Lessons For The Young Economist Manual PDF
Lessons For The Young Economist Manual PDF
Lessons For The Young Economist Manual PDF
ess
onsf
ort
heY
oung
ECONOMI
ST
ROBERTP
.MURPHY
Lessons for the Young
ECONOMIST
Teacher’s Manual
The Ludwig von Mises Institute dedicates this volume
to all of its generous donors
and wishes to thank these Patrons, in particular:
ECONOMIST
Teacher’s Manual
ROBERT P. MURPHY
LvMI
Mises Institute
Copyright © 2012 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute.
ISBN: 978-1-61016-204-3
Contents
PART I: FOUNDATIONS
1. Thinking Like an Economist . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Thinking Like an Economist . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
Is Economics a Science? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
The Scope and Boundaries of Economic Science . . . . . . . . . . 7
Why Study Economics? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Test Questions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Answers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
v
vi | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
T
his is the Teacher’s Manual to accompany the student
text, Lessons for the Young Economist, published by the
Ludwig von Mises Institute. The student text is available
for free online, or it can be purchased as a physical book, at
this web address: http://mises.org/resources/5706/Lessons-
for-the-Young-Economist. The student text was designed with
junior high students in mind, but it is applicable for younger,
precocious students, and also even for adults who never got a
solid grounding in free-market economic principles.
This Manual is intended to guide the teacher through the
course, giving the broader context of the material in the stu-
dent text, as well as offering suggested test questions and fur-
ther activities. It can be used by classroom teachers, but is also
ideally suited to homeschooling instruction by parents who
may not be confident in their own economics knowledge.
Here’s how the Manual works: First, before introducing a
particular chapter (or Lesson), the teacher needs to read it in
the student text. Then, the teacher should read the accompa-
nying material in the Manual. For each section of each chapter,
the Manual may give the historical context, clarify the relation-
ship between what the student is learning from the text com-
pared to a typical college textbook, warn about possible confu-
sions the student may encounter, give links for the teacher’s
own edification (not necessarily to be assigned to the student),
and so forth.
xi
xii | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
FOUNDATIONS
Lesson 1
A
lthough most economists would endorse the themes
of the material in Part I: Foundations, there are several
areas where the views in the student textbook differ
from what is taught in a standard text. We will point these dif-
ferences out to you as we work through the book, and explain
the reasons for the disagreement.
One of the biggest differences is the simple fact that we
spend so much time on foundations in the first place. In most
texts, there is an urge to “jump right into the economics.” How-
ever, in this course we have adopted the admittedly old-fash-
ioned idea that you need to lay a foundation before building a
house. We hope that the approach in this course, including its
emphasis on understanding the nature and scope of econom-
ics, is intuitive and commonsensical. In contrast, many of the
problems in higher economics—as practiced at the most presti-
gious universities—can be traced precisely to its failure to pay
attention to these issues which are often derided as “philoso-
phy” rather than economics.
As with much of the material in this course, our approach
to economic foundations is based on the work of Ludwig von
Mises. If you want to read more of Mises’s views, you can
read the first chapter of Mises’s Epistemological Problems of Eco-
nomics, available at: http://mises.org/epofe.asp. However, you
3
4 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Is Economics a Science?
In this section we adopt a definitely minority viewpoint,
so you should be aware of the controversy. Most economists
would agree with our take that economics is a science. How-
ever, many (perhaps most) economists would say that what
makes economics a science is its ultimate reliance on falsifiable
predictions.
The economists who adopt this view are (whether they
know it or not) following in the tradition crystallized by Mil-
ton Friedman in his famous essays on what is called “positive
economics.” If you want to learn more about this controversy,
you should first read the essays in the Supplemental Materials
for Lessons 1 and 2, and then for further discussion you should
listen to philosopher Roderick Long’s discussion of Friedman
versus Mises at http://mises.org/media/4006.
In a nutshell, the economists who follow Friedman adopt
the view of Karl Popper, who argued that in order for a state-
ment to be scientific, it had to be falsifiable. In other words, it
had to be at least possible in principle for the facts to turn out a
certain way, in order to render the statement false. If this were
6 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Gene Callahan, Economics for Real People available at
http://mises.org/resources/2031, Chapter 1 and Appendix A.
Callahan’s book was commissioned and published by
the Mises Institute (the producers of this course). It is
intended as an introduction to Austrian economics,
which is the school of thought associated with Ludwig
von Mises. Callahan’s book, as well as the Lew Rockwell
essay listed below, provide an explanation for the term
“Austrian” and explain the relationship of the Austrian
School to others, such as the Keynesian or Chicago
School. For this course, the student doesn’t need to learn
the particulars of Austrian economics vs. other types of
schools. But in the Supplemental Materials, these terms
unavoidably come up and so the student will need to
know what they mean.
We should make it clear that most of the lessons in this
course do not depend on “Austrian” economics per se;
any professional economist who has an affinity for free
markets would endorse or at least sympathize with the
approach. The only chapters that owe an explicit debt to
the Austrian School are Lessons 15 and 23, because they
rely on the particular theories of Ludwig von Mises, the
dean of the Austrian School in the twentieth century.
suggested
Discuss with the student
activities the various things that
every “well-rounded”
young adult should have
studied. For example, the list might include arithmetic and
algebra (but not necessarily calculus), famous works of
literature, key portions of world history, the major events
in the history of physics, and so on. The purpose of the
activity isn’t so much to come up with the list, but to discuss
what factors put something on the list (or keep it off).
After you have come up with a set of criteria for what puts
something on the list (or keeps it off), see if basic economic
principles should make the cut.
test — Lesson 1
Thinking Like an Economist
15
16 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
9. Explain how economics is indeed a science but not in the same sense
as physics or chemistry.
11. Explain why even phenomenally rich men and women need to
economize on their resources and choices.
Test answers have been deleted.
19
20 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
How We Develop
Economic Principles
T
he material in this chapter would not be contained in
standard textbooks, and indeed (as we explained in the
previous chapter) many economists might not even agree
with some of its themes. Naturally we will be clear in the sec-
tions below to point out these areas of disagreement.
If a particular student cannot handle abstract thought very
well, Lesson 2 can safely be omitted. However, the material
in this chapter is important to truly understand what we are
doing when we use economics to understand the world.
21
22 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
No, they are not. The brain is a physical organ of the body,
whereas the mind is an intangible concept that obviously bears
some relationship to the brain. (Note that someone can “lose
his mind” without losing his brain.) To repeat, we are not rul-
ing out particular theories of neuroscience that claim that cer-
tain mental states are caused by particular brain states. We are
making the very modest point that mental states or operations
(such as anxiety, happiness, long-range planning, multiplica-
tion, etc.) are different from brain states (such as firing neurons
and blood flow to the left hemisphere).
26 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Supplemental Materials
• Gene Callahan, Economics for Real People, Chapter 2.
This material should be self-explanatory. Callahan jumps
ahead to deal with some concepts that we will cover in
later lessons of this course.
1. Biology
2. Economics
3. Criminology
4. Astronomy
31
32 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Mindless behavior:
Mindless behavior:
Purposeful action:
Purposeful action:
Test: Lesson 2 | 33
10. Explain why the “scientific method” simply won’t do well in the realm
of social science.
35
36 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Introduction
I
n Lesson 3 we illustrate the payoff of our attention to appar-
ently philosophical concerns in the previous chapter. The
general concepts we develop here would be ones endorsed
by most professional economists, and yet (as we’ll see) they are
all logical implications of the fact that humans act purpose-
fully. If a student is perplexed as to why we spent so much
time in Lesson 2 on the distinction between purposeful action
and mindless behavior, the answer is that purposeful action
provides a proper foundation for the basic principles shared by
all modern economists—even if those economists themselves
don’t know it!
39
40 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
to spend his life with her.” One of his beliefs that motivated
this action is that she will say yes. But she very well might say
no. Even in that case, the man’s action was still purposeful; he
just didn’t fulfill the purpose as he had expected. In business,
entrepreneurs make faulty forecasts all the time. Their actions
are still purposeful, and they still fall under the scope of eco-
nomic theory.
