to fully achieve this objective, they would restore the taxing rights of all jurisdictions involved.
As with CFC rules, transfer pricing rules often achieve this objective by deterring business from entering
into certain arrangements. Because controlled foreign company rules by definition address related parties
(as the companies that are captured by such rules are controlled by another party), jurisdictions often also
use these rules to combat the adjusted prices charged between related parties. In other words, CFC rules are
seen as a way for a parent jurisdiction to capture income earned by a foreign subsidiary that may not have
been earned had the original pricing of the income-creating asset been set correctly. CFC rules are thus
often referred to as “backstops” to transfer pricing rules. 17 That terminology, however, is misleading, in
that CFC rules generally do not complement transfer pricing rules in a coherent manner. Instead, CFC
regimes applying a sufficiently high rate of tax may make certain transfer pricing outcomes irrelevant to
the MNE by removing the benefit of engaging in transfer pricing manipulation. It is generally therefore not
that the principle of CFC rules is to capture income from transfer pricing manipulation but that certain
CFC provisions may sometimes have this effect.
22. CFC rules may target the same income as transfer pricing rules in some situations, but it is
unlikely that either CFC rules or transfer pricing rules in practice eliminate the need for the other set of
rules. Instead, while CFC rules may capture some income that is not captured by transfer pricing rules (and
vice versa), neither set of rules fully captures the income that the other set of rules intends to capture for a
number of reasons.
23. Firstly, the type of CFC rule that would most effectively replace transfer pricing rules for
transactions within the same control group would be a full-inclusion system. Given a sufficiently high tax
rate, such a system, where there is no exemption for income arising from economic activity undertaken by
the CFC (and all income is therefore included as attributable CFC income), provides the most complete
example of the backstop effect because it removes the benefit to related parties of engaging in transfer
pricing manipulation. 18 In fact, full inclusion removes the benefit associated with any type of intragroup
16
For more on the effect of Action Item 3 and the other action items on developing countries, see the BEPS
Action Plan and the BEPS Report, both of which refer to the knock-on effect of CFC rules on source
countries.
17
See, e.g., J. Clifton Fleming, Jr., Robert J. Peroni and Stephen E. Shay, Worse than Exemption, 59 Emory
L.J. 79 (2009).
18
See Mitchell A. Kane, Milking versus Parking: Transfer Pricing and CFC Rules under the Internal Revenue
Code, 66 Tax Law Review (2013).
13
arbitrage because all income from such transactions will be taxed at the parent company level under a full-
inclusion system. Partial-inclusion systems, particularly those that focus on formal classification of
income, often only capture transfer pricing schemes haphazardly, since the determination of which income
is attributed for CFC purposes does not align with the determination of what prices should be charged. 19
24. Secondly, to the extent that CFC rules do not fully deter BEPS, they only restore (or transfer)
taxing rights to parent jurisdictions, which are not necessarily the jurisdictions which have suffered the
profit shifting.
25. Thirdly, if the tax rate of the parent state is lower than the tax rate applicable to some of the
subsidiaries, it will still be advantageous to the MNE to shift profits away from those higher-tax
subsidiaries.
26. Fourthly, businesses can avoid the effect of CFC rules by restructuring under companies resident
in jurisdictions without CFC rules or with low tax rates while still accessing the same capital markets.
Transfer pricing rules, in contrast, can be applied by all countries where economic activity takes place to
protect their own tax bases.
27. Finally, even a full-inclusion system would not necessarily capture transfer pricing or arbitrage
transactions between related parties that are not in the same control group. Therefore, the fact that CFC
rules are limited to parents and their controlled subsidiaries rather than sibling enterprises or other related
parties that do not have control over each other means that, even if jurisdictions were to shift to full-
inclusion systems, there would still be a need for transfer pricing rules to capture transactions beyond the
narrow parent-subsidiary context. In other words, transfer pricing rules are necessary because there are
some companies (e.g., those that are not controlled by taxpayers in the jurisdiction implementing CFC
rules) that would not be subject to CFC rules because of the scope of such rules.
28. In addition, transfer pricing rules alone will not capture all the income that would be targeted by
CFC rules. Whilst both transfer pricing rules and CFC rules can be regarded as preventing the erosion of
domestic tax bases, transfer pricing rules do so by focusing on individual transactions between related
parties, while CFC rules do so by focusing on profit earned by a controlled party from transactions with a
variety of counterparties. The overlap between these two rules is thus not exact, and not all profit earned by
foreign subsidiaries that would be captured by CFC rules would be captured by transfer pricing rules. Also,
while transfer pricing rules intend to align primary taxing rights with value creation, they are not designed
to address the challenges raised by profit shifting to low-tax jurisdictions or stateless income. Effective
CFC rules would, however, deter taxpayers from shifting profits into foreign subsidiaries in
low-tax jurisdictions or jurisdictions that do not recognise the subsidiary for tax purposes, and they would
therefore ultimately complement transfer pricing rules as a backstop. A further reason to have both CFC
rules and transfer pricing rules is that this combination provides tax administrations with two different
enforcement tools to combat BEPS. Finally, CFC rules are designed to be deterrent measures, which means
that they may have the effect of eliminating structures and transactions entirely. The reasons above
highlight why both transfer pricing rules and CFC rules may be necessary.
19
See id.
14
CHAPTER 2: DEFINITION OF A CFC
29. The first step in establishing whether CFC rules apply to a foreign subsidiary requires
consideration of whether that subsidiary is itself a CFC. The first three building blocks address this
question: this building block addresses whether an entity is of the type that would be considered a CFC, the
next building block (discussed in Chapter 3) addresses whether the entity was subject to a sufficiently high
level of tax to escape CFC taxation, and the third building block (discussed in Chapter 4) addresses
whether the parent company has sufficient influence over the foreign entity for the foreign entity to be a
CFC.
I. Recommendations
30. The recommendation is to broadly define entities that are within scope so that in addition to
including corporate entities CFC rules would also apply to partnerships, trusts, and permanent
establishments (PEs) when those entities are either owned by CFCs or treated in the parent jurisdiction as
taxable entities separate from their owners.
31. A further recommendation is to include a modified hybrid mismatch rule that would prevent
entities from circumventing CFC rules by being treated differently in different jurisdictions.
II. Explanation
32. Although CFC rules would appear based on their name only to apply to corporate entities, most
countries have a broad definition of which entities can be considered CFCs. Many include trusts,
partnerships and PEs to ensure that companies in the parent jurisdiction cannot circumvent CFC rules just
by changing the legal form of their subsidiaries, but these entities are only treated as CFCs in limited
circumstances.
33. Many transparent entities such as partnerships should not be treated as CFCs to the extent that
their income is already taxed in the parent jurisdiction on a current basis. However, CFC rules will apply to
transparent entities in two cases. The first case arises when entities that are not taxable in one jurisdiction
are subject to taxation in the parent jurisdiction. This would, for example, lead to partnerships being treated
as CFCs if they are taxable entities under the laws of the parent jurisdiction. The second case arises when
entities that would not otherwise be taxable are owned by another CFC. Since the CFC itself raises the
possibility of deferral, and since an entity owned by this CFC may allow for the blending of low and high
tax rates that could in turn lead to the avoidance of CFC rules, entities owned by a CFC should also be
taken into account, both for calculating income and for determining whether the CFC is subject to low
taxation. 20
20
The question of blending tax rates is relevant to the low-tax threshold discussion in Chapter 3.
15
34. Permanent establishments should be taken into account for CFC rules in cases where the
residence jurisdiction of the company of which the PE is a part applies the exemption method to the
income of the PE. 21
35. A further issue that arises in determining which entities could be CFCs is how to treat hybrid tax
planning. Differences in the way the parent and CFC jurisdiction characterise instruments and entities can
result in payments that might otherwise be attributed under CFC rules being ignored or treated as being
outside the scope of CFC rules. For example, entity classification rules in the parent jurisdiction can allow
the payer and payee in a multinational group to be treated as the same entity for CFC purposes so that a
deductible intra-group payment between these entities is not taken into account under the parent’s CFC
rules. These rules ultimately exclude income that would otherwise be attributable as CFC income and they
have this effect because they do not recognise certain entities. To the extent that the payment is deductible
in the payer’s jurisdiction this implicates foreign to foreign base erosion issues.
36. One way to tackle this issue could be to consider a modified hybrid mismatch rule that requires
an intragroup payment to a CFC to be taken into account in calculating the parent company’s CFC
income. 22 This solution could apply either broadly or narrowly. Under the narrow option, an intragroup
payment would be taken into account if:
• the payment is base eroding (e.g. deductible in one jurisdiction and subject to a nil or low rate of
taxation in the jurisdiction of receipt);
• the payment would have been included in CFC income if the parent jurisdiction had classified the
entities and arrangements in the same way as the payer or payee jurisdiction.
37. Such an approach focuses on base eroding payments that exploit conflicts in the classification of
instruments and entities in order to produce mismatches in tax outcomes under the CFC rules of the parent
jurisdiction. Under the broad option, in contrast, an intragroup payment would be taken into account if:
• the payment would have been included in CFC income if the parent jurisdiction had classified the
entities and arrangements in the same way as the payer or payee jurisdiction.
38. Such an approach may be more consistent with existing CFC rules since CFC rules typically do
not require a payment to be base eroding in order to take account of the payment in calculating the parent
company’s CFC income. In theory this could potentially subject more income to CFC taxation than is
necessary to combat BEPS. However, this may not be the case as the income would ultimately only be
attributable if all the other requirements of CFC rules were met. The broad option also re-establishes the
coherence of CFC rules since it allows any income that would be subject to CFC rules to be taken into
account by those rules, rather than only allowing a narrow category of that income to be taken into
account.
21
The same applies for countries operating a territorial system where income from foreign PEs of domestic
companies is not included in the tax base.
22
This is not the only way to tackle this issue. A jurisdiction that implements an excess profits approach
similar to that described in Chapter 5, for example, may not need an additional rule to address these types
of hybrid mismatches if such an approach does not ignore the income earned in situations such as those
illustrated in Figure 1.
16
39. The example below explains how both rules might operate. In the structure illustrated below, A
Co, a company resident in Country A, holds all the shares of B Co, a company resident in Country B. B
Co, in turn, holds all the shares in C Co, a company resident in Country C. Country A and Country C are
high tax jurisdictions while Country B is a low tax jurisdiction. C Co is a disregarded entity for Country A
tax purposes. C Co borrows money from B Co, and because C Co is treated as transparent under the laws
of Country A, the payment of interest to B Co is ignored under the laws of Country A and therefore not
included within the calculation of CFC income for Country A purposes. Note that this example would not
currently be caught by the rules designed under Action Item 2 since this payment does not create a hybrid
mismatch under the rules of either Country B or Country C, which are the resident jurisdictions of the
counterparties. Instead, it only creates a hybrid mismatch for purposes of Country A, which is the country
that treats C Co as transparent.
Figure 1. Modified hybrid mismatch rule
High tax A Co
Country A
Country B
+
Low tax B Co
Interest
Loan
41. While the example illustrated above involves a conflict in entity classification, a similar result
can be achieved using a loan that is treated as equity for Country A purposes (so that the interest payment
is characterised under Country A’s CFC rules as an exempt dividend). The effect can also be achieved by
exploiting differences in the treatment of residence for tax purposes. For example, Country A, applying its
own rules on tax residency, could treat B Co as tax resident in Country C so that the interest payment is
ignored under a same country exception, 23 under which Country A’s CFC rules do not include income in
CFC income if it was received from taxpayers resident in the CFC jurisdiction. As these arrangements all
rely on a conflict in the characterisation of the entity or instrument they would also be caught under both
approaches outlined above.
23
Several countries including the US have exceptions in their CFC rules for payments made between
companies in the same country.
17
Questions for consultation
1. Would any particular practical issues arise from treating transparent entities as separate entities in the
cases listed above? If so, what are they and how could they be dealt with?
2. Should the recommendations consider any other issues related to determining which entities could be
considered to be CFCs?
3. Are there any practical problems with either the narrow or the broad version of the modified hybrid mismatch
rule mentioned above?
18
CHAPTER 3: THRESHOLD REQUIREMENTS
42. Threshold requirements can be used to limit the scope of CFC rules by excluding companies that
are likely to pose little risk of base erosion and profit shifting and instead focusing attention on cases that
are higher-risk because they exhibit some characteristic or behaviour that means there is a greater chance
of profit shifting. Thresholds can therefore both help make CFC rules more targeted and effective and also
reduce the overall level of administrative burden by ensuring that certain companies are not affected by the
rules, although these companies may still need to satisfy certain reporting requirements to show that they
fall below any threshold requirements.
I. Recommendations
43. The recommendation is to include a low-tax threshold where the tax rate calculation is based on
the effective tax rate. The low-tax threshold should also use a tax rate that is meaningfully lower than the
tax rate in the country applying the CFC rules.
II. Explanation
44. Three different types of threshold requirements were considered by the countries involved in this
work:
(i) a set de minimis amount below which the CFC rules would not apply,
(ii) an anti-avoidance requirement which would focus CFC rules on situations where there
was a tax avoidance motive or purpose, and
(iii) a low-tax threshold where CFC rules would only apply to CFCs resident in countries with a
lower tax rate than the parent company.
A. De minimis threshold
45. A de minimis threshold could reduce administrative burdens and make CFC rules more targeted
and effective by ensuring that certain companies are not subject to the rules. 24 Many countries’ rules
already include a de minimis threshold under which income that would otherwise be treated as CFC
income is not included in the taxable income of the parent company if it falls under a certain
ceiling. Generally, countries provide an entity-based exemption where the entity’s attributable income is
less than either a certain percentage of the CFC’s income or a fixed amount of the CFC’s income or where
the taxable profits are less than a fixed amount. Some rules also include a separate cap for certain types of
profits that present a higher risk of being diverted. The UK rules, for example, use two different thresholds.
They either set a relatively low threshold regardless of the type of income or they set a much higher
threshold that applies if non-trading profits (which are generally easier to divert) do not exceed the lower
number. In other words, a much higher de minimis threshold applies to CFCs if they can show that they do
not earn much income that is likely to be highly mobile.
24
A de minimis threshold could also eliminate the need for a special rule for exempting working capital
under a transactional approach. See infra Chapter 5.
19
46. One possible way that de minimis thresholds can be circumvented is through fragmentation,
under which companies split their income amongst multiple subsidiaries, each of which falls below the
threshold. Countries’ current rules often include safeguards to protect against such circumvention.
Although this may add some complexity to the rules, countries’ experience has shown that these
safeguards may not necessarily be inconsistent with the threshold’s purpose of reducing administrative and
compliance burdens. For example, the de minimis test under the United States rules includes a general anti-
abuse rule which looks at the income of two or more controlled foreign corporations in aggregate and treats
it as the income of a single corporation if a principal purpose for separately organising, acquiring, or
maintaining such multiple corporations is to prevent income from being treated as attributable under the de
minimis test. Although such an anti-abuse rule increases the potential administrative burden of the de
minimis threshold, this increased burden is counteracted in the U.S. rule with a rebuttable presumption that
automatically treats the income of multiple CFCs as that of a single corporation if the CFCs are related
persons. Under the German rules, the general de minimis test is subject to the condition that the attributable
income must not exceed the same amount at the level of the CFC and at the level of the shareholder. This
means that even if the attributable income of one CFC does not exceed the threshold, the CFC may still be
subject to CFC rules if the same threshold is exceeded by adding all of a taxpayer’s shareholdings in
several CFCs. Examples of these two different types of anti-fragmentation rules are set out below.
47. In Figure 2 below, A Group rearranges its operations to ensure that profits that previously
arose in a single CFC are split between three CFCs in different territories. After the reorganisation, A Co.
is the sole shareholder of three controlled foreign corporations. CFC1, CFC2 and CFC3 all have the same
taxable year, and they are partners in FP, a foreign entity in Country C classified as a partnership. For their
current taxable years, each of the CFCs derives part of its attributable income from FP and part from other
activities undertaken separately.
