Japan's Long Stagnation, Deflation, and Abenomics
Japan's Long Stagnation, Deflation, and Abenomics
Japan's Long Stagnation, Deflation, and Abenomics
Japan’s
Long Stagnation,
Deflation, and
Abenomics
Mechanisms and Lessons
Japan’s Long Stagnation, Deflation, and Abenomics
Kenji Aramaki
Japan’s Long
Stagnation, Deflation,
and Abenomics
Mechanisms and Lessons
Kenji Aramaki
Tokyo Woman’s Christian University
Tokyo, Japan
University of Tokyo
Tokyo, Japan
This Palgrave Macmillan imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature
Singapore Pte Ltd.
The registered company address is: 152 Beach Road, #21-01/04 Gateway East, Singapore
189721, Singapore
Preface
The objective of this book, which covers the Japanese economy since the
1980s, is to identify the mechanism of formation and collapse of a huge
bubble and the subsequent long economic stagnation and deflation and to
discover challenges that the current Japanese economy faces.
I worked mainly in the field of international finance in the Ministry of
Finance of Japan for about 30 years and then moved to Tokyo University,
where I taught international economics for more than 10 years. The rea-
son why I have written a book on the Japanese economy, which is not
strictly my specialty, is that I have had a strong desire to find out an answer
to my long-held questions, that is, “Why did the Japanese economy fall to
its current situation?” and “Was it inevitable?”
It was 1976, when I started to work, more than 40 years ago. The
Japanese economy at that time was dynamic and filled with increasingly
strengthened confidence. At the height of the euphoria of the bubble of
the late 1980s, I was working as economist at the International Monetary
Fund. Personally, I did not like what was going on with the Japanese
economy at that time, but my confidence in the strength of the Japanese
economy did not change. Even after the collapse of the bubble in the
1990s, I felt that the Japanese economy would be able to return at any
moment to the previous conditions, which had been filled with vitality.
However, the reality did not turn out that way. The Japanese economy
experienced a serious financial crisis in the late 1990s, and deflation set in.
Even after entering the 2000s, low growth continued, and the Japanese
economy lagged behind the growth of the global economy for decades.
Japan held a share that was higher than 9% in the world exports of goods
v
vi PREFACE
and services in the first half of the 1990s, but at present it is less than half
that, at about 4%. China’s nominal GDP, which was 18% of Japan’s nomi-
nal GDP in 1996, is 2.3 times larger than that of Japan, as of 2017.1 No
one at that time expected to see the economy as it is in 2017, and I have
thought that it is the responsibility of our generation to answer “why?”
However, the work to find out an answers presented many difficulties,
as there were limited opportunities to exchange views outside the field of
my expertise, which is international finance. I chose, for the first time, to
examine the issues of the Japanese economy as a topic in a seminar class
that I taught at the Faculty of Arts and Sciences of Tokyo University in the
summer term of 2011, and I started to read extensively the relevant arti-
cles and materials. In 2014, I was awarded the opportunity to conduct
research as a visiting professor at the School of Oriental and African Studies
(SOAS) of London University. There, I gave lectures on the Japanese
economy as a guest lecturer, while conducting research on international
financial crises. Preparatory work for these guest lectures motivated me to
further analyze the Japanese economy. Since the summer of 2015, when I
left SOAS, I have given presentations on the Japanese economy in London,
Berlin, and Zurich at the conferences of the Japan Economy Network
(JEN), which is an international network of researchers on the Japanese
economy that my colleagues at the SOAS, including Dr. Ulrich Voltz,
Prof. Machiko Nissanke, and Dr. Sotoshi Miyamura, and myself organized
in 2015 at a conference, together with the economists in attendance. The
book gradually came into a concrete shape, and it has taken more than
seven years to complete.
The central argument of the book is that, at the center of the anomalies
and difficulties of the Japanese economy over an extended period of time
including formation and collapse of the bubble, the financial crisis, and
deflation, were corporate behaviors that have changed while showing sub-
stantial fluctuations. For example, the biggest negative legacy that the
bubble left with Japan was excess assets (those assets for which sufficient
demand is not expected and, therefore, are necessarily unprofitable) of the
corporate sector. The reason why the economy did not show a strong
growth for a long time after the collapse of the bubble is that, as sales by
companies stopped growing and economic growth decelerated following
1
IMF World Economic Outlook, April 2018. Nominal GDP in terms of home currency of
each country is converted to the dollar using market exchange rate.
PREFACE vii
the burst of the bubble, the excess assets (unprofitable assets) expanded.
Companies could not swiftly dispose of such excess assets, and investment
was depressed for an extended period of time. Furthermore, despite sales
not increasing, wages continued to increase in the early years after the col-
lapse of the bubble, and profits of companies were further depressed by
this factor. Companies’ responses at that time to the problems brought
about by the collapse of the bubble were “passive,” and this passivity led
to a lengthening of the economic stagnation. When the financial crisis
broke out in the late 1990s, under the deteriorating business conditions
and with a sharp aggravation of funding environments, which were
described as not only “new loan curbing” but also as “outstanding loan
withdrawing,” company response shifted at a stroke to a “crisis response.”
Companies forcefully proceeded with wage reduction, replacement of
regular workers with non-regular workers, further restraint of investment,
and strengthening of their net asset position. Around this period, deflation
started with the declining wage level. The Japanese economy slowed fur-
ther, and fundamental changes occurred with the financial crisis.2
Due to such responses by companies, excess assets together with excess
debts and excess employment were removed by the mid-2000s, and the
economy returned to the normal. However, a defensive attitude of compa-
nies that emerged after the financial crisis was maintained, such that restraint
on investment and wages continued (“continued defensiveness” emerged).
The biggest characteristics of the stagnation of the Japanese economy are,
first, that it took as long as 15 years from the collapse of the bubble in the
early 1990s to the elimination of the excesses and, second, that a defensive
attitude on the part of companies continued (it has not been eliminated
even now), even after the problems with the balance sheets of companies,
which lay at the heart of the difficulties, had been rectified.
This book argues that behind the defensive attitude of companies is the
low-growth expectations held by companies. Low-growth expectations
became firmly rooted and settled under the reality of low growth that
2
Companies changed their behavior significantly after the financial crisis. Many Japanese
companies, which once placed a high priority on employment, forcefully pressed ahead with
labor cost reduction through wage cuts and replacement of regular workers by non-regular
workers, while protecting the employment of existing workers (Wakita [2014] described this
as “fortified Japanese companies”). Under such developments, there has emerged serious
social costs, such as very low marriage rates of young non-regular workers (see Chap. 7).
Defensive behaviors of companies are producing negative externalities.
viii PREFACE
extended over a long period of time, from the 1990s (the average growth
rate in 22 years from 1991 to 2012 was 1.0%). The total amount of (nom-
inal) sales of all the profit-making companies in Japan increased by merely
1.9% from fiscal 1990, when the collapse of the bubble started, to fiscal
2016.3 Japanese companies have been living in a world where growth does
not exist for more than a quarter of a century.
Regarding the low-growth expectations formed under such reality, one
view argues that, as the problems with the balance sheets of companies
were resolved, the low-growth expectation has become not so much a
reflection of economic reality, but rather a result of a habitualized way of
thinking (i.e., a mindset), and therefore, it will change if the mindsets of
companies are changed. In contrast, there is another view that argues that
the low-growth expectations have a rational, most likely structural basis. A
representative point of the latter view stresses the expected shrinkage of
domestic markets due to population decline.
As I explain in the book, I do not think the latter view (one that con-
tends that long-term and structural factors brought about the defensive
attitudes of companies or low-growth performance) applies to the major
part of the two-decade stagnation from the collapse of the bubble to the
beginning of the 2010s (this is the period which we call “the long stagna-
tion period” in the book). More specifically, I do not think that the view
can explain the mechanism of stagnation during the period up to the mid-
2000s, when the corporate sector finally eliminated the aftereffects of the
collapse of the bubble. In particular, although it is highly possible that
expectation of population decline will restrict corporate behaviors in the
future, it is only since the second half of 2000s that the population decline
has become a reality,4 and it was not so long ago, probably only after the
beginning of the 2010s, when the population decline was widely recog-
nized as an important problem by the general public. In this book, it is
argued that the fundamental mechanisms for the major part of the long
stagnation was, one, the lengthening of the process of disposition of excess
assets and, two, the strengthened defensiveness of companies after the
financial crisis. Furthermore, while it is difficult to clearly distinguish the
degree of their influence, factors arising from the defensive mindset (the
3
Ministry of Finance of Japan “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by
Industry.”
4
Statistics Bureau, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications, “Population
Estimates.”
PREFACE ix
part of defensiveness that does not seem to have a rational basis) still
remain in the mechanism of low-growth expectations by companies and
low-growth performances since the mid-2000s to the present.5 Therefore,
attempts to change such mindsets (e.g., governance reform that encour-
ages companies to employ outside directors in their management, promo-
tion of wage increases, and facilitating realization of higher growth than
before through alteration of foreign demand to domestic demand by pro-
moting such activities as tourism and inward foreign investment) are
thought to be effective. However, the mindset of companies cannot
explain the whole process and, particularly for the future, there is no deny-
ing that substantive issues still exist.
The comprehensive policy package that has been implemented by the
Abe administration, known as Abenomics, aims at both encouraging
changes in the mindset and addressing the substantive issues for the future.
The package has brought about some positive outcomes. However, cor-
porate behaviors have not significantly changed in a positive direction, and
the process is only half accomplished. At the same time, concerns are ris-
ing about by-products, including the declining growth contribution of
consumption, accumulation of potential risk in the financial system, and
continued significant deterioration of the fiscal position. This describes the
present condition of the Japanese economy.6
In writing this book, many people have extended their help to me. I
would like to thank the undergraduate students who passionately partici-
pated in my seminar class in the summer of 2011, in which I first started
to examine the Japanese economy intensively, and the undergraduates,
graduates, and alumni of my seminar who participated in “the workshop
on the Japanese economy,” which I held in the Faculty of Arts and Sciences
of Tokyo University. I am also very grateful to Dr. Takashi Omori (ex-
director of the division in charge of writing the “Economic White Paper”
in the Economic Planning Agency of Japan) who read the manuscript and
gave very many fundamental as well as technical comments; Dr. Teru
5
See Supplement to Chap. 6, in which the mechanism of stagnation is shown, with a focus
on company behaviors, by flowcharts, respectively, for three periods: “Period of passive
response” immediately after the collapse of the bubble; “Period of crisis response” after the
financial crisis in the latter half of the 1990s; and “Period of continued defensiveness” from
the mid-2000s.
6
While the objective of the book is to identify the mechanism of anomalies and difficulties
of the Japanese economy over the past 30 years from the bubble formation to present, it
briefly touches on measures to deal with current challenges in the Chap. 7.
x PREFACE
Last but not least, I would like to thank Professor Frank Rövekamp of
the Ludwigschafen University of Applied Sciences for his detailed and
positive review of the book’s outline, and to Palgrave Macmillan for pub-
lishing the book.
I will be very happy if this book could make some contribution to
reconstruction of the Japanese society and economy and also could offer
any useful lessons to other countries.
Bibliography341
Index361
xiii
List of Figures
xv
xvi List of Figures
Fig. 5.1 The Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food): Changes
from the previous year 190
Fig. 5.2 The GDP deflator and Consumer Price Index (excluding
fresh food) (year-on-year change) 191
Fig. 5.3 Import penetration 193
Fig. 5.4 Price developments in imports and import-competing
products194
Fig. 5.5 Cumulated changes in GDP deflator from 1990 to 2009 by
sector (%) 194
Fig. 5.6 Price changes from 1990 to 2009 of deregulation-related
products195
Fig. 5.7 Interest rates 200
Fig. 5.8 Stock price: Japan in 1990s and US in the Great Depression 201
Fig. 5.9 Consumer Price Index: Japan in 1990s and US in the Great
Depression201
Fig. 5.10 Taylor rule analysis of US and Japanese interest rates 202
Fig. 5.11 M2 and Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food)
(year-on-year change) 212
Fig. 5.12 Base money and M2 (year-on-year change) 213
Fig. 5.13 Loans and government bonds held by domestic banks 213
Fig. 6.1 Sales and wages (all industries excluding financial and
insurance companies) 222
Fig. 6.2 Ratio of wages to sales and operating profits 223
Fig. 6.3 Operating profits, non-operational profits, and current profits
(all industries excluding financial and insurance companies) 224
Fig. 6.4 Current profits and changes in wages from previous year 225
Fig. 6.5 Assets and liabilities of companies (all industries excluding
financial and insurance companies) 226
Fig. 6.6 Assets and their breakdown between fixed and liquid assets
(all industries excluding financial and insurance companies) 226
Fig. 6.7 Liquid assets and their components (all industries excluding
financial and insurance companies) 227
Fig. 6.8 Fixed assets and their major components (all industries
excluding financial and insurance companies) 228
Fig. 6.9 Investment securities and Foreign Direct Investment 228
Fig. 6.10 Liabilities and their breakdown between liquid and fixed
liabilities (all industries excluding financial and insurance
companies)230
Fig. 6.11 Liquid liabilities and their major components (all industries
excluding financial and insurance companies) 230
Fig. 6.12 Fixed liabilities and their components (all industries excluding
financial and insurance companies) 231
xx List of Figures
Fig. 6.13 Net assets and their components (all industries excluding
financial and insurance companies) 232
Fig. 6.14 Earned surplus and its components 233
Fig. 6.15 Capital/assets ratio 233
Fig. 6.16 Number of manufacturing companies by capital size (all
industries excluding financial and insurance companies) 234
Fig. 6.17 Ratio of physical assets (excluding land) to sales 240
Fig. 6.18 Estimated excess physical assets, investment, and depreciation
(all industries excluding financial and insurance companies) 241
Fig. 6.19 Real gross private investment 242
Fig. 6.20 Cash flow, private investment, and private investment/
cash flow 243
Fig. 6.21 Dividends received from abroad and their share in non-
operational revenue 245
Fig. 6.22 Expected growth rate held by companies 246
Fig. 6.23 Ratio of current profits to sales (%) 246
Fig. 6.24 Ratio of outstanding Foreign Direct Investment (all sectors)
to physical assets (excluding land) (all industries excluding
financial and insurance companies) 247
Fig. 6.25 Overseas production ratio (manufacturing) 248
Fig. 6.26 Private investment, outward Foreign Direct Investment,
and cash flow 248
Fig. 6.27 Monthly nominal cash earnings per worker (in establishments
with five employees or more, year-on-year change) 250
Fig. 6.28 Monthly real cash earnings per worker (in establishments
with five employees or more [2015 = 100]) 251
Fig. 6.29 Real wages and labor productivity (1990 = 100) 252
Fig. 6.30 Labor income share 253
Fig. 6.31 Monthly cash earnings per worker for normal workers
and for part-time workers (2015 = 100) 254
Fig. 6.32 Ratio of wages of non-regular workers to those of regular
workers255
Fig. 6.33 Compensation of employees/net national income
(at factor price) 256
Fig. 6.34 Labor cost/value added 256
Fig. 6.35 Value added and ratio of wage increase, dividends, and
increase in net assets to value added 258
Fig. 6.36 Annual average wage (1991 = 100) 259
Fig. 6.37 Hourly earnings (manufacturing) (1990 = 100) 259
Fig. 6.38 Annual rate of increase in CPI (excluding food, energy) 260
Fig. 6.39 Export price index (yen base) (2015 = 100) 260
Fig. 6.40 Developments in terms of trade (output deflator and input
deflator): manufacturing (2005 = 100) 262
List of Figures xxi
Table 2.1 Major economic and political developments in the 1970s and
1980s42
Table 2.2 Average growth contribution of private investment in plant
and equipment and net exports: 1956–1973 (high-speed
growth period), 1974–1984 (stable growth period), and
1985–1990 (bubble period) (%) 45
Table 2.3 Major trade disputes between Japan and US 45
Table 2.4 Major cases of export restraint 49
Table 2.5 BOJ’s explanation of monetary policy changes in the late 1980s 56
Table 2.6 Factor analysis of Japan’s current account surplus (estimate)
(in 100 million US dollars) 65
Table 2.7 GDP growth rate and private investment (year-on-year
change, period average): 1956–1973, 1974–1984,
1985–1990 (%) 66
Table 2.8 Developments in real estate-related loans by banks
(%, trillion yen) 70
Table 2.9 Dependence of manufacturing companies on borrowing
from financial institutions (%) 71
Table 3.1 Five periods of the Japanese economy since the high-speed
growth era 88
Table 3.2 Comparison of real GDP growth rate: Japan and other
advanced countries, 1980–2012 88
Table 3.3 Contribution to real GDP growth by major demand
components97
Table 3.4 Economic cycles during the long stagnation period 98
xxiii
xxiv List of Tables
yen in 2017, only greater by mere 11.0 trillion yen (2.1%) 20 years later,
after its peak in 1997.1
Why did such a long stagnation, which nobody could have imagined,
occur? Although there have been extensive arguments, there is no definite
consensus on the mechanism of the stagnation, and therefore, views still
diverge on the lessons to be drawn. As briefly described later in this chap-
ter, while the US economy recovered relatively speedily from the Global
Financial Crisis (GFC) that struck in 2008, the European economies con-
tinued to show weaknesses in their recovery, and worries about a fall into
deflation were not entirely dismissed until rather recently. Furthermore,
the Chinese economy, which had been growing rapidly for several decades,
started to decelerate and while the situation has stabilized, concerns over
the future course of its economy have not been eliminated entirely. Did
these economies face the risk of falling into long stagnation and deflation
(or low inflation) that the Japanese economy experienced? If there was
such a risk, at least at certain point in time after the crisis, what was the
mechanism of such a risk? Assuming that these economies have successfully
emerged from such a risk, what worked? If the economies did not success-
fully avoid the risk, what are the remaining problems? In order to answer
such questions, it helps to have an understanding of the mechanism of
long stagnation and deflation experienced by the Japanese economy.
While attempting to explore the mechanism of the bubble, stagnation,
and deflation in Japan from the 1980s throughout this book, we seek
answers to the following concrete key questions:
• Why was the bubble formed? What could have been done to prevent it?
• How did the bubble collapse? What impacts did the collapse of the
bubble have on the economy?
• Why did the financial crisis break out in the late 1990s, as much as
seven years after the collapse of the bubble? Why were the
non-performing loan (NPL) problems that underlay the crisis not
resolved sooner?
1
In real terms, the average real growth rate since the collapse of the bubble until today has
been 1.2%, which is about half of the average growth rate of the advanced countries (2.2%)
(or, just one-third of the average growth rate of the world economy [3.6%]) over the period.
If the Japanese economy had grown at the average rate of growth of advanced countries
(2.2%), then the real GDP would have been 1.3 times as big as the actual size (if it had grown
at the world average rate, it would have been 2 times as large). (Calculated using the IMF
“World Economic Outlook April 2108 database”).
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 3
• First, to capture the real cause of the anomalies and difficulties of the
Japanese economy, we have taken an approach, based mainly on a
thorough examination of data and facts. Since the early 2010s when we
started examining the long stagnation of the Japanese economy, we did
not espouse any theory or views in advance, but aimed to first study and
analyze extensive arguments, data, and facts. This book draws on such
work and tries to present a view that can most coherently explain what
the data and facts indicate. This book has tried to comprehensively
describe and understand the three-decade-long period of anomalies
and difficulties of the Japanese economy, thereby offering a new per-
spective on the problem and contributing to the economic literature.
• Second, we present a view that it is appropriate to analyze the Japanese
economy over 30 years by dividing the whole period into subperiods.
The basic divisions are three: the bubble period from the mid-1980s to
the beginning of the 1990s; the long stagnation period of more than
20 years from the beginning of the 1990s to the early 2010s; and the
period of Abenomics from 2013. However, what is unique to this
study is that the analysis of the long stagnation period is conducted by
further dividing this period of more than 20 years into four subperiods.
This view arose from the observation that the changes in the Japanese
economy emerged suddenly after the collapse of the bubble, and the
changes developed into a long-term phenomenon. In other words, the
mechanism of stagnation is thought to have changed from one of an
2
The negative legacy, as is explained in the book, refers mainly to the hangover of excessive
assets and debt in the corporate sector.
4 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
250.0
200.0
150.0
Japan
100.0 US
Euro area
China
50.0
0.0
01.03.1970
01.01.1973
01.11.1975
01.09.1978
01.07.1981
01.05.1984
01.03.1987
01.01.1990
01.11.1992
01.09.1995
01.07.1998
01.05.2001
01.03.2004
01.01.2007
01.11.2009
01.09.2012
01.07.2015
Fig. 1.1 Total credit to private nonfinancial sector (in percent of nominal GDP).
Source: Bank for International Settlements (BIS)
Lehman Brothers. The US ratio declined after that and became stabilized
at a level near 150% since about 2012. The ratio for the Euro area rose
from a level over 120% in 1999, to over 160% in the latter half of 2008,
and has stayed at this level, showing no sign of decline. The ratio for China
had been around 120% after entering the 2000s before a rapid increase,
starting at the end of 2008. It rose over 200% in mid-2015 and has become
flat more recently. It was at an extremely high level of 210.2% at the end
June 2017.
Figures 1.2 and 1.3 show a breakdown of the ratio into that for corpo-
rate and household sectors. A rapid increase in debt in Japan took place in
the corporate sector while debts of the household sector did not show a
big increase. The problem of excessive debts (and accompanying excessive
assets) was a problem of the corporate sector in Japan. A sharp increase in
debts emerged in the household sector in the United States. As was indi-
cated by the fact that the subprime loan problem triggered the GFC, the
original problem in the United States was not with the corporate sector
but with the household sector, and the figure shows that reduction in the
debt level of the household sector progressed speedily. The relatively quick
recovery of the US economy seems to have been founded on progress
made in adjustments of debt level. By contrast, the problem in the Euro
area was with the corporate sector, and there has been no progress in the
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 7
(%)
180.0
160.0
140.0
120.0
100.0
Japan
80.0 US
60.0 Euro area
40.0 China
20.0
0.0
01.07.1998
01.05.2001
01.03.2004
01.01.2007
01.11.2009
01.09.2012
01.07.2015
01.03.1970
01.01.1973
01.11.1975
01.09.1978
01.07.1981
01.05.1984
01.03.1987
01.01.1990
01.11.1992
01.09.1995
Fig. 1.2 Total credit to nonfinancial corporations (in percent of nominal GDP).
Source: BIS
(%)
120.0
100.0
80.0
60.0 Japan
US
40.0 Euro area
China
20.0
0.0
01.03.1970
01.01.1973
01.11.1975
01.09.1978
01.07.1981
01.05.1984
01.03.1987
01.01.1990
01.11.1992
01.09.1995
01.07.1998
01.05.2001
01.03.2004
01.01.2007
01.11.2009
01.09.2012
01.07.2015
Fig. 1.3 Total credit to households (in percent of nominal GDP). Source: BIS
8 K. ARAMAKI
adjustments of debt level, which seems to be the reason behind the weak
recovery in that region. In China, while the debt level of the household
sector is increasing, the corporate sector seems to have a more serious
problem. The rapid increase in debt level was triggered by the economic
stimulus package amounting to 4 trillion RMB announced at the end of
2008. There should have been an expansion of assets behind the increas-
ing debt. If these assets are not accompanied by sufficient demand, then it
is possible that the excessive assets could become a burden similar to those
excessive assets formed in the bubble era in Japan and could depress eco-
nomic activities in the future for a long period of time in China. The cor-
porate debt level hit a peak at the end of 2016 after the rapid increase and
declined slightly in most recent period. However, it is still at a level of
160%, which is higher than the level in the bubble period in Japan, and is
a matter of great concern.
Figure 1.4 shows total credit to the government sector. Together with
Fig. 1.1 that shows total credit (in GDP ratio) to the private nonfinancial
sector (corporate and household), these figures show that Japan’s govern-
ment debt increased by 121.8%, from 91.7% at the end of 1997 to 213.5%
at the end of June 2017, while the private nonfinancial sector’s debt
(%)
250
200
150
Japan
100 US
Euro area
China
50
0
01.03.1970
01.11.1972
01.07.1975
01.03.1978
01.11.1980
01.07.1983
01.03.1986
01.11.1988
01.07.1991
01.03.1994
01.11.1996
01.07.1999
01.03.2002
01.11.2004
01.07.2007
01.03.2010
01.11.2012
01.07.2015
Fig. 1.4 Total credit to general government (in percent of GDP). Source: BIS
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 9
declined by just 50.3%, from 209.8% to 159.5% over the same period.
Although the rise in government debt level was due mainly to growing
social security expenditures arising from the aging of the population, falls
in tax revenue due to stagnation, and repeated expenditure of fiscal stim-
uli, particularly in the 1990s, it may be said that the government bore
much of the direct costs (such as the use of public funds to resolve NPL
problems) and indirect costs (such as a rise in government expenditure in
the form of unemployment allowances and economic stimulus, as well as
revenue losses due to stagnation), which arose in the process of removing
excessive debt (or excessive assets) from the economy. The US
Government’s debt increased by 30.0%, from 68.0% at the end of June
2008 (before the Lehman collapse) to 98.0% at the end of June 2017,
while the private nonfinancial sector’s debt declined by 16.9%, from
168.4% to 151.5% over the same period. The increase in government debt
is about twice as big as the decline in the private nonfinancial sector’s debt.