Supplemental Materials
• Murray Rothbard, Man, Economy, and State, with Power
and Market (Scholar’s Edition, available at http://mises.
org/resources.aspx?Id=e8f5e0fa-d5bb-4844-9a4b-
831c6a090d9e), pp. 1–33.
This large volume is Rothbard’s grand treatise on
economic theory. The serious student who wishes to
really master modern Austrian economic thought at
some point will have to read Rothbard’s book, which is
surprisingly easy to read in spite of the complex subject
matter. For this course, we are including excerpts to
whet the advanced student’s appetite and also to give
longer discussions on certain points. Another benefit for
the advanced student is that Rothbard’s terminology
and discussion is more formal than the approach taken
in this course, and so will provide an easier transition
for those students who go on to study economics at
a higher level. If the student decides to slog through
large portions of Rothbard’s treatise, there is also a
dedicated study guide available at http://mises.org/
resources/3318/Study-Guide-to-Man-Economy-and-
State.
suggested
activities
Have the student
browse a newspaper
or watch the nightly
news, and note how many times a collective entity (such
as a country or government) is reported to have taken a
purposeful action.
test — Lesson 3
Economic Concepts Implied
By Action
Subjective or Objective:
Identify the following statements as either subjective or objective.
A. Subjective B. Objective
Matching EssentialTerminology:
Write the appropriate term on the line beside its description.
47
48 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
10. Guess at Jordan’s preference and belief (two separate things) from
the following statement.
11. List your top three books or movies. In making the list, did you have
to measure how much enjoyment you got from each book or movie?
Explain.
(1)
(2)
(3)
Test answers have been deleted.
49
50 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Introduction
A
s the student text explains, the purpose of “Robinson
Crusoe” economics is to introduce economic concepts
in a simplified setting. After the student has mastered
the principles in an “economy” consisting of one person, we
then generalize it to a real economy with many people.
It used to be common for economics books to use examples
of Robinson Crusoe (or perhaps the Swiss Family Robinson)
to illustrate ideas, though the practice is rarer now. We have
retained the practice for two reasons. First, students seem to
respond well to the discussion. Second, the Robinson Crusoe
environment is perfect for showing the interaction of natural
resources, labor, and capital goods.
51
52 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
much (or even more so) than things like ladders and apples.
But because gravity, oxygen, etc., are (at least in most cases)
not scarce, they don’t have to be economized, and so don’t fall
under the umbrella of economic analysis. (Note that some texts
might refer to these things as free goods, to show that they are
still useful but not economic goods.)
The second point ties in with the modern subjective the-
ory of value. Economic goods are defined not by their physi-
cal attributes per se, but by the valuing human mind which
appraises them.
good condition. The student should find that Crusoe can enjoy
more leisure in the short run if he ignores depreciation, but
then when the pole deteriorates Crusoe faces a crisis and must
either sharply cut back on his coconut consumption, or begin
drawing down his stockpile. The lesson will obviously apply
to a modern economy that goes through a “boom and bust”
cycle, as we explain in Lesson 23.
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Gene Callahan, Economics for Real People, Chapter 3.
Callahan adapts the television reality show “Survivor”
for his own version of Robinson Crusoe economics.
suggested
(1) Ask the student to think
activities of situations in which typically
non-scarce goods can become
scarce and hence subject
to economic analysis. For example, deep sea divers must
purchase tanks of oxygen, and we could imagine space
travelers buying gravity-generating devices for their ships.
(3) The next time you and the student are at a store, ask
about the status of the items on the shelf, from the point
of view of the store owner and the customer. For example,
the student could say that all of the items on the shelves
are producer goods to the owner, because he or she
looks at them as a means of earning money. But from the
point of view of the customer, some of the items (such as
a loaf of bread) could be classified as a consumer good,
while others (such as a drill) could be classified either way,
depending on how the student frames the situation. (Note
that in one sense, a drill doesn’t confer direct happiness on
the consumer, except in a Tim Allen-macho-man fashion.)
Furthermore, even “obvious” consumer goods could be
classified as producer goods, depending on how the student
frames the issue. A woman might buy expensive clothes in
order to fit in with a certain group of people, for example,
even though she would rather wear sweatpants; in this
sense the items are a means to an end, i.e., producer goods.
Lesson 4: “Robinson Crusoe” Economics | 61
(4) Have the student draw up a 7-day plan for Crusoe in the
new equilibrium, showing exactly how he allocates his hours
each day in a typical week, so that the supply of coconuts
never drops below 100. (A footnote in the text sketches the
answer.)
test — Lesson 4
“Robinson Crusoe” Economics
4. A paring knife.
63
64 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
13. Explain why an object only becomes a good when a person incorpo-
rates it into his plans.
16. Water is necessary for life, but restaurants give it away for free.
Diamonds are mere décor, serving only vanity, but they cannot be had
cheaply. Explain this so-called “water-diamond paradox.”
66 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Rory looked at the mess that the burglars had made, sat down on
the edge of his bed and wept. The thieves had made away with three
hundred dollars in cash, his laptop, his iPod, his Xbox 360, and all of his
games; but that’s not why he wept. More than any of those expensive
items, Rory most regretted the theft of his father’s class ring. It was only
ten carat gold, and the red center stone wasn’t even a real ruby. No
pawnshop would have given him more than fifty dollars for the ring, but it
was the loss of this ring that now left Rory emotionally distraught.
Test answers have been deleted.
67
68 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
CAPITALISM:
THE MARKET ECONOMY
Lesson 5
The Institution of
Private Property
T
o reinforce the connection between Lesson 4 and Part II,
you may want to stress this opening section. The general
principles we discussed regarding Crusoe still apply to
him, once he returns to civilization. In other words, it’s not that
the rules of Lesson 4 only work on tropical islands with one
inhabitant.
However, there is a problem once we recognize that in a
modern city, there are millions of Crusoes walking around,
appraising goods and trying to achieve their most preferred
goals. To settle conflicts, people assign property rights to
scarce goods. It’s not so much that the laws of economics need
to be altered to deal with a modern market economy. It’s more
accurate to say that the existence of property rights (with their
corresponding “rules of engagement”) provide a new form
of tradeoffs or constraints that each “Crusoe” must take into
account when making decisions.
To help the student see the big picture, make sure he or she
understands the layout of the text. Part I laid out the nature
and scope of economic theory, and then applied it (in Lesson 4)
73
74 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
example, even if someone owns his own body, and has the
legal right to shave his head or to get a vulgar tattoo, it may
still violate his religious beliefs to do so. It wouldn’t be a valid
argument against his religious peers to say, “I’m the owner so
you can’t tell me what to do with my hair!”
In an introductory course, we are not dealing with exotic
applications of private property, such as private ownership of
roads, or even private ownership of tanks and aircraft carri-
ers. This is not a course on political philosophy so we are not
addressing the important questions of the proper role of gov-
ernment in society. Rather, we are sketching the operation of
a pure market economy in order to show the student “raw”
capitalism in contrast to other institutional settings, and to
understand some of the economic effects of handling partic-
ular resources through private property, government owner-
ship, or a mixture of the two.
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Ludwig von Mises, Human Action (Scholar’s Edition, available at
http://mises.org/resources/3250), Chapter XV, Section 1, pp.
258–60, 264–70.
As should be clear by now, this course relies heavily
on the work of economist Ludwig von Mises.
Unfortunately, Mises’s writing can be quite difficult for a
newcomer, because not only is his language very formal,
but he also assumes that his readers are familiar with
a wide range of subjects. Even so, advanced students
should at least try to read the excerpts from Mises’s
magnum opus, Human Action. Assure them that even
professional Austrian economists can struggle with some
portions of the book, but it is worth sampling because
of its importance in the development of the modern
Austrian School. For students who want to jump in,
there is a study guide to the book at http://mises.org/
books/humanactionstudy.pdf.
suggested
activities (1) Especially if the
student is an animal
lover, you could ask
whether it’s really correct to say that Crusoe was the only
intelligent mind on his island, appraising the scarce goods.