A Co.
CFC1
CFC2
CFC3
FP
Attributable and
non-attributable income
20
48. Under the de minimis test in Country A, attributable CFC income is not taken into account for
the purposes of residence taxation if the sum of the attributable CFC income is less than the lesser of 5% of
total income or 1,000,000. Based on the figures in the table below, the attributable income derived by each
CFC for its current taxable year, including income derived from FP, is less than five percent of the gross
income of each CFC or is less than 1,000,000.
49. Therefore, without the application of an anti-abuse rule, each CFC would be treated as having no
attributable income after the application of the de minimis test.
50. If, however, Country A were to have either an anti-abuse rule similar to the U.S. rule or an anti-
fragmentation rule similar to the German rule, A Co. would be subject to CFC taxation on the income
earned by its foreign subsidiaries. If Country A has an anti-abuse rule that treats the income of all three
CFCs as the income of one CFC for the purposes of calculating the de minimis threshold if the CFCs are
related persons (or if the principal purpose for separately organizing, acquiring, or maintaining such
multiple corporations is to prevent income from being treated as attributable under the de minimis test),
then the attributable income is aggregated. The sum of the attributable income of the CFCs is 1,035,000, so
it exceeds the 1,000,000 de minimis threshold and will be taken into account under Country A’s CFC rules.
If, instead, Country A has a rule that the attributable income at the level of the shareholder must not exceed
the attributable income at the level of the CFC, the de minimis threshold would also be overcome because
the attributable income at the level of the shareholder is 1,035,000, while it is significantly less at the level
of the CFCs.
51. Therefore, although there is no general recommendation under this building block for or against
de minimis thresholds, if jurisdictions choose to implement such a threshold, best practice would be to
combine this with an anti-fragmentation rule. Annex I sets out information on the de minimis rules that
several jurisdictions have implemented.
B. Anti-avoidance requirement
52. An anti-avoidance threshold requirement would only subject transactions and structures that were
the result of tax avoidance to CFC rules. This could narrow the effectiveness of CFC rules as preventative
measures, and it could also increase the administrative and compliance burdens of CFC rules if it were
administrated as an up-front rule. Additionally, an anti-avoidance rule should not be necessary if the rules
defining the income within the scope of a CFC regime are properly targeted. An anti-avoidance
requirement has therefore not been considered further in this paper, but this is not intended to imply that an
anti-avoidance requirement can never play a role in CFC rules that tackle base erosion and profit shifting.
C. Low-tax threshold
53. Most CFC rules include a low-tax threshold for two reasons. First, this approach means that the
rules only apply to companies that benefit from low foreign taxes and therefore pose the greatest risk of
profit shifting. Second, a focus on low-tax CFCs can provide greater certainty for taxpayers and reduce the
overall administrative burden. A low-tax threshold can, however, mean that CFC rules do not prevent all
21
base erosion and profit shifting since they still allow erosion of the parent jurisdiction’s base to high- or
medium-tax jurisdictions, so a few jurisdictions do not include such a threshold.
54. There are different ways for jurisdictions to determine when a CFC has paid a low rate of tax.
Jurisdictions may require taxpayers to apply a comparative approach on a case-by-case basis, or they may
use a black list or white list to simplify the process. Using a list generally eliminates the need for a case-by-
case analysis of a jurisdiction’s tax rate and is a way of communicating whether jurisdictions apply a lower
level of tax. The use of black or white lists can make it easier for tax administrations to determine when
CFC rules do and do not apply and for taxpayers to know whether they will be subject to CFC rules. The
United Kingdom, for example, has a white list that excludes CFCs located in listed jurisdictions which are
sufficiently similar in terms of tax base and tax rate to the United Kingdom, provided that several other
conditions are also met. 25 Finland issues a list of tax treaty countries (not including EU Member States) to
be considered low-tax based on nominal tax rates and tax incentives but only regards a company in those
countries as a CFC if the company itself pays less than 3/5 of the taxes that would have been paid in
Finland. This approach therefore sets a presumption that a CFC is lowly taxed, but that presumption must
be supported with an actual comparison of taxes paid. Sweden applies a similar approach under which
countries are broken into three categories: (i) countries where no entities would be CFCs, (ii) countries
where entities without CFC income would not be CFCs while entities with CFC income would be
compared against the low-tax threshold, and (iii) countries where all income will be compared against the
low-tax threshold. Australia applies a white list approach under which companies resident in countries with
an income tax system comparable to Australia’s tax system are not subject to CFC taxation. CFCs in a
listed jurisdiction are therefore exempt from Australia’s CFC rules unless they are subject to a concessional
tax regime.
55. Low-tax thresholds require that the rate at which the CFC was taxed be below a given
benchmark. Low-tax thresholds apply one of two benchmarks. They either compare the tax rate in the CFC
jurisdiction to a particular fixed rate that is considered low-tax or they compare the tax rate in the CFC
jurisdiction to a portion or percentage of the parent country’s own rate. Both approaches seem equally
relevant within the context of designing rules to combat BEPS as both recognise that the incentive to shift
profits will be greater where there is a significant differential between effective tax rates.
56. Under the first approach, countries would need to set a fixed tax rate below which their CFC
rules would potentially apply. An example of such an approach would be the German CFC rules, which
define any level of taxation below 25% as low taxation. The second approach instead calculates the low-
tax threshold based on a percentage of the tax that would have been paid to the parent jurisdiction, which
thereby includes both tax rate and tax base in the analysis. The UK and Finnish CFC rules provide
examples of this approach. Under UK law, there is no low taxation if the “local tax amount” is at least 75%
of the “corresponding UK tax”. As mentioned above, under the Finnish rules, a low-tax regime is
considered to exist if the company itself pays less than 3/5 of the taxes that would have been paid in
Finland. Whichever approach is adopted, the benchmark should be meaningfully lower than the tax rate in
the country applying the CFC rules. As shown in Annex II, most CFC rules apply benchmarks that are at
the most 75% of the statutory corporate tax rate. It is therefore recommended that the benchmark be set at
this level or lower.
25
These conditions are that there cannot be more than insignificant amounts of certain defined types of
income that are not effectively taxed in the CFC’s territory of residence, that none of the CFC’s income has
been generated using IP that has been effectively transferred from a UK related party in the previous six
years, and that the CFC is not involved in any arrangement intended to create a UK tax advantage for any
person.
22
57. Once the benchmark has been set, CFC rules must determine the tax rate in the CFC jurisdiction
in order to compare this to the benchmark. Current CFC rules do this in one of two ways. They either
compare the benchmark to: (1) the nominal (or statutory) tax rate in the CFC jurisdiction or (2) the
effective 26 tax rate of the CFC. Although using the statutory tax rate may reduce administrative complexity
and compliance costs, the recommendation is to use the effective rate. This latter approach takes into
account the tax base or other tax provisions that may increase or reduce the effective rate paid by the CFC
and therefore is likely to create a much more accurate comparison than focusing on the statutory tax rate.
Using the effective tax rate, however, means that whether the low-tax threshold has been met must be
determined in two steps. First, there must be a calculation of the effective tax rate, which requires
determining both how much tax the CFC paid and how much income the CFC earned. Second, the
effective tax rate must be compared to the benchmark.
58. The determination of the effective tax rate is typically based on the ratio of the actual tax paid in
the CFC jurisdiction to the total taxable income either computed according to the rules of the
parent/shareholder’s country or according to an international accounting standard such as IFRS. This
method generally recognises that even in a situation where the statutory tax rate is not considered a low tax
rate, low taxation may occur as a result of (1) reducing the tax base or (2) lowering the tax burden by
subsequent rebates of taxes paid or through non-enforcement of taxes. This can be illustrated in the
following two examples.
a) Example 1: A CFC in Country C generates 80,000 of income in one year. Country A applies
its CFC rules if the effective tax rate applied to the CFC was below a fixed rate of 25% taking into account
the tax base as computed under Country A’s rules. Country C allows an exemption of 20% when
computing the taxable income to promote investments.
Income in Country C:
19,200/80,000 24%
26
The effective tax rate may be computed as an average of the effective tax rates over several years.
27
For the reasons described below, the income is calculated according to Country A’s rules. All other
calculations in this table are calculated using Country C’s rules since they were used to determine the tax
actually paid to Country C.
23
b) Example 2: A CFC in Country C generates 80,000 of income in one year. Country A applies
its CFC rules if the effective tax rate applied to the CFC was below a fixed rate of 25% taking into account
the tax base as computed under Country A’s rules. Country C does not provide for an exemption to
promote investments. However, according to Country C’s rules, shareholders of the CFC may claim a
refund in the amount of 20% of the corporate income tax paid by the CFC upon distribution of dividends.
The dividends would be tax exempt in Country A.
Income 80,000
Income in Country C:
19,200/80,000 24%
59. In both Example 1 and Example 2, the low tax requirement is met in reality because the effective
tax rate is below the fixed rate of 25%. The calculation of the effective tax rate should therefore ensure that
situations such as those illustrated in Example 1 and Example 2 are found to meet the low tax requirement,
and the discussion below provides ways to ensure this.
60. The calculation of the effective tax rate uses a fraction where the numerator is the actual tax paid
and the denominator is the CFC’s income. Although the determination of the actual tax paid could require
proof that tax was in fact collected and not refunded, the definition of the numerator could be more
straightforward if it instead focuses just on the final tax burden (including, for example, subsequent rebates
of taxes paid and non-enforcement of taxes).
61. Compared to calculating the actual tax paid, the determination of what to include in the total
taxable income (i.e., the denominator) may be more problematic. If the denominator were to refer to the
foreign tax base, the effective tax rate would equal the statutory tax rate of the CFC jurisdiction, 29 which
would undermine the purpose of the effective tax rate calculation. The denominator should therefore be
either the tax base in the parent jurisdiction had the CFC income been earned there or the tax base
28
The income is calculated according to Country A’s rules. All other calculations in this table are calculated
using Country C’s rules since they were used to determine the tax actually paid to Country C.
29
This is, of course, only true if there are no rebates and the tax was in fact collected and enforced.
24
computed according to an international accounting standard such as IFRS, with adjustments made to reflect
the tax base reductions that result in low taxation of the CFC income. 30
62. In theory, the effective tax rate calculation could find a higher effective tax rate than the
statutory tax rate in the CFC jurisdiction if the base calculated under the rules of the parent jurisdiction is
smaller than that calculated under the rules of the CFC jurisdiction. In reality, however, this situation is
unlikely to occur much in practice as groups would not structure themselves into jurisdictions where the
advantage of a low statutory tax rate is entirely or partially set off by a tax disadvantage in the tax base
computation (e.g. non-deductible expenditures).
63. The effective tax rate computation could also be influenced by the “unit” used for the calculation.
Country rules generally calculate the effective tax rate on a company-by-company basis, but it could in
theory be computed either narrowly or broadly. A narrow approach could, for example, calculate the
effective tax rate for each item of income earned by a company. Computing the effective tax rate on a
narrower basis allows jurisdictions to apply the low-tax threshold just to the income that has been defined
as attributable income under the rules. For example, if royalties were subject to taxation under a
jurisdiction’s definition of CFC income, the low-tax threshold would apply more precisely to that income
provided that the effective tax rate was computed narrowly for each type of income. This may also more
directly address situations where only certain types of income benefit from a low tax rate, while others are
subject to regular taxation. Calculating the effective tax rate on a narrower basis would, however, increase
both the administrative complexity and compliance burden associated with the low-tax threshold. A broad
approach could calculate the effective tax rate on a company-by-company or country-by-country basis. A
country-by-country approach would aggregate the income of all entities of a group in a single country to
calculate the effective tax rate. These broader approaches would reduce the administrative complexity and
compliance burden compared to the narrow approach, but calculating the low-tax threshold on a country-
by-country basis would add complexity compared to doing so on a company-by-company basis because it
would require aggregating the calculations for all the CFCs in each jurisdiction rather than just calculating
30
This tax base would require a determination of how to treat loss carry forwards of the CFC from previous
years and any losses permitted in a consolidation or group relief regime. If CFC legislation uses the rules of
the parent jurisdiction to calculate taxable income, they could also deal with losses in accordance with the
rules of the parent jurisdiction (this could mean that a consolidation regime in the CFC jurisdiction would
be ignored for purposes of CFC taxation by the parent jurisdiction). If, instead, they use a common
standard, then there would need to be a common rule for how losses should be used to calculate taxable
income.
Most countries generally apply their own rules to compute the tax base of the CFC. In principle, however,
not all differences in computing the tax base of the CFC under the rules in the CFC and the parent
jurisdiction raise the policy concerns that are typically associated with preferential tax provisions or
practices that could shrink the tax base for certain income and therefore have the effect of significantly
reducing the taxes paid by the CFC. In theory, therefore, CFC rules could take account of only those
differences that raise such policy concerns when calculating the tax base of the CFC. For example, if the
tax base in the parent jurisdiction is higher than that in the CFC jurisdiction only because of timing
differences in accounting, this may not need to be reflected in the denominator. A participation exemption
also may not fall within the scope of tax advantages that are considered in determining the denominator
because it is typically granted to eliminate double taxation and not to reduce the actual tax burden.
However, the denominator should take into account any differences that are a result of a tax advantage in
the CFC jurisdiction that attracts offshore capital and therefore increases the risk of profit shifting. A
notional interest deduction may be an example of such a tax advantage. While differentiating between tax
base definitions that implicate the policy concerns underlying CFC rules and those that do not may make
sense in theory, however, the only rules that would be likely to make this differentiation are those that start
with the tax base calculated under the rules of the CFC jurisdiction and then adjust this upward to reflect
the rules of the parent jurisdiction.
25
the effective tax rate for each CFC. If CFC jurisdictions exempt PEs from taxation, the effective tax rate of
permanent establishments of a CFC should be calculated separately from that of the CFC to ensure that the
tax rates of the PE and CFC cannot be blended to avoid the low-tax threshold.
4. What practical problems, if any, arise when applying a low-tax threshold based on an effective tax rate
calculation?
5. How could these problems be addressed or mitigated?
6. Does the discussion above correctly address the situation of permanent establishments that are subject to a
different tax rate than CFCs?
26
CHAPTER 4: DEFINITION OF CONTROL
64. Control is the third building block and is a key element of CFC rules because it determines what
entities CFC rules can be applied to. Existing regimes variously refer to a person’s “control”,
“participation”, or “influence” in a foreign entity. Generally speaking, requiring control reflects countries’
view that resident shareholders should only be taxed on income earned by a foreign company if they
appear to have had some input in how, when and where that income was earned. Control is important in the
context of BEPS because it may be an indication that resident shareholders had sufficient influence over
the foreign company and its tax policy to use it to shift profits. A control requirement can also be used to
reduce the scope of CFC rules and limit the compliance costs for minority shareholders where they have no
real ability to influence the foreign company.
I. Recommendations
65. The definition of control requires two different determinations: (i) of the type of control that is
required and (ii) of the level of that control. The recommendation for control is that CFC rules should at
least apply both a legal and an economic control test so that satisfaction of either test results in control.
Countries may also include de facto tests where they achieve the same effect. Secondly, a CFC should be
treated as controlled where residents hold, at a minimum, more than 50% control, although countries that
want to achieve broader policy goals or prevent circumvention of CFC rules may set their control threshold
at a lower level. This level of control could be established through the aggregated interest of related parties
or unrelated resident parties or from aggregating the interests of any taxpayers that are found to be acting
in concert. Additionally, CFC rules should apply where there is either direct or indirect control.
II. Explanation
66. In order to arrive at the above recommendation, the two different determinations were considered
in greater detail.