By contrast, while the Euro area’s government debt increased by 22.2%,
from 66.9% at the end of June 2008 to 89.1% at the end of June 2017, the
private nonfinancial sector’s debt also increased by 4.3% from 157.3% to
161.6% over the same period. Debt levels of both private and government
sectors have been rising. As there is no progress in reducing the private
sector’s debt, we need to determine if it is at a sustainable level or if adjust-
ments are needed. In the case of China, the government debt increased by
17.9%, from 27.8% at the end of June 2008 to 45.7% at the end of June
2017, while the private nonfinancial sector’s debt increased by 94.9%,
from 115.3% to 210.2% over the same period. We should expect that the
government debt level will significantly rise if the private nonfinancial sec-
tor’s excessive debts (and excessive assets) are to be reduced.3
The aforementioned is the most important inference, that is, the d anger
of holding excessive assets or assumption of excessive debt. Japan is a case
3
The magnitude of increase in government debt depends on various factors including the
pace and the magnitude of adjustments and whether the economy experiences a financial
crisis or not. However, considering that even in the United States, where relatively quick
adjustments were conducted, the increase in government debt is nearly twice as big as the
decline in the private sector’s debt, then the possible increase in government debts in China
could be rather large, particularly if a financial crisis is experienced. If a reduction by 50% of
the private sector’s debt, say, to 160% (current level of Japan) (that is, a reduction by 50
percentage points) was conducted, it could be possible for government debt in China to go
beyond 100% of GDP, which still seems to be a manageable level.
10 K. ARAMAKI
in which the risk involved was manifest in the worst possible way. It
emerged through two channels. First was the extensive and deeply nega-
tive impacts on the economy, arising from the collapse of the bubble and
the breakout of the financial crisis. As will be explained in the book, a
financial crisis broke out in the latter half of the 1990s, that is, seven years
after the collapse of the bubble, and the crisis greatly and deeply altered
corporate behaviors. The biggest change was a drastic alteration of the
employment policies of companies. Companies regarded the provision of
employment as their social responsibility until the early 1990s, but they
drastically changed their policies in the face of the crisis. Specifically, com-
panies not only reduced the nominal wages but also cut down on regular
employment and replaced their regular employees with non-regular
employees such as fixed-term or part-time workers. Companies also started
to rapidly remove excessive assets and debt, and the absolute size of physi-
cal assets started to decline. Under these circumstances, deflation emerged.
The Japanese economy, having essentially returned to a normal position,
does not seem to have fully rid itself of the aftereffects of the collapse of
the bubble and shocks of the financial crisis. Overcoming this legacy con-
tinues to be an important challenge for Japan. A crisis can alter even basic
behavioral principles of economic agents.
The second channel relates to expectation formation. If time necessary
to remove excesses is lengthy after the collapse of a bubble, as well as to
overcome impacts of a financial crisis, expectations held by companies and
household may change, raising a risk of shifting the whole economy to a
different equilibrium. Of particular importance is the effect of the length-
ening of stagnation on the growth expectation of companies. A high-
growth expectation may raise investment and accordingly, raise growth
performance in a self-fulfilling way. By contrast, a low-growth expectation
can discourage investment and tends to bring about low-growth perfor-
mance. Therefore, in order to achieve high growth, it is important to
maintain a high-growth expectation. However, if the actual growth per-
formance continues to be low, then the growth expectation will be adjusted
downward. As is discussed in this book, in Japan, elimination of excessive
assets did not speedily progress after the collapse of the bubble; or rather,
the total asset size increased until the mid-1990s, and it took around
15 years after the collapse of the bubble to eliminate excessive assets by the
mid-2000s. Therefore, a significant restraint on investment continued for
a long period of time, producing prolonged low growth. As a result, the
growth expectation was adjusted downward, and the resultant low-growth
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 11
expectation seems to have become firmly rooted. Once the growth expec-
tation has been lowered, it is not easy to raise it. The difficulty in raising
growth expectations is shown in the responses of companies (in their con-
tinuation of restraints on wages and investment) to the comprehensive
economic policy package called “Abenomics,” which includes large-scale
monetary policy easing since 2013.
This book is structured as follows: Chap. 2 covers the formation of the
bubble. Chapter 3 briefly describes the collapse of the bubble and subse-
quent economic developments, and proposes to divide some 20 years of
stagnation from the collapse of the bubble to just preceding the Abenomics
period into four subperiods. This chapter also examines Period I, which is
the initial adjustment period after the collapse of the bubble until just
before the financial crisis. Chapter 4 covers the financial crisis in the late
1990s and its impacts (Period II), the subsequent long recovery (Period
III), and the turbulent era initiated by the GFC (Period IV). Chapter 5
examines the issue of deflation and monetary policy. Chapter 6 analyzes
corporate behaviors in order to identify the real mechanism of stagnation
and deflation. Chapter 7 covers Abenomics and challenges for the Japanese
economy. The main points of each chapter are summarized below.
Then, the chapter identifies two factors as causes of the bubble formation:
one, problems with economic policy management in this period; and two,
behaviors of financial institutions under financial liberalization. With
respect to policy management, we note that the economic policies in this
period were operating under two constraints, which altered policies and
promoted the formation of the bubble. The first and biggest constraint on
the economic policy management at that time was a fierce trade dispute
with the United States. The market-oriented economic policies, including
large-scale tax cuts adopted by the Reagan administration in the United
States starting at the beginning of the 1980s (“Reaganomics”) led to
“twin deficits,” that is, huge fiscal deficits and trade deficits in the United
States. In contrast, against such factors as the surging dollar, Japan’s cur-
rent account surplus expanded, leading to fierce trade disputes with the
United States. Solving the disputes became a serious challenge for Japan,
which is dependent on the United States for its national security.
The second constraint on the policy management was a deterioration of
the fiscal position, which proceeded rapidly due to economic stagnation
after the two oil crises and the strengthening of social security since the
first half of the 1970s. The administration at that time, which had aban-
doned the introduction of a consumption tax (the general consumption
tax proposed under the Ohira administration), maintained a policy of fiscal
consolidation without tax increase, that is, a policy of containing fiscal
expansion during the major part of the 1980s. So, the principal policy
agenda in the 1980s was focused on how to address the external friction
without imposing a policy burden on the fiscal side.
Under these two constraints, the Nakasone administration, which started
in the first half of the 1980s, pushed forward with deregulation, particularly
urban redevelopment through deregulation on land use, as an important
tool to expand domestic demand, but this policy provided a first drive for a
rapid land price increase. As the external imbalances continued and protec-
tionist movements mounted in the United States, Japan’s administration
took the position of accepting coordinated depreciation of the US dollar
(or, yen appreciation), and moved forward with the United States to the
adoption of the Plaza Accord by G-5 in 1985. However, once the apprecia-
tion of the yen gained a momentum in the market, it went far beyond the
expectations of the related countries, doubling its value in about two years’
time. Halting a further yen appreciation became an important policy agenda
for the administration. Despite such yen appreciation, the external imbal-
ances did not diminish soon and therefore, the United States did not soften
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 13
its demand of Japan for domestic demand expansion. Under the circum-
stances, monetary easing was maintained for a prolonged period of time in
order to solve the external disputes and also to prevent further appreciation
of the yen. When the monetary policy stance switched to the tightening
stance at the end of the 1980s, more than nine years had passed since any
previous tightening. Furthermore, since about the mid-1980s, the admin-
istration started to emphasize the importance of transforming the Japanese
economy into one that would not produce internationally incompatible
external imbalances, by structurally reforming the economy (Maekawa
Report 1986). In this way, the focus of the economic policies shifted from
domestic economic objectives to external objectives to correct external
imbalances. Deregulation, continued monetary policy easing, and the pol-
icy stance to give precedence to external objectives over domestic objectives
all seem to have substantially contributed to the formation and expansion of
the internal bubble, through implementation of such measures as enact-
ment of laws promoting real estate-related development projects including
resort facilities across Japan. These problems with economic policy manage-
ment are the main factors that contributed to the formation of a bubble.
In addition to the problems with policy management, there was a sec-
ond factor that worked toward the formation of the bubble—bank behav-
iors under financial liberalization. Financial liberalization started in the
latter half of the 1970s. Due to such factors as reduced demand for funds
after the end of the high-growth era and increased availability of diversi-
fied funding channels under the financial liberalization, large companies,
which were once the important clients of financial institutions, reduced
their dependence on borrowing from financial institutions. Against the
background of such erosion of the traditional client base and declining
profit margin under the financial liberalization, financial institutions
expanded activities in new markets, particularly in real estate-related loans,
substantially contributing to the formation of the bubble. It should be
noted that financial liberalization was not accompanied by sufficient
strengthening of regulation and supervision of risk management by finan-
cial institutions. In addition to these factors, active financial activities by
companies, called “Zaiteku” (financing technology) and “Tochi Shinwa”
(mythical trust in landholding) are also seen as causes of the bubble.
Due to the formation of the bubble, the private nonfinancial corporate
sector, particularly the non-manufacturing sector, came to hold huge assets
(typically, physical assets such as buildings and facilities) that were far greater
than the size implied by the trend before the bubble period, and this
imposed a very heavy burden on the Japanese economy in subsequent years.
14 K. ARAMAKI
policy easing was criticized for bringing about the long stagnation and
deflation. As for fiscal policy, it is important to point out that fiscal policy
substantially contributed to economic growth after the collapse of the
bubble through a series of stimulus packages that were compiled almost
yearly. Thus, it is argued, although there might have been a problem of
timing in the adoption of fiscal tightening, the fundamental cause of the
long stagnation from the beginning of the 1990s should be found in other
factors. While monetary policy management is examined in detail in Chap.
5 (Deflation and monetary policy), it is suggested that the problem with
the handling of monetary policy may have been more serious in crushing
the bubble, through aggressive monetary tightening and quantitative
restriction on real estate-related loans, rather than in the period after the
collapse of the bubble. This point is exemplified by the fact that the rate
of growth of money stock, which was over 10% per annum during the
preceding years, collapsed into negative territory at the beginning of the
1990s. The financial sector-problem views contend, for example, that
credit crunch, which reflected problems with financial sector soundness
due to the NPLs, led to the stagnation. However, the lending attitudes of
financial institutions were generally eased in the 1990s, excepting periods
immediately after the collapse of the bubble and during the financial crisis
in the latter half of 1990s. Therefore, credit tightening by financial institu-
tions could not have been the cause of the stagnation, at least not during
the early period of the stagnation after the collapse of the bubble and
before the financial crisis (this initial period is considered to be the most
critically important in the long stagnation).
After the overview, the chapter argues, as evidenced by the sudden halt
of nominal GDP growth, the long stagnation was started by a discontinu-
ous and abrupt factor (non-structural factor). At the same time, consider-
ing that the stagnation continued for more than 20 years, it seems that the
changes that were started by an abrupt factor were structuralized in the
process of stagnation, suggesting that the mechanism of the long stagna-
tion seems to have changed in the process. Drawing on this argument and
with a view to identifying the nature and change of the mechanism of
stagnation (disease) from the examination of characteristics of the econ-
omy (symptoms), it is proposed that we adopt an approach of dividing
these 20 years after the collapse of the bubble and until the start of the
Abenomics, that is, from 1991 to 2012 inclusive, into four subperiods
with different economic characteristics, so as to analyze the mechanism of
stagnation in each subperiod. In light of developments in such factors as
16 K. ARAMAKI
the bubble and until the mid-1990s. This is particularly true with the non-
manufacturing sector. This is probably because many of the excessive assets
formed during the bubble era were the types of assets that needed substan-
tial lead time before completion, such as real estate-related development
projects. Due to such a time lag and because companies did not choose to
quickly remove such low-profitability assets, stagnation of profits of com-
panies continued for a long time, damaging their financial position and
lowering their ability to repay their debts. This made the problems with the
NPLs increasingly more serious and finally led to a crisis of the financial
sector. An implication is that fiscal stimulus and monetary easing may have
succeeded in buying time by creating additional demand (the government
came to have huge debt as a result, though), but these macroeconomic
policies did not (could not) contribute to the speedy disposition of the
companies’ excessive assets (or supply capacity) formed during the bubble
era—a capacity that could not expect sustainable demand—and thus, were
unable to prevent the crisis.
use of tax money for the financial sector became almost taboo. However,
in November 1997, after the failure of medium-sized securities companies
led to a default in the interbank market for the first time since the Second
World War, it became difficult for some financial institutions to obtain
funding in the interbank market. Soon after, in the same month of
November 1997, Hokkaido Takushoku Bank, one of the largest banks in
Japan, and then Yamaichi Securities, one of the big four securities compa-
nies, failed one after the other. Long lines to withdraw funds formed in
front of local banks, and the situation came close to a crisis. Against this
background, a law that made possible capital injection into banks was
enacted, and public money was used to strengthen the capital base of
major banks in March 1998. While the situation was stabilized temporar-
ily, troubles with the Long-Term Credit Bank of Japan (LTCB) surfaced
in the summer of 1998, and new laws were enacted so as to introduce a
strengthened capital injection scheme, tied with early correction measures
based on the capital asset ratio and also to introduce a comprehensive
resolution system for failed banks, including nationalization. Under the
new laws, injection of capital four times as great as the funds injected in
March 1998 was implemented in 15 banks in March 1999, and the LTCB
and the Nippon Credit Bank, another LTCB, were nationalized in late
1998. Making use of this comprehensive safety net framework, the gov-
ernment strongly promoted disposition of NPLs. The goal of halving the
NPL ratio, set by the government in 2002, was achieved in 2005, and
the NPL problems (or, excess asset hangovers in the corporate sector)
that had long been a burden on the Japanese economy were finally
resolved.
Why were the NPL problems, which stayed with the economy for some
15 years, not resolved sooner? Companies did not promptly dispose of
excessive assets that lay behind the NPL problems, and banks did not
swiftly dispose of NPLs. Behind these developments, there were optimistic
expectations for the future course of the economy in the initial stage: the
magnitude of expected negative impacts that could result from prompt
resolution of excessive assets or NPLs; managerial judgments to avoid real-
ization of losses, increase in bankruptcies and unemployment, and aggra-
vation of the economy; and the governance system that made such
judgments possible. In the same vein, the government, charged with the
responsibility of maintaining soundness of the economy and financial sys-
tem, also took a long time to resolve the NPL problems. The reasons for
this may include optimistic expectations for the future in the initial stage
again, but also nonavailability of such a comprehensive safety net frame-
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 19
following the Second World War. Although the two economic recoveries
in the 1990s were both short-lived, the recovery in the 2000s continued
for a long period of time extending longer than six years and was relatively
strong in that investment made a positive contribution to growth. This was
due to two factors: (1) The so-called three excesses, that is, excessive capi-
tal stock, excessive debt, and excessive employment, which the corporate
sector assumed due to the formation and collapse of the bubble, had been
eliminated and their levels returned to the pre-bubble levels by around
mid-2000s. Thus, the negative legacy of the bubble was finally eliminated
(this corresponds to the resolution of the NPL problems for the financial
sector side). The second factor was favorable external environments of
high growth with low inflation in the world economy, which was later
termed “the great moderation.” However, even during the long recovery,
fundamental changes that had emerged in the Japanese economy (an ele-
vated unemployment rate, the decline in nominal wages, the shift from
regular to non-regular employment, companies’ shift to net saver posi-
tions, and deflation) continued, and restraints on investment and on labor
costs were maintained. In this period, in addition to these changes, other
developments became more apparent, such as a decline in growth contri-
bution of consumption under real wage reduction and increasing depen-
dence on foreign trade, characteristics which are observed in the current
Japanese economy.
Period IV (2008–2012) was a period when the Japanese economy expe-
rienced a series of external shocks, including the GFC, the European debt
crisis, and the Great East Japan Earthquake. The Japanese economy
recorded one of the deepest negative growth (annualized rates of 8.8% in
Q4 2008 and 18.2% in Q1 2009) among the major advanced economies
after the GFC, and its trade balance fell into deficit after the earthquake due
to the increase in energy-related imports. Despite these developments, the
yen-dollar exchange rate recorded a historic high. All these developments
showed increasing external vulnerability of the Japanese economy.
Despite the economy having eliminated the negative legacy of the bub-
ble and overcome shocks of the financial crisis in 15 years by the mid-
2000s, the solid economic growth did not come back. The average growth
rate over Periods III and IV (i.e., 2003–2012) was just 0.9%. Some factors
may have been depressing the growth potential of the Japanese economy.
Viewed in this way, the Japanese economy seems have assumed two
problems, even after having overcome the negative legacy of the bubble.
The first is the lasting shortage of domestic demand and the growing
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 21
the zero interest rate as an abnormal interest rate, and deterring decline in
the long-term interest rate. Regarding the monetary policy management
after entering the 2000s, that is, after the Japanese economy had fallen
into deflation and had been placed under the zero lower bound con-
straint, the BOJ introduced the quantitative easing policy, targeting at the
outstanding balance of the current accounts with the BOJ, which contrib-
uted to the fall in short- and medium-term interest rates. However, the
rate of money stock increase did not change, bank loans continued to
decline until mid-2000s, and deflation continued, showing a limitation of
the policy effects.
We conclude that monetary policy, if managed differently, might have
had greater stimulating effects on the economy in the period immedi-
ately after the collapse of the bubble. However, one can argue if the
fundamental problem of the Japanese economy in that period was not
demand shortage as is typically presumed, but rather excessive produc-
tion capacity (excess assets), as previously suggested, then the most
important action was not to stimulate demand but to reduce excessive
capacity (excessive assets). For the latter (i.e., removal of excessive
assets), what macroeconomic policies, including monetary policy, could
do was limited.
rent profits started to recover in a rising trend in the 1990s due to improve-
ments in the non-operational balance, which includes such items as interest
payments, but unlike the 1980s, improvements in current profits did not
lead to wage increases in and after the 1990s.
From the analysis of assets and liabilities, it is observed that both started
to expand from the mid-1980s to a level greater than that implied by the
then trend, continuing to grow, albeit at a slower pace in the first half of
the 1990s. Subsequently, assets and liabilities started to shrink from the
mid-1990s, returning to a level close to that implied by the pre-bubble
trend by around mid-2000s. This means that it took about 15 years after
the burst of the bubble for the corporate sector to complete its downward
adjustments of the excessive assets and liabilities. A look at the composi-
tion of assets shows that physical assets, such as buildings and machineries
(excluding land), started to decline from around the time of the financial
crisis in the latter half of the 1990s. The total asset size started to expand
again in the first half of 2000s, but physical assets (excluding land) contin-
ued to shrink until 2012. By contrast, securities held for investment pur-
poses significantly increased.4,5,6 The composition of assets has been
altered. Parallel to the curtailment of domestic physical assets, the size of
liabilities started to significantly decline after the mid-1990s, and then
became flat as of the early 2000s.
4
Most of the securities held for investment purpose are stocks, but their breakdown to
domestic and foreign stocks is not available. If we convert the outstanding balance of Japan’s
foreign direct investment (FDI) vis-à-vis the rest of the world (year-end, denominated in US
dollars) into yen using year-end exchange rates, we can see that the FDI balance accounts for
30–50% of the amount of securities held for investment purposes. In other words, half of the
securities held for investment purposes may be stocks of domestic companies. They are can-
celed out in a consolidated basis and do not contribute to strengthening of the net asset
position.
5
Since the mid-2000s, outward FDI started to significantly increase and, particularly after
the Lehman shock, the pace of outward FDI was accelerated.
6
The combined amount of physical assets (excluding land) and the outstanding balance of
FDI vis-à-vis the rest of the world (year-end, converted to yen) had been almost flat (or
marginally decreased until 2012) after the financial crisis in the late 1990s, and only recently
has started to show a rising trend. After the financial crisis, companies have proceeded with
the reduction of domestic physical assets and the expansion of overseas production bases,
gradually shifting production capacity from inside to outside the country.
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 25
to the financial sector in the form of increasing NPLs, and then a finan-
cial crisis broke out in late 1990s. Faced with the crisis, the way the
corporate sector addressed the problem of excessive assets dramatically
changed, and with this change, the stagnation entered the second stage,
as stated before. Specifically, with the breakout of the financial crisis, in
addition to the deterioration of economic conditions, the lending atti-
tude of financial institutions was suddenly tightened, including for
small- and medium-sized borrowers for which the tightening, of lending
attitudes after the burst of the bubble had been relatively moderate. In
the face of such adverse changes in funding environments, the corporate
sector seems to have started to forcefully strengthen its capital base. The
net asset position and the capital asset ratio started to rise sharply.
Strengthening of the net asset position was achieved mainly through the
accumulation of profits. Under the prolonged sales stagnation, the only
options open to companies to secure profits were reduction of labor
costs, reduction of interest payments through repayment of debts, and
sales of assets. Therefore, the companies embarked on full-fledged labor
cost reduction through nominal wage reduction and curtailment of reg-
ular workers, replacing them with non-regular workers. They also started
substantial repayments of debts and disposition of assets. Furthermore,
companies strengthened their stance toward restraining investment,
with a result that the size of physical assets, such as buildings and machin-
eries, started to decline. Companies’ responses in the second stage of
stagnation suggest that the previous corporate behavioral pattern under
which priority was given to securing employment and investment had
been significantly altered. Companies now gave the first priority to
strengthening their net asset position and placed importance on labor
cost reduction, restraining investment, and accepting reduction in physi-
cal assets. In Chap. 6, in light of changes of company behaviors, the
period from the financial crisis up to the first half of the 2000s is called
“Crisis Response” period.
By the mid-2000s, shocks of the financial crisis were overcome, and
removal of excessive assets and debt as well as excessive employment had
been completed (it took about 15 years to remove excesses after the burst
of the bubble). However, such defensive behaviors of companies to
restrain labor costs and investment continued. Thus, in Chap. 6, the
period from the mid-2000s to present is called the “Sustained
Defensiveness” period. Such defensiveness of companies placed
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 27
7
In addition to such behavioral changes of companies, however, it is possible that external
factors such as international competition through cost reduction under the yen appreciation
and a rapid catching-up of emerging market economies contributed to the nominal wage
decline and the emergence of deflation. See Chap. 6 on this point.
8
Under the continued restraint of investment, return on asset (ROA), which had been
declining since the 1960s, hit a bottom in the latter half of 1990s and showed a slight
increase in the 2000s.
28 K. ARAMAKI
third arrow, that is, for the growth strategy, the administration adopted
the “Japan Revitalization Strategy” in June 2013. The strategy set a goal
of achieving around 3% nominal and 2% real GDP growth on average over
the coming 10 years. The revised revitalization strategy, adopted in June
2014, included such items as reducing the effective rate of corporate tax
to below 30% and deregulation in hard core areas, such as agriculture,
health care, and energy (the revitalization strategy was further revised in
June 2015, and June 2016).
The initial impacts of Abenomics, particularly those of the introduction
of QQE, were dramatic. Stock price (Nikkei 225) rose by 88% in just over
a one-year period to the end of 2013, and the yen depreciated against the
US dollar until May 2013, by more than 20%, from the high of below 80
yen to over 100 yen to the dollar in a half year. However, subsequent
developments are not as one-sided or dramatic as in the initial period, with
positive movements and stagnation intermingled.
Chapter 7 assesses five years under the Abenomics as follows. First, the
Abenomics, particularly in its initial phase, produced substantial deprecia-
tion of the yen and sharp rise of stock prices. This is most likely due to the
change of expectation held by the foreign investors regarding Japanese
economy, stock prices, and yen rate, which were triggered by bold mone-
tary easing. Second, depreciation of the yen rate and the rise of stock
prices have not changed the trend of real GDP growth by much so far.
However, since Abenomics started, the interest rate has declined across
the maturity from short term to long term, and bank lending has been
maintaining the growth trend since the recovery period after the Lehman
shock. The recovery momentum has been maintained. Third, a break-
down of the economic growth structure under Abenomics by demand
components indicates, as compared with the period preceding Abenomics,
the growth contribution of net exports has significantly increased, and the
growth contribution of government expenditure has nearly doubled; in
contrast, the contribution of consumption halved, and the growth contri-
bution of private investment more or less remained unchanged. Fourth,
price levels showed positive increase for more than two years from May
2013. This increase, however, is affected to a substantial degree by exter-
nal developments, including yen depreciation (rather than improvements
in domestic demand/supply conditions). Fifth, while company profits
have been registering record highs, private investment, while increasing,
has not shown significant increase; restraint on wages continues and cash
INTRODUCTION: OBJECTIVES AND MAIN ARGUMENTS OF THE BOOK 31
9
The expected real growth rate of the Japanese growth rate held by companies (Cabinet
Office, “Survey on Company Behavior”) slightly rose after Abenomics started, but it then
declined and has stayed at a level of just over 1% for the last few years.
32 K. ARAMAKI
Bibliography
English Reference
Kosai, Yutaka (1986) The Era of High-Speed Growth – Notes on the Postwar
Japanese Economy. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.
10
Kosai (1986) wrote, in the famous paragraph from the 1956 Economic White Paper,
which announced the end of the postwar recovery, “there was … a concealed but profound
fear that a slackening of the growth rate would accompany the end of postwar reconstruc-
tion” (Kosai 1986, 106). “Since high growth was not expected to continue beyond the
recovery period, it was not generally thought that plant and equipment investment was
undertaken in earnest on an all-out scale.” “If growth were to continue beyond the recovery
period, the capital stock would have to be expanded …. Firms that had begun to be confi-
dent that growth would continue set about as though with one accord to renovate their plant
and equipment” (Kosai 1986, 108–9). This episode implies that the reality of high growth
drove the companies toward investment, which led to the continuation of high growth.
CHAPTER 2
1
The rate of change in the urban commercial land price index (six largest cities) from six
months before started to rise at a significantly higher pace than before, as early as in 1983,
with the rate of increase nearly doubling from 3.1% in March 1983 (which was about the
average rate of increase in the preceding two to three years) to 5.7% in October 1983, and it
600
500
400
Commercial use
300
Residential use
200
100
0
10/1/1954
4/1/1957
10/1/1959
4/1/1962
10/1/1964
4/1/1967
10/1/1969
4/1/1972
10/1/1974
4/1/1977
10/1/1979
4/1/1982
10/1/1984
4/1/1987
10/1/1989
4/1/1992
10/1/1994
4/1/1997
10/1/1999
4/1/2002
10/1/2004
4/1/2007
10/1/2009
4/1/2012
Fig. 2.1 Urban land price index: Six largest cities (end March 2000 = 100)
October 1954–April 2012. Source: Japan Real Estate Institute
Urban land prices started to decline from October 1990 and continued
to fall for 14 years to 67.2 in April 2004 (a decline of 87.0% from the peak
in April 1990), which was the level in 1972–73, before it showed a mini-
mal increase of 0.2% in October 2004.