For example, what if Crusoe’s activities destroyed bird
nests? There is no preferred answer here, but you should
point out the difficulties in actually assigning property
rights to birds, monkeys, etc. Note too that just because
someone has the legal right to use an object (i.e., is its
owner), doesn’t relieve him or her of moral or religious
responsibilities. For example, even if we can agree that
Crusoe is the effective owner of everything on the island,
we can still consider it deeply immoral for him to commit
wanton cruelty to the animals on it.
4. The system in which individuals may choose to enter any line of work
that they so choose is called
A. Crusoe economics.
B. mixed market.
C. free enterprise.
D. socialism.
83
84 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Market
Free Enterprise
Guilds
Slavery
Private Property
87
88 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
O
ne of the most crucial principles in all of modern eco-
nomics is that both parties benefit from a voluntary
exchange. (Or more precisely, both parties expect to
benefit.) For the purists, note that technically we mean benefit
on net, or in other words, both parties expect the benefits to
outweigh the costs when they engage in a voluntary trade.
This is possible because preferences are subjective. For
example, it would not be possible for both parties in a trade
to walk away with a heavier object than each started out with.
That’s because weight is an objective fact, an intrinsic property
of an object. In contrast, value is in the mind of the beholder,
and that’s why two people can both feel they gave up some-
thing of lesser value, in exchange for something of greater
value, when they make a voluntary trade.
The text mentions the caveat that the parties expect to ben-
efit. This is because, after the fact, one or both parties might
regret the decision. For example, if someone sells a parcel of
land for a certain sum of money, and then later discovers that
there was a large oil deposit on the property, the seller will
probably regret the earlier decision.
89
90 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Prices
The material in this section is fairly straightforward. Just
make sure the student understands that money is a good, and
why we can reverse prices as we normally express them to talk
about how many units of some other good (cars, bubble gum,
etc.) one needs to sell in order to “buy” one unit of money.
For example, if a car’s price is $15,000, then that is equivalent
Lesson 6: Direct Exchange and Barter Prices | 91
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Gene Callahan, Economics for Real People, Chapter 4.
Callahan outlines the basics of direct exchange. Reading
his chapter 4 in conjunction with this course’s Lesson
6 may help the students to really grasp the material.
However, Callahan begins his chapter with a discussion
of the division of labor, a topic we won’t cover until
Lesson 8.
(2) If you have at least four students, you could also try
conducting different trials in which the students are isolated
in smaller markets on Day 1, and then all lumped together
in a single market on Day 2. It would be very interesting to
see if the same Snickers:Milky Way price were established
in each of the smaller markets on Day 1, and (if not) what
price was established in Day 2 in the big market including
all students.
Test — Lesson 6
Direct Exchange and
Barter Prices
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
99
100 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
103
104 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
F
or this chapter you should understand some technical
distinctions to place this material in context with other
books. Most economists use the term barter to refer to any
non-monetary exchange. Therefore, a “barter economy” under
this broad definition would still allow for people to use media
of exchange, that is, to engage in indirect exchanges.
For advanced students, you should therefore be careful in
the presentation of the material below, especially the first sec-
tion. There, we are showing the limitations of a world strictly
confined to direct exchange. Notice that this is more restrictive
than a world confined merely to barter. In other words, in our
considerations of “The Limitations of Direct Exchange,” we
aren’t just ruling out the use of money, we are going much fur-
ther and ruling out the use of any medium of exchange at all.
This is a harsher condition, because money is a very special
kind of medium of exchange, namely one that is accepted by
almost everyone in the community.
Then, in the middle of the lesson, we introduce generic
indirect exchange, but do not yet suppose that there is one
medium of exchange involved in every transaction. This is a
subtle point, but should help advanced students clarify their
thinking. (It is also related to the 5th study question.)
Finally, at the end of the lesson we explore an economy that
not only has indirect exchange (i.e., where people use media
107
108 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Doug French, “Money…” video at http://mises.org/media/4286.
French’s talk is aimed at high school students and
provides a very understandable introduction to the
Austrian view of money. He shows exhibits of different
types of money that should interest students.
suggested
activities (1) If appropriate for
the student, draw up
(or have the student
do so) a simulated economy on a sheet of paper, listing 5 –
10 different people and their offer prices for 3 – 5 different
commodities. (You should start on the low end of these
ranges and then increase them, to see how quickly the
complexity increases.) For example you might initially try
something like the following:
In the context of the above community, ask the student to
find the way to achieve the most eggs, starting with a pound
of bacon. If limited to direct exchange, the answer would
be obvious: Only Alice and Charlie are willing to offer eggs
for bacon, and Alice’s offer is better. So clearly—if limited to
direct exchange—the student should trade with Alice and
achieve 10 eggs for a pound of bacon.
However, with the possibility of indirect exchange, things
are not so simple. The student needs to check if there is
an indirect way to achieve more than 10 eggs, starting with
an initial pound of bacon. (Note that we assume that Alice,
Bob, etc., will trade as many units as the student wants, at
the posted price ratios.) For example, if the student trades
with Charlie, he or she can obtain 22 apples for the original
pound of bacon. Then the student can take those 22 apples
Lesson 7: Indirect Exchange and the Appearance of Money | 117
5 apples 1/10 pound 7 apples for 8 eggs for 1/3 pound 1 egg for
for 1 ounce of bacon for 1 ounce of 1 ounce of of bacon 1 ounce of
of silver 1 ounce of silver silver for 1 ounce silver
silver of silver
Using the above table, the first move is easy enough: The
student should sell his or her pound of bacon to Charlie,
in order to receive 2 oz. of silver. Because all transactions
work “through” silver—in other words, nobody is trying to
buy bacon with anything other than silver—the student
obviously puts him or herself in the most advantageous
118 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
are being sold on the bottom row for a lower unit price
than they are being purchased along the top row. Because
of the way fractions work, this is equivalent to checking
that the number of units of a good (apples, eggs, or
pounds of bacon) is lower in the bottom row, than it is
in the top row. For example, to check that there are no
arbitrage opportunities in apple investment, the student
just needs to verify that the 5 apples and 7 apples on
the bottom row (in Alice and Charlie’s columns) are lower
numbers than the 100 apples and 8 apples in the top row
(in Bob and Ed’s columns).
Although there is always the possibility of arbitrage—
buying low and selling high for a virtually “riskless”
gain—speculators are much more likely to spot such
opportunities and eliminate them in a monetary economy.
Just as it is straightforward for the student to check for
such opportunities, so too could Alice, Bob, etc., look
around and see if there were easy ways to make silver in
this fashion.
In summary, not only does the use of money greatly
simplify the first step for a trader—he or she knows to sell
wares to the person offering the most units of the money
good—but the use of money also makes it easier to see if
there is a speculative opportunity because of the pricing
among others in the community. Furthermore, in practice
average buyers and sellers wouldn’t even need to worry
about such possibilities, because savvy speculators would
most likely have already spotted the arbitrage opportunity
and whittled it away through buying and selling.
(To see how this works, consider that if Alice initially were
willing to give up 12 apples for an ounce of silver, while
Ed gave an ounce of silver for 8 apples, then traders
would make a silver gain by buying apples from Alice and
selling them to Ed. In principle, a speculator would want to
carry out this operation an infinite number of times. But in
reality, of course, eventually Alice would run low on apples,
120 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
2. Explain how a community could use indirect exchange but not have
money.
121
122 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Listing: For each commodity, list the attributes (you can put more than
one) of a good money that each has.
A. Very durable
B. Easily divisible
C. Easily transportable
D. Convenient market value (by weight)
E. Units very similar quality
4. House
5 Horse
6. Bananas
7. Gold
8. Silver
9. Aluminum
10. Plutonium
11. Emeralds
Test answers have been deleted.
125
126 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
T
he material on the division of labor and specialization
is fairly standard. One difference is tying the concepts
to the use of money. Because most textbooks don’t dwell
much on a monetary vs. a barter economy in the first place,
they typically don’t explain that money allows a much greater
development of the division of labor.
It is a fairly basic point, but be sure the student sees the
connection between labor productivity and the standard of liv-
ing. The only way everyone can continue to consume more stuff
over time, is if everyone produces more stuff over time.