A. Type of control
67. Control can be established in various ways, which are outlined below.
• Legal control generally looks at a resident’s holding of share capital to determine the percentage
of voting rights held in a subsidiary. Legal control is a relatively mechanical test that is easy for
both tax administrations and taxpayers to apply and reflects the fact that a sufficient degree of
voting rights should enable residents to elect the board of directors or an equivalent body
responsible for the affairs of the foreign entity and thus ensure that a CFC acts in accordance with
their instructions. However, corporate law often provides a large degree of flexibility in designing
the share structure of a corporation, thus enabling the use of artificial share terms and structures to
circumvent the control requirement. A focus on legal control is therefore likely to be too narrow,
and most countries also use a concept of economic control. Although tests that consider the
entitlement to acquire shares, and therefore voting rights, through certain contingent rights such as
options may help mitigate some of the weaknesses of legal control.
• Economic control focuses on rights to the profits, capital and assets of a company in certain
circumstances such as dissolution or liquidation. Such a test recognises that a resident can control
an entity through an entitlement to the underlying value of the company even where they do not
hold the majority of the shares. This entitlement may result from rights to the proceeds in the
27
event of a disposal of the entity’s share capital or the entity’s assets on a winding up. It may also
include rights to a distribution of profits other than on a disposal or winding up. Economic
control is also a relatively mechanical test that focuses on facts that can be objectively assessed.
It does add some complexity but in reality those with a majority stake in a company are likely to
be aware of that fact and may have other reporting obligations in respect of that controlled
relationship. However, economic control rules may be circumvented, most obviously by means
of group reorganisations involving the insertion of a new group holding company. In such
situations, both legal and economic control may change even though there is little or no change in
the underlying business or the level of decision-making and business control exercised by the
previous parent.
• De facto control can look at similar factors to those considered by many countries when
considering where a company is resident for tax purposes. For instance, countries can look at
who takes the top-level decisions regarding the affairs of the foreign company or who has the
ability to direct or influence its day-to-day activities. Another approach could focus on any
particular contractual ties with the CFC that permit taxpayers to exert a dominant influence over
it. However, a de facto control test would require a significant analysis of the facts and
circumstances and some subjective assessment of these. This will lead to added costs, complexity
and uncertainty for taxpayers. In addition, based on countries’ experience in operating residence
rules, the type of criteria mentioned above may also be relatively easy to avoid and therefore
difficult for a tax administration to prove. If a de facto control test could be designed to arrive at
accurate results without these significant administrative and compliance burdens, it could also be
included in a recommendation, but it would have to capture at least as many situations as
captured by tests that look at legal or economic control.
68. The above approaches are often combined to prevent circumvention and to ensure that rules
operate effectively. Based on the above analysis it was agreed that a control test should focus on a
combined approach that includes at least legal and economic control. Both of these tests are reasonably
mechanical and so should limit the administrative and compliance burden involved. However, countries
could also consider supplementing these tests with either a de facto test or a test based on consolidation for
accounting purposes. Both of these, but particularly a broad de facto test, could increase complexity and
compliance costs. Therefore countries that are attracted to using one of the latter two tests to address
specific problems (such as those raised by inversions) may find that these problems could be better
addressed with separate targeted provisions rather than through an extension of the concept of control for
CFC purposes.
28
B. Level of control
69. Once a CFC regime has established what actually confers control, the next question is how much
control is enough for the CFC rules to apply. If the aim is to catch all situations where the controlling party
has the ability to shift profits to a foreign company, then, as a minimum, CFC rules would need to capture
situations where resident taxpayers have a legal or economic interest in the foreign entity of more than
50%. Some existing rules find control when the parent owns exactly 50%, but the majority of rules require
more than 50% control. Because owning 50% or less could still allow parent companies to exert influence
in certain situations, jurisdictions are free to lower their control threshold below 50%. 31
70. The determination of whether this 50% threshold has been met is straightforward when control is
held by a single resident shareholder. Shareholders can exert influence in other situations, however, and
existing rules generally attempt to capture these instances as well with their control rules. The general
principle underlying control tests is that minority shareholders that are acting together to exert influence
should have their interests aggregated when determining whether the control test has been met. Whether or
not minority shareholders are acting together can be determined in at least three ways, and it is
recommended that jurisdictions adopt one of these approaches to ensure that minority shareholders who are
in fact exerting influence are taken into account when determining whether there is control.
71. The first way of determining whether minority shareholders are acting together is to apply an
“acting-in-concert” test, which applies a fact-based analysis to determine whether the shareholders are in
fact acting together to influence the CFC. If they are, their interests will be aggregated to determine
whether the CFC is subject to CFC rules. This approach is not very common because it creates significant
administrative and compliance burdens, but one of its advantages is that it may more accurately identify
when shareholders are in fact acting together than a more mechanical test. An example of how an acting-
in-concert test would work is illustrated below.
31
Some CFC rules recognise that control can be exercised below 50% ownership. For instance, New
Zealand’s CFC rules find that the control threshold has been met when a New Zealand resident owns 40%
or more of the foreign subsidiary. Note that a much lower control threshold may raise EU legal concerns
for Member State CFC rules, even if they do not apply to CFCs in other Member States. This is because, as
the control threshold is reduced, CFC rules may implicate not just the freedom of establishment but the free
movement of capital, which applies to Member State rules that are discriminatory toward residents of third
countries as well as residents of other Member States. This concern would only arise when the threshold is
reduced below the level of “significant influence”.
29
Figure 3. Control interest held by unrelated parties acting in concert
C Co
35%
Country C
A Co
35%
Country A
Acting in concert
B Co
Country B
30%
CFC
72. C Co, A Co and B Co are all unrelated parties. Country A’s CFC rules require a controlling
interest of more than 50% before they can be applied. There is no other resident taxpayer in Country A so
unless Country A has an acting-in-concert rule that aggregates the interest of both residents and non-
residents, and the acting in concert rule can be shown to apply, then there will be no attribution of the
income of CFC to A Co. As mentioned above, an acting-in-concert rule would add complexity and
compliance costs, especially where it is applied to both residents and non-residents. However, it could also
prevent circumvention of CFC rules. 32
73. The second way that some rules determine whether minority shareholders are acting together is to
look to the relationship of the parties. If rules only include the interests of related parties when determining
whether the 50% threshold has been met, this would eliminate the need for a fact-based acting-in-concert
test, but it will apply more narrowly since it focuses more directly on the profit shifting opportunities
created by structures involving related parties. However, since BEPS structures often involve wholly
owned subsidiaries or at least subsidiaries owned by related parties, a focus on related parties may still
capture most structures that raise BEPS concerns. 33 An example of how a related party test would work is
illustrated below.
32
A similar scenario to that above could arise where there is a joint venture. Some countries have specific
rules to deal with joint ventures. Under the UK CFC rules, a UK resident 40% joint venture partner would
be treated as having control if there is a non-UK resident that holds at least 40% and no more than 55% of
the legal and economic interest in the joint venture. This rule has a similar effect to an acting-in-concert
type rule.
33
This may not capture all structures that raise BEPS concerns, however, and other action items have
recognised that unrelated parties may act together to achieve a certain outcome. The work on hybrid
mismatch arrangements, for example, includes structured arrangements involving unrelated parties.
30
Figure 4. Control interest held by related parties
Parent
100%
100%
A Co 1 A Co 2
Country A
B Co
30% 40%
Country B
30%
CFC
74. A Co1 and A Co2 are unrelated residents in Country A. For Country A’s CFC rules to apply,
related parties or residents that act in concert must hold an aggregate interest in the CFC of more than 50%.
Parent Co splits the interest in CFC between A Co1 and B Co, in order to circumvent the control
requirement in country A. If, however, Country A applied a related party rule that aggregates the interests
of related parties to determine control, then A Co1 would be found to be a controlling shareholder because
of the shared ownership between A Co 1 and B Co, which are both owned by Parent. This would mean that
30% of the income of CFC would be attributed to A Co 1. No income would be attributed to A Co 2. The
same outcome is likely to arise under an acting-in-concert test. Whether or not income is attributed to B Co
would depend on the rules in operation in Country B but if they operated the same form of related party
rule, then 30% of the income of CFC would also be attributed to B Co.
75. The third way that CFC rules determine whether minority shareholders are exerting influence
over the CFC is to impose a concentrated ownership requirement. In the United States, for example, the
interests of all residents in the CFC are aggregated so long as each interest is higher than a set percentage
(e.g., 10%). This approach leads to the interests of a concentrated group of residents being considered, and
it also eliminates the need for separate rules for attribution, since the 10% threshold for control can also be
used to determine which residents will have income allocated to them. Alternatively, a concentrated
ownership requirement could require just that ownership be divided between a small number of resident
shareholders (e.g., 5 or fewer), regardless of their ownership percentage, but this may raise administrative
and compliance concerns, and focusing just on the number of owners may also not always accurately
identify whether taxpayers are in reality acting together.
76. A concentrated ownership rule can be illustrated with reference to Figure 4 above. If Country A
expanded its control requirement and applied its rules where there were a small group of resident
31
shareholders, in this situation A Co 1 and A Co 2, then the CFC rules would apply and 30% of the income
of CFC would be attributed to A Co 1 and 40% to A Co 2. This would prevent circumvention of the rules
but would attribute income to A Co 2. This might not be a concern in the context of a 40% holding but a
test that focuses on a small group of residents would potentially attribute profits to A Co 2 even if it was
not acting in concert with A Co 1 and had no real ability to transfer income or profits to the CFC.
77. Including the interests of non-resident taxpayers in any of these three approaches could add to the
complexity of the control provisions but such an addition could be considered if countries were concerned
about either related or unrelated parties acting together to try and circumvent the CFC control provisions. 34
The recommendations above therefore do not recommend that non-residents are also taken into account in
determining the level of control, but, as with all recommendations, the recommendation included in this
document only establishes a minimum, and jurisdictions with different policy aims could include non-
resident interests when determining whether the 50% threshold (or any lower threshold) was met. If
jurisdictions chose this option, limiting taxation of resident taxpayers to their actual share of CFC income
(rather than the aggregated amount) should eliminate any concerns about double taxation.
78. Regardless of which of the three approaches is taken, control should be defined to include both
direct and indirect control since profit-shifting opportunities also arise where a subsidiary is held indirectly
through an intermediate holding company. If CFC rules do not apply to indirect holdings then they can be
very easily sidestepped. The example below illustrates one of the questions raised by indirect control,
which is whether a level of indirect control that falls below the control threshold should still lead to a
finding of control if the control threshold is met at each level in the chain of ownership.
Parent
70%
A Co
60%
CFC
79. In this example, Parent has a 70% interest in A Co, which holds a 60% interest in CFC. There is
therefore more than 50% control at each tier, but Parent itself only has an interest of 42% (70% x 60%) of
CFC. Despite this limited economic control, A Co. has enough economic control to influence CFC and
Parent has enough economic control to influence A Co., so it is recommended that CFC rules should find
34
Non-resident taxpayers whose interests could possibly be included could include family members of
resident shareholders or board members of domestic parent companies.
32
Parent to have sufficient influence over CFC to meet the control threshold since the control threshold is
met at each level in the chain of ownership. 35 The amount attributed to Parent should, however, be limited
to its actual economic interest of 42%.
80. Although including both direct and indirect control in the control analysis could arguably
increase the potential for double taxation if all countries were to introduce CFC rules, this situation could
be addressed with rules to reduce or eliminate double taxation. 36
81. Determining whether a company in the parent jurisdiction has control also requires a rule
determining when control should be established as well as what types of entities can be considered to have
control. On the first question, many rules determine control based on how much of an economic or legal
interest was held at the end of the year, but jurisdictions concerned about circumvention of this rule can
also include anti-abuse provisions or a test that looks at whether the parent company had the necessary
level of control at any point during the year. On the second question, in order to ensure that all situations
where resident shareholders have the opportunity to shift income into a foreign subsidiary are captured,
CFC rules should consider the interests held by all resident taxpayers, rather than limiting this inquiry to
corporate entities or other limited groups.
35
For example, once control is established at a level, some CFC rules deem the control at that level to be
100% for the purpose of determining the level of indirect control at the next level.
36
See infra Chapter 8.
33
CHAPTER 5: DEFINITION OF CFC INCOME
82. This chapter discusses the fourth CFC building block on the definition of CFC income. Once a
foreign company has been determined to be a CFC, the next question is whether the income earned by the
CFC is of the type that raises BEPS concerns and should be attributed to shareholders or controlling
parties. CFC rules therefore need to define attributable income, which is also referred to here as “CFC
income”. Existing CFC regimes apply one of two approaches. They apply either a full-inclusion system,
which treats all income earned by a CFC as CFC income regardless of its character, or a partial-inclusion
system, which only attributes certain types of income earned by a CFC. As all income is included under
full-inclusion systems, there is no need to separately define CFC income, but such an approach will catch
categories of income that do not raise specific profit shifting concerns. Partial-inclusion systems, however,
need to accurately define CFC income.
83. Many countries have chosen to implement CFC rules because they are more mechanical than
transfer pricing rules. More mechanical rules, however, are generally broader by nature and cannot be as
easily targeted to BEPS concerns. Therefore, existing CFC rules that are more mechanical may attribute
more income than is required in order to combat BEPS. This is the case for all CFC rules that apply
full-inclusion systems and for many partial-inclusion systems that define CFC income broadly. Although
jurisdictions can implement a full-inclusion approach or a broad partial-inclusion approach if they are
focused on broader policy aims than combating profit shifting, 37 this chapter focuses on more narrowly
targeted partial-inclusion systems that only attribute income that raises profit shifting concerns. Member
37
The ability of jurisdictions to implement a full-inclusion system is, of course, subject to jurisdictions’ other
international obligations.
34
States of the European Union in particular may need to combine more mechanical CFC rules with a
substance test to ensure that CFC rules do not attribute income earned from genuine economic activities. 38
84. This chapter does not set out general recommendations for how to define CFC income, but it
instead discusses several possible approaches that jurisdictions could adopt. Whichever approach is
adopted, CFC rules should accurately attribute income that raises base erosion and profit shifting concerns.
In particular, CFC rules should be able to accurately define attributable income in the context of income
earned by CFCs that are holding companies, income earned by CFCs that provide financial and banking
services, income earned by CFCs that engage in sales invoicing, income from IP assets, income from
digital goods and services, and income from captive insurance and re-insurance. In practical terms, this
means that CFC rules must be capable of dealing with at least the following types of income:
• Dividends
• Interest and other financing income
• Insurance income
• Sales and services income
• Royalties and other IP income
85. Accurately attributing this income does not mean that CFC rules should include all of this
income in CFC income. It instead means that, at a minimum, CFC rules should attribute income that raises
BEPS issues within each category and should not attribute income that arises from value-creating activity
in the CFC jurisdiction. If CFC rules are designed to apply only to stripping of the base of the parent
jurisdiction, then income should not be attributed if it arises from value-creating activity in any jurisdiction
other than the parent jurisdiction.
86. The general principle underlying most existing partial-inclusion rules is that highly mobile and/
or “passive” income should be attributed to shareholders because it is likely to have been diverted away
from the parent jurisdiction or a third jurisdiction and into the CFC jurisdiction. CFC rules generally
achieve this principle by defining CFC income to include, at a minimum, interest, royalties, and dividends,
and by excluding “active” income that was earned in the course of an active trade or business from the
definition of CFC income.
87. The fundamental challenge that CFC rules face is how to define CFC income so that highly
mobile income that does in fact represent profit shifting is attributed but income that arises from actual
activities undertaken by the CFC is not. One approach that some jurisdictions take is a form-based analysis
that categorises income as CFC income based on its formal classification. This analysis would, for
example, include dividends, interest, and royalties in CFC income and exclude sales, services, and other
income that is by its nature more associated with the carrying on of a trade or business. These traditional
and formal categories may be based on the principle that, if the income earned by a CFC arises from a
trade or business in the CFC jurisdiction, treating that income as attributable may undermine the
competitiveness of the CFC. By only attributing income that does not arise from actual activities, therefore,
CFC regimes are able to strike a balance between creating a disincentive for shifting income to a non-
resident subsidiary and maintaining the competitiveness of subsidiaries engaged in actual activities in their
own jurisdictions.