For residential land, the urban land price index (residential use, end
March 2000 = 100) for the six largest cities increased by about three times
from 77.5 in April 1983 to the peak of 231.5 in April 1990. Then, it
declined to 76.9 (the bottom at the time) in October 2004, losing 66.8%
from the value at the peak.
Figure 2.2 shows that stock prices (Nikkei 225 [monthly average])
increased 5.4 times in a period slightly longer than seven years from
7,042 in August 1982 to 38,130 in December 1989.2 The Nikkei 225
continued to rise to hit a peak of 27.2% in April 1987. Although it is not easy to determine
the exact timing when the bubble started, it does not seem to be as late as the late 1980s
(that is when the rate of increase started to fall) as sometimes argued (e.g., Okina et al.
(2001) treats the four years from 1987 to 1990 “bubble period,” partly due to difference in
the definition of a bubble).
2
From September 1982, the Nikkei monthly average almost continuously recorded posi-
tive growth from the previous month with occasional brief falls until December 1989, before
it started to collapse in January 1990.
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 35
(yen)
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
6/1/1949
7/1/1952
8/1/1955
9/1/1958
10/1/1961
11/1/1964
12/1/1967
1/1/1971
2/1/1974
3/1/1977
4/1/1980
5/1/1983
6/1/1986
7/1/1989
8/1/1992
9/1/1995
10/1/1998
11/1/2001
12/1/2004
1/1/2008
2/1/2011
Fig. 2.2 Nikkei 225 (monthly average) June 1949–February 2013. Source:
NIKKEI NEEDS
started to fall in January 1990, hit the bottom at 15,790 (−58.6% from
the peak) in August 1992, that is, in less than three years, and then became
fairly stabilized in the range of 16,000–21,000, before it resumed a fall in
late 1997.
P = R / i, (2.1)
P = R / (i + a - g), (2.2)
where α is the risk premium (an additional return on top of the return to
a risk-free asset that is required for a risk asset to be held), and g is the
growth rate of the return (R).
See the supplement to this chapter for the derivation of theoretical price (i.e., price based
3
on fundamentals).
4
In calculating the theoretical price, the prevailing levels of return and the interest rate
were assumed to be unchanged for the future. See Nenji Keizai Hokoku (Annual Economic
Report) 1991 (Economic Planning Agency).
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 37
Fig. 2.3 Actual and theoretical land price (land for business use, Central
Tokyo.1983 = 1) 1971–1991. Note: In calculating the theoretical price, the pre-
vailing levels of return and the interest rate are assumed to be unchanged for the
future. Source: Economic Planning Agency, “Nenji Keizai Hokoku (Annual
Economic Report) 1991”
800.0
700.0
500.0
400.0
300.0
100.0
70 72 B 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90
71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91
Fig. 2.4 Actual and projected land price (all uses) in Tokyo metropolitan area.
Note: Land price is regressed on GDP of Tokyo and the long-term interest rate for
1970–1986. Source: Fiscal and Monetary Research Institute, Ministry of Finance,
Japan, “Shisan kakaku hendo no mekanizumu to sono keizai koka” (The
Mechanism of Asset Price Movements and its Economic Impacts), November
1993 Finansharu Rebyu
38 K. ARAMAKI
Fig. 2.5 Rate of land price increases by area and by type of use in the Tokyo
metropolitan area, 1983–1991. Source: Economic Planning Agency, Nenji Keizai
Hokoku (Annual Economic Report) 1991
5
This is when the rate of commercial land price increase nearly doubled (see Endnote 1 in
this chapter).
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 39
Fig. 2.6 Spillovers of land price increases from Tokyo to Osaka and Nagoya
metropolitan areas and to local areas. Source: Economic Planning Agency, Nenji
Keizai Hokoku (Annual Economic Report) 1991
There are factors that might have triggered the initial rise in commer-
cial land prices in central Tokyo, such as increasing attention from
abroad in financial markets in Tokyo and the expectation that a growing
number of offices of foreign financial institutions would be established
in Tokyo. Figure 2.7 shows that the vacancy rate of office space in Tokyo
was rapidly falling and reached almost 0% in the mid-1980s. This implies
that there was a real factor, that is, a tightening of demand/supply con-
ditions for office space to explain the rise in the price of commercial land
in Tokyo in the early 1980s. So, the significant rise in land prices may
well have started by a fundamental factor at the beginning. Through the
process of subsequent spillovers of price increase, however, to other land
uses and to other areas, an element of bubble may have begun at that
point, leading to a huge asset price bubble in extensive areas and sectors
in Japan.
(ha) (%)
Average vacancy rate (RHS)
1750 2.5
Aggregate floor size (LHS)
1500 2.0
1250 1.5
1000 1.0
750 0.5
Office vacancy rate (RHS)
500 0
75 80 85 89
Fig. 2.7 Aggregate floor size of the buildings belonging to the Tokyo Building
Association and average vacancy rate. Source: Bank of Japan, “Chosa Geppo”
(Monthly Research Report) April 1990
Summary
From the foregoing, the following observations may be made:
6
See 2.3 (Stock price) of Supplement to this chapter.
7
The theoretical price rises if the risk premium (α) decreases, and/or the expected growth
rate (g) of return increases in Eq. (2.2) on page 36.
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 41
First, the initial commercial land price rise in the central Tokyo may have
been based on fundamental factors.
Second, the subsequent price surge in commercial land from around the mid-
1980s in Tokyo, the spillovers to residential land prices in Tokyo and also
to other areas in Japan, however, seem to have been a bubble.
Third, the stock price rise in the late 1980s may have reflected an increase
in expected profit growth (GDP growth rate may have acted as its
proxy) and a fall in risk premium under strong confidence in the econ-
omy (which seems to have led to positive risk taking by companies and
individuals). However, both the high-growth expectation and low-risk
premium were not realistic.
Chronology
A brief chronology of the important developments that happened in the
two decades over the 1970s and 1980s is shown in Table 2.1.
We can see from this brief chronology that these two decades were full
of many external turbulent incidents. The 1970s saw, first, the demise
of the stable exchange rate regime (Nixon shock). The peg system was
abandoned, and under the float system, the yen basically continuously
appreciated for subsequent decades, bringing the Japanese economy from
time to time to the state of “high yen driven stagnation.” The 1970s also
saw two oil crises, which drove the crude oil price (in terms of Arabian
light) to nearly 20 times higher than its 2 US dollars per barrel in the
early 1970s to around 40 US dollars per barrel in 1979,8 and the world
economy fell into a severe stagnation coupled with high inflation (stagfla-
tion). For Japan, both these developments (i.e., the collapse of the peg
system and the yen appreciation, and the worldwide stagflation), together
with the end of high-speed growth of the early 1970s, imposed a heavy
burden on the fiscal policy management, bringing about a sharp aggrava-
Table 2.1 Major economic and political developments in the 1970s and 1980s
8
See Komine, Takao (2011a).
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 43
tion of the government fiscal position. Then, the 1980s saw a growing
friction between Japan and the United States against the background of a
worsening external trade balance of the United States during the first
Reagan administration and expanding external surpluses of Japan.
These two factors, that is, deterioration of fiscal position and intensifying
external disputes with the United States, provided the basic constraints on
the Japan’s economic policy management in this period. This is the first factor
affecting the bubble formation. The deterioration of the fiscal position also
acted as a push factor for financial liberalization to be explained later, which
is the second factor affecting the bubble formation. We will first look at how
Japan’s economic policy management was conducted under these constraints,
that is, trade disputes with the United States and deterioration of the fiscal
position, and find out what such policy management has brought about.
(millions of US dollar)
40000
20000
0
-20000
1966
1968
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1965
1967
1969
1971
1973
1975
1977
1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
-40000
-60000
-80000
-100000
-120000
-140000
-160000
-180000
Fig. 2.10 Current account balance: Japan 1966–1990. Source: Cabinet Office,
“Choki Keizai Tokei Heisei 24” (Long-term economic statistics FY 2012)
(%)
4.0
3.0
Ip
85-90 Ave
-1.0
-2.0
Fig. 2.11 Real GDP growth contribution by private investment in plant and
equipment (Ip) and net exports (NE) in 1956–1973 (high-speed growth era),
1974–1984 (stable growth era), and 1985–1990 (bubble era). Source: Cabinet
Office, GDP statistics
1950s– Textiles
1960s– Steel, color TVs
1970s– Beef and oranges, NTT (Nippon Telegraph and Telephone Corporation)
procurement, automobiles
1980s– Semi-conductors, mobile phones, etc.
46 K. ARAMAKI
9
See Komine (2011a).
10
In 1982, a tragic incident happened in which a young Chinese man, who was mistaken
for a Japanese man, was killed by laid-off automobile workers in Detroit.
11
See Volcker and Gyoten (1992).
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 47
(%)
3
0
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
-1
(FY)
-2
-3
-4
-5
Fig. 2.12 General government fiscal balance (GDP ratio): Japan 1965–1990.
Source: Cabinet Office
12
Ahead of the summit meeting in London in 1978, an argument gained a high profile
that Japan, West Germany, and the United States, with their relatively good performance,
should act as the locomotive countries to lead the recovery of the world economy.
48 K. ARAMAKI
majority in the lower (i.e., more powerful) house election in late 1979.
After a hard fought internal battle within the ruling party (the “40 day
battle”), Ohira was reelected as PM. The battle continued, however, and
finally, a non-confidence resolution was adopted in the lower house in the
absence from voting of a large number of ruling party members. Ohira
dissolved the lower house, but in the midst of the campaign, he passed
away. Although the ruling party won the election, the Suzuki administra-
tion, which succeeded Ohira’s, committed itself to the pursuit of fiscal
consolidation without tax increase, which constrained the scope of fiscal
measures to cope with the policy agenda, including with the growing
external frictions during most of the 1980s.
13
Komine (2011a, 112)
14
Komine (2011a, 115–17)
15
Komine (2011a, 123–4) quotes a writing by an ex-official of the Ministry of Construction,
50 K. ARAMAKI
who interviewed 20 local real estate agents that were actively buying land in the center of
Tokyo. He wrote that out of 20 agents, only one mentioned the intended use of the land that
it purchased, suggesting that they were buying land to resell at higher prices.
16
However, in 2000, the size of office space in the central Tokyo turned out to be 8000 ha,
not very far from the projection (Komine 2011a, 284).
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 51
17
Komine (2011a, 148)
18
See Funabashi (1988) and Kondo (1999).
19
See Funabashi (1988, 28–9). It has not been made publicly available yet.
52 K. ARAMAKI
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
Jan-80
Jun-80
Nov-80
Apr-81
Sep-81
Feb-82
Jul-82
Dec-82
May-83
Oct-83
Mar-84
Aug-84
Jan-85
Jun-85
Nov-85
Apr-86
Sep-86
Feb-87
Jul-87
Dec-87
May-88
Oct-88
Mar-89
Aug-89
Fig. 2.13 Yen–dollar exchange rate (monthly average) 1980–1989. Source:
Bank of Japan
–– The large current account deficit has its root in our economic struc-
ture, including its export orientation.
–– In order to realize an internationally compatible economy, we have to
realize a domestic demand-led economic growth and fundamentally
change the structure of imports and exports and industries.
“The Ministers and Governors agreed that the substantial exchange rate
changes since the Plaza Agreement … have now brought their currencies
within ranges broadly consistent with underlying economic fundamentals ….
In current circumstances, therefore, they agreed to cooperate closely to fos-
ter stability of exchange rates around current levels.”
five times, by a total of 5.5%, to reach 9.0% in March 1980). As the econ-
omy started to slow down from around the spring of 1980, monetary
policy was eased gradually from August 1980, and the discount rate came
down to 5.5% in December 1981. The economy started to recover, led by
export growth in the spring of 1983, and the monetary policy was broadly
unchanged. Although reduced to 5.0% in October 1983, interest rates
were kept high due to the high overseas interest rates (the US interest rate
was exceptionally high at around 10–14% throughout the first half of
1980s), and concerns for the further yen depreciation.
(%)
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Jan-80
Jul-80
Jan-81
Jul-81
Jan-82
Jul-82
Jan-83
Jul-83
Jan-84
Jul-84
Jan-85
Jul-85
Jan-86
Jul-86
Jan-87
Jul-87
Jan-88
Jul-88
Jan-89
Jul-89
Jan-90
Jul-90
Fig. 2.14 Official discount rate: Japan 1980–1990. Source: Bank of Japan
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 55
Table 2.5 BOJ’s explanation of monetary policy changes in the late 1980s
Date of Contents of Explanation by the BOJ
policy the change
changes
21
Komine (2011a, 118, 213, 232).
22
The combined share in the total amount of physical assets of non-manufacturing indus-
tries held by these four industries accounted for 57% as of 1990, 6.1% for construction,
18.8% for transportation and postal services, 18.1% for wholesale and retail, and 14.1% for
real estate. Major holders of physical assets, other than these four sectors as of 1990, are
electricity (17.3%), entertainment (5.2%), and advertising (10.8%).
58 K. ARAMAKI
(t rillion yen)
250
All industries
200 (excluding
financial and
150 insurance
companies)
100 Manufacturing
Non-
50
manufacturing
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 2.15 Land holdings by all industries (excluding financial and insurance
companies) and their breakdown between manufacturing and non-manufacturing
sectors. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of
Corporations by Industry”
(t rillion yen)
400
350
All industries
300 excluding financial
and insurance
250 companies
200 Manufacturing
150 Non-manufacturing
100
50
0
FY1960
FY1964
FY1968
FY1972
FY1976
FY1980
FY1984
FY1988
FY1992
FY1996
FY2000
FY2004
FY2008
FY2012
FY2016
Fig. 2.16 Physical assets (excluding land) held by all industries (excluding
financial and insurance companies) and their breakdown between manufacturing
and non-manufacturing sectors. Source: Ministry of Finance “Financial Statements
Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 59
(trillion yen)
50
45
40
35 Construction
30 Transportation
25 and postal
20 service
15 Real estate
10 Wholesale
5 and retail
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 2.17 Physical assets (excluding land) held by four major non-manufacturing
industries. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of
Corporations by Industry”
23
A detailed analysis of the balance sheets of the corporate sector is given in Chap. 6.
60 K. ARAMAKI
In the 1980s, policies were bound by two constraints, that is, external fric-
tion with the United States and fiscal deterioration, with the former
playing the dominant role. In early years, efforts to cope with these two
constraints through deregulation and “Minkatsu,” particularly in the
form of urban redevelopment promotion, apparently sowed a seed for
subsequent land price hikes.
Under the extreme intensification of friction with the United States in the
mid-1980s, Japan chose exchange rate adjustments, while the United States
preferred domestic demand expansion. Furthermore, the then administra-
tion of Japan set as a medium- to long-term goal the transformation of
Japan into an economy led by domestic demand to correct external imbal-
ances, thus gradually shifting the focus of economic policy from domestic
economic issues to solutions for external disputes. In the meantime, a seri-
ous domestic problem—the formation of a huge bubble—was in progress.
In parallel, Japan made efforts to halt further appreciation of the yen. Such
efforts and the policy orientation toward a domestic demand-led econ-
omy apparently constrained macroeconomic policy management, which
is responsible for the stabilization of the domestic economy, and led to
a series of instances of monetary policy easing and then fiscal expansions,
aggravating asset price inflation into the late 1980s. In this situation, the
corporate sector acquired hugely excessive assets.
24
The IS balance approach to current account determination may be helpful in capturing
this process.
We have a national account identity:
Y = Cp + Ip + Cg + Ig + X - M, (24.1)
Where Y = GDP, Cp = private consumption, Ip = private investment, Cg = government
consumption, Ig = government investment, X=export, M = import
Using T for Tax and rearranging the identity, we have:
{( Y - T - Cp ) - Ip} + ( T - Cg ) - Ig = X - M, (24.2)
Dollar Appreciation
The US dollar appreciated substantially under a policy combination of
stable monetary policy and expansionary fiscal policy. The nominal yen
rate against the dollar was kept fairly low for the first half of the 1980s (see
Fig. 2.13).
As the inflation rate was higher in the United States than in Japan in the
1980s (Fig. 2.19), the yen rate in real effective terms was fairly low, despite
expanding external surpluses throughout the first half of 1980s, contribut-
ing to the continuation of current account imbalances (Fig. 2.20).
(%)
1.0
0.0
-1.0 Savings/
investment
-2.0 balance of
government
-3.0 Current
account
-4.0 balance
-5.0
-6.0
-7.0
(%)
16
US
14
Japan
12
10
0
1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991
Fig. 2.19 Consumer Price Index (year-on-year change): US and Japan. Source:
IMF, World Economic Outlook database October 2015
(yen)
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
Apr-78
Mar-79
Feb-80
Jan-81
Dec-81
Nov-82
Oct-83
Sep-84
Aug-85
Jul-86
Jun-87
May-88
Apr-89
Mar-90
Jan-70
Dec-70
Nov-71
Oct-72
Sep-73
Aug-74
Jul-75
Jun-76
May-77
Fig. 2.20 Real effective exchange rate of the yen (2010 = 100), 1970–1990.
Source: Bank of Japan
64 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
8
U.S.
Japan
6
0
1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985
-2
-4
Fig. 2.21 Real GDP growth rate: US and Japan, 1980–1985. Source: IMF,
World Economic Outlook database October 2015
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 65
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
Fig. 2.22 Crude oil prices (Dubai, in dollar per barrel), 1965–1999. Source:
IMF, “International Financial Statistics” (“IFS”)
Table 2.6 Factor analysis of Japan’s current account surplus (estimate) (in 100
million US dollars)
FY 1982 FY 1983 Change
Source: Nenji Keizai Hokoku FY1984 (Annual Economic Report), Economic Planning Agency
Table 2.7 GDP growth rate and private investment (year-on-year change, period
average): 1956–1973, 1974–1984, 1985–1990 (%)
1956–1973 1974–1984 1985–1990
25
Assume that companies invest in plants and equipment so as to keep the capital–output
ratio (K/Y) constant (a) under the expected GDP growth rate (ge) and also assume for the
sake of simplicity there is no disposition of assets, then we have:
K / Y = DK / DY = I / DY = a, (25-1)
DY / Y = ge (25-2)
From Eqs. (25.1) and (25.2):
I / DY = I / ( Y ´ ge ) = a
(25-3)
So, we have:
I / Y = a ´ ge (25-4)
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 67
That is, the share of private investment in plants and equipment in GDP has positive cor-
relation with the expected GDP growth rate, i.e., if the expected GDP growth rate falls, then
the share of private investment in GDP also falls.
Relaxing the unrealistic assumption of zero disposal of assets, let us assume that the
amount of disposed assets (D) is a fraction (b) of capital stock (D = bK). Then, ΔK = I−bK,
and therefore, Eq. (25.4) changes into
I / Y = a ( ge + b )
(25-5)
So, basically, the same argument applies even under this formulation.
26
As an argument for a need to enhance consumption in Japan, see Katz (1999).
Whether we can raise growth contribution of consumption in a sustainable manner is an
unanswered question even now, 30 years after the bubble period (see Chap. 7 for
this point).
68 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
25.0
20.0
10.0 Share of
private
investment
5.0 in real GDP
0.0
-5.0
Fig. 2.23 Real GDP growth rate and share of private investment in plants and
equipment in real GDP. Source: Cabinet Office
(%)
30.0
25.0
20.0
Private
15.0 investment
Government
10.0 expenditure
Net exports
5.0
0.0
-5.0
Fig. 2.24 Share in real GDP of private investment in plants and equipment,
government expenditure, and net exports: Japan 1965–1990. Source: Cabinet
Office
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 69
The examination thus far of the situation that prevailed at that time
indicates, first, that it was becoming difficult to expect a rapid increase in
private investment in plants and equipment after the end of the high-
growth era with the slowing down of the growth rate, and, second, that,
in light of the deteriorating fiscal position, it also became difficult to fur-
ther expand government expenditures that had already been expanded to
make up for the decline in the growth contribution by private investment.
It is questionable whether private consumption, a major remaining com-
ponent of domestic demand, could have become a driver of growth when
the rate of economic growth was decelerating and the share of private
consumption in GDP was declining after the two oil crises and subsequent
recession.
If this were the case, it might have been difficult from the beginning to
drastically reduce external imbalances (current account surpluses) that
had been largely exogenously created, through expansion of domestic
demand on the side of Japan.27 It is possible that, in the process of politi-
cally pursuing goals difficult to achieve economically from the outset, seri-
ous problems emerged in the management of relevant economic
policies.28
27
There may well be an argument that adjustments in the exchange rate or liberalization
of domestic markets will contribute to correcting external imbalances through changes in
exports and imports. However, effectiveness of the market opening depends largely on reac-
tions of companies and households and is therefore uncertain. Adjustments in foreign
exchange rates were actually implemented, and the external imbalance of both Japan and the
United States declined. As is shown in Fig. 2.18, however, the decline in current account
deficits of the United States took place in conjunction with the decline in the size of excess
investment in investment/savings balance, implying that the US external imbalance was a
domestically driven phenomenon after all.
28
It may be said that this is an outcome of external consideration taking precedence over
the stabilization of the domestic economy and society, given the circumstances that Japan
depends on a foreign country for its national security.
70 K. ARAMAKI
Table 2.8 Developments in real estate-related loans by banks (%, trillion yen)
Outstanding loan balance as of end fiscal year Average rate of
increase from FY
1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1985 to 1989
Source: Fiscal and Monetary Research Institute, Ministry of Finance, Japanese Government (1993)
(%)
35
30
25
20 Real estate
Non-bank
15 Construction
Total share
10 of three
sectors
5
Fig. 2.25 Share of loans to three real estate-related sectors in total outstanding
loans. Source: Tabulated based on Komine (2011a, 77)
Figure 2.25 shows that the shares held by three real estate-related sec-
tors (real estate, non-bank financial institutions, and construction) in total
loans significantly increased from the first half of 1980s.
We need to determine why banks increased real estate-related loans
in this period. Behind such behaviors, there were two pressures at
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 71
work. First was the erosion of the traditional client base of banks (par-
ticularly, big manufacturing companies). This was due to such factors
as the decline in investment needs of companies with the end of high-
speed growth era, accumulation of their own funds, and financial liber-
alization that had made financing through capital markets easier,
particularly for big companies. Second was the shrinking profit margin
of banks, also due to financial liberalization, which had made competi-
tion harder for banks in both funding and lending markets. These fac-
tors pushed banks to new profitable markets, including real estate-related
loans, longer term loans, and loans to medium- and small-sized com-
panies and individuals.
Let us look at these factors in some more detail.
29
Ministry of Finance (1993).
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 73
sought business providing high profits in new markets, such as small- and
medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), individuals, and real estate-related loans.
30
“Tochi Shinwa,” which literally translated means “land myth,” is a perception that there
is no asset more profitable than land. This perception held well until 1980s. For example, an
estimate is made that, although investment of 3 million yen in deposits in 1955 would have
increased to 22.83 million yen in 1985, investment of the same amount in land in one of the
six largest cities would have increased to 402 million yen, 17.6 times more in 1985 (Ministry
of Finance 1993). Price of land continued to rise after the Second World War, with an excep-
tional fall in 1974, after the oil crisis. There had been land price surges twice (early 1960s and
around 1972–73) after the war, but neither of them were later found to be a bubble. In the
1980s, the asset price surge was generally not considered as a bubble at that time. Noguchi
(1992) counted the number of the articles that appeared in the media, such as Nihon Keizai
Shimbun, which have the word “bubble” for each year from 1985 to 1992. He found that
74 K. ARAMAKI
banks and the spillovers to other banks helped spur this transformation of
what had been a traditionally conservative business model for banks.31
Summary
In this chapter, we have examined that the two factors that affected the
formation of the bubble—economic policy management and bank behav-
iors in the 1980s. The trade disputes with the United States and the dete-
rioration of the fiscal position imposed constraints on the management of
economic policies in the 1980s.
Under these constraints, the government tried to stimulate the economy
through deregulation, including urban redevelopment, which seems to
the number was 1–8 in each year from 1985 to 1988, 11 in 1989, the peak year of the
bubble, 194 in 1990, and then a dramatic increase to 2,546 in 1991, and 3,475 in 1992.
These numbers suggest the asset price developments started to be recognized as a bubble
only after those prices had started to fall.
31
In the 1980s, aggressive profit-seeking by banks was under way. One famous phrase that
was spoken by the chairman of one of the biggest city banks in the early 1980s conveys well
the thinking of the era; “Mukou Kizu ha Towanai” (literally, frontal scar will not bother).
“Mukou Kizu” is a scar that one receives from a frontal assault, when fighting an enemy,
while “Ushiro Kizu” (a scar on the back) is the kind one would suffer when trying to escape
from the enemy. Samurai regarded Ushiro Kizu as a shame. This phrase indicates that the
management of banks at the time accepted or even encouraged aggressive profit-seeking by
their staff (see Kusu [2005]). Presumably, raising objections to such profit-seeking activities
meant dropping out from internal competition in the institution.
32
Ministry of Finance (1993).
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 75
have planted seeds for the formation of a bubble in the early 1980s although
there was a real factor for asset price increases in the very initial stage. Under
continued disputes with the United States, the government accepted the
appreciation of the yen (Plaza Accord) and also tried to transform Japan’s
economy into a more domestic demand-led one. However, with the sharper-
than-expected appreciation of the yen, the BOJ was motivated to ease mon-
etary policy repeatedly to promote the expansion of the domestic economy
and to stabilize the yen rate in the late 1980s. Furthermore, in the process
of formulating international consensus for exchange rate stabilization, the
government committed to use fiscal policy to expand the domestic econ-
omy, which all created the conditions for the development of a bubble.