129
130 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Leonard Read, “I, Pencil,” at http://www.econlib.org/library/
Essays/rdPncl1.html.
Read’s article is truly one of the most famous economics
pieces of all time. It is self-explanatory.
suggested
(1) Have the student
activities keep track of examples
of the division of labor
during the day, which
are not part of someone’s paid job. (E.g., the neighbors
tending to their yard, with the husband cleaning out the
gutters while the wife pulls weeds, as opposed to each
spouse pulling half of the weeds and cleaning out half of
the gutters.)
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
137
138 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
141
142 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Entrepreneurship
and Competition
Entrepreneurship
B
elieve it or not, many standard economics textbooks do
not even mention the role of entrepreneurs, let alone
describe them as the “driving force” of a market econ-
omy. Ludwig von Mises and other members of the Austrian
School naturally focus on entrepreneurship as the heart of a
market, because Austrians focus on processes rather than
equilibrium snapshots. In other words, economists who con-
centrate on how a market evolves over time will be very inter-
ested in the role that entrepreneurship plays.
Strictly speaking, entrepreneurs strive after psychic profit.
In other words, everyone seeks to improve his or her situation,
according to subjective preferences. This applies to Mother
Teresa as well as to Henry Paulson. However, at this level it’s
probably easiest to have students concentrate on the familiar
notion of a businessperson trying to “make money.” But to
remain technically accurate, we use the term monetary profit,
and take care not to make sweeping statements to the effect
that all entrepreneurs seek to generate monetary profits.
145
146 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Jeffrey Tucker, “Technology and Social Change,” video at http://
mises.org/MediaPlayer.aspx?Id=4990.
Tucker’s talk is aimed at high school students and
provides a very good introduction to the idea of
competition as “imitation and innovation.”
suggested
activities (1) Have the student
identify examples
where competition regulates behavior. For example, if one
grocery store begins offering carts designed as racecars
(for little kids to use while their parents shop), then others
usually follow suit. Or perhaps the student knows a
particular teenager who is quite rude in personal affairs,
but is a model of courtesy when working as a waiter at a
country club. (In this case, the student could explain that
the waiter is competing against other waiters for tips—in
other words, the diners will judge his performance based
on how it stacks up with other waiters’ performances—or
the student could say that the waiter is part of the whole
restaurant’s effort to compete against other businesses for
the customer’s dollars.) There are also examples that are
not so obviously tied to markets, for example athletes lifting
weights and watching their diets in preparation for a sports
season, or boys and girls buying expensive clothes and
otherwise grooming themselves in an effort to compete for
the most attractive dates.
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
153
154 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
157
158 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
I
n terms of practical life lessons, this chapter is one of the
most important in the book. Be sure the student really
understands the power of compound interest, and that even
people with modest paychecks can become millionaires if they
begin saving early in their career.
Note that the possibly unfamiliar term dissaving refers to
someone who lives above his means—in other words, con-
sumes more than his income—but doesn’t borrow from out-
side lenders. Rather, the person finances his extra consumption
by drawing down previously accumulated savings.
161
162 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Retirement
Depending on your own views, you may want to tie in the
discussion of saving for retirement with a broader discussion
of the importance of thrift and self-reliance. In other words, one
doesn’t need to become a financial burden on the next genera-
tion if he or she has adequately saved during the prime work-
ing years. (More sophisticated students should learn about life
and health insurance policies as well.)
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Gene Callahan, Economics for Real People, Chapter 8.
In this chapter Callahan spells out the Austrian view of
the structure of production. It is more advanced than our
discussion, but should still be quite accessible to most
students.
(3) For the advanced student, discuss the idea that the
working generation must support the older (retired)
generation. In one sense this is always true; anytime a
retired person goes grocery shopping, she’s “skimming”
food from the harvest of current workers. However, so long
as the retired person is living off of previously saved wealth,
part of what’s happening is that the current workers are
more productive because of previous investments by the
now-retired person. So the total output of food is greater,
because there are more tractors, fertilizer, etc., due to the
years of abstinence and accumulation during the now-
retired person’s working years. For more on this idea (in the
context of debates over Social Security), see this article:
http://mises.org/daily/5658/Is-Social-Security-a-
Ponzi-Scheme.
Test — Lesson 10
I n c o m e , S av i n g , a n d
Investment
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
5. If you expect to live to at least 80 years old, why should you seriously
consider saving a large amount of your income and investing it while you
are young?
169
170 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
6. Respond to someone who says, “It hurts the economy when people
save too much, because if people don’t spend, then businesses can’t hire
workers.”
7. How does the accumulation of capital goods help workers who don’t
own them?
Test — Lesson 10 | 171
8. Respond to someone who says, “For every lender who grows rich,
there must be a borrower who grows poor.”
Test answers have been deleted.
173
174 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
T
he material in this lesson is standard. As the text explains,
supply and demand graphs are very useful to keep our
thoughts organized when we work through the effects of
a hypothetical change in the market. Even professional econo-
mists often start their basic analysis with some version of a
supply and demand graph.
For the advanced student, you should stress that there is
not a “theory” of supply and demand. All changes in market
prices can be “explained” by reference to movements of sup-
ply and demand curves or schedules. It is possible that future
economists will abandon the framework in favor of something
more convenient, but even if this occurs, it won’t be because
of some future empirical finding. Rather, future economists
might develop an alternative framework that provides a supe-
rior understanding of market prices.
177
178 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
One subtlety that might shed some light on the Law of Sup-
ply is that some producers drop out of the market altogether
below a certain price point. In other words, even if the stu-
dent has trouble seeing why a given producer would sell more
units at $100 rather than $99—if the producer still earns profit
at $99 per unit—the student should be able to understand that
producers are not identical, and so some of them might not be
able to turn a profit at a price of $99. Of course this analysis too
runs the risk of teaching the student the false theory that “costs
determine prices,” so you will have to decide whether to pur-
sue this train of thought.
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Murray Rothbard, Man, Economy, and State, pp. 238–49.
In this excerpt, Rothbard goes from individual
preference rankings to market demand and supply
curves. Remember that in Rothbard’s exposition, items
in parentheses refer to things that the individual does
not have in his or her possession.
Lesson 11: Supply and Demand | 185
suggested
(1) Look at the sample
activities test questions for supply
and demand graphing
exercises. Invent your own to give the student practice.
Multiple Choice:
Write the letter of the best answer.
1. Rebecca left for the store hoping to benefit from a huge sale on a
particular LCD TV. However, by the time she arrived, a sales clerk
informed her that the store had only stocked 10 of that particular TV,
and that they sold out of them within twenty minutes. And, of course,
there are no rain checks. How should we describe this situation?
A. glut
B. shortage
C. surplus
D. equilibrium
3. Ryan worked furiously in his studio, sculpting little trolls from manure.
However, no matter how little he asked for a price, he could find no
buyers. Someone might have told Ryan that there was probably little
____________ for manure-based troll sculptures?
A. supply
B. equilibrium
C. cost
D. demand
187
188 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
A. glut
B. shortage
C. equilibrium
D. premium
Test — Lesson 11 | 189
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
10. Explain how the demand for something can remain constant, but the
quantity demanded can decline.
Test — Lesson 11 | 191
11. Explain how a glut in the orange market can be bad news for the
producers of apples.
Test answers have been deleted.
193
194 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
A
s the student text indicates, the theory of interest is
one of the most complicated areas in economics. Nat-
urally we are not going to reproduce or even allude
to the high-level debates among economists over the nature
and causes of interest. Most economists would agree with the
statements we make in this chapter, although some of them
might have included other claims—such as the idea that the
interest rate reflects the “productivity of capital”—that we are
consciously omitting because they are actually controversial in
certain camps.
The analogy between interest rates and currency exchange
rates is meant to help the advanced student. If a student is
struggling with the point, you can safely skip it. There is no
point in burdening the student with an extra concept (exchange
rates) just to shed light on the topic of interest.