38
Jurisdictions that are applying CFC rules narrowly to focus on profit shifting may also combine more
mechanical CFC rules with a substance test.
35
88. A pure form-based analysis does not, however, accurately attribute income earned in the modern
business environment. Although this mechanical approach has the benefits of reduced administrative and
compliance costs, it can be easily manipulated and does not attribute all income that arises from base
erosion and profit shifting. Attributing only interest, dividends, and royalties means that income that was,
for example, earned from the use of an IP asset but was legally treated as sales income would escape CFC
taxation, an issue that is exacerbated in the digital economy. Attributing all interest, dividends, and
royalties also means that income that falls into these categories but in fact arose out of an active business
(for example, income earned from a business engaged in active financing) will be attributed even if it does
not raise any concerns about base erosion or profit shifting.
89. Because of these weaknesses with a pure form-based analysis, existing CFC rules typically apply
some sort of substance analysis that looks to whether the income arose from substantial activities
undertaken by the CFC itself. This rule may apply in place of or alongside a form-based analysis, but most
existing substance analyses apply alongside other more mechanical rules and are not stand-alone rules.
Although such rules add to the complexity of CFC rules, they appear to be necessary to accurately identify
and quantify shifted income. They may also be particularly necessary in CFC rules that apply between
Member States of the European Union, since a substance analysis could prevent CFC rules from attributing
income that arises from genuine economic activities. A substance analysis could take at least three forms:
• One option would be a substantial contribution analysis. This would be a threshold test that
applies a facts and circumstances analysis to determine whether the employees of the CFC have
made a substantial contribution to the income earned by the CFC. Once the CFC has shown a
given level of activities, all income earned by that CFC would then not be treated as
attributable.39
• A second option could be a viable independent entity analysis. Rather than trying to determine
what constitutes a substantial contribution, this option would look at all the significant functions
performed by entities within the group to determine whether the CFC is the entity which would
be most likely to own particular assets, or undertake particular risks, if the entities were
39
An example of this is in the U.S. CFC rules. Under the substantial contribution test that applies to
manufacturing income earned by a CFC, manufacturing income that would normally be treated as
attributable will not be attributable if “the facts and circumstances evince that the controlled foreign
corporation makes a substantial contribution through the activities of its employees to the manufacture,
production, or construction of the personal property sold”. 26 CFR 1.954(3)(a)(4)(iv)(a). The test then
provides a list of seven activities that could indicate that the CFC did make a substantial contribution, all of
which essentially consider whether the CFC was engaged in actual value creation. These activities include
(1) oversight and direction of the activities or process pursuant to which the property is manufactured,
produced, or constructed; (2) activities that are considered in determining whether the products were
substantially transformed or if the assembly or conversion of component parts into a final product are
substantial in nature and generally considered to constitute the manufacture, production, or construction of
property; (3) material selection, vendor selection, or control of the raw materials, work-in-process or
finished goods; (4) management of manufacturing costs or capacities (for example, managing the risk of
loss, cost reduction or efficiency initiatives associated with the manufacturing process, demand planning,
production scheduling, or hedging raw material costs); (5) control of manufacturing related logistics; (6)
quality control (for example, sample testing or establishment of quality control standards); and (7)
developing, or directing the use or development of, product design and design specifications, as well as
trade secrets, technology, or other intellectual property for the purpose of manufacturing, producing, or
constructing the personal property. 26 CFR 1.954(3)(a)(4)(iv)(b). The Regulations then provide examples
to illustrate how this facts and circumstances test would apply.
36
unrelated. 40 If the CFC would not own an asset or risk, the profits arising from it should be
included in CFC income. 41 For CFCs that received IP income, this could, for example, involve
consideration of all the group’s activities to manage and control the development, enhancement,
maintenance, protection, and exploitation of intangibles. Under this analysis, there are no set
thresholds for the activities that must be performed by a CFC or must not be performed by
affiliates. Whether or not profits are included in CFC income depends on the balance of activities
between entities and how unrelated parties would have been most likely to allocate assets and
risks.
− The viable independent entity analysis could be applied in all circumstances, including
those which involve IP-related profits. In the context of a group that continues to own,
develop, and exploit IP, the location of capabilities and functions which enable the group
to manage risks associated with that IP can be used to identify which group entity would
own the IP under normal commercial conditions, which would determine where the
substance was located. An assessment of whether, and to what extent, a CFC has the
relevant capabilities would consider all the key functions that the group usually performs
and where they are performed. The capability to approve decisions would therefore not be
sufficient.
− The viable independent entity analysis could be combined with a carve-out under which
income that was earned with the substantial contribution of a related party would
automatically be included in CFC income. This alternative would include all income
earned from related party outsourcing, and it would arrive at an outcome that was similar
to that achieved under the third option. 42
• A third option would be an employees and establishment analysis. This would use employees and
establishment as a more mechanical way of determining whether the activities required to earn
the CFC income are located in the CFC jurisdiction. 43 Existing CFC tests generally look at,
40
A similar approach has been adopted by the United Kingdom, which has used the concepts and guidance
developed by the OECD for Article 7 to identify the group’s significant people functions associated with
each asset, so that it can be determined whether the CFC undertakes those functions.
41
This proposal has the potential to address foreign-to-foreign stripping. If CFC rules are targeted only at
income shifted from the parent jurisdiction, the viable independent entity approach could be designed in
such a way that profits would only be included if the asset or risk would be owned by an entity resident in
the parent jurisdiction.
42
A similar approach has been adopted by Germany, where CFC rules first apply an analysis similar to the
viable independent entity analysis and then include income that would otherwise have been excluded if a
related party made a substantial contribution to that income.
43
Examples include the now-repealed UK exempt activities test and the South African foreign business
establishment test. The UK test exempted all the profits of the CFC if it met the following three
requirements: (i) it had a business establishment in a territory of residence, (ii) it was effectively managed
in its territory of residence, and (iii) it did not have as its main business any of a group of listed activities,
including investment business and dealing in goods for delivery to or from the United Kingdom (although
it could be a holding company if it met specific requirements). The test defined a business establishment to
include “premises which are, or are intended to be, occupied and used with a reasonable degree of
permanence, and from which the company’s business in its territory of residence is wholly or mainly
carried on.” The test defined effective management to mean that “the number of persons employed by the
company in the territory in which it is resident is adequate to deal with the volume of the company’s
business, and any services provided by the company for persons resident outside that territory are not in
fact performed in the United Kingdom.” Under the South African foreign business establishment test,
income of a CFC is not attributable if it is produced by a foreign business establishment (FBE) that
37
among other things, whether the CFC had the necessary business premises and establishment in
the CFC jurisdiction to actually earn the income and whether the CFC had the necessary number
of employees with the requisite skills in the CFC jurisdiction to undertake the majority of the
CFC’s core functions. This approach therefore builds on existing ideas but looks just at
employees and establishment and this approach may remove some of the complexity of more
fact-intensive tests, such as the viable independent entity analysis. There are two main
differences between this option and the viable independent entity analysis:
− First, the employees and establishment analysis will subject income to CFC taxation if the
CFC outsources its core business functions and some of the value-creating activities are
actually undertaken elsewhere. Therefore the CFC itself must have the employees and
establishment necessary for earning the actual income, rather than just the employees and
establishment necessary for managing or overseeing the value-creating activities. Even as
a proportionate test this analysis may apply to more CFCs because it will apply where
core functions are outsourced whereas the viable independent entity analysis may allow a
greater amount of outsourcing if it focuses more on managing and overseeing, rather than
actively undertaking.
− Second, the employees and establishment analysis does not require an analysis of risks or
asset ownership. Instead, it just asks whether the CFC had the employees and
establishment necessary to earn the income. If a CFC earned IP income, for example, the
CFC would have to show that it had the skilled employees required to undertake the R&D
and other value creating activities and that it had the research facilities and other business
premises required to develop the IP. It would not, however, need to identify the IP assets,
establish ownership of the assets, or show that it managed or controlled the risks. An
employees and establishment analysis could therefore act as a factual but more
mechanical approach as compared to a more complex functional analysis.
90. Both the second and third options could be applied as either threshold tests or proportionate tests.
If they were threshold (or “all-or-nothing”) tests, a set amount of functions or employees and establishment
would allow all income of the CFC to be excluded. Therefore, if the viable independent entity test were
applied as a threshold test, a CFC that had engaged in sufficient management or control to qualify as a
viable independent entity would have all of its income excluded from CFC taxation. A CFC that had not
engaged in these activities would have all of its income included in CFC income. If the employees and
establishment test were applied as a threshold test, a CFC that had the required employees and
establishment would have all of its income excluded, but a CFC that did not have all of these required
employees and establishment would have all of its income included. If they were applied as proportionate
tests, this would allow some income to be excluded from CFC taxation if the CFC carried out some of the
required substantial activities. In order to apply a proportionate test, the CFC rules would have to
determine the substance and activities which would have to in fact be performed to earn the CFC’s income
and compare this to the substance and activity of the CFC. This would increase the administrative
complexity and compliance costs of the rules, 44 but it could also ensure that only income that arose from
BEPS would be attributed. Although many CFC rules with substance analyses apply these analyses as
operates at arm’s length. FBEs are places of business with a physical structure that are used (or will
continue to be used) for at least one year. These places of business must be where the business of the CFC
is undertaken and they must be suitably equipped and staffed with managerial and operational employees
who render services for the purpose of conducting the CFC’s primary operations.
44
It may be possible to design a proportionate substance analysis that considers more mechanical factors,
such as expenditures. More mechanical proportionate approaches, however, are looking at proxies for
substantial activities, so they may not always be accurate in their attribution.
38
threshold tests, some CFC rules do apply substance analyses as proportionate tests. The proportionate
application of a substance analysis should prevent businesses from locating just the right type and amount
of activity in a CFC to ensure that its profits are excluded by the CFC rules of its parent jurisdiction. One
further advantage of applying a substance test on a proportionate basis is that it is more likely to comply
with EU law because it would allow CFC rules to attribute only the income that does not arise from
genuine economic activities
91. The differences between all of these versions of a substance analysis can be illustrated in the
following example. Sub B is a CFC in Country B that is wholly owned by Parent, which is resident in
Country A. Sub B made a buy-in payment, and Sub B and Parent have entered into a cost-sharing
agreement for producing software in Region B under which Sub B undertakes all the regional production,
translation, packaging, distribution, and marketing activities for the software and then receives all sales
income from the sale of the software in Region B. Parent undertakes all research and development of the
software.
• Under the substantial contribution analysis, as the employees of Sub B made a substantial
contribution to the income earned by Sub B, none of the CFC’s income would be included.
• The viable independent entity analysis could be applied as either a threshold test or a
proportionate test. If it were applied as a threshold test, the inclusion of Sub B’s income would
depend on whether Parent or Sub B would be more likely to own all the IP rights to region B.
There would in effect be a comparison with unrelated parties and, if in that context the party
responsible for R&D would own the assets and subcontract the marketing, Sub B’s income would
be included. If, instead, the party responsible for marketing was likely to own the software assets
and subcontract any residual or ongoing R&D activity necessary to maintain and enhance the
product, then Sub B’s income would be excluded. If the viable independent entity analysis were
applied as a proportionate test, any profits arising from the activities performed by Sub B would
be excluded, as would some of the profits due to ownership of the IP if and to the extent that Sub
B would have an ownership in those IP assets if it were an unrelated party.
• The employees and establishment analysis could also be applied as either a threshold test or a
proportionate test. If it were applied as a threshold test, all of the income of Sub B would be
included in CFC income because Sub B did not have all the required employees and
establishment to develop the software (even if it did have the required employees and
establishment to exploit the software). If the employees and establishment analysis were applied
as a proportionate test, a portion of the CFC’s income that was proportionate to the employees
and establishment that the CFC did not have would be included. This portion could be calculated,
for example, by determining what type of establishment and what employees and skills would be
required to both develop and produce the software and comparing the actual establishment and
employees to this base. One possible way of applying the employees and establishment analysis
on a proportionate basis would be to use expenditures as a proxy in certain contexts.
92. The advantages and disadvantages of these approaches are set out below:
• The advantages of the substantial contribution analysis are that, since it was developed in the
context of manufacturing income, it may accurately attribute many types of income. One
disadvantage is that it may not accurately attribute IP income. Another disadvantage is that the
threshold may be low enough to allow “swamping”, which occurs when a CFC uses the fact that
it undertook a minimum level of substantial activities to shield income from CFC taxation and
therefore not attribute any of the income.
39
• Many of the advantages and disadvantages of the viable independent entity analysis are based on
its similarity to a transfer pricing analysis or the analysis required under the Authorised OECD
Approach. 45 An advantage of this similarity is that this may reduce overall administrative
complexity and compliance costs because taxpayers will already be performing related analysis
and providing the information for transfer pricing purposes. A further advantage is that this
approach eliminates one of the complexities of transfer pricing as there is no need to decide
where to allocate income that was not actually earned by the CFC. Instead, CFC rules
automatically attribute this income to the parent, thereby simplifying the overall analysis.
Although the similarity to transfer pricing means that the viable independent entity analysis may
appear duplicative, it builds on the work to correctly price actual contractual arrangements and
determines whether the intragroup asset and risk allocation resulting from those contracts is what
would be expected on a commercial basis. The main disadvantage is that it requires a fact-
intensive analysis involving an element of judgment, which would increase administrative
complexity and compliance costs and may lead to uncertainty. These issues could, however, be
minimised by the use of suitably targeted entity-level exemptions.
• The main advantage of the employees and establishment analysis is that it requires a less fact-
intensive analysis and is potentially more mechanical than the viable independent entity analysis.
This approach also requires more activity than the substantial contribution analysis. It should
therefore reduce administrative complexity and compliance burdens relative to the viable
independent entity analysis, and it should reduce swamping relative to the substantial
contribution analysis. If the employees and establishment analysis is applied as a threshold test,
however, this second advantage would only be true if the threshold were set at a sufficiently high
level to prevent swamping. If, however, it were applied as a threshold test and the threshold were
set at even a moderately high level, there is a risk of including income even when the CFC
engaged in substance. A proportionate approach would therefore reduce the risks of under-
inclusion and over-inclusion, but one disadvantage of a proportionate employees and
establishment analysis is that this would require a comparison of the employees and
establishment in the CFC to the employees and establishment that would be required to earn the
overall income, which may be a difficult comparison to undertake.
93. Along with applying form-based analyses and substance tests, existing CFC rules also try to
determine whether income is highly mobile by looking at from whom it was earned (i.e., from related
parties or from others) and where it was earned. On the first point, many existing CFC rules include
income if it was earned from a related party on the grounds that income is more likely to be shifted in that
situation. Some jurisdictions apply a very broad related party test that includes both income from sales to a
related party and income from a sale of a good originally purchased from a related party. Another version
of a related party rule would apply to income from goods that were developed in conjunction with a related
party (e.g., intellectual property that was developed with a related party or as part of a cost-sharing
agreement with a related party). 46
94. On the second point, existing CFC rules consider where the income was earned, as well as from
whom it was earned. This approach can take the form of either an anti-base-stripping rule or a source-
country rule, and the underlying principle is that income that was earned from sales and services provided
in the CFC jurisdiction is less likely to raise concerns about profit shifting, while income that was earned
45
The Authorised OECD Approach (AOA) to attributing profits to permanent establishments as set out in the
report issued on 22/06/2010.
46
Such a rule was proposed by the U.S. administration as part of its definition of foreign base company
digital income in 2015.