Furthermore, the policy idea to transform the Japanese economy to a
domestic demand-led one regrettably produced laws that promoted unsus-
tainable land-related development projects throughout the country.
Another factor that might have been responsible for the bubble was the
banks’ behaviors during the financial liberalization. With the erosion of
traditional client base and shrinking profit margins under liberalization,
banks tried to enter new markets and sharply increased their real estate-
related loans, which spurred the increase in land prices. Companies’
aggressive engagements in financial activities also contributed to the stock
market surge.33
These activities, taken together—heavy involvement by banks in real
estate-related loans and aggressive financial activities by companies—were
inevitably accompanied by high risk. With hindsight, strengthening of risk
management by banks and tightening of regulation and supervision to
that end was needed, but the issues were not sufficiently addressed at the
time. Why were these risky (in hindsight) activities left unchecked? Who
should be held responsible? Bank and company managers? Bank and com-
pany shareholders? Government? Mass media? We need to ask what could
have been done when all these agents had strong confidence in the
Japanese economy, and yet, were trapped by the “Tochi Shinwa” and
accordingly, could not see the risk of land price collapse?34
33
The number of individual shareholders increased by around 10% each year in this period,
from over 16 million in FY1985 to over 24 million in FY1989 (Ministry of Finance 1993).
Privatization of government-owned Japan Telegram and Telephone Corporation and sales of
its shares to the public in 1987 attracted nationwide attention.
34
See Kusu (2006).
76 K. ARAMAKI
However, we should note that all these actions occurred amid fierce
disputes with, and strong pressures from the United States, on which Japan
was (and still is) dependent for its national security. It is most regrettable
that, under the circumstances, policy focus shifted from domestic issues to
external problems, and the evolving problems, that is, the formation of a
huge bubble, went unchecked, and necessary actions (i.e., giving priority to
the consideration of domestic economy over external considerations, or at
least limiting external considerations within the range of what was compat-
ible with the stability of the domestic economy) were not taken.
3 Supplement
Fundamental Price
The price based on fundamentals (=theoretical price) is expressed as below:
If the asset has no risk and the return is fixed:
P = R / i, (2.1)
P = R / (i + a - g), (2.2)
where α is the risk premium (an additional return that is required for a
risk asset to be held, on top of the return to a risk-free asset)
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 77
Derivation
Risk-free Case
Derivation of theoretical price (price based on fundamentals)
Assumption: There is no difference in risk profile across assets
Formulation: The rate of return will be equalized across different assets
via arbitrage, so that we have
R/P=i (2.3)
P=R/i (2.4)
P = R / (i + a ) (2.5)
The aforementioned assumes that the asset price is constant. If the asset
price changes, then, the formulation changes as follows.
The rate of return for buying the asset in period 1 for P1 and selling it
in period 2 for P2 is shown in the left-hand side of Equation (2.6). and it
will be equal to the rate of return of the risk-free asset on the right-hand
side of the equation.
(R + (P 2 - P1 ) ) / P1 = i
(2.6)
Or,
P1 = ( R + P2 ) / (1 + i ) (2.7)
In the same way, the asset price in period 2 (P2) may be expressed as
follows.
78 K. ARAMAKI
P2 = ( R + P3 ) / (1 + i ) (2.8)
By inserting (2.8) into (2.7), we have
P1 = ( R + ( R + P3 ) / (1 + i ) ) / (1 + i ) (2.9)
Or,
P1 = R / (1 + i ) + R / (1 + i ) + P3 / (1 + i )
2 3
(2.10)
P1 = R / (1 + i ) + R / (1 + i ) + R / (1 + i ) + ,
2 3
(2.11)
Growth of Return
If we assume that the return (R) grows every period at a fixed rate of g,
then we have
P11 = R / (1 + i ) + R (1 + g ) / (1 + i ) + R (1 + g ) / (1 + i ) +
2 2 3
(2.12)
P1 = R / ( i - g ) (2.13)
P1 = R / ( i + a - g ) (2.14)
P= r /i (2.15)
The interest rate- adjusted PER (i × (Actual stock price/profit per one
unit of stock (ρ))) corresponds to the ratio of Actual stock price to
Theoretical stock price:
( r / i ) = Actual stock price / Theoretical stock price (2.16)
The theoretical price rises if the risk premium decreases, and/or the
expected growth rate of return increases
Note: PER = price/earning ratio, that is, stock price divided by profit
per one unit of stock
Bibliography
English References
Flath, David (2005) The Japanese Economy, 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Kosai, Yutaka (1986) The Era of High-Speed Growth – Notes on the Postwar Japanese
Economy. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.
Okina, Kunio, Masaaki Shirakawa, and Shigenori Shiratsuka (2001) “Asset price
bubbles and monetary policy: Japan’s experience in the late 1980s and the
lessons: Background Paper.” Monetary and Economic Studies 19 (S1):
395–450.
Okina, Kunio, and Shigenori Shiratsuka (2002) “Asset price bubbles, price stabil-
ity, and monetary policy: Japan’s experience” Monetary and Economic Studies
20 (3): 35–76.
80 K. ARAMAKI
Japanese References
Bank of Japan (1990) Chosa Geppo (Monthly Research Report), April 1990.
Cabinet Office (2012) “Choki Keizai Tokei Heisei 24 Nendo” (Long-term
economic statistics FY 2012), http://www5.cao.go.jp/j-j/wp/wp-je12/h10_
data00.html (accessed on October 7, 2018).
Economic Planning Agency (1984) Nenji Keizai Hokoku (Annual Economic
Report) 1984.
Economic Planning Agency (1991) Nenji Keizai Hokoku (Annual Economic
Report) 1991.
Economic Planning Agency (1993) Nenji Keizai Hokoku (Annual Economic
Report) 1993.
Fukao, Kyoji (2002) “Nihon no Chochiku Choka to ‘Baburu’ no Hassei” (Japan’s
Excess Savings and the Emergence of the ‘Bubble’), In Heisei Baburu no
Kenkyu I (Study of the Heisei Bubble I), edited by Michio Muramatsu and
Masahiro Okuno, Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Funabashi, Yoich (1988) Tsuka Retsu Retsu, Asahi Shimbun Sha (English transla-
tion: Managing the Dollar: From the Plaza to the Louvre 1989 Washington, DC:
Institute for International Economics).
Japan–US Joint Working Group of Special Meeting on Yen–Dollar Exchange Rate
and Financial and Capital Markets (1984) “Nichi Bei Kyodo En-doru Reto
Kinnyu Shihon Shijo Tokubetsu Kaigo Sagyo Bukai Hokoku Sho,” (Report of
the Japan–US Joint Working Group of Special Meeting on Yen–Dollar
Exchange Rate and Financial and Capital Markets: Report of the Yen–Dollar
Committee), May 1984.
Jinushi, Toshiki, Yoshihiro Kuroki, and Ryuzo Miyao (2001) “1980 nendai Kohan
iko no Nihon no Kinnyu Seisaku- Seisaku Taio no Okure to sono Riyu”
(Monetary Policy in Japan from the Latter Half of the 1980s – Delay in Policy
Response and its Background). In Nihon no Kinnyu Kiki – Beikoku no Keiken
to Nihon heno Kyokun (Monetary Policy in Japan – US Experience and Their
Lessons for Japan), edited by Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam A. Posen. Tokyo:
Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Kanagawa, Toru (1987) Boeki Masatsu to Kokusai Keizai no Shomondai-Nihon to
Amerika no Boeki Masatsu wo Chusin ni- (Trade Frictions and Issues in
International Economy–Centering on Trade Frictions between Japan and the
US-) 1987, Keibun Sha.
Kanagawa, Toru (1989) Nichi Bei Boeki Masatsu-Tairitsu to Kyocho no Kozu-
(Japan–U.S. Trade Frictions-Structure of Confrontation and Cooperation).
Keibun Sha.
Kano, Tadashi (2006) Doru En Soba no Seiji Keizaigaku – Kawase Hendo nimiru
Nichibei Kankei (Political Economy of the Yen–Dollar Exchange Rate—Japan–
US Relationship Observed in the Foreign Exchange Movements). Nihon
Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Katz, Richard (1999) Kusariyuku Nihon toiu Sisutemu (Japan, the System that
Soured). Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
FORMATION OF A BUBBLE AND ITS BACKGROUND 81
Komine, Takao, ed. (2011a) Nihon Keizai no Kiroku – Dai Niji Sekiyu Kiki heno
Taio kara Baburu Hokai made (1970 nendai~1996 nen) (Record of Japanese
Economy From Responses to the 2nd oil shock and the Collapse of the Bubble
[1970s to 1996]) (“Baburu/defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku Rekisi
hen dai 1 kan” (Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in the Period of
Bubble and Deflation – History Vol. 1)), Economic and Social Research
Institute, Cabinet Office, Japanese Government.
Komine, Takao, ed. (2011b) Nihon Keizai no Kiroku – Kinnyu Kiki, Defure to
Kaifuku Katei (1997 nen~2006 nen) (Record of Japanese Economy - Financial
Crisis, Deflation and Recovery Process [1997 to 2006] (“Baburu/defure kino
Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku Rekisi hen dai 2 kan” (Japanese Economy and
Economic Policy in the Period of Bubble and Deflation – History Vol. 2)),
Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office, Japanese Government.
Kosai, Yutaka, Osamu Ito, and Ritsuko Arioka (2001) “Baburuki no Kinnyu
Seisaku to sono Hansei” (Monetary Policy in the Bubble Era and Its
Reconsideration). In Baburu to Kinnyu Seisaku – Nihon no Keiken to Kyokun
(Bubble and Monetary Policy – Japan’s Experience and Lessons), edited by
Yutaka Kosai, Masaaki Shirakawa, and Kunio Okina. Nihon Keizai Shimbun
Sha.
Kubota, Isao (2008) Shogen : Miyazawa Daiichiji [1986-1988] Tsuka Gaiko
(Testimony – First Currency Diplomacy [1986–1988] by Miyazawa). Nishi
Nihon Shimbun Sha.
Kuroda, Haruhiko (2005) Zaisei Kinnyu Seisaku no Seiko to Shippai (Success and
Failure of Fiscal and Monetary Policy). Nihon Hyoron Sha.
Kusu, Toshiharu (2005) “Baburu no Gennin Saiko (jo)” (Re-examining Causes of
the Bubble [1]). In Yokin Hoken Kiko (Deposit Insurance Corporation) Yokin
Hoken Kenkyu, October.
Kusu, Toshiharu (2006) “Baburu no Gennin Saiko (ge)” (Re-examining Causes of
the Bubble [2])). In Yokin Hoken Kiko (Deposit Insurance Corporation) Yokin
Hoken Kenkyu, November.
Kondo, Takehiko (1999) “Puraza Goi no Kenkyu” (A Study of the Plaza Accord).
Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Land Economy and Construction Industries Bureau, Ministry of Land,
Infrastructure, Transport and Tourism (2012) “Fudosan Shijo niokeru Shisan
Kakaku Hendo ni kansuru Kenkyu Kai Hokoku Sho” (Report of the Study
Group on Asset Price Developments in Real Estate Markets) 2012.
Matsuzaki, Masahiro (1988) Nichi Bei Masatsu no Seiji Keizai Gaku (Political
Economy of Japan–U.S. Frictions) 1988. Yachiyo Shuppan.
Ministry of Finance (1984) “Kinnyu no Jiyuka oyobi En no Kokusaika nitsuiteno
Genjo to Tenbo” (Current conditions and future prospect of financial liberal-
ization and internationalization of the yen), May.
Ministry of Finance, Japan (1993) “Shisan kakaku hendo no mekanizumu to sono
keizai koka” (The Mechanism of Asset Price Movements and its Economic
Impacts) November 1993 Finansharu Rebyu Fiscal and Monetary Research
Institute.
82 K. ARAMAKI
In this chapter, we will first provide an overview of how the bubble col-
lapsed at the beginning of the 1990s and what happened to the Japanese
economy during the subsequent decades after the collapse of the bubble.
Then, to identify the mechanism of the long stagnation, a division of the
stagnation period of about two decades until Abenomics (i.e., 1991–2012)
into four subperiods is proposed. After the division into subperiods, this
chapter focuses on the first subperiod, that is, around seven years from the
beginning of the 1990s to just before the financial crisis that broke out in
late 1997. This period can be characterized as the starting period of the long
stagnation and, therefore, is very important in that its examination should
be able to give clues for the fundamental mechanism of the stagnation.
Long Stagnation
The asset price finally began declining at the beginning of the 1990s.
Nobody knew at that time that it was going to be the start of a two-
decade-long stagnation of the Japanese economy. In this section, we
briefly look first at what happened to the Japanese economy by comparing
economic performances before and after the burst of the bubble. Then,
we will list major arguments and counterarguments on the causes of the
long stagnation. Next, we will consider, in a more detailed manner, char-
acteristics of the stagnation, giving particular attention to their changes
1
Real estate-related loans to construction and non-bank sectors were excluded.
2
Yoshimasa Nishimura, who was director-general of the Banking Bureau, Ministry of
Finance, in 1994–1996, later stated that the Banking Bureau at the time was very reluctant
to intervene in the banks’ lending activities in such a direct way as to set an aggregate lending
limit when the Bureau was pushing forward with financial liberalization, but had to introduce
it under the mounting criticism from the ruling Liberal Democratic Party (LDP)’s commit-
tees and media on surging land prices (Matsushima and Takenaka 2011, pp. 308–314).
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 87
over the time span of about two decades, that is, from 1991 to 2012 (we
denote these two decades as the period of long stagnation). Based on this
examination, we will present our view that we need to divide the whole
period of two decades into four subperiods, in order to find out the real
mechanism of stagnation.
(%)
15.0 1956–1973
9.3%
10.0 1985–1990
1974–1984 5.2%
3.6% 2013–2017
5.0
1991–2012 1.3%
1.0%
0.0
1956
1959
1962
1965
1968
1971
1974
1977
1980
1983
1986
1989
1992
1995
1998
2001
2004
2007
2010
2013
2016
-5.0
-10.0
Fig. 3.1 Real GDP growth rate: Japan 1956–2017. Note: Data for 1956–1980
are from GDP statistics with base year = 1990, data for 1981–1994 are from sta-
tistics with base year = 2000, data for 1995–2016 are from statistics with base
year = 2011, and data for 2017 are from the preliminary quarterly estimate basis.
Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
3
The years from 2013 onward are examined as the Abenomics period in Chap. 7.
88 K. ARAMAKI
Table 3.1 Five periods of the Japanese economy since the high-speed growth era
Table 3.2 Comparison of real GDP growth rate: Japan and other advanced
countries, 1980–2012
1980–1989 1990–1999 2000–2012
(%) (%) (%)
Source: International Monetary Fund (IMF), World Economic Outlook April 2018 database
Growth rate during the long stagnation is about one-tenth of that in the
high-speed growth era and less than one-fifth of that in the bubble period.
Unemployment Rate
Japan’s unemployment rate was fairly low, staying in the range of 1–3% for
nearly four decades after the Second World War. After the collapse of the
bubble, it sharply increased, rising over 5%, and then remaining at an ele-
vated level that averaged 4% in the long stagnation period (Fig. 3.2).
4
In terms of growth rate of real GDP per capita, the Japanese economy also underper-
formed. A simple average of the rate of growth of GDP per capita in national currency (con-
stant price base) for Japan over 1991 to 2012 is 0.8%, while the simple average for the other
four advanced countries (the United States, Germany, France, and the United Kingdom) is
1.4%.
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 89
(%)
6 1991–2012
4.0%
2013–2017
5
3.4%
4
1985–1990
3 1974–1984 2.5%
2.1%
1956–1973
2
1.5%
Supply-Side Views
There was always a certain number of people, if not many, who took the
supply-side view. To quote some examples of such arguments from their
books or articles:5
5
For Hayashi (2003), Noguchi (2005), and Motani (2010), quoted sentences are transla-
tions, by the author of this book, of the Japanese original texts.
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 91
(trillion yen)
600.0
500.0
400.0
300.0
200.0
100.0
Base year = 1990
Base year = 2011
0.0
1955
1958
1961
1964
1967
1970
1973
1976
1979
1982
1985
1988
1991
1994
1997
2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
Fig. 3.3 Amount of real GDP: Japan 1955–2015. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP
statistics
First, can such an abrupt change be caused by structural factors that take
time to be formed and change only slowly and, therefore, make the
economy difficult to change in a short period of time? In other words,
was it something cyclical or something of abrupt nature that played a
crucial role in causing such an abrupt change in nominal GDP?
Second, however, why did such an abrupt change continue for the long
period of two decades? If caused by some abrupt factor, did it become
structuralized in the process? If yes, when and how?
6
The economy peaked in February 1991, but the real growth rate still recorded a relatively
high level of 3.3% in 1991, as compared with the below 1% growth in the subsequent three
years.
92 K. ARAMAKI
(trillion yen)
600.0
500.0
400.0
300.0
200.0
100.0
Base year = 1990
Base year = 2011
0.0
1955
1959
1963
1967
1971
1975
1979
1983
1987
1991
1995
1999
2003
2007
2015
2011
Fig. 3.4 Nominal GDP. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
Can the supply-side view give a satisfactory answer to the first question?
Such structural factors as productivity growth, erosion of competitiveness,
and demography all proceed only gradually and, therefore, are unlikely to
cause such an abrupt change as in the development of nominal GDP that
we saw.
Another point that should be explained by the supply-side view is that
the Japanese economy generally suffered from a deflationary gap (supply
> demand) during the long stagnation (Fig. 3.5); therefore, it is difficult
to consider that inefficiency on the supply side, such as low productivity
growth or shortage of supply capacity, was a problem. Supply capacity was
sufficient.
Demand-Side Views
Next, let us look at demand-side views. As the Japanese economy primarily
suffered from demand shortage during the long stagnation, as touched
upon in the preceding subsection, and also, because demand level can be
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 93
(%)
4
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
Fig. 3.5 Output gap (in GDP ratio). Source: IMF World Economic Outlook
Database. October 2017
changed quickly by cyclical factors, there are many people who support
the demand-side view. With respect to the cause of demand shortage,
many arguments focus on the mistake or inappropriate handling of poli-
cies, in the fiscal or monetary areas.
(%)
14.0
12.0
10.0
8.0
6.0
4.0
2.0
0.0
Jan-85
Oct-85
Jul-86
Apr-87
Jan-88
Oct-88
Jul-89
Apr-90
Jan-91
Oct-91
Jul-92
Apr-93
Jan-94
Oct-94
Jul-95
Apr-96
Jan-97
Oct-97
Jul-98
-2.0
Fig. 3.6 Money stock (M2 + CD) (year-on-year change): Japan, 1985–1998.
Source: Bank of Japan
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 95
(%)
40
30
20 Large
companies
10
Semi-large
companies
0
Small- and
Mar-90
Dec-90
Sep-91
Jun-92
Mar-93
Dec-93
Sep-94
Jun-95
Mar-96
Dec-96
Sep-97
Jun-98
Mar-99
Dec-99
Sep-00
-10 medium-
sized
companies
-20
-30
-40
Fig. 3.7 The lending stance of financial institutions (share of “Eased” – share of
“Tight”): Japan 1990–2000. Source: Bank of Japan, “Tankan Survey”
96 K. ARAMAKI
factors that normally change slowly and, therefore, affect the economy
only gradually. So, it may be that some cyclical or other discontinuous fac-
tors caused such an abrupt change. At the same time, we also noted that
such an abrupt change remained for many years and entirely altered the
trend of nominal GDP. In other words, the abrupt change was perpetual-
ized. So, the stagnation may have been caused by discontinuous elements
but seems to have been structuralized as years went by. This fact implies
that the mechanism of stagnation changed from the one that is of an
abrupt nature to the one that is of a sustainable nature. If this is the case,
we will not be able to see the real mechanism of stagnation if we lump the
two decades together and try to find a single stagnation mechanism.
Rather, we may be able to get closer to the real cause of the stagnation if
we seek to find what factors played an important role in causing stagnation
in what subperiod and examine whether and how such factors changed
over time in the whole process of stagnation.
Thus we need to divide the whole process into appropriate subperiods
in such a way that each subperiod is governed by its unique stagnation
mechanism, which may be different across subperiods. Then, the question
is how we can identify such subperiod, which was governed by a specific
stagnation mechanism. As we do not or rather cannot know the answer
beforehand, we take a two-staged approach; we first make a tentative divi-
sion of the whole period into subperiods by looking at changes in the
characteristics of economic performance during the two decade-long stag-
nation, and then try to identify the mechanism of stagnation in respective
subperiods, and, second, drawing on the findings of the first-stage analy-
sis, we try to capture the whole picture of the stagnation mechanism in the
second stage.7 Here, we will look at economic performance in the stagna-
tion period in light of various indicators, so as to make tentative subdivi-
sions of the entire stagnation period.
7
Chapters 3 and 4 conduct mainly the first-stage analysis, based on four subdivisions of the
whole period that is introduced in this chapter. Drawing on the findings of these analyses,
Chap. 6 conducts the second-stage analysis to find the real mechanism of stagnation. As a
result, the four subperiod analyses will develop into the three-staged evolution of stagnation
mechanism that focuses on corporate behavior.
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 97
8
The words “private investment” and “private investment in plants and equipment” are
used interchangeably in this book.
98 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
8.0
6.0
4.0
-6.0
-8.0
Fig. 3.8 Real GDP growth rate and contribution by private investment: Japan,
1991–2012. Note: Data for 1988–1994 are from GDP statistics, with 2000 as the
base year; and for 1995–2012 from statistics, with 2011 as the base year. Source:
Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
respectively, by the financial crisis and by the dot-com bubble collapse, and
one long recovery interrupted by the GFC (Fig. 3.9).
The average growth rate in the expansion phase over 1994Q1–1997Q2
(2.1% on a year-on-year basis) was markedly weak, compared with the
preceding expansion in the bubble period (5.5% over 1987Q1–1991Q1).
The expansion phase after the financial crisis in the late 1990s was also
weak (1.5% over 1999Q2–2000Q4) and short (less than two years). In
this way, two expansions in the first 10 years after the burst of the bubble
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 99
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
1997
1998
1999
2000
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2010
2011
2012
1990
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1995
1996
were weak (and short in the case of the second expansion phase). By con-
trast, the recovery from the early 2000s was fairly long, extending over
more than six years (the longest after the war), while the average growth
rate over 2002Q2–2008Q1 was 1.5%, that is, the same as in the preceding
expansion phase (Fig. 3.10).9
Unemployment Rate
Figure 3.11 shows developments in the unemployment rate. A difference
from the previous chart (Fig. 3.2) is that the long stagnation period
(1991–2012) has been divided into two periods: the pre-financial crisis
period (1991–1997) and the post-financial crisis period (1998–2012).
The unemployment rate was not very high until 1997, that is, before the
financial crisis, averaging 2.8%, but it sharply increased after the financial
crisis to a level near 5%.
9
The expansion phase in this growth rate calculation is defined as starting from the first full
quarter after the quarter in which the preceding bottom was identified, and ending in the
quarter in which subsequent peak was identified.
100 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
15
10
0
1987/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
1990/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
1993/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
1996/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
1999/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
2002/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
2005/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
2008/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
2011/ 1- 3.
10-12.
-5
-10
(%)
6 1998–2012
4.6% 2013–2017
5
3.4%
1991–1997
4
1985–1990 2.8%
3 1974–1984 2.5%
1956–1973 2.1%
2 1.5%
The first dividing line may be the financial crisis. The unemployment rate
was moderate up to 1997, but it was elevated from 1998. The economy
apparently suffered serious impacts during the financial crisis and under-
went a substantial change.
Another dividing line may be the start of the long recovery in the early
2000s. There were two weak recoveries before the early 2000s and one
long recovery after that.
One more dividing line may be the outbreak of the GFC. The long recov-
ery was interrupted in 2008, and the economy was thrown into a turbu-
lent era due to a series of external shocks.
Period I 1991–1997: After the burst of the bubble to just before the
financial crisis. This subperiod may be called “Initial adjustment period”
102 K. ARAMAKI
Period II 1998–2002: From the financial crisis and to just before the long
recovery. This subperiod is called “Financial Crisis and its impacts”
Period III 2003–2007: This period covers most of the long recovery and
is termed “Long recovery”
Period IV 2008–2012: This subperiod covers the turbulent era from the
GFC to just before the period of Abenomics that substantively started
in 2013 and is called “Global financial crisis and after.”
Growth rate became less than one-third of the rate in the preceding bub-
ble period (from 5.2% to 1.7%).
The most important negative factor for growth was private investment in
plants and equipment (its growth contribution declined by 2.1% points,
from +2.0% points in the bubble period to −0.1% points in Period I).
The growth rate further fell to 0.4%. Private investment stagnation aggra-
vated (its growth contribution further declined to −0.2% points).
We would like to reiterate a need to divide the two decades into subpe-
riods with different characteristics. In many analyses of Japan’s stagnation,
more than 20 years, after the burst of bubble, are often lumped together
and called the “Lost Decades.” Arguments are presented to explain a sin-
gle “long stagnation.” However, problems with the economy seem to have
changed over the period of two decades. In this book, we divide the long
stagnation period into subperiods based on characteristics of the economy
and aim to identify the real mechanism of the Japan’s long stagnation.
In this section, we will look at Period I that spans from 1991 to 1997, that
is, a period from the collapse of the bubble up to just before the financial
crisis in the late 1997, which brought about far-reaching impacts on the
economy, as we see later. We start with fact findings, that is, we will see
what happened to the Japanese economy in this period and examine pos-
sible causes of the stagnation, with particular focus on the decline in pri-
vate investment (that played the most important role in the stagnation in
Period I). We also will see what the government did to find out what
104 K. ARAMAKI
should (could) have been done to prevent such a long stagnation, as the
economy actually experienced.