It is important, however, that all students take away the
idea that interest rates in a free market help to coordinate the
actions of savers and investors. In particular, when the com-
munity saves more and frees up resources, (other things equal)
interest rates fall and give the signal to entrepreneurs to invest
resources in longer projects. The student will need to know
this in order to make sense of the business cycle theory pre-
sented in Lesson 23.
197
198 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
exactly how the money supply and credit interact with each
other. (There is a further complication in our fractional reserve
banking system, in which new bank loans do expand the quan-
tity of money.) However, this might be too subtle a point for
some students. For the truly advanced student who wants to
learn the accounting treatment of modern fractional-reserve
banking, consult this video lecture: http://www.youtube.com/
watch?v=6HAEPSt_12U.
Bonds
The concept of bonds can be very intimidating, so you
should make sure that the student understands it is simply
a formalized way of borrowing money. When a corporation
“sells” or “issues” a new bond, it is not producing something
like a TV. It is simply borrowing money, in exchange for a stan-
dardized IOU spelling out the terms of the loan. The advan-
tage of a bond issue (versus drawing up specific loan contracts
with different lenders) is that it’s very easy for the initial lender
to sell the bond to someone else, and thus transfer the iden-
tity of the person to whom the corporation owes the remaining
interest and principal payments.
Banks
Be sure the student understands the legitimate function that
credit intermediaries serve, in assessing and spreading risk.
Just as middlemen (and women) in physical products provide
a definite service when they (say) buy oranges at a low price
from Florida growers, and then sell them at a higher price in
New York, by the same token the banks perform a valuable
service when they borrow at a low rate and lend at a higher
rate.
The student text did not spell it out, but all parties—includ-
ing the lenders and the borrowers—benefit from the existence
of banks, at least if we assume that the banks do their jobs
properly and make sound loans. (This doesn’t always occur,
200 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
of course; the late 1920s and the late 2000s are great examples.
However many economists would argue that this poor perfor-
mance by the banks was caused or at least exacerbated by the
government and Federal Reserve.)
Credit Cards
In the student text we have tried to be neutral, as many par-
ents do not want their children ever using credit cards for obvi-
ous reasons. Economists must be able to explain the operations
of this market, just as they need to understand how farmers
and others fit into the cigarette market. Naturally the fact that
some people buy cigarettes doesn’t mean economists endorse
smoking.
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Henry Hazlitt, Economics In One Lesson, Chapter VI.
Hazlitt illustrates the harmful outcome when
government uses credit to divert production. His
analysis shows, however, that credit provided
voluntarily by lenders on the free market leads to
the beneficial results desired by the proponents of
government loans to business.
suggested
(1) For the truly
activities advanced student,
you could elaborate
on the tuxedo analogy
presented above. At
first it might seem impossible for a young guy to rent a
tuxedo on a Friday, and then return not only that same
tuxedo, but the “interest” payment of another tuxedo (or
a piece of one—maybe a vest) the following Monday. Yet
note that this is exactly what happens when we borrow
dollars from a bank—we are expected to return more
dollar bills than the bank originally handed to us. Remind
the student that by hypothesis, tuxedos are money.
So the loan could be a productive loan in the literal
sense, where (say) the borrower puts on the tuxedo
and performs a lounge singer routine, in exchange for
payment in the form of tuxedos. But it’s also possible
that the borrower uses the lent tuxedo to hire workers
to make something which he then sells to customers
for money (i.e., tuxedos), before paying off the loan plus
interest. The point of this rather silly thought experiment
is to drive home exactly what’s happening with loans
and interest, and why tuxedos would be an awfully
inconvenient money.
Multiple Choice:
Write the letter of the best answer.
A. principal
B. credit
C. debt
D. interest
A. exchange rate
B. maturities rate
C. market interest rate
D. commodities market
A. interest
B. exchange
C. omninational
D. international
207
208 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
A. borrowing
B. earning
C. saving
D. lending
A. the government
B. collateral
C. credit history
D. credit intermediaries
A. secured debt
B. unsecured debt
C. collateral debt
D. productive debt
Test — Lesson 12 | 209
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
8. Explain why the deal between Justin and Vraj was mutually beneficial.
210 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
9. Other things equal, an increase in interest rates will have what effect
on the quantity demanded of loans?
10. Identify what happens to interest rates when a community saves more
in general, and generalize the signal that this sends to entrepreneurs.
Test — Lesson 12 | 211
13. Discuss this statement: “Getting rid of all records of credit histories
and credit reports would help borrowers.”
14. Explain why the interest rates on unsecured loans tend to be higher
than those on secured loans.
Test answers have been deleted.
213
214 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
T
his section contains one of the most important insights
in the entire course. Most people do not understand that
the economy is a dynamic system in which people must
always respond to changing conditions, be they unexpected
weather, changes in consumer tastes, or a new invention.
Make sure the student really understands how profits and
losses guide entrepreneurs. There is no objective “right way”
to run a business in a particular industry; entrepreneurs need
to discover this through competition. (The Hayek reading in the
Supplemental Materials elaborates on this important point,
though it may be too difficult reading for some students.)
As a consequence, when we see businesses in the real world
earning “excessive” profits, that isn’t a signal that the owners
are ripping people off. On the contrary, it’s a signal that the
owners are adjusting serious imbalances (or “false prices”) in
the market.
217
218 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Ludwig von Mises, “Profit and Loss,” Sections 1–5, at http://
mises.org/story/2321.
Although Mises’s writings are always formal, this is
actually an accessible introduction to Mises’s views on
profit and loss. His analysis covers much of the same
ground as our (simplified) student lesson.
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
227
228 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
3. Does the profit and loss system force movie theaters to stay open on
Christmas? Explain.
4. Explain how the profit and loss system communicates the desires of
consumers to resource owners and entrepreneurs.
Test — Lesson 13 | 229
231
232 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
235
236 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
The corporation can issue debt (i.e., sell bonds) or equity (i.e.,
sell new shares of stock).
Supplemental Materials
• Robert Murphy, “The Social Function of Stock Speculators,” at
http://mises.org/daily/2381.
This is a slightly more formal exposition of the material
in the student text.
suggested
activities (1) One popular
exercise is to have
students assemble a
“fantasy stock portfolio”
(analogous to “fantasy football teams,” etc.). Especially if
you have multiple students, you can allocate each student
an initial sum of money and have him or her spend it on
blocks of stock from various corporations. You can then
use a simple Excel file to track the movements of the total
market value of each student’s stock portfolio by plugging
in the prices from a site such as http://www.cnbc.
com/. (The student can enter the stock ticker in the search
engine at the top of the main page.)
(2) You can have the student read financial articles either
online or in a print newspaper such as the Wall Street
Journal. The goal is not to have the student grapple with
the opinions that are offered, but just to understand
the basic terms used in a typical financial news story.
For example, a stock price can go up even when the
corporation reports losing money, just so long as “the
market” had been expecting an even worse report.
Fair warning: Much of the mainstream financial press
is economically illiterate, as judged by the economic
principles in this course. The student is not looking to the
press to learn economics by any stretch. But a complete
novice can start learning about the business world by
occasionally watching CNBC or reading the Wall Street
Journal.
Stock exchange
Stock brokerage
Bonds
Dividend
Leverage
Speculator
245
246 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
7. Explain why companies might want to raise outside funds, rather than
financing any desired spending out of profits.
249
250 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
SOCIALISM:
THE COMMAND
ECONOMY
Lesson 15
The Failures of
Socialism—Theory
253
254 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Gene Callahan, Economics For Real People, Chapter 10.
Callahan covers much of the same territory in his
chapter, as we have done in the student text (though
in a different order). One thing to note is that the
“knowledge problem” is very similar to the “calculation
problem”; they both flow out of the writings of Mises
and Hayek in their debate against the socialist theorists.