40
from another jurisdiction is more likely to raise such concerns. Anti-base-stripping rules would include
CFC income if it was earned for sales to a related or unrelated party located in the parent jurisdiction or for
services or investments located in the parent jurisdiction. This raises an important policy question which is
whether CFC rules should only attribute income that has been stripped from the base of the parent
jurisdiction or whether they should also attribute income that has been stripped from the base of third
countries. If CFC rules take the first approach, then only income generated in the parent jurisdiction will be
categorised as CFC income. This does raise the question of how to determine whether income was or could
have been earned in the parent jurisdiction, and this narrower approach may therefore create opportunities
for manipulation. A broader approach would be to include income stripped from the base of any
jurisdiction and to categorise any such income as CFC income. A broader anti-base-stripping rule could
therefore treat any income generated in a jurisdiction other than the CFC jurisdiction as CFC income. This
would be harder to manipulate but may attribute income that has genuinely been earned from activities
carried out by the CFC. Such a situation could arise, for example, where a foreign company that previously
had customers in the parent jurisdiction became a CFC when it was purchased as part of a merger or
acquisition. This shows that either a narrow or a broad approach could be over-inclusive, but this is more
likely to occur in the context of broad approaches that attribute more income. An anti-base-stripping rule
could also take the form of a source-country rule, which excludes highly mobile income from CFC income
if it was earned in the CFC jurisdiction. One question to consider in this context is how to determine when
such income has been earned in the CFC jurisdiction.
95. Existing CFC rules generally use a combination of a form-based analysis and a substance-based
analysis, often combined with rules that focus on related parties and the jurisdiction where the income was
earned. As highlighted by Action Item 3, however, these rules still struggle to accurately attribute income
earned by many types of CFCs. The section below therefore discusses possible ways to more accurately
attribute income that gives rise to particular difficulties for existing CFC rules.
II. How CFC rules can accurately attribute income that raises BEPS concerns
• Dividends
• Interest and other financing income
• Insurance income
• Sales and services income
• Royalties and other IP income
97. Jurisdictions can, of course, apply CFC rules to a wider category of income than those listed
above, but the categories listed above raise BEPS concerns and can pose challenges for existing CFC rules.
Other types of income such as rents and leasing fees, for example, are not discussed in detail here, but
jurisdictions could include these types of income within CFC income when the property is located outside
41
of the CFC jurisdiction or when the rents are earned from related parties. CFC rules could also attribute
certain types of capital gains where they raise BEPS concerns. 47
i. Dividends
98. Under a form-based analysis, it would appear appropriate to treat dividends as passive income,
but many existing CFC rules treat dividends as active income in one of two situations. First, if the
dividends were paid out of active income (because the company paying dividends to the CFC was engaged
in an active trade or business), many current CFC rules treat those dividends as active income to the extent
those are non-portfolio dividends or dividends paid by a related party. Many countries now exempt certain
dividend income, and they continue to exempt dividends earned by the CFC if those dividends would have
been exempted from taxation in the parent jurisdiction had they been earned by the parent company.
Second, if the CFC is in the active trade or business of dealing in securities then dividends paid to that CFC
are treated as active income if they are linked to the CFC’s trade or business.
99. Dividend income therefore could most accurately be attributed by categorising it first as passive
but then excluding it from CFC income if it were paid out of active income (or by related parties out of
active income) or if the CFC were in the active trade or business of dealing in securities. This could in
effect require some degree of a substance analysis to ensure that the company paying dividends to the CFC
is engaged in an active trade or business. Countries operating a dividend exemption could implement this
rule by applying the exemption only to dividends that would be exempt from taxation in the parent
jurisdiction if they had been earned by the parent company.
100. The general concern underlying the treatment of interest and financing income is that this income
is easy to shift and therefore could have been shifted by the parent into the CFC, leading to overleveraging
of the parent and overcapitalisation of the CFC. This situation, which raises significant BEPS concerns,
can be identified either by looking at objective factors such as whether the income was earned from a
related party or whether the CFC was overcapitalised 48 or by determining whether the CFC had the
substance required to earn the interest and financing income itself. The majority of existing CFC rules treat
interest and other financing income as passive when earned by the CFC, but some take a different approach
and only treat interest as CFC income in specific circumstances such as when it has been earned from
related parties, when the CFC is overcapitalised, or when the activities contributing to the interest were
located outside the CFC jurisdiction. Even CFC rules that generally characterise interest and other
financing income as passive have exceptions for interest that was earned from an active financing business.
101. Interest and other financing income could therefore be attributed by categorising this income first
as passive but excluding it from CFC income if the CFC was in the active trade or business of financing
and it was not overcapitalised. 49 This would require applying one of the substance analyses to determine
47
It is unlikely that capital gains arising from fixed property assets located in a CFC jurisdiction would raise
BEPS concerns, but capital gains arising from mobile non-fixed assets may be a more appropriate inclusion
in CFC income.
48
As an example of what would be considered overcapitalisation, the UK CFC rules include a safe harbour
for banking income under which a CFC is not considered to be overcapitalised if the tier one capital ratio
(i.e., tier one capital over the total risk weighted assets) of the CFC does not exceed 125% of its UK
banking group’s capital ratio.
49
This could also be combined with a look-through rule that treated interest paid out of active earnings as
active, although this could raise foreign-to-foreign base stripping issues.
42
whether the CFC was in fact engaged in the activities required to earn the financing income. It would also
require some method of determining whether the CFC was overcapitalised.
102. The general concern underlying the treatment of income from the insurance of risks is that
profits can be shifted away from jurisdictions in which those risks are located and into a low-tax
jurisdiction. For example, an insurance company that is licensed to carry on an insurance business in a
particular jurisdiction may underwrite insurance policies in respect of persons or businesses located in that
jurisdiction and then reinsure some or all of these risks to a CFC that is resident in a low-tax jurisdiction
(and that is generally not licensed to carry on an insurance business in the particular jurisdiction), thereby
shifting profits associated with the insurance of those risks. In addition groups that are not generally
involved in insurance activities may establish “captive” insurance companies (often in a low-tax
jurisdiction), and by various means insure risks associated with the groups normal business activities with
the captive insurance company, thereby shifting profits to the captive insurance company. Generally
speaking, little activity is required in the management of these reinsurance operations or these “captive”
insurance operations. Further, due to the complexity of the insurance of risks generally, taxing authorities
may not have the capacity or ability to successfully challenge the extent to which companies have actually
transferred the risks to related CFCs. As such, CFC attribution rules may play a key role in preventing
BEPS in this context.
103. As shown in Annex III, existing CFC rules typically take one of two approaches. Some treat
insurance income as passive income, but they generally provide an exception when the CFC was engaged
in the active trade or business of providing insurance. Because the question of whether an insurance
company is engaged in an active trade or business may be difficult to answer, other CFC rules attribute
insurance income in one or more of the following three cases: (i) the CFC was overcapitalised relative to
comparable companies in the business of providing insurance, (ii) the policy holder, annuitant, beneficiary,
or location of the risks insured were outside the jurisdiction, or (iii) the insurance income was derived from
contracts or policies with a related party. In the third situation, some CFC rules are narrower and only
attribute insurance income derived from related parties if the related party also received a deduction for the
payment of the insurance premium.
104. Effective CFC rules could therefore focus on one or more of the following factors: (i) whether
the income was derived (directly or indirectly) from a related party (and, for a narrower rule, whether the
related party was able to deduct insurance premiums paid to the CFC), (ii) whether the parties to the
insurance contract or the risks insured were located outside the CFC jurisdiction, (iii) whether the CFC had
sufficient substance to assume and manage the risks on its own accord, and (iv) whether the CFC was
overcapitalised.
105. Existing CFC rules generally treat sales and services income as active, but this treatment creates
problems, which are exacerbated in the digital economy, in at least two contexts: (i) invoicing companies
and (ii) IP income. In the context of invoicing companies, which earn sales and services income for goods
and services that they have purchased from related parties and to which they have added little or no value,
treating sales and services income as active allows groups to shift their income into CFCs engaged in
invoicing activities and escape taxation even though the CFCs have not themselves added any value. In the
context of IP income, income from IP that was shifted into the CFC and to which the CFC has added little
to no value is often re-characterised as sales and services income and again escapes CFC inclusion. In
order to prevent these outcomes, rules often only treat sales and services income as active if it was not
earned from a related party and if the CFC had the substance required to produce the goods or provide the
43
services. With regards to the first requirement, CFC rules can define related parties in at least three ways.
Sales or services income earned from a related party can include only income actually paid by a related
party, it could include that income and income from the sale of a good originally purchased from a related
party, or it could be even broader and include all of that income and also include income from goods that
were developed in conjunction with a related party.
106. CFC rules could therefore treat sales and services income as active unless the income was earned
from a related party or the CFC lacked the substance to earn the income itself. However, this rule would
still require CFC rules to distinguish between sales and services income and IP income, and, as suggested
below, that distinction is one of the most difficult issues facing CFC rules. CFC rules may therefore be
more effective if they eliminate the distinction between sales and services income and IP income and treat
all sales and services income as passive unless the CFC had engaged in the substantial activities (including
the development of the IP) required to earn the income. Although this would be a very broad approach, it
would address one of the main challenges facing existing CFC rules, which is how to differentiate between
IP income and sales and services income, and it would mean that taxpayers could no longer avoid CFC
taxation by treating IP income as sales and services income.
107. As mentioned above, one of the most difficult types of income to attribute accurately is income
earned from IP. This includes income earned from digital goods and services. Although the digital
economy cannot generally be defined separately from other parts of the economy, one trait is that the value
of digital goods and services is typically due to intellectual property. 50 In the context of both general IP
income and digital goods and services, there is not always an identifiable IP asset, but income earned in
both contexts is typically due to IP of some sort. Income from digital goods and services is therefore not a
separate category of income but rather a subset of IP income.
108. IP income produces at least four particular challenges for CFC rules:
• IP income is particularly easy to disguise because it can be exploited and distributed in many
different forms, all of which may have different formalistic classifications under the CFC rules of
different countries. For instance, income from IP could be embedded in income from sales and
therefore treated as active sales income under the CFC rules of different countries.
• IP assets underlying IP income are highly mobile, which makes it easier for the income to be
diverted from the location where the value of the IP asset was created.
• IP assets are also hard to value because there are generally no exact comparables, and the cost
base of these assets is often an inaccurate measure of the income they can generate.
• Income that is directly earned from the underlying IP asset is often difficult to separate from the
income that is earned from associated services or products.
109. These challenges mean that neither a form-based analysis nor a substance analysis may be able to
accurately attribute IP income because a form-based analysis can be circumvented by manipulating formal
classifications and a substance-based approach may lead to under-inclusion if it excludes all of a CFC’s
income once the CFC has engaged in a fixed amount of activities, even if the CFC could not itself have
generated all the income since it did not contribute to the value of the underlying IP. As highlighted above
one of the fundamental concerns with IP income is that, because IP itself is highly mobile, the value of the
50
The discussion of CFC rules and the digital economy builds on the work done by the Task Force on the
Digital Economy.
44
IP can be developed in one jurisdiction (often the parent jurisdiction) and then shifted out of that
jurisdiction to a related party in order to earn income in a low-tax jurisdiction. The development activities
that created the actual value of the IP are therefore not carried out by the CFC, but the CFC receives the
income generated by the IP. A further concern is that IP income can be easily disguised so that payments
for the use of IP can be presented as sales or services income in order to avoid CFC rules. This
combination of highly mobile assets and the difficulty of identifying all IP income means that current CFC
rules face significant challenges in accurately identifying and attributing this income.
110. Some existing CFC rules treat royalties as passive, but given the challenges above this will not by
itself accurately attribute all IP income. Other CFC rules focus on whether the CFC had the required
activities to develop the IP, and some proposed rules have suggested that there should be a special rule for
IP that looks at whether the IP was developed with a related party and whether the CFC made a substantial
contribution to the IP. To effectively attribute IP income, CFC rules could consider both whether the
income was earned from a related party (including whether it was earned for IP developed with a related
party) and whether the CFC carried out the required activities to develop the IP underlying the asset. This
would still require distinguishing between IP income and other income, however, and this distinction
creates many of the challenges above. CFC rules may therefore be more effective if they apply just one
rule to sales and services income and IP income that would treat all sales, services, royalty, and other IP
income as passive unless the CFC had engaged in the substantial activities required to earn the income.
11. How can CFC rules accurately attribute income that raises concerns about BEPS (i) in a business that is
licensed under an appropriate regulatory body and is market-facing in a particular jurisdiction, (ii) in a
reinsurance business carried on by a CFC of a multinational insurance group or (iii) in a “captive” insurance
business of a CFC that is not part of an insurance group? Are there practical problems with current rules that
distinguish between (ii) and (iii)? If so, what are they and how can they be dealt with?
12. Are there practical problems with applying the same rule to sales and services income and IP income?
13. Are there existing CFC rules that accurately attribute any or all of these categories of income while also
reducing administrative and compliance burdens?
14. Does the discussion above consider all categories of income that should be attributed under CFC rules?
111. The above section described in general terms how the five main types of income could be attributed
under CFC rules. This section sets out two different approaches that jurisdictions could use to accurately
attribute income earned by a CFC. These approaches could be combined so that, for example, the IP income
test in the first approach could be replaced by the second approach if jurisdictions prefer the latter.
A. Categorical approach
112. Some existing CFC rules have separate rules for different types of income, and this approach
builds on these rules and has one rule for dividends, another rule for interest, and separate rules for other
types of income. If jurisdictions adopt this approach, they could have rules similar to those discussed
above. The rules would therefore set out the following treatment:
• Dividend income – Dividend income earned by a CFC will generally be treated as passive (and
therefore included) unless the dividend was received from a company that was engaged in an
active trade or business that produced active income (or, if the company received partly active
income and partly passive income, then only the proportion of the dividend that represents the
proportion of active income to the company’s overall income will be excluded) or the CFC itself
45
was engaged in the active trade or business of dealing in securities. If dividend income is
generally exempt from taxation, this exemption will continue to apply to any dividends that would
have been exempt if they had been earned by the parent company.
• Interest and other financing income - Interest and other financing income earned by a CFC will
generally be treated as passive (and therefore included) unless the CFC had the required
substance to earn the income itself and the CFC was not overcapitalised.
• Insurance income – Income from insurance will generally be treated as active (and therefore
excluded) unless (1) the income was derived from contracts or policies with a related party or (2)
the parties to the insurance contract or the risks insured were located outside the CFC
jurisdiction. However, income from insurance that falls under these two exceptions will only be
treated as passive (and therefore included) if the CFC was overcapitalised or did not have
sufficient substance to assume and manage the risks on its own accord. 51
• Sales, services, royalties, and IP income – Income from sales, services, royalties, and IP will
generally be treated as passive (and therefore included) unless the CFC had the required
substance to earn the income itself.
113. The advantages and disadvantages of the categorical approach are set out below:
• Advantages:
− The categorical approach allows jurisdictions to tailor their rules so that each type of income
is treated accurately. This may make it easier for jurisdictions that already have CFC rules to
modify their rules to incorporate certain reforms that apply only to certain types of income.
− Because it is targeted and does not require a distinction to be made between sales and
services and IP income, the categorical approach should accurately attribute income in the
ways discussed in Section II.
• Disadvantages:
− The categorical approach requires taxpayers and jurisdictions to categorise income in order to
determine whether it is attributable. By combining sales and services income and IP income,
however, this approach significantly reduces this disadvantage, but it does bring a greater
range of activities within the ambit of CFC rules.
− As the categorical approach depends in many cases on a substance analysis for accurate
attribution, it requires jurisdictions to design and implement an effective substance analysis.
As discussed in Section I, substance analyses vary in their effectiveness and the
administrative and compliance burdens that they create, so this disadvantage depends on each
jurisdiction’s choice of substance analysis.
114. This categorical approach is not dissimilar to a traditional CFC rule that combines a form-based
analysis with a substance analysis, and jurisdictions could achieve similar outcomes to the categorical
approach by applying it as a two-step approach. In this version of the categorical approach, the first step
51
However, as mentioned earlier, jurisdictions, particularly those that are not Member States of the EU, can
implement CFC rules that apply more broadly and attribute insurance income even when the CFC did not
engage in the insurance activity itself.