1800
1600
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
1990
1990
1991
1992
1992
1993
1993
1994
1994
1995
1996
1996
1997
1997
1998
1999
1999
2000
2000
1985
1985
1986
1986
1987
1987
1988
1989
1989
10
The longest contraction phase is 36 months from February 1980 (peak) to February
1983 (trough) after the second oil crisis.
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 105
(%)
12
10
0
1985/ 1- 3.
1988/ 1- 3.
1991/ 1- 3.
1994/ 1- 3.
1997/ 1- 3.
2000/ 1- 3.
10-12.
10-12.
10-12.
10-12.
10-12.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
-2
-4
confirms that the most important negative factor was private (corporate)
investment in plants and equipment, recording negative growth contribu-
tion in many years in the first half of 1990s. By contrast, government
expenditure and private consumption supported the growth in the initial
adjustment period in 1991–1997 (Fig. 3.14).11
11
Growth contributions by each of demand components tend to fluctuate, and therefore
in Fig. 3.14, the three-year moving average of growth contributions of each demand compo-
nent is shown, so as to see the basic trend.
106 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
7.0
6.0
5.0 GDP
growth rate
4.0
Private
consumption
3.0
Private
2.0 investment
Government
1.0 expenditure
Net export
0.0
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
-1.0
-2.0
asset deflation. The former two factors played a fundamental role, and the
third factor provided an extra burden.
Stock Adjustments
12
As implementation of investment tends to have a lag, the peak of investment comes later
than the peak of economic cycle.
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 107
(%)
20.0
18.0
Private
16.0 investment
14.0
12.0 Housing
investment
10.0
8.0 Government
6.0 investment
4.0
2.0
0.0
1955
1958
1961
1964
1967
1970
1973
1976
1979
1982
1985
1988
1991
1994
1997
2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
Fig. 3.15 Share in real GDP of private investment, housing investment, and
government investment. Source: Cabinet Office
(trillion yen)
1800.0
1600.0
1400.0
1200.0 Assets
1000.0 Liabilities
800.0 Net
600.0 assets
400.0
200.0
0.0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
Fig. 3.16 Assets, liabilities, and net assets of companies (all industries excluding
financial and insurance companies): FY 1960–2013. Source: Ministry of Finance
“Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
(trillion yen)
1800
1600
All industries
1400
(excluding
1200 financial and
insurance
1000 companies)
800
Manufacturing
600
Non-manufacturing
400
200
0
FY1960
FY1964
FY1968
FY1972
FY1976
FY1980
FY1984
FY1988
FY1992
FY1996
FY2000
FY2004
FY2008
FY2012
Fig. 3.17 Total sales of companies (all industries excluding financial and insur-
ance companies) and their breakdown between manufacturing and non-
manufacturing sectors. Source: Ministry of Finance “Financial Statements Statistics
of Corporations by Industry”
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 109
Due to the sudden halt of sales growth, the size of physical assets, such
as buildings, machineries, and equipment, became excessive relative to the
sales volume.13 The fact that companies had such assets, for which the
companies could not expect sufficient sales, surely imposed another
depressing impact on investment.
13
This point is examined in detail, based on combined financial statements of companies
in Chap. 6.
14
See Footnote 25 in Chap. 2.
15
Note that both sales and investment are in nominal terms in the figure.
110 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
8
6
Real GDP
4 growth
rate
2 Growth
rate in
coming
0 3-years
expected
1973
1975
1977
1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
by
-2 companies
-4
-6
Fig. 3.18 Real GDP growth rate and expected growth rate held by companies for
the next three years. Source: Cabinet Office “Survey on company behavior”
(%)
50
40
Rate of
30 nominal
investment
20 increase
(3-year moving
10 average)
0 Rate of
nominal sales
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
-10 increase
(3-year backward
-20 moving
average)
-30
-40
Fig. 3.19 Growth rate of nominal sales and growth rate of nominal investment
(both in three-year moving average). Source: Ministry of Finance “Financial
Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 111
(yen)
160 350
140 300 Nominal
120 effective
250 exchange rate
100 of the yen
200 Real effective
80
exchange rate
150
60 of the yen
100 Nominal
40 yen = dollar
20 50 exchange rate
2010 = 100 (RHS)
0 0
Jan-73
Sep-75
May-78
Jan-81
Sep-83
May-86
Jan-89
Sep-91
May-94
Jan-97
Sep-99
May-02
Jan-05
Sep-07
May-10
Jan-13
Fig. 3.20 The exchange rate of the yen to the dollar and real and nominal effec-
tive exchange rate (2010 = 100). Source: Bank of Japan
16
A Ministry of Finance official in charge of international financial matters, including
exchange rates, later wrote as follows: “Bickering over trade between Japan and the United
States, which was intensively covered by the mass media, regrettably helped convince market
players that the yen’s surge would not be halted unless Japan’s current account surplus was
brought down” (Sakakibara 2000, 174).
112 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
200.0
150.0
Capital
100.0 gains/losses
related to
stocks
50.0
Capital
gains/losses
0.0 related to
land
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
-50.0
-100.0
Fig. 3.21 Capital gains and losses accruing to land and stocks (in GDP ratio).
Note: Bars show the combined amount of realized and unrealized capital gains and
losses. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
17
As of 1990, 91.4% of land and 93.6% of stocks were held by the private sector (FY 2009
GDP statistics, Cabinet Office).
114 K. ARAMAKI
(trillion yen)
450.0
400.0
350.0
300.0
250.0
200.0
150.0
100.0
50.0
0.0
FY1960
1963
1966
1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
1996
1999
2002
2005
2008
2011
Fig. 3.22 Outstanding balance of long-term debt of companies (all industries
excluding financial and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of Finance
“Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
18
These price declines aggravated non-performing loan problems for banks, as examined
in Chap. 4.
19
IMF (2003) examined the historical experiences of booms and busts in equity and hous-
ing prices. The study covered equity prices in 19 industrial countries, for which equity price
indices were generally available from 1959, and housing prices for 12 countries, for which
housing price indices generally started in 1970. A bust was defined as a peak-to-trough
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 115
(%)
7.0 350
6.0 300
Expected real
5.0 250 growth rate
for coming
4.0 200 3-years
Commercial
3.0 150 land price (6
largest cities)
2.0 100 Mar 2000 = 100
(RHS)
1.0 50
0.0 0
FY1973
FY1976
FY1979
FY1982
FY1985
FY1988
FY1991
FY1994
FY1997
FY2000
FY2003
FY2006
FY2009
FY2012
Fig. 3.23 Expected growth rate and land price. Note: Urban land price is calcu-
lated as of April 1 of each respective year. Source: Japan Real Estate Institute,
Cabinet Office “Survey on company behavior”
continued decline in the expected real growth rate, which may well have
reflected continued stagnation, reduced the expected rate of return to
landholdings and thus depressed demand for land. This process continued
until the early 2000s and then was temporarily suspended as the expected
growth rate started to rise, most probably reflecting the long recovery.
Land prices started to rise in the latter half of the 2000s, but this positive
process did not continue for long with the impacts of GFC.
Thus, companies continued to incur realized/unrealized capital losses
due to the collapse of the bubble and subsequent asset deflation, con-
tinuing for more than a decade until the beginning of the 2000s. During
the excess capacity hangover, profits stagnated (as will be examined in
Chap. 6 in more detail), and the balance sheets of companies continued
decline where the price change fell into the top quartile in all declines during bear markets
(both indices were deflated by the Consumer Price Index (CPI). The study identified 52
equity price busts between 1959:Q1 and 2002:Q3 (one bust per country for every 13 years).
On average, busts involved a price decline of about 45% and unfolded over a period of 10
quarters. The study identified 20 housing price crashes between 1970:Q1 and 2002:Q3 (one
bust per country every 20 years). Price correction in the busts averaged 30% and lasted about
4 years, about a year and a half longer than equity price busts.
116 K. ARAMAKI
Fiscal Policy
The government implemented as many as 12 large economic stimulus pack-
ages in less than 10 years between August 1992 and December 2001, and
6 out of 12 packages were implemented in Period I (Table 3.6). A new pack-
age was announced every year after the contraction started, except in
1996–1997, when no package was compiled, reflecting a short recovery
and a fiscal consolidation policy that was pursued in that period but aborted
shortly thereafter. The scale of eight packages were over 2% of the GDP.20
Table 3.6 Economic stimulus packages after the burst of the bubble (trillions of
yen)
August April September February April September
1992 1993 1993 1994 1995 1995
Package volume 10.7 13.2 Approx. 6.0 15.3 Approx. 7.0 14.2
(percent of GDP) (2.2%) (2.7%) (1.2%) (3.1%) (1.4%) (2.8%)
Amount of public 8.6 10.6 5.2 7.2 11.4
investment in the
package
Package volume Over 16.0 Over 20.0 Approx. Approx. Approx. Approx.
(percent of GDP) (3.2%) (4.7%) 18.0 11.0 5.9 (1.2%) 4.1 (0.8%)
(3.5%) (2.1%)
Amount of public 5.2 8.0 7.2 4.2 2.5
investment in the
package
Source: Summarized from Table 1 in Nakao (2002)
20
The largest stimulus package in 1998 was over 4.7% of GDP.
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 117
Monetary Policy
The discount rate, which was among the major tools of monetary policy
at the time, was raised five times from the level of 2.5% to 6.0% in a year
and three months from May 1989 to August 1990. Then, from July 1991,
only 10 months later, it was lowered seven more times to reach 1.75% in
September 1993. In 1995, the discount rate was further reduced twice to
reach 0.5%, a level close to zero (Fig. 3.27).
(%)
4
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
Fig. 3.24 Fiscal balance of general government (in GDP ratio). Source: IMF,
World Economic Outlook Database, October 2017
118 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
6
4
2
0 Japan
-2 US
-4 UK
-6 Germany
-8 France
-10
-12
-14
Fig. 3.25 General government deficit (in GDP ratio): Japan, US, the United
Kingdom, Germany, and France. Note: General government net lending/borrow-
ing (in percent of GDP). Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook October 2013
database
(%)
300
250
200 Japan
US
150 UK
Germany
100 France
50
Fig. 3.26 Outstanding balance of general government debt (in GDP ratio).
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook Database, October 2013
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 119
(%)
7
0
Jan-85
Oct-85
Jul-86
Jan-91
Oct-91
Jul-92
Apr-93
Jan-94
Oct-94
Jul-95
Apr-96
Jan-97
Oct-97
Jul-98
Apr-99
Apr-87
Jan-88
Oct-88
Jul-89
Apr-90
excesses by the corporate sector took a long time. The reason for the long
time of disposition may be as follows. Initially, there was some delay in
recognizing that assets were in excess and had to be downward adjusted,
even after the collapse of the bubble and the halt of sales growth. Next, the
excess itself expanded as the actual growth rate, and therefore, the expected
economic growth rate (which leads to the expected sales growth rate) fell.
(This point will be examined in detail in Chap. 6). Lastly, after the problem
of excess assets came to the surface, the magnitude of the excess (to be
discussed in Chap. 4 and its Supplement 2), and therefore, the expected
negative impacts of their disposition when swiftly disposed of may have
lengthened the disposition.
Furthermore, the sharp appreciation of the yen rate around the mid-1990s
hurt exports and also imposed dampening effects on business confidence.
Worsening balance sheet conditions imposed an additional burden.
Substantial capital losses incurred by nonfinancial and financial corpora-
tions due to sharp asset deflation imposed damages to their balance
sheets, making these corporations cautious toward investment and debt
assumption.
Continued decline in growth rates also reduced expected return to
landholding and therefore reduced demand for land, depressing the land
prices and further creating capital losses each year.
In this way, in the initial adjustment period, the Japanese economy was
deprived of two major important drivers of economic recovery: private
investment and exports.
The government supported the economy, and private consumption
provided certain stabilizing effects to the economy, but sustainability of
their growth contribution could not be expected under the prolonged
stagnation.
With hindsight, Period I seems to be of critical importance. The prob-
lem of overinvestment in the bubble period and balance sheet damages by
the collapse of the bubble were addressed by companies through their
curtailing of investment and refraining from additional borrowing, so as to
adjust production capacity downward and repair their balance sheets.
Meanwhile, the government implemented very extensive stimulus and
macroeconomic policies to support the economy. However, external devel-
opments, particularly sharp appreciation of the yen during trade disputes
with the United States, limited the scope of more export-led recovery.
Under these circumstances, the weakness of economic performance con-
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 121
tinued for a long time, which in turn lowered growth expectation held by
companies for the future, leading to continued, self-fulfilling low growth.
Costs of lengthened adjustments of excess capacity of the corporate
sector were gradually shifted to the financial sector and surfaced as the
worsening of non-performing loan problems. This culminated in the late
1990s in the form of the first systemic financial crisis after the Second
World War. Despite huge (realized and unrealized) losses arising from
excess (unprofitable) assets formed during the bubble, Japan did not have
a social or political crisis per se during the two decade-long stagnation,
largely due to extensive government support. The lengthened adjustment
process left Japan with negative legacy, however, including sharply ele-
vated government debt and a downward shift of growth, trending to a
very low level.
If the disposition of excess assets had been swiftly completed in the first
half of 1990s, the economy would have been rapidly freed from the over-
hang of the adjustment burden and could have made a fresh start relatively
early, with such strength as in the past. The magnitude of necessary adjust-
ment, however, seems to have made this choice difficult. The fact that we
could not or did not solve the problem in Period I turned out to be most
crucial in the subsequent two-decade developments. After all, the Japanese
economy, while avoiding swift adjustment, could not avoid in-depth
adjustment (disposition of excesses), and in the end, there developed a
crisis. The topic of the financial crisis, including reasons for non-disposal
of excesses in a short period of time, is covered in the next chapter.
122 K. ARAMAKI
Supplement
Table 3.7 Chronology of relevant events
(continued)
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 123
(continued)
April 1998 Comprehensive Economic Measures decided
May 1998 Fiscal Structure Reform Act amended (in December 1998, its
implementation was suspended)
October 1998 Government decided to nationalize the Long-term Credit Bank of
Japan (first nationalization of private bank after the war)
November 1998 Emergency economic measures decided (historically largest size)
December 1998 Nippon Credit Bank nationalized
Bibliography
English References
Hayashi, Fumio, and Edward C. Prescott (2002) “The 1990s in Japan: A Lost
Decade,” Review of Economic Dynamics 5 (1): 206–235.
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2003) World Economic Outlook April 2003.
Washington, DC: IMF.
Mori, Naruki, Shigenori Shiratsuka, and Hiroo Taguchi (2001) “Policy Responses
to the Post-bubble Adjustments in Japan: A Tentative Review.” Monetary and
Economic Studies, Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan,
19 (S1): 53–102.
Nakao, Takehiko (2002) “Japan’s experience with fiscal policy in the 1990s in the
aftermath of the bubble economy.” Presentation at the 4th Banca d’Italia
Workshops on Public Finances, “The Impact of Fiscal Policy, Perugia,” March
21–23, 2002.
Okina, Kunio, Masaaki Shirakawa, and Shigenori Shiratsuka (2001) “Asset price
bubble and monetary policy: Japan’s experience in the late 1980s and the les-
sons.” Background Paper, February. Monetary and Economic Studies (Special
Edition): 395–450.
Okina, Kunio, and Shigenori Shiratsuka (2002) “Asset Price Bubbles, Price
Stability, and Monetary Policy: Japan’s Experience” Monetary and Economic
Studies, Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan, 20 (3):
35–76.
Sakakibara, Eisuke (2000) “US-Japanese economic policy – conflicts and coordi-
nation during the 1990s.” In Japan’s Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to
U.S. Experience, edited by Ryoichi Mikitani and A.S. Posen. Washington, DC:
Institute for International Economy.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012a) “Deleveraging and Growth: Is the Developed World
Following Japan’s Long and Winding Road?” Lecture at the London School of
Economics (LSE) and Political Science, co-hosted by the Asia Research Center
and Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related
Disciplines (STICARD), LSE, January 10, 2012, Bank of Japan.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012b) “Japan’s economy and monetary policy.” June 4,
2012, Bank of Japan.
124 K. ARAMAKI
Japanese References
Bernanke, Ben (2001) “Mizukara kino mahi ni ochiitta nihon no kinnyu seisaku”
(“Japanese monetary policy – A case of self-induced paralysis?). In Nihon no
Kinyu Kiki – Beikoku no Keiken to Nihon heno Kyokun (Monetary Policy in
Japan – “US Experiences and Their Lessons for Japan), edited by Ryoichi
Mikitani and Adam A. Posen. Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Fukao, Mitsuhiro (2002) “1980 nendai kohan no shisan kakaku baburu hassei to
90 nendai no fukyo no gennin” (“Causes of asset price bubble in the late 1980s
and recession in the 1990s”). In Heisei Baburu no Kenkyu I (Study of the
Heisei Bubble I), edited by Michio Muramatsu and Masahiro Okuno. Tokyo:
Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Fukao, Mitsuhiro (2009) “Choki Fukyo to Kinnyu Seisaku Kawase Reto Ginko
Shinnyo” (“The long stagnation and monetary policy, foreign exchange rate
and bank credit). In Furyo Saiken to Kinnyu Kiki, edited by Kazuo Ikeo,
(Cabinet Office “Baburu/defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 4”
(Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in the Period of Bubble and Deflation
4), Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office).
Fukuda, Shin-ichi (2009) “Baburu Hokai gono Kinnyu Shijo no Doyo to Kinnyu
Seisaku” (Instability of Financial Markets after the Collapse of the Bubble and
Monetary Policy). In Defure Keizai to Kinnyu Seisaku (Deflationary Economy
and Monetary Policy), edited by Hiroshi Yoshikawa, (Cabinet Office Baburu/
defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 7 (Japanese Economy and Economic
Policy in the Period of Bubble and Deflation 7), Economic and Social Research
Institute, Cabinet Office).
Hamada, Koichi, and Akiyoshi Horiuchi (2004) Ronso: Nihon no Keizai Kiki –
Choki Teitai no Shin-in wo Kaimei suru (Debates: Japan’s Economic Crisis –
Examining Real Cause of the Long Stagnation). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Hayashi, Fumio (2003) “Kozo Kaikaku Nakushite Seicho Nashi” (No growth
without structural reform”). In Usinawareta 10 nen no Shin-in ha Nanika
(What is the Real Cause of the Lost Decade?), edited by Kikuo Iwata and
Tsutomu Miyagawa. Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Hori, Masahiro (2009) “Ajia no Hatten to Nihon Keizai – Gaiju Doko Kawase
Reto to Nihon no Kyoso Ryoku-” (“Growth of Asia and Japan’s economy –
Evolution of foreign demand, foreign exchange rate, and Japan’s competitive-
ness”). In Makuro Keizai to Sangyo Kozo (Macroeconomy and Industrial
Structure), edited by Kyoji Fukao, (Cabinet Office, Baburu/defure kino Nihon
Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 1 (Japanese economy and economic policy in the
period of bubble and deflation 1), Economic and Social Research Institute,
Cabinet Office).
Horioka, Charles Yuji (2007) “Nihon no ‘Ushinawareta 10 nen’ no Gennin”
(“Cause of Japan’s ‘Lost Decade’”) In Keizai Teitai no Gennin to Seido (Causes
COLLAPSE OF THE BUBBLE AND THE START OF THE LONG STAGNATION 125
Okina Kunio (2009) “Baburu no seisei hokai no keiken ni terashita kinnyu Seisaku
no Ayumi – FED view to BIS view wo fumaete” (Evolution of monetary policy
in light of experience of the formation and collapse of the bubble – Drawing on
FED views and BIS views) In Defure Keizai to Kinnyu Seisaku (Deflationary
Economy and Monetary Policy), edited by Hiroshi Yoshikawa. (Cabinet Office
Baburu/defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 2 (“Japanese Economy
and Economic Policy in the Period of Bubble and Deflation 2”) Economic and
Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office).
Tanaka, Takayuki (2002) Gendai Nihon Keizai – Baburu to Posuto Baburu no
Kiseki (Current Japanese Economy – Trajectory of the Bubble and Post-
Bubble). Nihon Hyoron Sha.
Tanaka, Takayuki (2009) Kinnyu Kiki ni Do Tachi Mukau ka –Ushinawareta 15
nen no Kyokun (How to Cope with Financial Crises? Lessons from ‘the Lost 15
years’). Chikuma Shobo.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi (2009) “Defureshon to kinnyu seisaku” (“Deflation and mon-
etary policy”) In Defure Keizai to Kinnyuu Seisaku (Deflationary Economy and
Monetary Policy), edited by Hiroshi Yoshikawa. (Cabinet Office Baburu/
defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 7 (Japanese Economy and Economic
Policy in the Period of Bubble and Deflation 7), Economic and Social Research
Institute, Cabinet Office).
Yoshikawa, Mototada (1998) Mane Haisen (“Defeat in monetary war.”), Bunshun
Bunko.
CHAPTER 4
1
Description in this chapter owes much to Nakaso (2001).
Bank Failures
Under the severe systemic stress, failures of financial institutions reached
an unprecedented level. In total, 181 financial institutions failed in the
1990s and the first half of 2000s. A total of 161 (89%) of 181 failed in five
years from 1997 to 2001, and more than two-thirds were credit coopera-
tives (Fig. 4.1).
The number of financial institutions dramatically decreased by 500
(−44.9%) from 1,080 at the end of March 1990 to 580 at the end of
March 2014. More than 42.4% (212 institutions) of these 500 closures
occurred in five years from the end of March 1997 to the end of March
2002, with the outbreak of the financial crisis of 1997–1998, and 84.0%
(178 institutions) of these 212 institutions were either credit banks or
credit cooperatives. While the decline reflects not only closure due to fail-
ures but also mergers under changing business environments, such a rapid
decline in the number of banks illustrates how serious the impacts of the
crisis were to the Japanese economy.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 131
60
50
40
Credit
cooperative
30
Credit bank
Bank
20
10
(%)
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
FY1980
FY1982
FY1984
FY1986
FY1988
FY1990
FY1992
FY1994
FY1996
FY1998
FY2000
FY2002
FY2004
FY2006
FY2008
FY2010
FY2012
FY1960
FY1962
FY1964
FY1966
FY1968
FY1970
FY1972
FY1974
FY1976
FY1978
(trillion yen)
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
FY1992
FY1994
FY1996
FY1998
FY2000
FY2002
FY2004
FY2006
FY2008
FY2010
FY1980
FY1982
FY1984
FY1986
FY1988
FY1990
to recover, companies could continue to hold the assets and wait for
the recovery of sales. If not, that is, if sales could not be expected to
recover, companies should dispose of these assets to avoid low profit-
ability for an extended period of time. What happened in reality was a
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 133
rolonged sales stagnation (see Fig. 3.17 in Chap. 3), so, the right choice
p
in hindsight was to dispose of the excess of unprofitable assets promptly.2
However, the corporate sector took time to address the problem of excess
assets, which made low profitability linger, gradually eroding the financial
strength of the corporate sector.
From the financial sector’s point of view, the erosion of financial sound-
ness of the borrowing companies was a cause for their declining ability to
repay their debts. The value of collateral was also being eroded after the
burst of the bubble. This was particularly true with commercial mortgage
loans, which were aggressively provided during the bubble. The financial
sector came to have an increasingly difficult problem with their NPLs as
years went by in the 1990s.3
2
In this case, disposition of assets does not necessarily mean demolition or destruction of
the assets concerned. Typically, disposition of assets is conducted in such a way that the assets
are sold at a price lower than the acquisition cost, entailing losses, and these losses are shared
by relevant parties. It may be possible for the assets to become profitable, as the acquisition
costs are low for the acquirer. Through the sale of assets at a lower price, the combined
amount of assets of the corporate sector will decline.
3
A report by the Deposit Insurance Corporation (DIC) (2005), which analyzed causes of
the failures of 180 financial institutions to which DIC extended financial assistance, con-
cluded that, for 165 (91.7%) of the total 180 failures, the NPL problem was listed among the
causes of the failure (multiple listing). Out of these 165, 83 (46.1%) listed concentration of
credit to real estate-related sector, 49 (27.2%) listed other factors including economic stagna-
tion, and 47 (26.1%) listed concentration of credit to sectors other than the real estate-
related sector as causes of failure.
134 K. ARAMAKI
half of 1990s to around 30 trillion yen in the latter half of 1990s. Against
the background of prolonged stagnation and the break-out of the financial
crisis, the amount of NPLs hit the peak of 42 trillion yen (NPL ratio equal
to 8.4%) in the period ending in March 2002 (Table 4.1).4,5,6,7
4
As the definition of NPL was gradually expanded, there is an issue whether a rigorous
time-sequential comparison is possible.
5
The amount of NPL and the resultant losses arising from the resolution of NPL tend to
increase with the lapse of time if economic stagnation continues. This is because economic
stagnation typically means sales stagnation, and therefore, revenue and profit stagnation of
borrowing companies.