(Specifically, the knowledge problem refers to the
inability of central planners to actually assemble all
the information they would need in order to rationally
design the economy, whereas the calculation problem
in its purest form takes this information as given and
still says that the planners would not know how best to
deploy resources.) The knowledge/calculation problems
are completely distinct from the incentive problem of
socialism.
suggested
activities (1) Have the student
identify appealing
versus distasteful
jobs that require
comparable skill levels. (For example, serving food in
Disneyworld versus serving food to the workers at a
chicken slaughterhouse.) If the central planners are not
allowed to pay more for the distasteful occupations,
what other incentives could they use to prevent
everyone from volunteering for the appealing jobs
and no volunteering for the distasteful ones? (For
example, the planners could insist that everyone who
volunteers to work at Disneyworld first pass a difficult
trigonometry exam, or that anyone who volunteers at
the slaughterhouse gets to have lunch with a movie
star once per year.) Have the student think through the
implications of these changes.
Multiple Choice:
Write the letter of the best answer to each question.
263
264 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
7. Explain why you probably receive better service at Walmart than at the
Department of Motor Vehicles.
266 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
8. Contrast the very worst that a capitalist “tyrant” can do to you (as a
malcontented worker or an obnoxious customer) versus what a socialist
tyrant can do to you.
Test answers have been deleted.
267
268 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
The Failures of
Socialism—History
271
272 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Yuri Maltsev, “What Soviet Medicine Teaches Us,” at http://
mises.org/daily/3650.
Maltsev earned his Ph.D. in economics in Moscow and
served on a team of Soviet economists working on
President Mikhail Gorbachev’s policy of perestroika,
before defecting to the United States. Maltsev is a
champion of the market economy, and has powerful
first-hand experience to justify his views. In this article
he warns of government “solutions” to health care.
suggested
(1) Have the student
activities scour news accounts
of “right wing” and “left
wing” governments or
guerrilla groups, and
try to isolate what the difference is supposed to
be. Typically, both groups are in favor of having
the government control property, it’s just that the
“right wing” groups want to redistribute wealth to
the owners of multinational corporations, whereas
the “left wing” groups want to redistribute wealth
to rural peasants.
A. communist B. fascist
A. socialism
B. communism
C. capitalism
D. fascism
A. socialism
B. communism
C. capitalism
D. fascism
279
280 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
10. Pol Pot’s Khmer Rouge communist regime killed up to 25% of its own
people in which country?
A. Vietnam
B. China
C. North Korea
D. Cambodia
11. “[O]ne particular feature of many Communist regimes [was] their sys-
tematic use of _____ as a weapon.”
A. famine
B. gas
C. poison
D. disease
E. Kalishnikovs
12. By far, which country’s experience with communism cost the most
lives?
A. U.S.S.R
B. North Korea
C. People’s Republic of China
D. Vietnam
Test — Lesson 16 | 281
13. Post WWII, where in Europe was the contrast between relative capital-
ism and communism the starkest?
A. Paris
B. Berlin
C. Warsaw
D. Moscow
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
16. Explain how the conventional “Left Wing/Right Wing” dichotomy (or
Left/Right Spectrum) with communists on the left and fascists on the right
makes little sense in terms of economics.
17. Does the material in this chapter show that we prove economic
theory with experimental evidence?
Test answers have been deleted.
283
284 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
INTERVENTIONISM:
THE MIXED ECONOMY
Lesson 17
Price Controls
I
n this final portion of the book, we focus on major compo-
nents of the “mixed economy.” Most intellectuals recognize
(at long last, in some cases) that pure socialism doesn’t work.
However, they are still unwilling to embrace a society with
complete private property rights. They reject both pure social-
ism and pure capitalism, and opt for a third way, an interven-
tionist system that (allegedly) avoids the unseemly excesses of
a pure market while stopping short of outright central plan-
ning.
Much of the analysis in this section of the book is compa-
rable to what is found in mainstream textbooks, though the
emphasis would be different. In a standard text, for example,
much space would be devoted to diagrammatic expositions of
the “welfare losses” arising from interventions such as tariffs.
In this course we do not dwell on the graphs, which leaves us
more space to analyze the various topics in greater detail.
Price Ceilings
The analysis in this section is fairly straightforward. We
offer just a few comments to help you allocate your time.
287
288 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Immediate Shortages
Immediate shortages are the most critical consequence of
price ceilings. For students wishing to go on in economics,
make sure they know how to use supply and demand curves
to illustrate the shortage.
Non-price Rationing
One of the functions of the (undisturbed) market price is
that it rations the available supply of a good among the com-
peting demands for it. In essence, if someone wants more units
of the good, he has to bid more dollars for it. This of course
strikes many observers as unfair, since it gives an obvious
advantage to the wealthy.
However, by placing a cap on the price, the government
doesn’t eliminate the fact of scarcity; there are still more people
who want to use the good, than there are units of the good to
go around. All that happens is that the rationing must occur
through non-price mechanisms. This actually might end up
being more distasteful to the proponents of the price control,
than the original price rationing.
For example, under rent control landlords can be much
pickier in which tenants they select for their available apart-
ments. They might insist on seeing several months’ worth of
paycheck stubs, run a background check on the applicant,
and require letters of reference from previous landlords. They
might also prefer tenants who travel in the same social circles,
or come from the same ethnic group, whether from outright
290 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Drop in Quality
Be sure the student understands that even the ostensible
winners from price ceilings are not as lucky as the first stage
of the analysis suggests. In other words, even the tenants who
receive a break on their rent may end up with lousier service
from the landlord.
Price Floors
As with the previous section, the analysis here is straight-
forward.
(up and to the left). But over time, the price floor (and the asso-
ciated higher-than-equilibrium price) leads the buyers to adapt
by reducing their dependence on the good or service in ques-
tion. The result can be a leftward shift in the entire demand
curve, so that even if the price floor were suddenly removed, a
wage (price) at the original, lower level would not draw forth
the same quantity demanded.
Non-wage Competition
One way of illustrating the consequences in this subsection
is to point out the different unemployment rates based on vari-
ous demographics. (As of this writing, the Bureau of Labor Sta-
tistics has links to such data at the bottom of this link: http://
www.bls.gov/cps/#data.) The very groups who are the most
economically vulnerable tend to have the highest unemploy-
ment rates, and one of the explanations is that these groups
are legally forbidden from underbidding other workers who
are earning the minimum wage. Proponents of the legislation
would argue that it is indecent for someone to make less than
the minimum wage, but it’s arguably more indecent for some-
one to be willing to work but unable to find a job.
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Henry Hazlitt, Economics In One Lesson, Chapters XVIII and
XIX.
As with all of Hazlitt’s chapters, these provide a
wonderful yet succinct analysis.
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
297
298 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
3. The textbook claims that price ceilings (a) cause immediate short-
ages and (b) lower long-run supply. What’s the difference? Use a specific
example to illustrate.
5. Explain how the poorest and most desperate are actually hurt by mini-
mum wage laws.
Test answers have been deleted.
301
302 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Government Spending
I
n the introduction to this lesson, we adopt the position of
Ludwig von Mises when it came to the “value-free” analysis
of government intervention: Mises believed that economic
science per se was objective and dispassionate; it could not say
whether a sales tax was a good thing or a bad thing. However,
in order for citizens to make informed decisions regarding
important issues such as taxes, they needed economics to show
them the full consequences of their decisions.
For some reason, standard economics texts do not typically
discuss the obvious point that government spending necessar-
ily diverts resources into channels where they otherwise would
not have gone. In contrast, standard texts will devote inordi-
nate amounts of time to discussing the “incidence” of particu-
lar taxes, depending on the relative elasticities of supply and
demand. (For example, if the government levies a sales tax on
cigarettes, the consumers will end up bearing the brunt of the
tax, whereas a comparable sales tax on Pepsi would probably
fall heavily on the company, as Pepsi drinkers would shift into
Coke.)
305
306 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Sales Taxes
To repeat, in a standard undergraduate economics text, they
will typically analyze sales taxes with the aim of understand-
ing the “incidence,” meaning whether the consumers or the
producers bear the brunt of a new tax. In these standard text-
books, there is a discussion of the general loss to the economy
in the form of a “deadweight loss.” The idea here is that when
the government makes goods and services artificially expen-
sive, potential trades do not occur, so that the gains from trade
among producers and consumers are reduced. We have tried
to get across the same idea in the student text, without using
the actual term deadweight loss and without recourse to supply
and demand graphs.