46
would require jurisdictions to divide income into formal categories. These could be the categories listed
below, and jurisdictions could include more categories, such as rents or other income.
115. The second step would then apply a substance analysis to the categories applied in the first step.
This second step may not be necessary in all cases if jurisdictions identify certain types of income that are
clearly passive and that do not need a substance-based prove-out. 52 The result of applying the two steps
would be as follows:
− Passive income will be included in CFC income unless the CFC can meet the requirements
of a substance analysis. This could be one of the three substance analyses described in
Section I.
− Active income will be excluded from CFC income unless the CFC cannot meet the
requirements of a substance analysis. This could be one of the three substance analyses
described in Section I. These exceptions would not apply to dividend income. 53
116. This two-step version of the categorical approach would arrive at the same results as those
reached under the first version of the categorical approach described above, but it makes it clear that
jurisdictions could add categories to the first step to attribute income that falls outside those considered in
this discussion draft.
117. Another approach to defining income could be an excess profits approach. This could involve a
simpler and more mechanical approach than the categorical approach referred to above, and could also be
52
Note that Member States of the European Union may not be able to eliminate the second step.
53
The substance analysis in the second step could be combined with other tests discussed earlier such as
related party tests or source jurisdiction tests.
47
used to deal with embedded IP. If such an approach were targeted at specific income, such as IP then
jurisdictions could choose to implement an excess profits approach alongside other, more traditional CFC
rules.
118. An excess profits approach is intended to target situations that give rise to BEPS by
characterising as CFC income excess profits in low tax jurisdictions. Such an approach could be relevant in
the context of IP income as, in some cases, taxpayers cannot expect to earn a profit in excess of the normal
returns from simply purchasing and selling and providing services or manufacturing, unless those activities
involve the use of IP. In certain situations, intangibles and risk-shifting transactions among related parties
could be susceptible to systematic mispricing, leading to a profit in excess of the normal returns that would
not occur if the same transactions were undertaken with unrelated parties. This should mean that, even
without any restrictions, an excess profits approach will tend to apply to income from intangibles and risk
shifting.
119. To improve the targeting and ensure that the excess profits approach was limited to such income,
jurisdictions could include a specific entry criterion so that the excess profits approach would only apply in
situations in which the CFC made use of intangible property acquired from or developed by or with the
assistance of a related party. Alternatively, this approach could be combined with a prove-out under which
the excess profits approach would apply to all CFCs unless they could show that they did not make use of
any intangible property acquired from or developed by or with the assistance of a related party. If either of
these provisions were included, intangible property would be defined broadly to mean something which is
not a physical asset or a financial asset, which is capable of being owned or controlled for use in
commercial activities, and which increases the value received by the company, over and above normal
returns. Under this definition, intangible property should include intangibles that are not legally protected,
such as trade secrets, know-how, customer lists, management systems, networks, data, goodwill, and other
similar items.
120. With or without an entry criterion or prove-out, an excess profits approach could address a
number of the challenges outlined in Section I. In particular, it would not rely on formal classification to
determine whether income was included; it would not be necessary to consider where or from whom
income was earned; 54 and it should not lead to swamping. This approach could, however, raise other
concerns. These include whether the approach could target BEPS income with sufficient accuracy and the
quantification of the normal return. The advantages and disadvantages of this approach are discussed
below.
121. There are different views on the excess profits approach. The differences arise because some
countries believe that an excess profits approach will include income irrespective of whether it arises from
genuine economic activity of the CFC and where there is appropriate substance. Other countries believe
that excluding a normal return on eligible equity is an effective method for identifying CFC income. The
focus of this discussion has been on the role of a substance-based exclusion.
122. An excess profits approach must calculate the “normal return” and then subtract this normal
return from the income earned by the CFC. The difference is the excess return, all of which is treated as
CFC income. An excess profits approach could follow the steps below. Note that transfer pricing rules
would apply prior to the application of the excess profits approach, so this would only apply to income that
remained after transfer pricing rules had been applied.
54
This approach could, however, be combined with a source country rule, which would allow income that
was earned from the market of the CFC jurisdiction (e.g., from customers in the CFC jurisdiction or for
services provided in the CFC jurisdiction) to be excluded from the excess profits calculation.
48
• Determination of normal return – In this context, the normal return means the return that a
normal investor would expect to make with respect to an equity investment. This normal return
could be calculated using the following formula:
− This formula requires a determination, first, of what rate of return to use and, second, of how
to calculate eligible equity.
Rate of return
− In terms of rate of return, normal investors are unlikely to accept a risk-free rate of
return with respect to an investment with an uncertain income stream. The normal
rate of return with respect to an equity investment therefore should be a risk-
inclusive rate of return that equals the risk-free rate of return plus a premium
reflecting the risk associated with an equity investment. 55
− The risk-free rate of return varies by country, and it can generally be calculated by
reference to an average of the government bond rate over several years. Although it
may at first appear sensible to use the risk-free rate of return in the CFC jurisdiction,
the principle underlying CFC rules is that the parent company has the influence to
determine where the CFC is located (and whether income is shifted to it). The parent
company is therefore likely to make its investment decisions based on the rate of
return in the parent jurisdiction. The risk-free rate of return used to calculate the
risk-inclusive rate of return could therefore be based on that in the parent
jurisdiction.
− The equity premium represents the additional expected return an investor requires in
order to be compensated for the uncertainty of the return from a particular
investment. Economic analysis has not conclusively determined what an appropriate
equity premium would be, but it varies across industries and depends on the leverage
of the company, and it is often calculated as being between 3% and 7%.
1. A set percentage such as 10%. This would be simpler than any of the
following approaches, but it may be less accurate.
55
There are arguments that a risk-free rate of return may be more appropriate in certain tax systems (e.g., in
the context of a symmetric income tax in a domestic tax system or worldwide system of taxation).
49
more accurate for individual groups than either of the above two options, but
it could be more complex for tax administrators and unlisted companies than
using a fixed percentage.
Eligible equity
− Eligible equity raises two questions: what equity should be included, and how
should that equity be calculated? In response to the first question, as the excess
profits approach is intended to provide an exemption for normal returns from assets
used in connection with the actual functions carried out in a low-tax jurisdiction,
then only equity invested in assets used in the active conduct of a trade or business,
including IP assets, should be treated as eligible equity. As income subject to
taxation under other CFC rules in the parent jurisdiction would not be included in
total returns, jurisdictions could exclude from eligible equity any equity invested in
assets that produced income that had been subject to taxation under other CFC rules
in the parent jurisdiction.
− In terms of how to calculate the equity invested in the assets above, one option
would be to use the book value of eligible assets less the liabilities apportioned to
the eligible equity. Book value may sometimes be a more accurate measure than
historic costs, but in other cases, assets are expensed as they are created and
therefore not recognised on the balance sheet at all. Another option would be to use
tax basis or tax acquisition cost for the valuation, as determined under the law of the
parent jurisdiction. Liabilities would need to be apportioned, most likely based on
relative asset values or earnings, potentially with the ability to trace liabilities
associated with non-recourse debt.
• Calculation of excess profits – In this step, the normal returns calculated in the previous step
would be subtracted from all income earned by the CFC that was not subject to taxation under
other CFC rules in the parent jurisdiction. The excess would then be included in CFC income.
• Substance-based exclusion – As mentioned above, countries have different views on the role of a
substance-based exclusion. Some countries believe a mechanical excess profits approach can be
easier to administer and effectively targets the income that gives rise to BEPS concerns. These
countries believe that it is not necessary to combine the excess profits approach with any other
exclusion 56, although jurisdictions could choose to adopt some form of exclusion, if desired.57
However, other countries consider that some design features of the excess profits approach could
56
Some countries also believe that form-based analyses do not need to be combined with an exclusion.
57
Other types of exclusions could include a prove-out that would allow a CFC to show that it did not make
use of IP acquired from or developed by or with the assistance of a related party.
50
attribute profits that were not shifted. These countries believe that it is necessary to address the
over-inclusion associated with the mechanical application of this approach. One way to achieve
this would be to combine the excess profits approach with a substance-based exclusion.
Moreover, most Member States of the European Union would consider that a form of substance-
based exclusion would be needed to ensure that the excess profits approach complies with EU
law.
123. For an example of how the excess profits approach would work, imagine that Sub B, located in
Country B, is a wholly owned subsidiary of Parent, which is located in Country A. Sub B uses its
manufacturing facilities in Country B to manufacture and distribute Product B, which uses IP purchased
from Parent. In Year 1, Sub B spent 600,000 to purchase the rights to IP developed by Parent, and Sub B
also invested a total of 500,000 in its manufacturing facilities. For book purposes, the acquisition of the IP
and the investment in manufacturing facilities result in assets on the balance sheet with a value equal to the
acquisition costs. Both the IP and the manufacturing facilities are used in Sub B’s active trade or business
of manufacturing and distributing Product B. In Year 2, Sub B earned 700,000 in profits from sales of
Product B. 58 To determine whether Sub B has attributable income, the excess profits approach would
calculate normal returns using the following formula:
124. If the rate of return for the excess profits approach had been set at 10%, then that formula would
show that the normal return was 110,000 per year. (This is because 110,000 = 10% x (600,000 + 500,000.)
The excess returns would then be calculated by subtracting 110,000 from Sub B’s profits. Sub B’s excess
returns for Year 2 would therefore be 590,000, and all of this income would be treated as attributable
income.
125. The above discussion sets out one method for calculating normal returns, but jurisdictions could
adopt different methods to calculate normal returns and identify excess profits which would be subject to
CFC taxation. In addition, some countries may also want to tax normal returns which arose from BEPS if
they were not taxed elsewhere. The advantages and disadvantages of the excess profits approach are set out
below:
• Advantages:
− The excess profits approach (when not combined with a substance-based exclusion) involves
a simpler and more mechanical approach than that required by a substance analysis.
− The excess profits approach responds to the observation of some economists that most
revenue loss from profit shifting results from shifting out of high-tax countries the
supernormal returns that accrue to IP and risk.
− Where swamping is a concern under an activity-based exception, the excess profits approach
is a mechanical approach (when not combined with a substance-based exclusion) that would
prevent swamping because taxpayers cannot rely on such exceptions to shelter IP-related
income simply by locating a minimal level of activities in a jurisdiction.
− The excess profits approach may respond to the concern of many jurisdictions that existing
CFC rules may not attribute the supernormal returns earned from IP.
58
For ease of calculation, this example assumes that there are no liabilities apportioned to the manufacturing
facilities.
51
− The excess profits approach also addresses concerns about manipulation of formal
classifications because it is not a form-based analysis. Where CFC rules rely on defining and
identifying sufficient levels of activity, or determinations of substance, such features have
created significant difficulties for some tax administrators. In contrast, an excess profits
approach would use mechanical criteria to identify the low-taxed excess profits that would be
subject to tax.
− Assuming the normal return is a proxy for the expected return from active operations absent
the presence of intangibles, the excess profits approach is targeted at supernormal returns,
including returns from the mispricing of intangibles or the inappropriate separation of
functions from risk. To the extent the approach captures the mispricing of intangibles or the
inappropriate separation of function from risk, the approach is consistent with the purpose of
CFC rules.
− The excess profits approach also appears to deal with the problem of IP cash boxes in low-tax
jurisdictions, which is fundamental to the BEPS Action Plan.
• Disadvantages:
− Without a substance-based exclusion, some countries believe that the excess profits approach
will not focus only on shifted income and will not meet the BEPS aim of ensuring that profits
are taxed where the economic activities giving rise to them took place. As with other
approaches, the excess profits approach uses a proxy to identify shifted income, and it may
therefore be both over-inclusive and under-inclusive. This is because the normal return, as
defined, may not approximate the return that the CFC’s assets and activities would
necessarily generate in the absence of BEPS.
− Some countries believe that absence of a substance-based exemption would lead to a shift
away from the traditional approach of excluding active income or income from value-creating
activities.
− As normal returns are not subject to taxation under an excess profits approach if it is applied
as a stand-alone rule, this approach could potentially create incentives to shift normal returns
to a CFC in order to escape taxation. However, given that normal returns are defined by
reference to equity invested in active assets, this disadvantage may not be unique to an excess
profits approach.
− It is difficult to value the various assets in order to calculate eligible equity. If book value is
used, the outcome could be manipulated by transferring assets, and the normal return may
overall be inaccurately low. If only certain types of assets give rise to eligible equity,
intragroup arrangements could be used to generate those types of assets, and it may be
difficult to determine which assets fit the definition of eligible assets.
− If the excess profits approach is combined with a substance-based exclusion, it will be less
simple and mechanical as the exclusion will add the related complexities of a substance-based
analysis.
− An entry criterion that narrows the scope of the excess profits approach may raise classification
issues and could mean that it does not attribute all the income that raises BEPS concerns.
52
Questions for consultation
15. Is it clear how the two approaches above would work? If not, what further detail is required to clarify the
approach?
16. What practical problems arise with applying the categorical approach and the excess profits approach?
17. How could the practical problems be addressed or mitigated?
18. Which approach is most likely to accurately attribute income that gives rise to BEPS concerns? Is one
approach likely to be more effective than the other in terms of dealing with IP income?
19. Could the excess profits approach be applied to income other than IP income and what would be the
practical implications of this?
20. What other approaches could be considered for determining excess profits or excess returns?
126. Once income has been determined to be within the definition of income to be caught by a CFC
regime, the next question is how CFC rules should attribute that income. Controlled foreign company rules
generally take one of two approaches to this question: the entity approach, which attributes income entity-by-
entity, and the transactional approach, which attributes individual streams of income. Under the entity approach,
an entity that does not earn a certain amount or percentage of attributable income or an entity that engages in
certain activities will be found not to have any attributable income, even if some of its income would be of an
attributable character. 59 Under the transactional approach, in contrast, the character of each stream of income is
assessed to determine whether that stream of income is attributable. The difference between the two approaches
is that, under the entity approach, either all or none of the income will be included depending on whether the
majority falls within the definition of CFC income. Under the transactional approach, some income can still be
included even if the majority does not fall within the definition of CFC income, and some income can be
excluded even if the majority does fall within this definition.
127. Best practices would be to apply a transactional approach that looks at specific income streams
rather than simply focusing on the entity and effectively treating its income as one block as that is likely to
be more accurate at attributing income. However, where countries adopt more mechanical broad-brush
rules, an entity approach may be appropriate in that context.
128. Each of these two approaches has multiple advantages and disadvantages. The entity approach
reduces administrative burdens because, once tax administrations have determined either that a certain
amount of income earned by an entity is attributable or that the entity engaged in a certain activity, CFC
rules are either applicable or not and no further analysis needs to be undertaken. The entity approach could
also reduce taxpayer compliance costs and increase certainty because taxpayers know that they will only
be subject to CFC tax if a significant portion of their income falls within the definition of attributable
income. The entity approach thus reduces the chances that a taxpayer will be subject to CFC rules if CFC
income makes up only a small portion of its overall income. However the main disadvantage of the entity
approach is that, by subjecting either all or none of an entity’s income to CFC rules, it is both over-
inclusive and under-inclusive. An entity that earns enough CFC income will have all its income attributed
(including income that would not otherwise be attributable), while an entity with some income that would
otherwise be included may be able to escape CFC rules by swamping that income with income that is not
59
Although full-inclusion systems can be seen as a version of the entity approach, the difference between
entity and transactional approaches is more appropriately discussed in the context of partial-inclusion
systems since they are both approaches to determining what entities or income will not be included.