6
The outstanding balance of NPLs is that of “risk-monitoring assets.” There are three
concepts of NPLs: “risk-monitoring assets,” “disclosed assets under the Financial Recovery
Act,” and “NPLs under self-assessment.” “Risk-monitoring assets” is a concept prescribed by
the Banking Act and covers a longer period of time than data under the other two concepts
do. It started to be disclosed from the year ending March 1993 and at that time covered only
those loans to failed borrowers [①] and past due loans (loans for which unpaid interest is
not recorded as revenue for six months or longer) [②]. Past due loans were disclosed only by
major banks. From the year ending March 1996, disclosure under this concept was extended
to cover loans for which interest was reduced or waived [③] and loans to those borrow-
ers for which such support as debt waiver had been extended [④]. Furthermore, from the
year ending March 1998 (for regional banks from the year ending September 1998), the
aforementioned Type ② loans were extended to cover loans past due three months or
longer [⑤], and a new type, “loans for which lending conditions had been eased” [⑥] was
introduced to include, but was broader than loan types ③ and ④ (the term “risk-monitoring
assets” began to be used from this point in time) (Watanabe 2001; Nakagawa 1996). The
second concept, “disclosed assets under the Financial Recovery Act,” was introduced by the
Financial Recovery Act, enacted in October 1998. The act imposed a disclosure obligation
under which major banks were required to disclose credit to legally bankrupt or de facto
bankrupt borrowers (Type ①), credit in danger (Type ②), credit that needs to be monitored
(Type ③), and normal credit (Type ④). It was implemented for major banks from the year
ending March 1999, and for regional banks, from the year ending September 1999. The
third concept, “NPLs under self-assessment” was made necessary by the Early Corrective
Measures implemented from April 1998, under which, if the capital–asset ratio of an indi-
vidual financial institution (to be calculated based on the self-assessment of loan quality) was
lower than the prescribed level (8% for international criterion banks, and 4% for domestic
criterion banks), authorities ordered the financial institutions to take corrective measures
such as the strengthening of capital base. In the self-assessment, borrowers are classified into
five categories: “failed,” “in danger of failing,” “risk of failure,” “to be monitored,” and
“normal.” Furthermore, respective assets are classified into four groups, from Class I (nor-
mal credit) to Class IV (credit impossible to recover or of no worth), depending on the
degree of risk of recovery. Financial institutions were not required to disclose the amount of
NPLs under the self-assessment and only the aggregate amount by type of financial institu-
tion and by classification of NPLs from Class I (normal credit) to Class IV (credit impossible
to recover or of no worth) were disclosed by the authorities (Watanabe (2001)).
7
The NPL ratio is the ratio of “disclosed assets under the Financial Recovery Act” (credit
to legally bankrupt or de facto bankrupt borrowers [①], credit in danger [②], and credit that
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 135
Outstanding 12.8 13.6 12.5 28.5 21.8 29.8 29.6 30.4 32.5 42.0 34.8 26.2 17.5
NPLs
(bank)
(trillion yen)
NPL ratio 6.2 5.9 6.3 8.4 7.4 5.8 4.0
(bank) (%)
NPL ratio 6.1 5.4 5.3 8.4 7.2 5.2 2.9
(major
bank) (%)
Note:
1. Data are for the period ending in March of each year
2. Evolution of disclosure requirements of NPLs is explained in detail in footnote 6
3. The concept of the NPL ratio is explained in footnote 7
4. “Bank” consists of city banks, long-term credit banks, trust banks, and regional banks
Source: Financial Services Agency (FSA)
needs to be monitored [③]) to the total credit. The basic concept of both the risk-monitor-
ing assets and the disclosed assets under the Financial Recovery Act is same as is shown by
the fact that both include failed loans, loans past due for three months or longer, and loans
for which lending conditions had been eased. However, the two concepts adopt different
classification methods, that is, while the starting point for risk-monitoring assets is the past
due interest payments and then loans concerned are classified into those to failed borrowers
and other loans (past due loans), under the disclosed assets of the Financial Recovery Act,
division is between credit to failed borrowers and credit to borrowers that have not failed but
have a high probability of non-recovery. In addition, risk-monitoring assets cover only loans,
but disclosed assets under the Financial Recovery Act cover total credit including securities
lending. Also, risk-monitoring assets are based on an asset-by-asset classification but dis-
closed assets under the Financial Recovery Act are based on a borrower-by-borrower
classification).
8
Nakaso (2001) gives a most detailed and clear chronological explanation of the unfolding
of the financial crisis and authorities’ responses.
136 K. ARAMAKI
In June 1996, the Deposit Insurance Law was amended to improve the
safety net, and under the amendment, the payoff cost limit on DIC assis-
tance was removed temporarily until March 2001.
Under the law, a failed bank could either be placed under the Financial
Reconstruction Administration (FRA), or temporarily nationalized. Under
the FRA, the authorities designate an administrator who replaces existing
management of a failed bank and tries to find a healthy bank to purchase
the business of a failed bank. When the administrator cannot find buyer,
he can transfer the business of a failed bank to a bridge bank, which the
DIC establishes. Under nationalization, large-scale banks with systemic
risk can be purchased by the government, and the authorities will desig-
nate a new management. It was generally conceived that financial institu-
tions with more systemic implications would be nationalized. For both
institutions under FRA and nationalized banks, business operations were
to be continued, with liquidity provision directly from BOJ in the case of
institutions under FRA and with liquidity support provided by the DIC in
the case of nationalized banks. In the latter case, the DIC was to borrow
from the BOJ to finance such liquidity support. Pursuant to the
Reconstruction Law, the LTCB was nationalized in October 1997, and
NCB, which was heavily exposed to the real estate industry and suffering
from a large amount of NPLs, was nationalized in December 1980.
Second, the other law that was newly introduced was a strengthened
capital injection scheme (again, effective through March 2001) tied into
the early correction measure.13 This measure was introduced by the
Financial Function Early Strengthening Law (“Early Strengthening Law”)
that replaced the Emergency Law in October 1998, and some 7.5 trillion
yen was injected into 15 banks in March 1999. The capital injection was a
significant step to address the undercapitalization of Japanese banks. The
amount injected was more than four times as large as the previous injection
in March 1998 (1.8 trillion yen), after which the Japan premium (extra
interest that Japanese banks were required to pay when they sought over-
seas funding) began to decline. Under the Reconstruction Law, the LTCB
was nationalized in October 1998. The size of public funds made available
for the new framework was doubled from 30 trillion yen to 60 trillion yen.
With the new comprehensive safety net framework in place, the authorities
were able to deal with a failed bank directly, without necessarily finding an
assuming bank beforehand. For viable but undercapitalized banks, large-
scale injections also became possible. The authorities quickly embarked on
a systematic clean-up operation, fully utilizing the new framework.
13
The early correction measure introduced in April 1998 is the scheme under which the
authorities order a bank to take corrective measures, such as the submission of a management
improvement plan or strengthening of its capital base, based on its capital–asset ratio.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 139
In April 2001, a strong encouragement for writing off NPLs was stated in
the Emergency Economic Package adopted by the government. Major
banks were required to remove from their balance sheets the existing
NPLs classified as “in danger of bankruptcy” or worse,14 in principle,
within two years and those NPLs newly classified as such, in principle,
within three years (“Two Year–Three Year Rule”). “The Financial
Revival Program” was announced by the government in October 2002,
aimed at halving the NPL ratio of major banks by March 2005 from the
level at the time (8.4% as of March 2002).
In January 2002, equity holdings by banks were restricted, and an entity
was established to purchase equities held by banks and firms (the BOJ
also started to purchase equities from banks).
In April 2003, the Industrial Revitalization Corporation was established,
which bought NPLs from non-main financing banks and endeavored to
revive the borrowers through cooperation with the main financing bank
(existed from April 2003 to June 2007).
In May 2003, public funds were injected into a large financial group,
Resona Group, to strengthen its capital base, and this became a turning
point for the NPL problems.15
14
Refers to “Bankruptcy,” “De facto bankruptcy,” and “In danger of bankruptcy.”
15
Nakaso (2014) wrote that, triggered by public funds injection into Resona Bank, stock
prices gradually started to rise, and it was finally felt that the crisis was gradually waning.
Nishimura (2011) pointed out that public funds injection into Resona Bank with no writing
off of stocks shows a clear example of a soft landing approach, which the administration of
the time was taking, despite its hard pressures on banks to dispose of NPLs.
140 K. ARAMAKI
16
The full deposit protection, which was introduced in 1996, was scheduled to be termi-
nated by end March 2001 but was extended to end March 2002 for time deposits and to end
March 2003 for checkable deposits. The full protection of checkable deposits was extended
further to end March 2005.
17
Supplement 2 in this chapter gives a very rough estimate of the size of the excess assets
(it is estimated that excesses accounted for nearly three-tenths of all assets), and an estimate
of an increase in the number of unemployed people and a rise in the unemployment rate if
excesses were promptly disposed of.
18
In the case where loans with the total face value of 100 incurred a loss of 10, there are
two types of disposition.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 141
bility side of the balance sheet. In this case, the troubled assets continue to be
held. The other is direct disposition, removing the troubled assets from the
balance sheets, and at the same time, reducing capital. In the case of direct
disposition, the troubled assets may be seized, and in a more serious case, the
borrower might be liquidated, leading to an increase in unemployment,
reduction in wages, and a fall in investment. Banks generally favored indirect
disposition and continued to hold relevant assets on their balance sheets.19,20
① Credit Crunch
There were two types of problems. One relates to the case where a
company itself is solvent but suffers from redundant unprofitable capacity.
The other relates to the case where the company holding assets itself is
insolvent. In the former case, early recognition and disposition of the
unprofitable assets is needed from the viewpoint of efficiency. If this is not
done, those assets that are not profitable continue to place burden on the
company, depressing risk-taking. Banks could have encouraged companies
to dispose of excess assets more promptly. However, the corporate sector
took time to resolve the excess capacity overhang; as is explained later (in
detail in Chap. 6), it took about 15 years to get rid of the excess assets,
lengthening investment stagnation. While postponing resolution is not
beneficial to the company, why did it opt for delaying the decision? The
answer may be found in the structure of governance of a company that
makes a drastic decision difficult to take without a crisis.
In the latter case of an insolvent company, usually it cannot continue to
obtain funding if its financial position is properly assessed. Figure 4.4 shows
that operating profits of the companies with capital less than 10 million yen
nearly disappeared after the collapse of the bubble. These companies
counted as many as 1.6 million (78.7% of total 2.0 million at that time) and
accounted for 29.9% of total employment by the corporate sector as of
1990 (but only 10.8% of total investment as of 1990).21 Stagnation of
wages (and to a lesser extent investment) is partly accounted for by these
companies’ poor performance. How could these companies with no profits
stay in the market? In the long stagnation period, the government provided
a loan insurance scheme for small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs),
under which 100% (later reduced to 80%, in principle) of loans were cov-
ered by government-subsidized funds, if defaulted. This scheme may have
helped those SMEs that temporarily had difficulty in funding while remain-
ing basically viable. It is also possible this scheme may have saved unprofit-
able and unviable companies, depressing the efficiency of the economy, at
the cost of the taxpayers.22
21
The number of companies with capital less than 10 million yen declined to 1.3 million
(i.e., 54.4% of total 2.4 million) in 1997, and their share in total employment declined to
15.9%. This decline reflects changes in capital requirements under the 1991 amendment of
the Commercial Law, which raised the minimum capital to 10 million yen for stock compa-
nies, with the transition period lasting until end March 1996.
22
This scheme is under the jurisdiction of the SME Agency of the Ministry of Economy,
Trade and Industry and is widely supported by political circle. The ratio of insurance has
been in principle reduced to 80%. As of February 2016, 2.8 million cases of loans are insured
and the outstanding balance insured amounts to as much as 25.8 trillion yen.
144 K. ARAMAKI
(million yen)
35000000
30000000
1 bil. or
25000000 more
5000000 10 mil.–
< 50 mil.
0
< 10 mil.
FY1960
FY1964
FY1968
FY1972
FY1976
FY1980
FY1984
FY1988
FY1992
FY1996
FY2000
FY2004
FY2008
FY2012
-5000000
23
Ministry of Finance, “Kinnyu gyosei no tomen no unnyo hoshin” (On the current policy
of the financial sector supervision), August 18, 1992.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 145
24
Fukao (2009) pointed out that the estimated combined amount of net business profits
(inclusive of losses due to disposition of NPLs) of banks (city banks, long-term credit banks,
and regional banks), a concept similar to operating profits, was negative for 10 straight years
from FY 1993 to FY 2002; that is, after the burst of the bubble, banks could not cover credit
risk by their profits from their main business operations. Banks recorded surplus in terms of
final profits in 5 out of the 10 years, through sales of assets. He also pointed out that the
accumulated losses of banks arising from disposition of NPLs amounted to 96.8 trillion yen
over 14 years from March 1992 to March 2006, equivalent to 19% of GDP in 2006.
25
Matsushima, and Takenaka (2011, 225–6). “Nihon Keizai no Kiroku Jidai Shogen
Shu Oraru Hisutori” (Records of the Japanese Economy—Testimony of the Era—
Collection of Oral History) 2011 Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet
Office, Japanese Government (“Baburu/ Defure ki no Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku
(Rekisi Hen) 3” (“the Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in the Period of Bubble
146 K. ARAMAKI
and Deflation Vol. 3 (History)”) 2011 Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet
Office, Japanese Government) pp. 225–226.
26
See Komine (2011, 473–6); Nishino (2003); and Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha (2000).
27
When dissolving Jusen, public funds were used to avoid negative impacts on the financial
system by imposing loan loss onto agriculture-related financial institutions that had lent
heavily to Jusen. However, according to a book written by a journalist (Nishino 2003), the
agricultural sector demanded that saving the agricultural-related financial institutions should
not be used in the explanation as objectives of the use of public funds. In the absence of a
clear and easily understandable explanation, the general public, and therefore, political circle,
considered that the public funds were used to bail out Jusen, for which cases of fraudulent
activities were widely reported in the media.
28
Disclosure requirements were gradually strengthened. See footnotes 6 and 7 in this
chapter.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 147
29
Matsushima and Takenaka (2011, 225).
30
The Ministry of Finance announced that the size of NPLs of large banks was 7–8 trillion
yen in April 1992 and around 12 trillion yen in October 1992. However, this covered only
major banks and did not cover all financial institutions. Also, the assets covered were limited
to bankrupt or past due claims. As for claims on non-bank financial institutions, including
Jusen, creditor financial institutions did not grasp the actual situation, and therefore, they
were not classified as bankrupt or past due.
31
Matsushima and Takenaka (2011, 220–1).
148 K. ARAMAKI
future course of stock and land prices (and the economy as a whole),
which was a crucial factor in the NPL problem. In fact, in the early stage
after the collapse of the bubble, there was a serious concern that the land
price surge might return if policy response was eased.32 Even after the
land price dropped substantially, it was difficult even to imagine that
the land prices would continue to fall for more than a decade. The govern-
ment, banks, corporations, media, and people at large were still trapped by
“Tochi Shinwa” (land myth), and it might have delayed an appropriate
response.
By contrast, Nakaso (2001) referred to a dilemma that the authorities
including the BOJ faced. Nakaso argued, if the BOJ called for introduc-
tion of a comprehensive safety net framework, it could trigger a financial
crisis. Without a clear strategy on how to address the issue, the authorities
continued with a piecemeal approach to the NPL problem. This is a logi-
cal argument, but with hindsight, postponing a comprehensive response
only aggravated the situation, leading to a serious financial crisis in the late
1990s.33
As has been repeatedly pointed out, the core problem was excess
(unprofitable) assets in the corporate sector. Unless the corporate sector
removed these excesses, the economy could not recover fully. What was
needed for the financial institutions was to help borrowing companies
remove these excesses, not to help them continue to hold these excesses.
The financial sector, however, did not act in this way.
What could have been done then, under the circumstances, when a much
needed comprehensive framework did not exist? If we are to make a mere
32
The official discount rate, which was raised to 6.0% in June 1990, but was lowered
beginning in July 1991. The aggregate lending limit, which was introduced in March 1990,
was lifted in December 1991. A Banking Bureau executive at that time said later, “When we
lifted the aggregate lending limit, most of the newspaper articles criticised (it), by writing ‘If
policy reaction is eased, land price will never fail to rise again’” (Matsushima and Takenaka
2011, 313).
33
In January 1997, Prime Minister Hashimoto (LDP) declared the intention to start dras-
tic reforms in six areas, including fiscal structure and the financial system. Directed by Prime
Minister Hashimoto, the Ministry of Finance, then the supervisory authority of banks and
securities firms, started examination of comprehensive liberalization of the Japanese financial
system called “Japan’s Financial Big Bang,” and reform plans were authorized by advisory
councils attached to the MOF in June 1997. Those reforms were surely necessary for Japan,
but their timing was not right. With hindsight, when the financial sector was fragile, as evi-
denced by series of failures of financial institutions, the greatest care should have been paid
to maintain stability of the sector and markets without embarking on drastic reforms.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 149
34
Supplement 2 in this chapter gives a very rough estimate of impacts on employment of
a prompt resolution of excess assets. According to the estimate, if the total excess assets had
been disposed of in fiscal 1991, the number of unemployed people would have increased by
more than 12 million, and the unemployment rate would spiked by more than 10 times,
increasing from an actual 2.1% to an estimated 21.2%.
35
Explanation in this part is based on IMF (1995).
150 K. ARAMAKI
in the late 1980s (Norway) and at the beginning of 1990s (Finland and
Sweden), these countries were faced with severe banking crises in the early
1990s (started in Norway in the late 1980s) (Figs. 4.5, 4.6, and 4.7).
As the NPL problem developed into a systemic banking crisis rather
quickly, the three governments responded by decisive measures.
In Norway, the loan loss problem surfaced in late 1980s, first with finan-
cial companies, spreading to banks, and even large banks were placed in
serious difficulty by the end of 1990. Substantial funds were injected, and
500 6
Norway
450 GDP
(right scale) Real estate prices (left scale) 5
400
350 4
300
3
250
Consumer prices (left scale)
2
200
150 1
Bank share prices (left scale)
100
0
50
0 –1
1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993
Fig. 4.5 Real GDP growth rate and asset price (1980 = 100): Norway. Source:
IMF (1995) “The Nordic Banking Crises: Pitfalls in Financial Liberalization?”
IMF Working Paper WP/95/61
1400 5
Sweden
GDP (right scale)
1200 4
Bank share prices (left scale)
3
1000
2
800
1
Real estate prices
600
(left scale) 0
400
–1
Consumer prices (left scale)
200 –2
0 –3
1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993
Fig. 4.6 Real GDP growth rate and asset price (1980 = 100): Sweden. Source:
IMF (1995) “The Nordic Banking Crises: Pitfalls in Financial Liberalization?”
IMF Working Paper WP/95/61
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 151
600 7
Finland
3
400 Real estate prices
Bank share prices (left scale)
(left scale) 1
300
Consumer prices –1
200 (left scale)
–3
100 –5
0 –7
1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993
Fig. 4.7 Real GDP growth rate and asset price (1980 = 100): Finland. Source:
IMF (1995) “The Nordic Banking Crises: Pitfalls in Financial Liberalization?”
IMF Working Paper WP/95/61
by the end of 1991 the government had become the sole or majority owner
of the three largest commercial banks in Norway.
In Sweden, while problems surfaced with financial companies in 1990,
large banks faced with financial difficulties in 1991. The Swedish govern-
ment injected funds into these large banks (including the largest bank
which was government owned), by way of such measures as direct pur-
chase of new equities and provision of loan guarantees from 1991.
In Finland, as the saving banks were most severely hit, most support was
directed to Skopbank (the central institution for the saving banks). Faced
with a liquidity crisis in September 1991, the Bank of Finland (BOF) took
over Skopbank. In April 1992, a fund, Government Guarantee Fund
(GGF), was established, and the GGF acquired Skopbank from the BOF in
September 1992 and injected capital. Forty-one savings banks were merged
into the Savings Bank of Finland (SBF), which was subsequently taken over
by the GGF, which then made capital injections.
Furthermore, Sweden and Finland used explicit blanket guarantees
on bank liabilities (Norway did not explicitly announce it). In Sweden, a
technique to split a troubled bank into a “good bank” and a “bad bank”
(an asset management company handling NPLs of the troubled bank)
was used.
By mid-1990s, GDP growth recovered, and the Scandinavian cases
were generally regarded as successes in handling banking crises (Fig. 4.8).
152 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
8
2
Norway
0 Sweden
Finland
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
-2
-4
-6
-8
Fig. 4.8 GDP growth rate: Norway, Sweden, and Finland. Source: IMF (2014)
World Economic Outlook database Oct. 2014
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
36
The expected growth rate held by companies for the next three years declined further
from 2.2% in Period I (Initial Adjustment Period, 1991–1997) to 1.0% in Period II (Financial
Crisis and Its Impacts Period, 1998–2002), as explained in Chap. 3.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 155
(%)
60
40
Large
20 companies
Semi-large
companies
0
Small- and
medium-
-20 sized
companies
-40
-60
Jul-93
Jul-98
Sep-92
Sep-97
Jan-91
Jan-96
Nov-91
Nov-96
Mar-90
May-94
Mar-95
May-99
Mar-00
Fig. 4.10 Economic conditions, as judged by companies. Note: The chart shows
the share of “good”-the share of “bad.” Source: Tankan Business Survey, BOJ
strong for SMEs, which were more dependent on lending than for larger
companies but, after the financial crisis, the sharp tightening of lending
stance was observed across company size.
Against the background of the sharp deterioration of the economy, fun-
damental changes took place in employment and company behaviors, and
deflation started at the same time.
(%)
40
30
20
Large companies
10
Semi-large
0 companies
Small- and
-10
medium-sized
companies
-20
-30
-40
Mar-90
Jan-91
Nov-91
Sep-92
Jul-93
May-94
Mar-95
Jan-96
Nov-96
Sep-97
Jul-98
May-99
Mar-00
(%)
6
1998–2012
4.6% 2013–2017
5
3.4%
1991–1997
4
1985–1990 2.8%
2.5%
3 1974–1984
1956–1973 2.1%
1.5%
2
(%)
6
0
Feb-91
Feb-92
Feb-93
Feb-94
Feb-95
Feb-96
Feb-97
Feb-98
Feb-99
Feb-00
Feb-01
Feb-02
Feb-03
Feb-04
Feb-05
Feb-06
Feb-07
Feb-08
Feb-09
Feb-10
Feb-12
Feb-13
Feb-14
Feb-11
-2
-4
-6
(%)
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
37
Financial surplus/deficit corresponds to the difference between the amount of financial
investment and the amount of fundraising, which is conceptually equal to net lending/net
borrowing (formerly called “the difference between savings and investment”) in the national
account.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 159
Fig. 4.15 Number of regular workers. Source: Statistics Bureau of Japan, “Labor
Force Survey—Special Survey”
(%)
15.0
10.0
Financial
institution
5.0
Nonfinancial
enterprise
0.0
General
80 83 86 89 92 95 998 001 004 007 010 government
19 19 19 19 19 19 1 2 2 2 2
-5.0 Household
Foreign
-10.0 sector
-15.0
Fig. 4.16 Financial surplus/deficit by sector (in percent of GDP). Note: Years
are fiscal year. Source: Bank of Japan, “Flow of Funds”
160 K. ARAMAKI
esponse by the Government
R
Faced with the financial crisis, the focus of policy was shifted from pre-
crisis long-term, structural measures, such as fiscal consolidation and the
financial big bang, to full-fledged crisis management measures, which
were composed of the following, as explained before:
(%)
10
0
Jul-89
Jan-80
Aug-81
Mar-83
Oct-84
May-86
Dec-87
Feb-91
Sep-92
Apr-94
Nov-95
Jun-97
Jan-99
Aug-00
Mar-02
Oct-03
May-05
Dec-06
Jul-08
Feb-10
Sep-11
Apr-13
Nov-14
Jun-16
-2
-4
Fig. 4.17 Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food) (year-on-year change).
Source: Statistics Bureau, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 161
Macroeconomic Policy
In fiscal policy, six economic stimulus packages were implemented after
the financial crisis (April and November 1998, November 1999, October
2000, October and December 2001).
As for monetary policy, a reduction of policy rate (uncollateralized
overnight call rate) to 0.25% (September 1998) and the adoption of a zero
interest rate policy (February 1999–August 2000) were implemented, and
a Quantitative Easing (QE) policy was put into force (March 2001–March
2006).
With these supportive policies, the economy started to recover beginning
in April 1999, but the recovery was weak and soon started to contract again
starting November 2000, with the stagnation of the world economy trig-
gered by the collapse of the dot.com bubble and the sudden deceleration of
the US growth from the second half of 2000. In Japan, production substan-
tially shrank, and the unemployment rate reached a historic high of over 5%
in 2001. In this way, the stagnation of the Japanese economy further aggra-
vated and entered the second decade with the impact of the financial crisis.
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
1997
1998
1999
2000
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2010
2011
2012
1990
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1995
1996
(%)
40
30
20
10
0
Jun-74
Mar-76
Dec-77
Sep-79
Jun-81
Mar-83
Dec-84
Sep-86
Jun-88
Mar-90
Dec-91
Sep-93
Jun-95
Mar-97
Dec-98
Sep-00
Jun-02
Mar-04
Dec-05
Sep-07
Jun-09
Mar-11
Dec-12
Sep-14
-10
-20
(%)
14
12
10
0
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
1972
(trillion yen)
450.0
400.0
350.0
300.0
250.0
200.0
150.0
100.0
50.0
0.0
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
1996
1999
2002
2005
2008
2011
FY1960
1963
1966
1969
1972
(%)
30
20
10
0
Jun-74
Mar-76
Dec-77
Sep-79
Jun-81
Mar-83
Dec-84
Sep-86
Jun-88
Mar-90
Dec-91
Sep-93
Jun-95
Mar-97
Dec-98
Sep-00
Jun-02
Mar-04
Dec-05
Sep-07
Jun-09
Mar-11
Dec-12
Sep-14
-10
-20
-30
-40
-50
(trillion yen)
250.0
200.0
150.0
100.0
50.0
0.0
Fig. 4.23 Cash and deposit holdings by nonfinancial companies. Source: Bank
of Japan, “Flow of Funds”
once later called the “Great Moderation,” after bottoming out in 2002
until the eruption of the GFC in 2008 (Fig. 4.24). Thanks to such exter-
nal environments, growth contribution of net export to the Japanese
economy significantly rose from 0.2% in Period I and 0.1% in Period II to
0.8 in Period III.