Income Taxes
Depending on your own judgment, you may wish to spend
more or less time on the issues of tax brackets, tax-deductible
expenses versus tax-exempt income, and so forth. For many
students, these are vague phrases that don’t really become sig-
nificant until they purchase their own houses and the tax code
has personal consequences. It is probably worth clearing up
two common misconceptions, which are: (1) people can alleg-
edly be hurt by a pay raise because it puts them in a higher tax
308 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
bracket, and (2) businesses don’t mind buying things that are
“tax writeoffs.” These views are false, though there is a grain
of truth to them. (Specifically, a pay raise is not as advanta-
geous when the marginal dollars are taxed at a high rate, and a
business will not watch its expenses as carefully if they are tax
deductible. But this is different from saying a person literally
is hurt by a pay raise, or that a business actually makes money
by increasing its expenses.)
The final example in the text illustrates the point that incen-
tives do affect behavior. High income tax rates definitely distort
the labor market. The distortion is not necessarily that highly
productive people leave the labor market, but rather that they
are guided more by non-pecuniary factors and in that respect
the guidance provided by other people’s spending is muted.
Lesson 18: Sales and Income Taxes | 309
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Thomas DiLorenzo, “Rothbard’s Economics of Taxation,” audio
at http://mises.org/media/1324.
This is a self-explanatory lecture. If the student is going
to read Rothbard’s selection below, he or she would
definitely benefit from first listening to DiLorenzo place
the material in context.
suggested
(1) The next time you
activities are at a gas station, point
out the sign indicating
that the posted price
includes all applicable
sales taxes. Ask the student to guess how much of the
pump price is due to federal and state sales taxes. Then
show the actual answer here: http://tonto.eia.doe.
gov/energyexplained/index.cfm?page=gasoline_
factors_affecting_prices.
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
315
316 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Test answers have been deleted.
319
320 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Mercantilism
T
he case for free trade is simultaneously one of the most
difficult to convey to skeptics, and yet endorsed by the
vast majority of economists. Not merely “free market
economists,” but even many otherwise interventionist econo-
mists, understand the mutual benefits when countries reduce
trade barriers and liberalize imports and exports.
There is a vast literature for the non-expert on the topic of
free trade. Obviously we could not summarize every argument
in the student text, and we couldn’t cite every relevant read-
ing below in the Supplemental Materials. But if the student is
interested, you can pursue the topic much further than some of
the other ones in this course. The case for free trade is crucial to
understanding markets generally, and so extra time spent on
this topic will not be wasted.
We open the discussion by explaining mercantilism. Make
sure the student recognizes that although mercantilism as an
official doctrine has long been discredited, it obviously sur-
vives in both government policies and the popular under-
standing of trade. The only real change over the centuries is
323
324 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Tariffs
There are numerous ways that free-market economists have
tried to show the flaws of protectionism, i.e., the philosophy
of using tariffs (or other trade barriers) to “protect” domestic
workers. You may want to first read all of the Supplemental
Materials before teaching this topic, to familiarize yourself
with the various arguments and styles.
As we stated in the student text, it actually concedes too
much to the protectionist position to “follow the money”; it’s
a bad habit that often leads to faulty conclusions. Yet Hazlitt
and others have focused on dollar expenditures simply to pin-
point precisely where the protectionist goes wrong. In other
words, if no one had ever uttered fallacious protectionist argu-
ments, we probably wouldn’t even talk about dollars going
into different sectors. Rather, we would explain that trade bar-
riers divert resources into less efficient sectors, and lower total
output. Therefore trade barriers make everyone in the world
poorer, on average.
Import Quotas
As the text explains, tariffs and import quotas can be quite
similar in their broad effects on domestic employment and
consumers. (One difference is that under a tariff, government
collects more revenue, whereas under a quota the foreign pro-
ducer can keep the higher earnings on the artificially restricted
number of units sold in the country.)
Lesson 19: Tariffs and Quotas | 327
The last point we make in the text is that a quota can poten-
tially cause far more damage than a tariff, simply because the
government could impose a draconian quota without it being
as obvious as if the government imposed a comparable tar-
iff. Especially with the passage of time, the effects of a quota
become harder to gauge, since we would have to know what
the free-trade level of imports would be. For example, if Coun-
try A originally imported 100,000 cars from Country B, and
then Country A’s government imposed a 90,000-vehicle quota,
that would probably be equivalent to a significant but not out-
rageous tariff rate. However, as the years passed, the original
90,000-vehicle quota would become more and more onerous.
This is because, in the absence of the quota, the number of
imports would probably have grown over the years.
328 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Frédéric Bastiat, “Petition of the Candlemakers,” at http://
bastiat.org/en/petition.html.
This is one of the most famous economics essays of
all time. It is (of course) a satirical play on standard
mercantilist arguments. Bastiat “proves” that shutting
out “unfair” competition from the sun would be a great
boon for industry.
suggested
Especially for the student
activities who will study economics
at higher levels, you
may wish to go over
the following numerical
example which illustrates comparative advantage in the
case of international trade. (This example was drawn from
the class notes for an introductory undergrad class in
macroeconomics.)
Suppose that the following table summarizes the physical
productivities of U.S. and Mexican workers in two different
industries:
U.S. MEXICO
2 TVs / worker day 1 TV / worker day
5 DVDs / worker day 2 DVDs / worker day
MEXICO IN AUTARKY
TV price is $10 each, DVD price is $5 each, and workers get
paid $10 / day.
Note that these numbers are also consistent with the
table above. A worker can yield his employer either $10
in TV production (1 per day @ $10 each) or through DVD
production (2 per day @ $5 each).
could only pay his or her workers $44 / day, yet the DVD
producers are offering $50. So no U.S. worker would
continue going to the TV factory.
By the same token, the previous Mexican producers of DVDs
can’t compete with the “overly productive” U.S. workers.
Even though DVD prices in Mexico have risen to $10 each,
nonetheless the Mexican DVD producer can only pay his
workers $20 per day (since each Mexican worker can only
make 2 DVDs / day). No Mexican worker would accept that
job, since the TV factory is paying $22 / day.
Finally, notice that all workers are richer in real terms than
under autarky. The U.S. worker has experienced a reduction
in nominal wages, but his smaller paycheck can now buy him
either 5 DVDs or more than 2 TVs. Similarly, the Mexican
worker’s wages can now buy him either 1 TV or more than
2 DVDs.
This makes perfect sense: If the worker in either country
wants to spend all of his or her paycheck on the good still
produced domestically, then he or she is unaffected by
trade. But if the worker wants to buy the product that is
now imported, the worker can buy more units than under
autarky. That’s the whole point of trading, after all. You
import things from foreigners when this is cheaper than
making it yourself.
In summary, make sure you understand the purpose of the
example: We are showing that the workers in the United
States benefit from free trade with Mexico, even though the
Americans’ labor is more productive in every line.
The example also shows (though this isn’t the crucial point)
that some Mexican firms would be unable to compete
with American imports, if all trade barriers were removed
between the two countries. Many people in discussions
of free trade seem to think that the country with cheaper
labor has a competitive edge in every industry, but they are
mistaken. In our example above, the Mexican firms couldn’t
334 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Multiple Choice:
Write the letter of the best answer to each question.
4. Taxes placed on goods and services bought from foreigners are called
A. tariffs.
B. exports.
C. quotas.
D. imports.
335
336 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
5. Limits on the total amount people can buy from foreigners are called
A. tariffs.
B. exports.
C. quotas.
D. imports.
True or False:
Write true if the statement is true or write false if the statement
is false.
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
14. Explain how tariffs are taxes on domestic citizens, not foreign compa-
nies.
339
340 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
The Economics of
Drug Prohibition
Drug Prohibition
The material in this chapter may be sensitive for obvious
reasons. We have tried to present it in a neutral fashion, without
glorifying drug use or otherwise condoning particular prac-
tices. However, when contrasting the outcome of a free market
in which people voluntarily exchange property titles, versus
an interventionist economy where the government coercively
overrides property rights, drug prohibition is one of the major
vehicles in today’s world. It is also an excellent illustration of
what is called “the law of unintended consequences,” because
many of the alleged problems of drug use are actually caused
by drug prohibition. We emphasize the point that just because
something is legal, doesn’t mean it is ethical or moral. (If some-
one thinks it would be a bad idea for the government to throw
cheating spouses in jail, that doesn’t mean the person is “for”
marital infidelity.)