53
subject to the CFC rules. For example, an entity that engages primarily in activities that generate active
income may be able to shield a large amount of passive income from CFC rules. 60
129. The transactional approach may increase administrative burdens and compliance costs relative to
the entity approach, and it may require tax administrations to consider a larger group of companies under
their CFC rules, depending on how other elements of those rules are designed. For instance, if CFC rules
set too high a threshold when considering if a CFC is lowly taxed and apply a proportionate substance
analysis, they may bring a large group of companies with the scope of CFC rules and this may be
compounded if they also apply CFC rules on a transactional basis. Despite these disadvantages, the
transactional approach is generally more accurate at attributing income. As a transactional approach
requires consideration of each stream of income to determine whether it falls within the definition of CFC
income it is better able to target specific types of income more effectively than the entity approach. It is
also possible to attribute only that income that raises BEPS concerns, and this greater proportionality
suggests that the transactional approach may be more consistent with both the goals of Action Item 3 and
EU law. 61 Transactional approaches may, however, require a threshold to ensure that active businesses that
hold a cash surplus do not have to treat that cash surplus as CFC income. This threshold could be a bright-
line de minimis threshold. In Australia, for example, none of the income of a CFC is attributed if 5% or
less of that CFC’s income is passive income. Alternatively, CFC rules could require a functional analysis
to determine how much otherwise attributable income is in fact being held as a cash surplus. The first type
of threshold would reduce administrative burdens and compliance costs but may not be accurate in all
situations, while the second type of threshold would be more accurate but would increase administrative
burdens and compliance costs. 62
60
EU Member States may need to consider whether an entity approach is consistent with EU law.
61
Although the ECJ has not yet considered genuine economic activities on a transaction-by-transaction basis,
it appears that CFC rules that attribute income on a transactional basis would be more narrowly focused on
income that raises concerns and therefore may be more consistent with EU law.
62
Some jurisdictions combine these two approaches into a hybrid approach and first determine whether an
entity has a sufficient amount of attributable income to be treated as a CFC before assessing whether
specific items of income are to be attributed. Japan’s CFC rules provide an example of such a hybrid
approach, under which certain entities are excluded from CFC taxation due to the type of income and
activities, but certain streams of income earned by those entities may still be subject to CFC taxation.
Because this approach ultimately considers different streams of income rather than just attributing all the
income of an entity, it is essentially a version of a transactional approach.
54
CHAPTER 6: RULES FOR COMPUTING INCOME
130. This chapter sets out recommendations for the fifth CFC building block on computing income.
Once CFC rules have determined that income is attributable, they must then consider how much income to
attribute and to whom.
I. Recommendations
131. Computing the income of a CFC requires two different determinations: (i) which jurisdiction’s
rules should apply and (ii) whether any specific rules for computing CFC income are necessary. The
recommendation for the first determination is to use the rules of the parent jurisdiction to calculate a CFC’s
income. The recommendation for the second determination is that jurisdictions should have a specific rule
limiting the offset of CFC losses so that they can only be used against the profits of the same CFC or
against the profits of other CFCs in the same jurisdiction.
II. Explanation
132. The first recommendation focuses on rules that are used to calculate taxable income. Four options
were considered to arrive at the first recommendation.
1. One option would be to apply the law of the parent jurisdiction (i.e., the jurisdiction that is
applying the CFC rules), which would be logically consistent with BEPS concerns particularly if
CFC rules focus on the erosion of the parent jurisdiction’s tax base. This option would also
reduce costs for the tax administration. Jurisdictions could achieve a broadly similar outcome by
starting with the income calculated according to the rules of the CFC jurisdiction and then
adjusting the income in line with the rules of the parent jurisdiction.
2. A second option would be to use the CFC jurisdiction’s rules for computing income, but this
would be inconsistent with the goals of Action Item 3 as using the CFC jurisdiction’s rules may
allow for less income to be attributed. This could also create complexity and increase the
administration costs for the tax administration that would have to apply unfamiliar rules.
3. A third option would be to allow taxpayers to choose either jurisdiction’s computational rules,
but this is likely to create opportunities for tax planning.
4. A final option would be to compute income using a common standard. For example, some
jurisdictions instruct taxpayers to use the International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS).
The advantage of this option is that it could in theory lead to international consistency as all
CFCs and parent jurisdictions would be using the same rules for calculating CFC income,
regardless of the residence of either the CFC or the parent. Since most countries do not currently
use such standards when calculating taxable income, however, this option may increase both
administrative and compliance costs if taxpayers have to recalculate the income of the CFC
according to standards that are applied by neither the parent jurisdiction nor the CFC jurisdiction.
55
133. Based on this analysis, the first option is recommended because it is consistent with the goals of
the BEPS Action Plan and it reduces administrative costs.
134. In arriving at the second recommendation, the question of how to treat losses was considered.
Most issues involving losses can be addressed by reference to pre-existing domestic laws in the parent
jurisdiction. 63 These include questions about whether the use of losses should be limited to offset against
profits of a similar character, which would mean that, for example, passive losses of a CFC could only be
used against passive profits if that limit applied in domestic laws on losses.
135. Another issue is whether CFC losses should only be offset against CFC profits or whether they
can also be used against profits in the parent company. Most existing CFC rules only allow the losses of
the CFC to be offset against the profits of CFCs in the same jurisdiction, and this is the recommended
approach since allowing CFC losses to be offset against the profits of parent companies or CFCs in other
jurisdictions could encourage manipulation of losses in the CFC jurisdiction. 64 However this may not be an
issue that is already dealt with in rules that apply in the domestic context, so a separate CFC-specific rule
may be required. A rule that prevents CFC losses being set off against non-CFC profits could apply
alongside a rule that limits the offset of losses to similar types of profits so that passive losses of a CFC
could only be offset against passive profits of that same CFC. Any concerns about over-taxation resulting
from this approach could be mitigated by allowing CFC losses to be carried forwards or backwards for use
against profits arising in other years.
136. The recommendation on loss limitation can be illustrated with the following example. Parent is a
resident in Country A and Sub B is a wholly owned subsidiary in Country B that is a CFC. Country A has
CFC rules. In year 1, Parent earns 1000 and Sub B earns 500 of CFC income. Parent has 200 in losses and
Sub B has 1000 in losses. This is illustrated in Figure 6.
1000 income
Parent
200 losses
Country A
Country B
63
Using domestic law provisions to answer questions about the treatment of specific items such as losses
would create complications if CFC income is generally calculated using the laws of a different jurisdiction
but this is another reason supporting the use of the parent jurisdiction’s rules and the first recommendation
above.
64
Jurisdictions could also implement rules permitting parent company losses to be used against CFC profits.
This situation is less likely to raise BEPS concerns since this would lead to fewer losses in the parent
company and fewer profits in the CFC.
56
137. If Country A’s CFC rules do not limit the losses of Sub B to the income of Sub B, then Parent
will only be taxed on 300 because the full 1200 of losses will be offset against the full 1500 of income. If,
however, Country A’s CFC rules do limit the losses of Sub B to the income of Sub B, then Parent will be
taxed on 800 (1000-200), and no income will be attributed to Parent from Sub B because all of Sub B’s
attributable income will be offset by the losses, and the remaining 500 can be carried forward to be used
against Sub B’s future income. This limit will prevent use of CFCs to reduce the taxable income in the
parent jurisdiction.
138. If Country A already has a rule that limits passive losses to passive income, this rule can be
combined with the recommended loss limitation as shown in Figure 7.
Country A
Country B
139. If all of Parent’s income is passive and all of Parent’s losses are active, while all of Sub B’s
income and losses are passive, Parent would be taxed on 1000 of its income. This is because Parent’s
active losses could not be used against its passive income and because Sub B’s passive losses would offset
all of its passive income, and the excess passive losses could not be used to offset Parent’s income under
the CFC loss limitation rule.
140. Another concern is potential loss importation. This concern could arise if a CFC has losses that
date from before its characterisation as a CFC or if another activity bearing losses is transferred to the CFC
to soak up profits. If losses are only available to be offset against CFC profits then the fact that the CFC
incurred losses in prior years may not be a problem. However, there may be concerns if the activity of the
CFC has changed and there is evidence that either profits or losses have been shifted to the CFC to reduce
the amount of income that is ultimately taxed. Many countries have domestic law provisions designed to
prevent tax avoidance that deal with these situations and these could equally be applied to the CFC’s
computation of income.
24. Do the rules on computing the income of a CFC present any difficulties in practice? If so, what are these
and how could they be dealt with?
25. Does this chapter accurately reflect the issues that could arise with losses or are there any other situations
that need to be considered?
57
CHAPTER 7: RULES FOR ATTRIBUTING INCOME
141. This chapter sets out recommendations for the sixth CFC building block on attributing income.
Once the amount of CFC income has been calculated, the next step is determining how to attribute that income
to the appropriate shareholders in the CFC.
I. Recommendations
142. Income attribution can be broken into five steps: (i) determining which taxpayers should have
income attributed to them, (ii) determining how much income should be attributed, (iii) determining when
the income should be included in the returns of the taxpayers, (iv) determining how the income should be
treated, and (v) determining what tax rate should apply to the income.
i) the attribution threshold should be tied to the minimum control threshold when possible, although
countries can choose to use different attribution and control thresholds depending on the policy
considerations underlying CFC rules.
ii) that the amount of income to be attributed to each shareholder or controlling person should be
calculated by reference to both their proportion of ownership and their actual period of ownership or
influence.
iii) and iv) that jurisdictions can determine when income should be included in taxpayers’ returns and
how it should be treated so that CFC rules operate in a way that is coherent with existing domestic law.
II. Explanation
144. In arriving at the above recommendations, each of the five steps was considered in greater detail.
145. In order to attribute income correctly, jurisdictions must first determine to whom the income is to be
attributed. Many existing CFC rules tie this determination to the earlier determination of control, so that, if a
taxpayer met the minimum control threshold, then that taxpayer would also have income attributed to it. In
jurisdictions that apply a concentrated ownership rule, CFC income is generally attributed not just to taxpayers
who meet the overall control threshold but also to all resident taxpayers who have the minimum level of control
(e.g., 10%) to be considered when calculating whether the control threshold has been met. The benefits of tying
the attribution threshold to the minimum control threshold include administrative simplicity and reduced
compliance burdens. However, using control rules to determine attribution could potentially lead to under-
inclusion if it is believed that a minority ownership could in fact have sufficient influence over the business
65
To limit competitiveness concerns, countries could also consider a top-up tax. This may be more
appropriate where a more approximate or mechanical rule could potentially capture active income.
58
decisions of a CFC to raise BEPS concerns, but this disadvantage can be reduced if the control rules
aggregate the interests of minority shareholders or otherwise do not limit control to majority owners.
146. Some CFC rules may, however, use a different rule to determine which taxpayers have CFC
income attributed to them, based on the theory that the amount of ownership that is sufficient for control
may not be the same as the level that is sufficient for attribution. Jurisdictions that want to deter even
minority investments in CFCs may use a lower attribution threshold, while those that are instead focused
on deterring investments by residents that can influence the CFC may set their attribution threshold higher
than their control threshold, particularly if their control threshold considers concentrated ownership.
Further, CFC rules that look at de facto control or otherwise establish control in a less mechanical way may
need to have different control and attribution tests to ensure that the correct taxpayers have income attributed to
them. Although having separate rules for attribution and control may in theory create additional compliance
costs or administrative burdens, actual attribution of profits may only occur relatively infrequently due to the
deterrent nature of CFC rules. Best practice would therefore be either to tie the attribution threshold to the
control threshold or to use another attribution threshold that attributed income to, at a minimum, taxpayers who
could influence the CFC.
147. Once CFC rules have determined which taxpayers will have income attributed to them, they must
then determine how much of that income to attribute. All existing CFC rules attribute income in proportion to
each taxpayer’s ownership, but they differ in how they treat taxpayers whose ownership lasted for only a portion
of the year. Some jurisdictions attribute the entire portion of income based on ownership on the last day of the
year. Whilst this could lead to inaccurate attribution and could create opportunities for tax planning, this may
accurately capture whether or not the taxpayer was able to influence the CFC if voting or other power is
determined based on ownership on the last day of the year. Other jurisdictions attribute income based on the
period of ownership, which results in taxpayers being taxed on an amount that is similar to their actual share of
the CFC profits. In addition, applying such a rule appears unlikely to add significant compliance costs in
practice. 66 Either of these approaches to determining how much income should be attributed can qualify as best
practice so long as the determination based on the last day of the year accurately captures the taxpayer’s
influence. 67
148. Many existing CFC rules specify that the attributed income must be included in the taxpayer’s taxable
income for the taxable year in which the end of the CFC’s accounting period ends, although some countries
have slightly different rules for determining the year in which the attributed income should be included. Korea’s
CFC rules, for example, state that the attributed income will be included on the return for the taxable year
to which the 60th day from the end of the CFC’s fiscal year belongs. Both approaches seem equally effective
at combatting BEPS, so there is no recommendation for this step and countries are free to adopt provisions that
ensure that CFC rules are coherent with general domestic law provisions.
66
It is assumed that such a rule would attribute income if the taxpayer held an interest in the CFC for a
portion of the year but did not hold that interest on the last day of the year. If not, the recommended rule
could be combined with a rule for imputing CFC income when CFC shares are disposed of in the middle of the
year.
67
One possible way of capturing influence would be to combine a rule that considers ownership on the last
day of the year with reporting requirements on ownership throughout the year.
59
D. How should the income be treated?
149. A further question to be answered when attributing income to taxpayers is how that income will be
treated in the parent jurisdiction. Existing CFC rules take several different approaches, including treating
attributed income as a deemed dividend or treating it as having been earned by the taxpayer directly (i.e., the
CFC is essentially treated as a partnership or flow-through entity but only for the purposes of attributing CFC
income). If attributed income is treated as a deemed dividend, then the tax treatment can build on existing
dividend rules with which taxpayers and tax administrations are already familiar. However jurisdictions may not
want to treat attributed income as a deemed dividend for all tax purposes and therefore the limit of any
“deeming” will need to be made clear. In contrast, treating attributed income as if it were earned directly by
shareholders of the CFC is likely to reduce the need for any separate characterisation rules since the income will
be characterised according to existing domestic rules. Both approaches seem equally appropriate in terms of
dealing with BEPS and therefore the question of how to treat attributed income could be left for jurisdictions to
decide in a manner that is coherent with domestic law.
150. Finally, attribution of income raises the question of how that income is taxed once it is attributed.
Whilst existing CFC rules subject CFC income to taxation at the rate that would apply to the parent company in
the parent jurisdiction, a second option would be to apply a “top-up tax”. A top-up tax, which builds closely on
the concept of a minimum tax, would only subject CFC income to the difference between the tax paid and a set
threshold. This threshold could be tied to the low-tax threshold used to determine whether CFC rules apply to a
given CFC, or it could be an entirely separate threshold. A top-up tax would set a floor for the rate at which
CFC income is taxed.
151. To illustrate how a top-up tax could work, imagine a parent jurisdiction with a flat 30% statutory tax
rate and a CFC rule that applied only to CFCs that were subject to an effective tax rate of less than 12%. If the
parent jurisdiction applied a top-up tax to a CFC that was subject to a 0% effective tax rate, it would only tax the
CFC income at 12%, instead of its normal rate of 30%. This approach could mean that MNCs located in higher-
tax jurisdictions with CFC rules would not be at a competitive disadvantage relative to MNCs located in some
lower-tax jurisdictions. However, they would remain at a competitive disadvantage compared to both MNCs
located in jurisdictions with CFC rules but with a tax rate below the top-up tax rate and MNCs located in
jurisdictions without CFC rules. It would also in theory be consistent with the principle of targeting those CFC
structures most likely to represent base erosion and profit shifting. However, the top-up tax would not
necessarily eliminate incentives to shift profits away from higher tax jurisdictions. For instance, in the example
above, MNCs located in the parent jurisdiction would have a considerable incentive to shift their income into
the CFC jurisdiction because the maximum rate at which they would be taxed on their CFC income would be
12%, so 18% lower than the rate that would apply if their income were earned in the parent jurisdiction.
Consequently using a top-up tax rate instead of the main tax rate could reduce the deterrent effect of CFC rules.