166 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
8
Japan
World
6
0
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
-2
-4
-6
-8
Fig. 4.24 Real GDP growth rate of the world and Japan. Source: IMF (2017)
World Economic Outlook database, October 2017
(%)
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
30,000.0 4.0
20,000.0
2.0
10,000.0
0.0 0.0
Fig. 4.26 Private investment and Foreign Direct Investment. Note: Private
investment is in nominal terms. Foreign direct investment, in terms of yen, is
obtained by converting the FDI, in terms of dollars, using the period’s average
exchange rate. FDI/Private Investment is the ratio of two values, both in three-
year moving average. Source: Tabulated using relevant data from Cabinet Office,
JETRO, and IMF
(million yen)
5,000,000
4,000,000
3,000,000
2,000,000 Electric
machinery
1,000,000 and
appliances
0
Automobiles
FY1961
FY1964
FY1967
FY1970
FY1973
FY1976
FY1979
FY1982
FY1985
FY1988
FY1991
FY1994
FY1997
FY2000
FY2003
FY2006
FY2009
FY2012
-3,000,000
-4,000,000
Fig. 4.27 Nominal investment by the electric machinery and appliances sector
and the automobiles and parts sector. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial
Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 169
that of the automobile and parts sector throughout the 1980s and 1990s,
significantly reduced the level of domestic investment, particularly after
entering the 2000s. By contrast, the automobile and parts sector main-
tained a relatively high level of investment, even after the financial crisis.
Another example of defensive behaviors of companies is found in the labor
cost reduction. Restraint of labor cost (salary and bonus) in terms of labor
share in value added (Fig. 4.28), which became clear after the financial crisis,
was strengthened after entering the 2000s and continued until the GFC.
Thereafter, the share of labor cost in value added increased, as the value
added sharply shrank after the GFC, but thereafter it started to decline again.
(%)
66
64
62
60
58
56
54
52
Fig. 4.28 Labor cost/value added. Note: Value added = salaries and bonuses for
employees and executive members + expenses for fringe benefits + rental fees +
taxes and other official charges + operating profits; labor costs = salaries and
bonuses for employees + expenses for fringe benefits. Source: Ministry of Finance,
“Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
(%)
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Fig. 4.29 Share of public fixed capital formation in real GDP. Source: Cabinet
Office
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 171
4.0
Real GDP
growth
2.0 rate
Growth
contribution
0.0
by
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2012
2011
consumption
-2.0 Average
growth
contribution
-4.0 by
consumption
-6.0
Fig. 4.30 Real GDP growth rate and growth contribution of private consump-
tion. Source: Cabinet Office
172 K. ARAMAKI
120.0
115.0
110.0
105.0
100.0
95.0
90.0
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
Fig. 4.31 Real wage (2015 = 100). Note: Real wage is obtained by deflating
total cash earnings in establishments with five or more employees by CPI. Source:
Ministry of Health, Labor, and Welfare, “Monthly labor survey”
As the nominal wages kept falling, the household savings ratio continued
to fall after the financial crisis and finally fell below zero in 2013 (Fig. 4.32).
Another change in the Japanese economy was an increasing dependence
on trade. The trade dependency ([exports + imports]/GDP) consistently
rose after the war, then became flat from the mid-1970s, and in the 1980s
stayed at a slightly lower level. However, the trade dependency rate signifi-
cantly rose from the mid-1990s through the long recovery period (from
15.4% in 1990 to the average of 24.4% in 2003–2007) (Fig. 4.33). This
development implies that the economy’s vulnerability to external shocks has
increased, posing a threat to the stability of economic performance.
One additional change to note is the growth potential of the Japanese
economy. The corporate sector continues to be a net saver (Fig. 4.16).
On the basis of Financial Statement Statistics, the amount of investment
in nominal terms is smaller than the amount of depreciation, that is, net
investment is negative, in 13 out of 15 years from fiscal 1998 to fiscal
2012 (Fig. 4.34). By contrast, the government sector continues to be
the biggest user of the savings. The fact that the government sector, not
the private sector, has been a net investor for a long time, since around the
time of the financial crisis, poses a concern over the future growth potential
of the Japanese economy.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 173
(%)
14.0
12.0
10.0
8.0
6.0
4.0
2.0
0.0
FY1994
FY1995
FY1996
FY1997
FY1998
FY1999
FY2000
FY2001
FY2002
FY2003
FY2004
FY2005
FY2006
FY2007
FY2008
FY2009
FY2010
FY2011
FY2012
FY2013
FY2014
FY2015
-2.0
(%)
40.0
35.0
Trade
30.0 dependence
25.0 Export
(in GDP
20.0 ratio)
15.0 Import
(in GDP
10.0
ratio)
5.0
Net export
0.0 (in GDP
ratio)
1955
1959
1963
1967
1971
1975
1979
1983
1987
1991
1995
1999
2003
2007
2015
2011
-5.0
-10.0
Fig. 4.33 Trade dependence, export, import, and net export (in GDP ratio).
Source: Cabinet Office
174 K. ARAMAKI
(trillion yen)
70
60
50
40
Nominal
30 investment
Depreciation
20
Nominal
10 investment–
Depreciation
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
-10
-20
-30
(trillion yen)
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0 Current
Account
10.0 Goods and
Services
5.0
Account
0.0
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
-5.0
-10.0
-15.0
Fig. 4.35 Current account and goods and services account. Source: Ministry of
Finance
176 K. ARAMAKI
(yen)
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
Oct-09
Mar-10
Aug-10
Jan-11
Jun-11
Nov-11
Apr-12
Sep-12
Feb-13
Jul-13
Dec-13
May-14
Jan-06
Jun-06
Nov-06
Apr-07
Sep-07
Feb-08
Jul-08
Dec-08
May-09
Fig. 4.36 Yen to dollar nominal exchange rate. Note: Spot rates at 17 pm,
monthly average. Source: BOJ
This chapter has examined the process of the financial crisis that broke out
in the latter half of the 1990s and its impacts on the Japanese economy.
After the bubble burst, while the corporate sector took time to dispose of
excess assets and liabilities, cost and risk of excess (unprofitable) assets grad-
ually shifted to the banking sector, and a financial crisis broke out seven
years after the collapse of the bubble. The government was unable to
promptly resolve the NPL problem. The background for this includes opti-
mistic expectations held by the government for the future course of econ-
omy and land prices in the initial stage, concern in the subsequent stage for
the huge negative impacts on the economy that could arise from prompt
resolution of the excesses, and also non-existence of a comprehensive
framework necessary to resolve the financial crisis. With the breakout of the
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 177
(%)
80
70
60 All
industries
50
Manufacturing
40
30 Automobiles
20 Non-
manufacturing
10
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
Fig. 4.37 Overseas investment/domestic investment. Note: Overseas invest-
ment is on a consolidated basis, and domestic investment is on an unconsolidated
basis. Source: Development Bank of Japan, “Investment plan survey fiscal years
2015・2016・2017”, August 4, 2016
First, private investment increased in recent years, but its level continued
to be constrained relative to cash flow.
Second, companies continued to restrain labor costs through reduction in
nominal wages and a shift from regular to non-regular employment.
Third, the growth contribution of consumption declined against the back-
ground of continued fall in real wages.
Fourth, dependence on foreign demand rose, possibly raising Japan’s vul-
nerability to external shocks.
Fifth, the government continued to be the biggest user of savings, with
possible negative effects on potential growth.
178 K. ARAMAKI
Supplement 1
1997
January Prime Minister Hashimoto (LDP) declared intention to start drastic
reforms in six areas, including fiscal structure and the financial system
April Consumption tax rate increased from 3% to 5%
June BOJ law amended (its independence strengthened)
June Comprehensive financial liberalization (Japan’s “Financial Big
Bang”) authorized by advisory councils to MOF
July Thai baht recorded a sharp fall (start of the Asian currency crisis)
November Sanyo Securities filed a petition for protection under the Corporate
Rehabilitation Law, causing default in the interbank market
November Hokkaido Takuchoku Bank announced its inability to continue
November Yamaichi Securities announced closure of business
November Fiscal Structure Reform Act enacted
1998
April Comprehensive economic measures decided
May Fiscal Structure Reform Act amended
October Government decided to nationalize the Long-Term Credit Bank of
Japan (first nationalization of private bank after the war)
November Emergency economic measures decided (historically largest size)
December The Nippon Credit Bank nationalized
1999
February BOJ introduced the zero interest rate policy
2000
August BOJ lifted zero interest rate policy
2000–2001
Collapse of the dot.com bubble
2001
March Government declared Japanese economy was under moderate
deflation for the first time after the war
March BOJ introduced Quantitative Easing Policy (QEP)
April Koizumi administration started (return to the fiscal consolidation
and policy orientation for structural reform)
2002
January The economy hit a bottom (start of the long economic recovery)
October Financial Services Agency (FSA) formulated financial revival program
(aimed at halving the NPL ratio of major banks by end March 2005)
(continued)
180 K. ARAMAKI
(continued)
2003
January 2003– Great intervention
March 2004
2008
September Lehman Brothers collapsed (start of the GFC of 2008–2009)
2009
September The Democratic Party took the power
October Misreporting of fiscal position by Greek government uncovered
(start of the European debt crisis)
2011
March East Japan Great Earthquake
2012
December Second Abe administration and Abenomics started
Supplement 2
(trillion yen)
1800
1600 y = 30.931x – 137.36
1400
1200 Total assets
1000
800
600
400
200
0
FY1960
FY1962
FY1966
FY1968
FY1970
FY1974
FY1976
FY1978
FY1982
FY1984
FY1986
FY1990
FY1992
FY1996
FY1998
FY2000
FY2004
FY2006
FY2008
FY2012
FY2014
FY2016
FY1964
FY1972
FY1980
FY1988
FY1994
FY2002
FY2010
-200
Fig. 4.38 Total assets of corporations (excluding financial and insurance compa-
nies) and their trend line. Total assets (for the red line). Trend line for the entire
period except for 1985–2004. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial statement
statistics of corporations by industry”
(%)
35
30
25
20
15
10
0
FY1994
FY1995
FY1996
FY1997
FY1998
FY1999
FY2000
FY2001
FY2002
FY2003
FY2004
FY2005
FY2006
FY2007
FY2008
FY2009
FY2010
FY1985
FY1986
FY1987
FY1988
FY1989
FY1990
FY1991
FY1992
FY1993
(10 thousand
(%) persons)
25 1400
Unemployment rate
1200 resulting from
20
1000 resolution of excess
15 assets
800
Actual unemployment
10 600 rate
400 Additional unemployed
5 resulting from
200
resolution of excess
0 0 assets (RHS)
FY2003
FY2005
FY2007
FY2009
FY1985
FY1987
FY1989
FY1991
FY1993
FY1995
FY1997
FY1999
FY2001
Fig. 4.40 Additional number of people unemployed and the unemployment rate
resulting from prompt resolution of excess assets. Source: Ministry of Finance,
“Financial statement statistics of corporations by industry”
(trillion yen)
500 0.3
y = –3.4224x + 455
400 0.25
Physical assets
200 0.15 (excluding land)/sales
y = 5.6607x – 16.335 Trend line
(before bubble)
100 0.1 Trend line (after
financial crisis)
0 0.05
FY1960
FY1962
FY1964
FY1966
FY1968
FY1970
FY1972
FY1974
FY1976
FY1978
FY1980
FY1982
FY1984
FY1986
FY1988
FY1990
FY1992
FY1994
FY1996
FY1998
FY2000
FY2002
FY2004
FY2006
FY2008
FY2010
FY2012
FY2014
FY2016
-100 0
land) and an approximate line (trend line) for the period from fiscal 1960 to
1984. If we regard the difference between the actual amount of physical
assets (excluding land) and the amount calculated by the trend line as excess,
then it can be shown that the size of excess assets amounted to greater than
four-tenths of the entire physical assets (excluding land) around the mid-
1990s. This implies that prompt disposal of excesses would have created
negative impacts greater than calculated in the preceding estimate.
Fig. 4.41 shows an approximate line (trend line) for the period from
fiscal 1998 onward. The trend of physical assets (excluding land) is entirely
different for the period between before the bubble and after the financial
crisis. The figure also shows the ratio of physical assets (excluding land) /
sales. The ratio swiftly rose from the 1980s, hit a peak in fiscal 1998,
sharply fell until the mid-2000s, and stabilized thereafter. It is implied that
in the 1990s, two processes were simultaneously ongoing, one, efforts to
overcome the collapse of the bubble (disposition of excess assets) and,
two, adjustment to new environments where sales do not grow (restraint
on asset size or its downward adjustments). In other words, going forward
from some point in time in the 1990s, possibly from the financial crisis,
companies began to exhibit investment behavior that assumes that the
domestic economy will not expand in the future.
184 K. ARAMAKI
Bibliography
English References
International Monetary Fund (IMF) (1995) “The Nordic Banking Crises: Pitfalls
in Financial Liberalization?” IMF Working Paper WP/95/61, IMF,
Washington, DC.
Nakaso, Hiroshi (2001) “The financial crisis in Japan during the 1990s: How the
Bank of Japan responded and the lessons learnt.” BIS Papers No. 6, BIS, Basel.
Nakaso, Hiroshi (2014) “What the lost decades left for the future.” Keynote
speech, 2014 International Conference of the International Association of
Deposit Insurers, Asia–Pacific Regional Committee, Bank of Japan, April 23.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012) “Japan’s economy and monetary policy” June 4, 2012,
Bank of Japan.
Japanese References
Asahi Shimbun (2009) “Henten Keizai” (Economy in Transition) News Collection
Group Ushinawareta ‘20 nen’ (Lost ‘20 years’), Iwanami Shoten.
Bank of Japan (1993) “Heisei 5 nendo no Kinnyu oyobi Keizai no Doko” (States
of Finance and Economy in FY 1993), in BOJ Chosa Geppo, June.
Bank of Japan (2001) “Saikin no Ginko Kashidashi Shijo no Doko nitsuite”
(Recent Developments in Bank Credit Markers), October, Market Review
2001-J-10.
Bank of Japan (2003a) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment), April.
Bank of Japan (2003b) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment), October.
Bank of Japan (2004a) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment), April.
Bank of Japan (2004b) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment), October.
Bank of Japan (2005a) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment), April.
Bank of Japan (2005b) “Wagakuni Kigyo niyoru Yurishi Fusai no Asshuku to Rieki
Bunpai Saku” (Reduction of Interest-bearing Debt by Japanese Companies and
Profit Distribution Policy) May, Nichigin Review 2005-J-7.
Bank of Japan (2005c) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment), October.
Bank of Japan (2009a) Kinnyu Keizai Geppo (Monthly Financial and Economic
Report), February.
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS IMPACTS, LONG RECOVERY, AND AFTERWARD 185
Cabinet Office (2001) Heisei 13 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku – Kaikaku
Nakushite Seicho Nashi- (Heisei 13 Annual Report on the Japanese Economy
and Public Finance–No Gains without Reforms), December.
Cabinet Office (2005) Heisei 17 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku (Heisei 17
Annual Report on Japanese Economy and Public Finance), July.
Cabinet Office (2008) Nihon Keizai 2008–2009 (Japanese Economy 2008–2009),
December.
Deposit Insurance Corporation of Japan (2005) “Kinnyu Kikan Hatan ni kansuru
Teiryo Bunseki” (Quantitative analysis of failures of financial institutions),
Yokin Hoken Kenkyu September.
Economic Planning Agency (1993) Heisei 5 nen Nenji Keizai Hokoku (Heisei 5
Annual Economic Report).
Fujii, Mariko (2009) Kinnyu Kakushin to Shijo Kiki (Financial Breakthrough and
Market Crisis), Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Fujii, Yoshihiro (2001) Kinnyu Saisei no Gosan (Miscalculations of Financial
Recovery), Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Fukao, Mitsuhiro (2009) “Ginko no Keiei Akka to Hatan Shori” (Deterioration of
performance of banks and their resolution). In Furyo Saiken to Kinnyu Kiki
(Non-Performing Loans and Financial Crisis), edited by Kazuto Ikeo.
(“Baburu/Defure ki no Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku Vol. 4”) (Japanese
Economy and Economic Policies in the Period of Bubble and Deflation-Vol. 4).
Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office.
Heisei Kinnyu Kiki heno Taio Kenkyu Kai (2005) “Hatan Shori Shuho no Shinka
to Kanren Ho no Seibi (Kinnyu Saisei Ho Igo)” (Progress in Tools for
Resolution of Failed Institutions and Provisions of Relevant Laws [Since the
Financial Recovery Act]) Yokin Hoken Kenkyu Vol. 4, September.
Himino, Ryozo (2005) Kensho BIS Kisei to Nihon (Examining BIS regulations and
Japan), Kinnyu Zaisei Jijo.
Hori Masahiro, and Hideaki Kitaki (2004) “Ginko kino teika genkyo setsu ha set-
toku ryoku wo mochiuruka” (Is the argument to blame declining bank func-
tion convincing?). In Ronso: Nihon no Keizai Kiki – Choki Teitai no Shin-in wo
Kaimei suru (Debates: Japan’s Economic Crisis – Examining Real Cause of the
Long Stagnation), edited by Koichi Hamada and Akiyoshi Horiuchi. Nihon
Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Horioka, Charles Yuji (2007) “Nihon no ‘Ushinawareta 10 nen’ no gen-in”
(Cause of Japan’s ‘Lost decade’). In Keizai Teitai no Gen-in to Seido, (Causes of
Economic Stagnation and Institutions), edited by Fumio Hayashi. Keiso Shobo.
Hoshi, Takeo, and Hugh Patrick, eds. (2001) Nihon Kinnyu Shisutemu no Kiki to
Henbo (Crisis in Japan’s Financial System and its Transition), Nihon Keizai
Shimbun Sha.
Ikeo, Kazuto, ed. (2009) Furyo Saiken to Kinnyu Kiki (Non-Performing Loans
and the Financial Crisis), Cabinet Office, “Baburu/defure kino Nihon Keizai
186 K. ARAMAKI
and Economic Policies in the Period of Bubble and Deflation – History Vol. 3),
Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office, Japanese Government.
Mikitani, Ryoichi, and Adam A. Posen, eds. (2001) Nihon no Kinnyu Kiki – Beikoku
no Keiken to Nihon heno Kyokun (Monetary Policy in Japan – US Experiences
and Their Lessons for Japan). Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Ministry of Finance (1992) “Kinnyu gyosei no tomen no unnyo hoshin” (Current
policy of financial administration), August 18, 1992, in Banking Bureau,
Ministry of Finance, “dai 42 kai Ginko kyoku Kinnyu Nenpo Heisei 5 nen ban”
(42nd Annual Report of Banking Bureau Heisei 5).
Nakagawa, Satoshi (1996) “Wagakuni kinnyu kikan no furyo saiken no genjo
nitsuite” (on the current status of non-performing loans of the Japanese finan-
cial institutions) Ministry of Finance Fainansu. October.
Nakahara, Nobuyuki (2006) Nichigin ha Dareno Monoka (Whom Is the BOJ
for?). Chuo Koron Sha.
Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha (2000) Kensho Baburu – Han-i Naki Ayamachi
(Examining the Bubble—Fault without Intention). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Nishimura, Kiyohiko (2005) Nihon Keizai Miezaru Kozo Tenkan (Japanese
Economy – Invisible Structural Transition). Kansai Shakai Keizai Kenkyujo.
Nishimura, Kiyohiko, and Yoshiro Miwa (1990) Nihon no Kabuka Chika Keisei no
Mekanizumu (Mechanism of Stock and Land Price Formation in Japan).
Tokyo: Tokyo University Press.
Nishimura, Yoshimasa (1999) Kinnyu Gyosei no Hai-in (Cause of Defeat in
Financial Administration). Bunshun Bunko.
Nishimura, Yoshimasa (2009) “Furyo Saiken Shori no Keii to Ronten” (Process
and Issues of Disposition of Non-Performing Loans). In: Furyo Saiken to
Kinnyu Kiki (Non-Performing Loans and Financial Crisis), edited by Kazuto
Ikeo (Non-Performing Loans and the Financial Crisis), Cabinet Office
“Baburu/defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 4” (Japanese Economy
and Economic Policy in the Period of the Bubble and Deflation 4) 2009,
Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office.
Nishimura, Yoshimasa (2011) Kinnyu Shisutemu Kaikaku 50 nen no Kiseki (50-
Year History of Financial System Reform), Kinnyu Zaisei Jijo Kenkyu Kai.
Nishino Tomohiko (2001) Kensho Keizai Meiso – Naze Kiki ga Tsuzuku noka
(Examining the Economy Straying off Course: Why Does the Crisis Continue?).
Iwanami Shoten.
Nishino Tomohiko (2003) Kensho Keizai An-un-Naze Sakiokuri Surunoka
(Examining Economy under Clouds—Why Is It Put Off?). Iwanami Shoten.
Noguchi, Asahi (2005) Ekonomisuto Tachi no Yuganda Suishodama (Distorted
Cristal Balls of Economists). Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Ogawa, Kazuo, and Heizo Takenaka (2001) Seisaku Kiki to Nihon Keizai (Policy
Crisis and Japanese Economy). Nihon Hyoron Sha.
188 K. ARAMAKI
Otake, Fumio, and Noriyuki Yanagawa (2004) Heisei Fukyo no Ronten (Issues in
Heisei Recession). Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
BOJ (2009) “Kigyo Shueki no Kaizen to sono Nihon Keizai heno Ganni”
(Improvements in Corporate Profits and Its Implications to Japanese Economy),
September 20. Research and Statistics Department.
Sakuragawa, Masaya (2003) “Furyo Saiken Mondai ga Nihon Keizai ni Ataeta
Dageki” (Damage Made to Japanese Economy by Non-Performing Loan
problems). In Ushinawareta 10 nen no Shinn-in ha Nanika (What is the Real
Cause of the Lost Decade?), edited by Kikuo Iwata and Miyagawa Tsutomu,
Economics Series. Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Sato, Takafumi (2003) Sinnyo Chitsujo Seisaku no Saihen – Wakugumi Ikoki toshi-
teno 1990 nendai (Reorganization of Policies for the Maintenance of Stable
Financial System – 1990s as a Period of Framework Transition). Nihon Tosho
Center.
Sato, Takafumi (2010) Kinnyu Gyosei no Zahyo Jiku – Heiji to Yuji wo Koete
(Coordinate Axis for Financial Administration – Beyond Times of Peace and
Crisis). Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Tanaka, Takayuki (2009) Kinnyu Kiki ni Do Tachi Mukau ka –‘Ushinawareta 15
nen’ no Kyokun (How to Cope with Financial Crises? – Lessons from ‘the Lost
15 Years’). Chikuma Shobo.
Ueda, Kazuo (2001) “1990 nendai niokeru Nihon no Furyo Saiken Mondai no
Gennin” (Cause of Non-Performing Loan Problems in the 1990s in Japan). In
“Nihon Kinnyu Shisutemu no Kiki to Henbo” (Crisis in Japan’s Financial System
and its Transition), edited by Takeo Hoshi and Hugh Patrick. Nihon Keizai
Shimbun Sha.
Ueda, Kazuo (2005) Zero Kinri tono Tatakai (Battle against Zero Interest Rate).
Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Uemura Shuichi, and Sato Yoshiko (2000) “Saikin no Chika Keisei no Tokucho
nituite” (On the Characteristics of Recent Land Price Formation), October,
BOJ Chosa Geppo.
Watanabe, Takashi (2001) Furyo Saiken ha Naze Kienai (Why Have Non-
Performing Loans Not Disappeared?). Nikkei BP Sha.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi, ed. (2009) Defure Keizai to Kinnyu Seisaku (Deflationary
Economy and Monetary Policy), (Cabinet Office “Baburu/defure kino Nihon
Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 7”) (Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in the
Period of the Bubble and Deflation 7). Economic and Social Research Institute,
Cabinet Office.
Yoshitomi, Masaru (1998) Nihon Keizai no Shinjitsu (Truth of the Japanese
Economy). Toyo Keizai.
Yuasa, Shoyo, and Masahiro Tsujihiro (1996) Dokyumento Jusen Hokai
(Documentary Collapse of Jusen). Diamond Sha.
CHAPTER 5
(%)
10
0
Jan-80
Aug-81
Mar-83
Oct-84
May-86
Dec-87
Jul-89
Feb-91
Sep-92
Apr-94
Nov-95
Jun-97
Jan-99
Aug-00
Mar-02
Oct-03
May-05
Dec-06
Jul-08
Feb-10
Sep-11
Apr-13
Nov-14
Jun-16
-2
-4
Fig. 5.1 The Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food): Changes from the pre-
vious year. Source: Statistics Bureau, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communication
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 191
Changes of the GDP deflator from the previous year have been almost
consistently negative from the mid-1990s. The phenomenon of deflation
is more clearly shown in the development of the GDP deflator, as com-
pared with CPI (Fig. 5.2).1
(%)
8
CPI (excluding
fresh food)
4 (year-on-year
change)
GDP deflator
(year-on-year
2
change) base
year = 2000
GDP deflator
0 (year-on-year
change) base
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
year = 2011
-2
-4
Fig. 5.2 The GDP deflator and Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food)
(year-on-year change). Source: Cabinet Office, Statistics Bureau, Ministry of
Internal Affairs and Communications
1
The GDP deflator is a deflator that covers the entire economic activities, including invest-
ment and exports, while CPI covers only private consumption. Two points should be noted.
First, prices of investment goods such as machinery tend to reflect price-reducing techno-
logical progress. Second, price movements of imports are excluded from the calculation of
the GDP deflator (i.e., if import prices rise at a higher pace than domestically produced
goods, then the GDP deflator tends to be lowered more than otherwise), while rise in import
prices are reflected in CPI (household sector consumes imported goods, too). Therefore, the
GDP deflator tends to record a lower rate of increase than that of CPI, if prices of domesti-
cally produced goods, including those for exports, rise less than import prices.
192 K. ARAMAKI
2
Translated by the author of this book into English from the original text.
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 193
Import Penetration
Japan’s import penetration ratio significantly rose from 6% at the end of
1980s to around 12% in the latter half of 2000s (Fig. 5.3).