341
342 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Mark Thornton, “The Economics of Prohibition,” at http://mises.
org/daily/2269.
Austrian economist Mark Thornton is an expert on the
topic. This article provides a good introduction to his
views.
suggested
(1) For students interested
activities in history, you could ask
them to explore the
origins of the current drug
prohibition regime. In
other words, it was not always the case in the United States
that someone selling cocaine could be sent to prison for
decades. (Some proponents of drug legalization point out
that hemp was used for commercial purposes in colonial
times. They even claim [perhaps apocryphally] that the
original U.S. Constitution and U.S. flag were made of hemp.)
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
351
352 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
355
356 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Inflation
T
here are some free market enthusiasts who are very par-
ticular about the careless use of the term inflation and so
be sure the student understands the two distinct mean-
ings.
Also note (as we explain in a footnote) that we have deliber-
ately used the term stock of money rather than the more familiar
money supply. Often when people discuss price inflation they
will say, “The supply of money rises, and so does the price
level.” This may confuse the student since we took such pains
earlier in the course to distinguish between “supply” (mean-
ing the supply schedule, as represented by the entire supply
curve) versus the quantity supplied. In most cases, when peo-
ple say, “The supply of money rises, pushing up prices,” they
are not referring to the supply (schedule) of money but rather
the actual quantity of money in existence.
We have not included selections from Milton Friedman
in the Supplemental Materials because of copyright issues.
However, for a well-rounded education in free market eco-
nomics, the student should be familiar with Friedman’s views
on money. A very simple introduction to Friedman’s overall
worldview is Free to Choose, whereas a more advanced book is
359
360 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
reasons. First, not all prices rise by the same amount; we know
this because relative prices bounce around all the time. (For
example, the price of a gallon of gas divided by the price of a
Big Mac, does not always yield the same ratio.) Second, it’s not
even true that on average prices must rise by the same percent-
age as the stock of money, even if we adjust for the increase in
production of real goods and services. The reason is that the
demand for money can change as well. Too often proponents of
free market economics focus on the supply side of the “money
market” while completely ignoring the demand side. But as we
know, the market price of something—including the exchange
value of units of money—is determined by the interaction of
supply and demand.
unit of the money good sees its “price” rise, this means that
people must offer more units of goods and services in order to
acquire a unit of money. This is the opposite of how we nor-
mally think of money and prices, because we usually quote
prices in terms of money. For example, if the price of a car rises
from $10,000 to $15,000, this actually reflects a falling price of
money. In other words, the purchasing power of money falls,
when the prices of all non-money goods and services go up.
What the average person means by (price) “inflation” is a gen-
eral rise in the prices of most goods and services. This is the
same thing as saying the general purchasing power of money
has fallen.
At the end of this section we discuss the case of the U.S. in
the mid-1980s, when the stock of money (at least as measured
by the aggregate M1) began rising much more quickly than the
CPI. Again, we are trying to make sure the student realizes that
there are no mechanical formulas in economics; people’s sub-
jective valuations ultimately determine the objective prices we
see in the market. For various reasons (probably involving the
sharp income tax rate cuts and the collapse in price inflation
rates) the world demand for U.S. dollar-denominated assets
rose quickly in the mid-1980s, so that the sharp increase in the
money stock did not coincide with large U.S. price inflation.
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Henry Hazlitt, Economics In One Lesson, Chapter XXIII.
Hazlitt deploys his characteristically snappy writing to
explain inflation.
The chart in the text shows CPI versus M1. The specific
series titles are “CPIAUCNS” (which stands for “Consumer
Price Index All Urban Consumer Non-Seasonally adjusted”)
and “M1NS” (which stands for “M1 Non-Seasonally
adjusted”). In order to graph this, we need to first tell FRED
which series we want.
scroll down a bit, you will see a green arrow with the
option to “Add Data Series.” After you click this, a box will
appear allowing you to type in a search term. Or, you can
click on the “Browse” (to the right of the search box) to
look for the next data series you want to add. Go ahead
and click “Browse.”
For each line (i.e., Line 1 and then Line 2), select the
Units pull down menu. Then pick the last option “Index
(Scale value to 100 for chosen period)”. Finally, type in
“1960–01–01” where FRED prompts you to “Or Enter An
Observation Date”.
After you have done this for both CPI and M1, click “Redraw
Graph” and you should now see the same graph (except
perhaps for a later ending date) as the one appearing in the
student text.
test — Lesson 21
I n f l at i o n
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
1. Explain how the Caesars quite literally debased their currency, and
discuss the consequences.
371
372 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
3. Does fiat money have whatever value the government assigns to it?
6. Explain how large and variable price inflation partially defeats the
purpose of using money in the first place.
Test answers have been deleted.
375
376 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Government Debt
A
s this is an Advanced Lesson, it pursues certain trains
of thought more deeply than the typical chapter in this
course. You will have to adjust the difficulty to the stu-
dent. Of course the most basic point is that government deficit
spending leads to higher debt, which entails future interest
payments to service the debt.
379
380 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• Robert Murphy, “Government Debt Has No Upside,” at http://
mises.org/daily/2006.
This essay covers some of the same ground as the
student text, but it also deals with two popular notions
that the student has probably heard. The first is the
view of Alexander Hamilton that a large national debt
is good because it gives people an incentive to support
the government, and the second is the claim that the
national debt is no real burden because “we owe it to
ourselves.”
Advanced Lesson 22: Government Debt | 385
suggested
activities (1) Use the table in
the student text as a
template, but change
the numbers. Leave
some of the cells blank and then see if the student
can fill them in. For example, you may want to chart
out the next three years of the hypothetical scenario
in the student text. In the year 2013, you could leave
the Interest payment cell blank, because that is already
pinned down by the debt level of $75 billion carried
forward from the year 2012. (The answer will be $3.75
billion in interest payments in the year 2013.)
Matching:
Write the letter of the correct term beside each concept.
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
387
388 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
391
392 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
T
his final chapter is the culmination of the entire course. It
draws on several tools developed in previous lessons, and
has a very ambitious scope. Without calling it by name,
we have laid out the Austrian business cycle theory, or what
is also called the Mises-Hayek trade cycle theory. In addition
to the Supplemental Materials, for further reading you can try
the pamphlet, The Austrian Theory of the Trade Cycle and Other
Essays available at: http://mises.org/tradcycl.asp.
395
396 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Study Questions
Supplemental Materials
• “Fear the Boom and Bust,” a Hayek-Keynes Rap Anthem, at
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=d0nERTFo-Sk.
A very popular music video that features a debate of
sorts between John Maynard Keynes and Friedrich
Hayek.
suggested
Discuss the master
activities builder analogy with the
student in more depth.
Hone in on the point that
the longer the builder sticks to the original blueprints, the
worse the final house will be. To get this point across, you
can work through several examples during the chronology.
If the builder realizes the mistake in the very beginning,
before the workers even begin digging, then he can revise
the blueprints in light of the true brick supply, and the
only “waste” will be his own time in drawing up the original
blueprints. If the builder realizes the mistake after the
first floor is already built, then things are far more serious,
because the builder has already gone down a particular
path and “locked in” much of the available resources. And
if the builder waits until he literally runs out of bricks, then
at that point he may have difficulty even sealing off the roof
to keep out rain, depending on how erroneous the original
brick estimate was.
Once the student really sees this point, you can ask him
or her to evaluate the response of world governments and
406 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
Short Answer:
On the lines provided, answer the questions in 1 to 3 sentences.
407
408 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
4. Why does the text say that government-driven economic growth can
be unsustainable?
Test — Lesson 23 | 409
411
412 | Lessons for the Young Economist: Teacher’s Manual
L
udwi
gvonMi
sesI
nst
i
t e•5
ut 18We
stMa
gnol
i
aAv
enue•Aubur
n,AL36832 • Mi
ses
.or
g