The top-up tax also may not be consistent with CFC rules designed to achieve broader policy goals or to address
deferral more generally, and it may add some complexity to the tax rules of the parent jurisdiction.
152. The top-up tax may therefore not be appropriate in all situations, but it could be seen as a middle way
that would enable jurisdictions to address some degree of competitiveness concerns. If the level set for the top-
up tax rate was the same as that as the low-tax threshold, it may also make CFC rules more internally consistent.
26. What difficulties, if any, arise under existing CFC provisions for attributing income?
27. Does the description of a top-up tax set out all the advantages and disadvantages of such an approach?
60
CHAPTER 8: RULES TO PREVENT OR ELIMINATE DOUBLE TAXATION
153. This chapter sets out recommendations for the seventh and final CFC building block on rules to
prevent or eliminate double taxation. As discussed in Chapter 1, one of the fundamental policy
considerations raised by CFC rules is how to ensure that these rules do not lead to double taxation, which
could pose an obstacle to international competitiveness, growth and economic development.
I. Recommendations
154. Jurisdictions are primarily concerned with at least three situations where double taxation may
arise: (i) situations where the attributed CFC income is also subject to foreign corporate taxes,
(ii) situations where CFC rules in more than one jurisdiction apply to the same CFC income, and
(iii) situations where a CFC actually distributes dividends out of income that has already been attributed to
its resident shareholders under the CFC rules or a resident shareholder disposes of the shares in the CFC.
However, double taxation concerns could arise in other situations, for instance where there has been a
transfer pricing adjustment between two jurisdictions and a CFC charge arises in a third jurisdiction. 68
155. The recommendation for addressing the first two situations is to allow a credit for foreign taxes
actually paid, including CFC tax assessed on intermediate companies. The recommendation for addressing
the third situation is to exempt dividends and gains on disposition of CFC shares from taxation if the
income of the CFC has previously been subject to CFC taxation, but the precise treatment of such
dividends and gains can be left to individual jurisdictions so that provisions are coherent with domestic
law.
II. Explanation
156. Generally, relief for double taxation can be granted in three different ways, all of which were
considered in arriving at the above recommendations. These three approaches allow the resident
shareholder (i) to set off the foreign tax against residence tax (credit method), (ii) to deduct the foreign tax
as a business expense (deduction method) or (iii) to reduce the attributable CFC income by the amount that
has already been subject to regular corporate taxation in another jurisdiction (exemption method). These
three approaches were considered in the context of each of the three situations outlined above, and they are
described briefly below.
157. Perhaps the most obvious situation where the application of CFC rules may lead to double
taxation is the one mentioned above under point (i) above, where the CFC income is subject to corporate
taxes in the CFC jurisdiction as well as to CFC taxation in the parent or controlling parties’ jurisdiction.
158. Most jurisdictions address the situation where the CFC income is subject to taxation in both the
CFC jurisdiction and the parent jurisdiction by providing for an indirect foreign tax credit that credits taxes
68
In certain circumstances, the interaction of CFC rules and transfer pricing rules could give rise to double
taxation issues. Whilst such circumstances may not be common, it is important that countries rules contain
provisions to eliminate any double taxation that would otherwise result.
61
that were incurred by a different taxpayer. This approach eliminates double taxation more comprehensively
than the deduction method as it directly sets off the foreign tax against domestic tax rather than reducing
the tax base to which the residence tax applies. Given that the purpose of a CFC regime is to assert taxing
rights over income that has been shifted to a low or no tax jurisdiction, the exemption method is not an
appropriate method for granting relief in this context since it would undermine the application of CFC
rules. An indirect foreign tax credit is generally limited to the amount of effective double taxation. This is
addressed in most countries’ rules by limiting relief to the lesser of the domestic tax or the foreign tax
actually paid. The focus on the actual tax paid ensures that relief is not given if the foreign tax is subject to
a refund or reimbursement claim.
159. Additional issues may arise when the income and profits arising in a CFC are taxed under the
CFC rules operating in more than one jurisdiction, and this scenario may become more common after the
publication of the final report on Action Item 3. If, for example, a subsidiary is treated as a CFC under the
rules operating in multiple jurisdictions, then the subsidiary’s income could potentially be taxed by the
CFC jurisdiction and by any other jurisdiction that considers the subsidiary to be a CFC. Again an indirect
foreign tax credit could be applied in this situation but in order to provide such a credit countries may need
to change their double taxation relief provisions in order for CFC tax paid in an intermediate country to
qualify as a foreign tax eligible for relief. There should also be a hierarchy of rules to determine which
countries should have priority, and this hierarchy could prioritise the CFC rules of the jurisdiction whose
resident shareholder is closer to the CFC in the chain of ownership.
A Parent
Country A
B Sub
Country B
Country C
C Sub Income
161. In this situation, C Sub is both a direct CFC of B Sub and an indirect CFC of A Parent, and B Sub
is also a CFC of A Parent. If both Country A and Country B have CFC rules, there must be a rule hierarchy
to determine which country’s CFC rules will apply first.
62
162. Figure 8 could raise two different issues, depending on the tax rates of Country A and Country B.
If Country C has a tax rate of 10%, Country B has a tax rate of 20%, and Country A has a tax rate of 30%,
then both Country B and Country A will want to collect their full amount of tax, potentially only giving a
credit for Country C’s tax. If the income of C Sub is 100, this would mean that Country A would want to
collect 20 (i.e., 30 minus 10) and Country B would want to collect 10 (i.e., 20 minus 10). The rule
hierarchy suggested above, where Country B’s rules apply prior to Country A’s rules, would require that
Country A provide a tax credit for taxes paid to both Country C and Country B. This would mean that
Country C would collect 10, Country B would collect 10 (i.e., 20 minus 10), and Country A would also
collect 10 (i.e., 30 minus 20).
163. If, in contrast, Country C still has a tax rate of 10% and Country A still has a tax rate of 30%, but
Country B has a tax rate of 40%, then Country A would no longer collect any taxes if it granted a tax credit
for taxes paid to Country B. Although this may raise concerns from the perspective of Country A, this is
likely to be consistent with the principle underlying Country A’s CFC rules as C Sub would be fully taxed
on its income at a tax rate greater than that in Country A. Also, if Country B has a tax rate that is higher
than the tax rate in Country A, it is less likely that the tax base that has been eroded is that of Country A. It
is more likely that in this situation, if it were to exist, it would be Country B’s tax base that was being
eroded. It would therefore be appropriate for Country A not to apply its CFC rules if the profits of C Sub
are taxed at an equivalent or higher effective tax rate in the jurisdiction of an intermediate party. The
recommended rule hierarchy in both situations is therefore for Country A to apply its CFC rules only after
Country B has applied its CFC rules (or to provide a credit for CFC taxes paid to Country B, which may be
simpler).
164. The third situation in which CFC taxation could lead to double taxation is where (1) the CFC
actually makes distributions out of the CFC income or (2) resident taxpayers of a CFC dispose of their
CFC shares. With regards to the first scenario, most jurisdictions provide some type of relief for
subsequent dividends paid by a CFC. In the majority of these jurisdictions, the dividends will qualify for
the regular participation exemption for foreign dividends. If CFC rules require a level of control that is at
least equal to the same percentage of shareholding as the participation exemption, then the participation
exemption is likely to apply. Therefore an additional relief provision will only be necessary if there is no
participation exemption or the participation exemption does not apply. In these cases, most jurisdictions
apply a separate provision that also exempts the dividends even if they do not qualify for the normal
participation exemption (or if there is no general participation exemption).
165. There may however be difficulties with the exemption method if only part of the CFC income has
been attributed to a resident taxpayer or if a CFC is indirectly held through another non-resident company
which does not have attributable CFC income. In these cases it may be hard to determine whether
dividends have, in fact, been paid out of attributed CFC income and are therefore subject to double
taxation. To address these difficulties, countries tend to adopt relatively mechanical approaches that
assume that dividends are likely to have been paid out of previously attributed CFC income. These
approaches include, for example, limiting the dividend exemption to the amount of profits generated by the
CFC during the tax years when CFC rules have applied.
166. A further issue that arises with regards to the first scenario occurs when the CFC jurisdiction
applies withholding taxes when the dividend is paid out. Since these withholding taxes represent income
taxation at the level of the CFC jurisdiction, it may be appropriate to provide a refund for CFC taxes paid
equal to the amount of withholding tax if the dividend was paid out of profits that were subject to CFC tax,
since this would essentially be equal to a credit had the CFC jurisdiction imposed tax on the income itself.
63
167. With regards to the second scenario, double taxation may also arise where the shares of a CFC
are disposed of and the taxpayer holding the shares has previously been taxed on undistributed income of
the CFC. Following the logic above in respect of dividends, countries may choose not to tax subsequent
gains realised by a taxpayer in respect of the shares of a CFC to the extent that the same amounts have
previously been taxed under CFC rules operating in the taxpayer’s jurisdiction. However, given countries’
different approaches to taxing gains on assets, the mechanism for providing relief is likely to vary to
accommodate the specific tax features in each jurisdiction, and this recommendation does not mean that
countries that do not otherwise exempt gains on disposition should change their overall rules to comply
with this recommendation for CFC rules.
168. The discussion draft recognises that double taxation can also arise in other ways, for instance
through the interaction of CFC rules and transfer pricing rules. These are not new issues but countries will
need to consider whether their existing double taxation relief provisions are effective in relieving all
instances of double tax. 69
69
For example Parent A resident in Country A owns two subsidiaries, Sub B resident in Country B and Sub
C resident in Country C. A transfer pricing adjustment is made between B and C resulting in higher profits
in C. If Country A applies its CFC rules to both B and C it will need to give relief for the reduced foreign
tax paid in B and the increased tax paid in C. In practice it seems more likely that where there are transfer
pricing adjustments they will decrease the profits of a CFC and increase the profits of a more highly taxed
subsidiary that is outside the scope of CFC rules. Therefore countries will need to be aware of any
subsequent adjustments to the tax paid by a CFC to ensure that they do not provide relief for tax that has
been repaid.
64
ANNEX I – DE MINIMIS THRESHOLDS
United … do not exceed 50,000 GBP, or do not exceed De minimis does not apply, if:
Kingdom 500,000 GBP and non-trading profits do not • one of main purposes of an arrangement
exceed 50,000 GBP. The threshold relates to is to secure the low profit exemption or
both total taxable and accounting profits. • CFC provides UK intermediary services
or
• low profit is result of hybrid arrangement
United States … is less than the lesser of 5% of the total Anti-fragmentation rule with rebuttable
gross income of the CFC or 1,000,000 $. presumption that treats income of multiple CFCs
as single entity income if CFCs are related.
65
ANNEX II - LOW TAXATION THRESHOLDS
Finland ETR of CFC less than 3/5 of ETR had the CFC income been Grey list consisting of tax treaty countries
calculated in accordance with Finnish GAAP and tax rules excluding EU Member States where the
foreign tax is on average lower than 75% of
the statutory tax rate in Finland or where
tax incentives are applied.
France The amount of tax paid by the CFC less than 50% of the N/A
amount of tax that would have been paid under French rules.
Germany ETR of CFC less than fixed rate of 25% N/A
Japan ETR of CFC is less than fixed rate of 20% N/A
Korea ETR of CFC does not exceed fixed tax rate of 15% N/A
Mexico ETR of CFC is less than 75% of Mexico's statutory tax rate N/A
Norway ETR of CFC is less than 2/3 of ETR had the CFC income been Black list for countries that are considered
calculated in accordance with Norwegian tax rules low tax countries; white list countries
excluded from CFC application, unless
CFC primarily income from dividends and
capital gains from low tax countries
70
The determination of the low tax threshold is based on a comparison between either a fixed rate or a portion of the effective tax rate had the attributable
income been calculated in accordance with the rules in the jurisdiction applying the CFC rules.
71
Most jurisdictions calculate the ETR of the CFC by dividing the tax amount paid by the CFC through the CFC income calculated in accordance with
the rules of the parent/shareholder’s jurisdiction. At least one jurisdiction uses as a starting point the tax base as calculated under the tax law of the CFC
jurisdiction and, then, makes necessary adjustments according to its own tax rules.
66
Country Determination of low taxation threshold 70 White list/black list as a
communication tool
Spain ETR of CFC is less than 75% of ETR had the CFC income N/A
been calculated in accordance with Spanish tax rules
Sweden ETR of CFC is less than 55% of ETR had the CFC income Different lists based on whether a country
been calculated in accordance with Swedish rules has (1) ordinary tax system or not or (2)
has ordinary tax system, but certain income
is subject to preferential tax rate
United Kingdom ETR of CFC is less than 75% of ETR had the CFC income White list in form of an excluded territory
been calculated in accordance with UK tax rules exemption broadly includes countries with
a headline tax rate of more than 75% of the
main UK corporation tax rate, provided
their income within certain categories does
not exceed the greater of 10% of the
company's pre-tax profits or 50,000 GBP
and provided that certain other conditions
are met.
Country
67
ANNEX III - DEFINITIONS OF INSURANCE INCOME
68
ANNEX IV - QUESTIONS FOR CONSULTATION
1. Would any particular practical issues arise from treating transparent entities as separate entities in
the cases listed above? If so, what are they and how could they be dealt with?
2. Should the recommendations consider any other issues related to determining which entities
could be considered to be CFCs?
3. Are there any practical problems with either the narrow or the broad version of the modified
hybrid mismatch rule mentioned above?
4. What practical problems, if any, arise when applying a low-tax threshold based on an effective
tax rate calculation?
5. How could these problems be addressed or mitigated?
6. Does the discussion above correctly address the situation of permanent establishments that are
subject to a different tax rate than CFCs?
9. What are the practical problems with any of the three substance analyses set out above? How
could these practical problems be dealt with?
10. Do you have experience with applying substance analyses in existing CFC rules? If so, how can
these be made more mechanical while still accurately attributing income?
11. How can CFC rules accurately attribute income that raises concerns about BEPS (i) in a business
that is licensed under an appropriate regulatory body and is market-facing in a particular
jurisdiction, (ii) in a reinsurance business carried on by a CFC of a multinational insurance group
or (iii) in a “captive” insurance business of a CFC that is not part of an insurance group? Are
there practical problems with current rules that distinguish between these two situations? If so,
what are they and how can they be dealt with?
12. Are there practical problems with applying the same rule to sales and services income and IP
income?
69
13. Are there existing CFC rules that accurately attribute any or all of these categories of income
while also reducing administrative and compliance burdens?
14. Does the discussion above consider all categories of income that should be attributed under CFC
rules?
15. Is it clear how the two approaches above would work? If not, what further detail is required to
clarify the approach?
16. What practical problems arise with applying the categorical approach and the excess profits
approach?
17. How could the practical problems be addressed or mitigated?
18. Which approach is most likely to accurately attribute income that gives rise to BEPS concerns? Is
one approach likely to be more effective than the other in terms of dealing with IP income?
19. Could the excess profits approach be applied to income other than IP income and what would be
the practical implications of this?
20. What other approaches could be considered for determining excess profits or excess returns?
21. What difficulties or practical problems arise in applying an entity approach or a transactional
approach?
22. What concerns arise from the two approaches in terms of administrative burdens and compliance
costs?
23. How could these concerns and/or practical problems be dealt with while still ensuring that the
CFC rules achieve an accurate result and attribute income that raises BEPS concerns?
24. Do the rules on computing the income of a CFC present any difficulties in practice? If so, what
are these and how could they be dealt with?
25. Does this chapter accurately reflect the issues that could arise with losses or are there any other
situations that need to be considered?
26. What difficulties, if any, arise under existing CFC provisions for attributing income?
27. Does the description of a top-up tax set out all the advantages and disadvantages of such an
approach?
28. Are there any other double taxation issues that arise in the context of CFC rules that are not dealt
with here?
29. What administrative or practical difficulties arise currently in respect of double tax relief rules
and how could these be mitigated or dealt with?
70