Changes from previous year of prices of imported and import-
competing goods that are included in CPI were lower than the changes of
prices of other goods in CPI from around mid-1990s, suggesting import
penetration of low price products contributed to lowering price level
(Fig. 5.4).
3
20
2
10
1
0 0
-1
-10
-2
-20
-3
-4 -30
96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04
(%)
40
20
–20
Cumulated
changes from
–40
1990 to 2009
–60
2000 → 2009
–80 1990 → 2000
–100
–120
–140
P
ta al
sa &
ra e &
en c
tio
ic
io
D
es Re
pm tri
le il
te
le
t
rv
at
G
ho eta
su c
c
ui ec
nc
in nan
ru
Se
ic
eq l
R
un
E
st
Fi
on
m
om
C
Fig. 5.5 Cumulated changes in GDP deflator from 1990 to 2009 by sector (%).
Source: Nishizaki et al. (2011)
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 195
(%)
10
5
0
–5
–10
–15
–20
–25
–30
–35
–40
fo ss
ts
e d
n
na inte
e
e
ty
)
ry nce
ar ke
ef
od
th an
in
io
ng
uc
in
sh (le
ci
Be
w
at
li
ol
a
tri
ra
od
e
ic
m
as
fre PI
d
ic
ec
O
pr
rte
un
R
C
El
m
po
C
om
ai
Im
D
C
Fig. 5.6 Price changes from 1990 to 2009 of deregulation-related products.
Source: Nishizaki et al. (2011)
3
Noguchi (2002) criticized the supply-side structural interpretation of deflation by con-
tending that positive shocks on the supply side, such as technological progress and availability
of less expensive materials from abroad, will shift the (upward sloping) short-term aggregate
supply curve to the right, bringing about a reduction of price level, and that this shift is
expected to produce an expansion of production, which does not seem to be in line with
Japan’s case in which the growth rate continued to decline from the 1990s. So, under this
argument, even if we admit the effects of price decline due to these (favorable) factors on the
general price level, it is clear that this mechanism was not dominant in the functioning of the
Japanese economy during the stagnant decades. We need to find out what was a dominant
196 K. ARAMAKI
mechanism that operated through the Japanese economy, which produced both stagnation
and deflation.
4
There are some arguments that refer to the quantity theory of money in their understand-
ing of deflation. However, the quantity theory of money, which advocates that the quantity
of money supplied in the economy determines the general price level, may be relevant in the
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 197
very long-term or under the extreme circumstances such as hyperinflation, but for other,
more realistic cases, the theory does not seem to be of practical use.
5
The timing of fiscal policy management may be questioned. Yoshikawa (1999) criticized
the timing of fiscal consolidation efforts in 1997, on the grounds that they were undertaken,
despite economic indicators showing that the economy might have entered a contraction
phase by mid-1997, and argued that it is impossible to achieve fiscal consolidation under a
recession.
6
Translated by the author.
7
Refers to the worsening real profitability, in particular.
198 K. ARAMAKI
factor … during the same period (i.e., 1992–94), the financial factor was
supportive. However, beginning 1997 … the credit crunch finally occurred.”
So, at least, as far as demand shortage or the stagnation in Period I
(1991–1997) is concerned, the financial sector problem does not seem to
be a major factor.
As we have seen here, neither the supply factor or financial sector prob-
lem arguments for deflation is sufficiently convincing. Therefore, in the
next section, we will look at the issues of monetary policy management in
the context of the demand factor arguments for deflation, which have
been extensively debated for the last two decades.
Percent
9
8 Call rates (overnight, uncollateralized)
7
6 Government bond yield (10-year)
5
4
3
Euro-yen
2 futures (3-month)
1 Official discount rate
0
1991 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99
Hayami, Yu (1998) “Azia Keizai to Nihon no Yakuwari” (The Asian Economy and the
8
Role of Japan), keynote speech by Governor Hayami of Bank of Japan, October 29. (BOJ
Home Page, https://www.boj.or.jp/en/index.htm/).
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 201
... had the BOJ loosened monetary policy to the extent modeled in the
simulations9 at any time up until early 1995, inflation could have been kept
positive through the end of the decade. (Ahearne et al. 2002, 21)
Given the inability of conventional monetary policy to stabilize an economy
under deflation, … there is a clear asymmetry of costs to deflation and infla-
tion ... given the very low rate of inflation and negative output gap that
existed in 1994–95, some precautionary further lowering of interest rates
would have been valuable to reduce the probability of deflation. (Ahearne
et al. 2002, 21–22)
A more expansionary monetary policy in 1994 might have avoided the sharp
increase in real long-term interest rates and hefty yen appreciation that
occurred that year. (Ahearne et al. 2002, 38)
Using real-time ... data, ... Japan was “too loose” on average from 1990
through 1994. Using revised data, Japanese policy was “too tight” over the
same period (Ahearne et al. 2002, 19).
Fig. 5.10 Taylor rule analysis of US and Japanese interest rates. Source: Ahearne
et al. (2002)
9
Simulation using the FRB/Global model.
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 203
time, but it was too tight if assessed using data that became available after-
ward. This is an argument that, as Japan’s economy was moving closer to
deflation, we should have been prepared for a downside risk.
Jinushi et al. (2000) presented a similar analysis and argued that the
actual call rate stayed high, as compared with the optimum call rate calcu-
lated using the Taylor rule.
It is true that, after the collapse of the bubble, the BOJ adopted “his-
torically unprecedented accommodative monetary policy” (Mori et al.
2001, 80). However, it was not recognized by the BOJ nor by the govern-
ment in general that the Japanese economy was faced with an unprece-
dented economic situation, that is, the formation and collapse of the huge
bubble, with its potentially far-reaching and serious negative impacts on
the economy, if not managed speedily and properly. Considering this, it
can be argued, with some hindsight, that the BOJ should have and could
have acted more aggressively with downside risk in mind, as argued in
Ahearne et al. (2002). However, a question still remains: had the BOJ
acted more aggressively, would the subsequent stagnation have been
avoided? Drawing on the discussion in this chapter, the answer seems to
be no. What is crucial when examining this point is how we interpret the
deflationary gap that the Japanese economy experienced. In other words,
the point is whether the Japanese economy was in a demand shortage or
whether supply capacity was in excess in light of the sustainable demand
level. Those arguments blaming the BOJ, including Ahearne et al. (2002),
seem to presume that demand was in short, so monetary policy could have
helped raising demand. If supply was in excess, however, what monetary
policy could do seems to be more limited than generally assumed. Through
lower interest rates and an eased liquidity provision, monetary policy
could favorably stimulate lending and investment, support asset prices
such as land and stocks, and affect foreign exchange rates. If supply capac-
ity was in excess of sustainable demand, then the most important task
should be the removal of such excess. More aggressive monetary easing
could have prevented stagnation to some extent in the first half of the
1990s, but it could not have (or rather should not have) raised demand to
such an unsustainable level that would make excessive assets profitable.
In this connection, we should rather remind ourselves of the fact that the
monetary policy was aggressively tightened from 1989 to 1990, raising the
discount rate five times, from 2.5% to 6.0% in little more than a year. Together
with the introduction of the aggregate lending limit by the Ministry of Finance
(MOF), this aggressiveness seems to have overkilled the economy, as is
204 K. ARAMAKI
shown by the nosedive of money stock growth (Fig. 3.6 in Chap. 3). Such
a tightening was reversed just one year later in 1991. The discount rate
was lowered seven times from 6.0% to 1.75% in just over two years,
between July 1991 and September 1993. A mishandling of monetary pol-
icy, if there ever was one, seems to be more relevant in the tightening
phase (1989–1990), rather than in the easing phase (1991–1993, and
1995).
Whether or not the monetary policy management was appropriate,
adjustments in the real sector that we saw in Chap. 4—disposition of
excesses, particularly unprofitable supply capacity, and relevant debt in
the corporate sector—had to be conducted in any event. So, the major
problem was not with the financial sector but with the borrowing compa-
nies that had accumulated unprofitable assets. Unless such excesses
formed during the bubble were removed, the economy could not have
recovered its strength (including, particularly, the positive risk-taking
behaviors such as investment). The BOJ could have done more to avoid
stagnation, but unless policies targeting more prompt disposition of
unprofitable assets and relevant debt in the corporate sector were taken,
stagnation was bound to continue.10 This mechanism is examined in
detail in Chap. 6.
10
Why could the removal of unprofitable assets from the balance sheets of corporate sector
not be conducted more speedily? There is an argument that funding from financial institu-
tions had an element of introducing capital rather than pure borrowing. Under this argu-
ment, when an investment project financed by financial institutions failed, financial
institutions acted as if they were a provider of capital and shared responsibility of failure,
through alleviation of repayment conditions and/or providing additional funds. Such behav-
iors helped delay the necessary adjustments and made it possible for companies to continue
to hold the unprofitable project. Probably, the best solution was to remove unprofitable
assets together with relevant debt from the rest of the borrower, that is, splitting a borrower
into a “good company” and a “bad company,” with the latter proceeding to a bankruptcy
procedure. See Harashima (2005) for an interpretation of bank loans as provision of
capital.
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 205
11
Manuscript of the press conference by Governor Hayami on July 21, 1998 (BOJ
1998a). The same statements were found in the manuscript of the press conference by
Governor Hayami on August 13, 1998. Such statements are also found in press releases by
the Monetary Policy Committee. For example, see Bank of Japan (1998c) “Kinnyu Shijo
Chosetsu Hosin no Henko ni tuite” (On the Changes of Monetary Adjustment Policies,
September 9, 1998).
12
Around the beginning of the 2000s, an argument that distinguishes between “good
deflation” and “bad deflation” attracted some attention. Under this argument, deflation
caused by such factors as technological progress or structural reform is said to be beneficial
to the economy. Then BOJ Governor Hayami contended in a press conference on March 10,
2000, that price declines arising from reductions in production and distribution costs due to
technological progress and a distribution revolution were beneficial to consumers. This con-
tention can be classified as a “good deflation” argument. The Annual Economic and Fiscal
Report FY 2001, pp. 43–49, of the Cabinet Office argued that the good deflation arguments
have problems: First, the arguments do not properly distinguish between changes of prices
of specific items (relative price change) and deflation (decline in general price level). Second,
decline in general price level does do harm to the economy. Under deflation, the burden of
debt in real terms increases, depressing investment. If the nominal interest rates or nominal
wages do not fall to the same extent as the general price level falls, the real interest rates or
the real wages rise, depressing investment and employment. Deflation may be beneficial to
the lenders for whom the real value of interest and principal repayments increase and those
employees whose employment and wages are protected; it is disadvantageous to borrowers
206 K. ARAMAKI
and new entrants to labor markets who may be squeezed out. In total, deflation discourages
investment and is detrimental to employment, bringing about significant damage to the
economy. Some media favored the “good deflation” argument. For example, Mainichi
Newspaper on March 17, 2001, in an article entitled “Deflation, Do Not Stop Prices from
Falling,” argued that price drops in recent years were due to import penetration or deregula-
tion, and therefore desirable. The article criticized the government’s interpretation of the
price developments at that time as deflation, as stated in the government monthly economic
report on March 16, 2001. The government report wrote that, if deflation is defined to
mean continuous decline in prices, then the Japanese economy is under a mild deflation.
13
The manuscript of the press conference by the Governor on May 20, 1999 (BOJ 1999a).
Governor Hayami also stated in another press conference that the BOJ had been providing
sufficient funds to the financial markets under the zero interest policy, and even if additional
finance was provided, further monetary easing effects would not be expected. See the manu-
script of the press conference, September 21, 1999 (BOJ 1999c).
14
In a press conference on August 17, 1999, Governor Hayami stated that there were four
by-products in relation to the zero interest policy: a distributional problem of reducing inter-
est income of the household, a concern that structural reforms may be delayed, moral hazard
of the market participants, and decline in market function. See manuscript of press confer-
ence by Governor Hayami on August 17, 1999 (BOJ 1999b). For similar comments, see
manuscripts of press conference by the Governor on February 15, 2000 (BOJ 2000a).
15
Manuscript of press conference by the Governor on March 10, 2000 (BOJ 2000b).
16
Manuscript of a press conference on April 12, 2000 (BOJ 2000c). In a press conference
on June 14, 2000, Governor Hayami said “(it) is an emergency measure adopted under an
emergency situation. Interest rate is something that goes up and down under the demand/
supply conditions like price; clearly, zero interest rate should not be continued limitlessly. We
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 207
have always a desire to recover space of maneuvering of monetary policy. See manuscript of
press conference by the Governor on June 14, 2000 (BOJ 2000d). In a press conference on
July 19, 2000, Governor Hayami stated that as the interest rates adjust monetary conditions,
the situation where interest rate is zero is a very distorted situation, while it may not be
appropriate to refer to the degree of freedom of monetary policy. See manuscript of press
conference by Governor, July 19, 2000 (BOJ 2000e).
17
The thought that monetary policy tools had been exhausted was later denied by the
policy actions of the BOJ itself, which included quantitative easing and its move to inflation
targeting. However, whether these policy actions contributed to the removal of the funda-
mental cause of the long economic stagnation is a different matter.
208 K. ARAMAKI
18
The classification in the text basically followed Tanaka Takayuki, “Zero Kinri Seiyakuka
niokeru Rifureshon Seisaku Rongi-Nichign ha Nani wo Okonai Nani wo Okonawa
Nakattaka-”(Reflation Policy Debate under the Zero Lower Bound Constraint on Interest
Rate—What Did the BOJ Do and Not Do?), downloaded on January 19, 2015, http://
ir.acc.senshu-u.ac.jp/index.php?active_action=repository_view_main_item_detail&page_
id=13&block_id=52&item_id=1426&it em_no=1
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 209
OJ Economists’ Views
B
BOJ’s economists were very skeptical of these unconventional policies at
that time:
210 K. ARAMAKI
Okina and Oda (2000) also argued that the introduction of inflation
targeting might hinder the flexibility of monetary policy operation.
(a) The policy target was changed from the overnight call rate to the
amount of deposits held by private banks with the BOJ’s current
account (a component of the base money).20
(b) It was committed that this policy would be maintained until the
change in CPI from the previous year stably recorded 0% or over.
(c) An increase in the amount of outright purchase of long-term gov-
ernment bonds was clearly indicated.
QEP lasted nearly five years before it was lifted on March 3, 2006.
Meantime, the BOJ increased the targeted balance in BOJ’s current
19
The aggressive outright purchase of long-term government bonds.
20
The base money is composed of deposits with the BOJ and cash (notes and coins in
circulation). As of February 2001, the amount of base money was 68.4 trillion yen, with
notes amounting to 56.4 trillion yen (87%), coins 4.2 trillion yen (6.4%), and deposits with
the BOJ 4.2 trillion yen (6.5%).
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 211
account nine times (4 trillion yen →30~35 trillion yen), and also increased
the amount of long-term JGB purchase four times (400 billion yen →1.2
trillion yen per month).
Although this policy is a novel step forward, some cautious comments
are presented on the BOJ’s QEP as follows (Adachi 2013):
Considering the upward bias of the CPI (as the weight is fixed, based on
the share of the adopted items in consumption in the base year), a 0%
increase is not sufficient for overcoming deflation.
The time schedule for overcoming deflation is not clear.
Now, let us look at some relevant data. Figure 5.11 shows develop-
ments in the rate of change in M2 and CPI (excluding fresh food) from
the previous year. It appears that the rate of change in both CPI (exclud-
ing fresh food) and M2 declined after entering the 1990s, implying that
movements in money stock and CPI may be related to each other.
However, Fig. 5.12 shows that the rate of change in base money, on
which the BOJ has a substantial degree of influence, does not seem to be
related to the rate of change in M2, casting doubts on the effectiveness of
quantitative easing.
(%)
35
30
25 M2 (average
balance)(year-
20 on-year
change)
15
CPI (excluding
10 fresh
food)(year-on-
5 year change)
0
Jan-70
Nov-72
Sep-75
Jul-78
May-81
Mar-84
Jan-87
Nov-89
Sep-92
Jul-95
May-98
Mar-01
Jan-04
Nov-06
Sep-09
Jul-12
May-15
-5
Fig. 5.11 M2 and Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food) (year-on-year
change). Source: Bank of Japan, Statistics Bureau, Ministry of Internal Affairs and
Communications
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 213
(%)
60
50
40 M2 (average
balance)(year-
30 on-year
20 change)
Base money
10 (average
0 balance) (year-
on-year
Jan-70
Nov-72
Sep-75
Jul-78
May-81
Mar-84
Jan-87
Nov-89
Sep-92
Jul-95
May-98
Mar-01
Jan-04
Nov-06
Sep-09
Jul-12
May-15
-10 change)
-20
-30
Fig. 5.12 Base money and M2 (year-on-year change). Source: Bank of Japan
(trillion yen)
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
Oct-93
Mar-95
Aug-96
Jan-98
Jun-99
Nov-00
Apr-02
Sep-03
Feb-05
Jul-06
Dec-07
May-09
Oct-10
Mar-12
Aug-13
Jan-15
Jul-16
Fig. 5.13 Loans and government bonds held by domestic banks. Source: Bank
of Japan
214 K. ARAMAKI
21
These factors must have been at work, albeit to a different degree, in other advanced
economies.
22
The situation changed with the outbreak of the financial crisis in the late 1990s, and the
lending attitude of the financial institutions was suddenly tightened. This fact implies that we
need to look at effects of the financial crisis on the behaviors of financial institutions and
companies.
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 215
However, it is not clear whether we could have avoided the long stag-
nation, if the monetary policy had been more aggressive and speedy. This
depends on whether we find the origin of the problem in the 1990s in
demand shortage or in excess supply. The argument of this book is that
the root cause of the investment (and economic) stagnation was in excess
(non-profitable) assets in the corporate sector. Under this view, what was
fundamentally needed was not to raise demand but remove these excesses.
To this end, monetary easing could be of no more help than buying time.
It seems that mishandling of monetary policy was more significant in
1989–1990, when extremely aggressive monetary tightening was con-
ducted, together with the introduction of an aggregate limit on real estate-
related lending by the MOF, crushing the bubble and overkilling the
economy. Those unprofitable investments in facilities and real estate-
related projects, undertaken by companies and local authorities partly
under the promotion by central government, which could not expect suf-
ficient demand, were destined to fail. So, intentional crushing of the bub-
ble was not necessary. Preventing the bubble from developing further was
what was essentially needed. It may have been beyond the ability of human
beings to contain (not crush) the bubble while keeping the economy on a
stable growth path. It is regrettable that policies not from an economic
efficiency or risk-control viewpoint but from an egalitarian viewpoint were
adopted to cope with the bubble, with little concern or awareness of dan-
gers of these policies to the economy.
After Period I passed, the Japanese economy experienced the financial
crisis. Simultaneously, the economy fell into deflation. ZIRP and QEP by
the BOJ could not bring the economy out of deflation. At this stage, on
top of the overhang of excess assets, which was the origin of the problem,
the economy may have become trapped in a vicious circle caused by
deflation.
If deflation continues, deflation may be incorporated in expectations of
enterprises. If a decline in nominal sales amount (nominal revenue) is
expected, the real burden of expenses with fixed nominal value, such as
wages, interest payments, and principal repayments, becomes heavier. Then,
new investment or employment may be contained, resulting in a reduced
investment and consumption demand. This may lead to a further decline in
sales, and the whole process enters into a declining cycle, making deflation
a chronic phenomenon. This process possibly acted as an extra depressing
factor on the Japanese economy, in addition to the fundamental burden of
excess assets and liabilities that the corporate sector continued to bear.
216 K. ARAMAKI
Bibliography
English References
Ahearne, Alan, J. Gagnon, J. Haltmaier, and S. Kamin (2002) Preventing
Deflation: Lessons from Japan’s Experience in the 1990s,” Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Paper Number
729.
Bank of Japan (1998) “Change of the Guideline for Money Market Operations”
September 9.
Bernanke, Ben (2000) “Japanese monetary policy: A case of self-induced paraly-
sis?” In Japan’s Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to U.S. Experience, edited by
Mikitani, Ryoichi and Adam S. Posen, 149–166. Washington, DC: Institute for
International Economics.
Fujiki, Hiroshi, Kunio Okina, and Shigenori Shiratsuka (2001) “Monetary Policy
under Zero Interest Rate: Viewpoints of Central Bank Economists.” Monetary
and Economic Studies/February 2001.
Jinushi, Toshiki, Yoshihiro Kuroki, and Ryuzo Miyao (2000) “Monetary policy in
Japan since the late 1980s: Delayed policy actions and some explanations.” In
Japan’s Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to U.S. Experience, edited by Mikitani,
Ryoichi, and Adam S. Posen, 115–48. Washington, DC: Institute for
International Economics.
Katz, Richard (1998) Japan: The System that Soured: The Rise and Fall of the
Japanese Economic Miracle. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Krugman, Paul (1998) “It’s Baaack: Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity
Trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 137–205.
Krugman, Paul (2000) “Thinking about the liquidity trap” Journal of the Japanese
and International Economies 14 (4): 221–37.
Mori, Naruki, Shigenori Shiratsuka and Hiroo Taguchi (2001) “Policy Responses
to the Post-bubble Adjustments in Japan: A Tentative Review.” Monetary and
Economic Studies 19 (S1): 53–112. (Institute for Monetary and Economic
Studies, Bank of Japan, February).
Motonishi, Taizo, and Hiroshi Yoshikawa (1999) “Causes of the Long Stagnation
of Japan During the 1990s: Financial or Real?” NBER Working Paper No.
7351, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Nishizaki, Kenji, Toshitake Sekine, and Yuichi Ueno (2012) “Chronic deflation in
Japan.” Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, No.12-E-6, Bank of Japan.
Okina, Kunio, and Nobuyuki Oda (2000) “Additional Monetary Easing Options
under the Non-negative Constraint of Interest Rate: Issues Drawing on Japan’s
Experience.” Kinnyu Kenkyu 2000.12, Institute for Monetary and Economic
Studies, Bank of Japan.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2010) “Japan’s economy and monetary policy.” January 29,
Bank of Japan.
DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY 217
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012) “Japan’s economy and monetary policy.” June 4, Bank
of Japan.
Swenson, Lars E. (2003) “Escaping from a Liquidity Trap and Deflation: Foolproof
Way and Others.” NBER Working Paper No. 10195, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Ugai, Hiroshi (2007) “Effects of the Quantitative Easing Policy: A Survey of
Empirical Analysis” Monetary and Economic Studies/ March 2007, BOJ.
Yamaguchi, Yutaka (1999) “Monetary Policy and Structural Policy: A Japanese
Perspective.” Remarks by Yutaka Yamaguchi, Deputy Governor of the Bank of
Japan, before Colloque Montaire International at Banque de France, October
8–9.
Japanese References
Adachi, Seiji (2013) “Kinnyu seisaku kettei purosesu to kinnyu seisaku ronso no
keifu” (Process of monetary policy determination and developments in mone-
tary policy debates). In Mazu defure wo tomeyo (Stop Deflation, First), edited
by Kikuo Iwata. Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Bank of Japan (1990) Chosa Geppo (Monthly Research Report) April 1990.
Bank of Japan (1998a) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), July 21, 1998.
Bank of Japan (1998b) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), August 13, 1998.
Bank of Japan (1999a) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), May 20, 1999.
Bank of Japan (1999b) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), August 17, 1999.
Bank of Japan (1999c) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), September 21, 1999.
Bank of Japan (2000a) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), February 15, 2000.
Bank of Japan (2000b) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), March 10, 2000.
Bank of Japan (2000c) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), April 12, 2000.
Bank of Japan (2000d) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), June 14, 2000.
Bank of Japan (2000e) Hayami Sosai Kisha Kaiken Yoshi (Manuscript of press
conference by governor Hayami), July 19, 2000.
Bank of Japan (2000f) “Wagakuni no Bukka Doko—90 nendai no Keiken wo
Chushin ni” (Developments in Prices in Japan—Centering on the Experience
in the 1990s), October, Department of Research and Statistics.
218 K. ARAMAKI
Miyao, Ryuzo (2004) “Ginko Kino no Teika to 90 nendai Iko no Defure Teitai–
‘Kashi Shiiburi’ Setsu to ‘Oigashi’ Setsu no Kento” (Deterioration of Banks’
Function and Deflationary Stagnation since the 1990s–‘Credit crunch’ theory
and ‘Rescue loans’ theory). In Ronso Nihon no Keizai Kiki, edited by Koichi
Hamada and Akiyoshi Horiuchi, (Debate on Japan’s Economic Crisis), Nihon
keizai Shimbun Sha.
Nishizaki, Kenji, Yoichi Ueno, and Tanaka Masahiro (2011) “Nihon no Bukka
Hendo no Haikei: Jijitu to Ronten Seiri” (Background of Price Developments
in Japan: Facts and Issues) December, Bank of Japan, Working Paper Series No.
11-I-9.
Noguchi, Asahi (2002) “Keizaigaku wo Shiranai Ekonomisuto Tachi” (Those
Economists Who Do Not Know Economics), Nihon Hyoron Sha.
Noguchi, Asahi (2006) “Ekonomisuto Tachi no Yuganda Suishodama” (Distorted
Crystal Balls of Economists). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Noguchi, Asahi (2013) “Kozo Mondai to Defureshon” (Structural Problems and
Deflation). In Mazu defure wo tomeyo (Stop Deflation, First) edited by Kikuo
Iwata, Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Noguchi, Yukio (2010) Nihon wo Hametsu kara Sukuu Tameno Keizaigaku
(Economics to Save Japan from Catastrophe). Diamond Sha.
Okamoto, Naoki (2001) “Defure ni Chokumen suru Wagauni Keizai – Defure no
Teigi no Saiseiri wo Fukumete” (Japanese Economy Facing Deflation –
Including Redefining Deflation), Cabinet Office, Business Condition
Judgement and Policy Analysis Discussion Paper DP/01-1.
Okina, Kunio (1992) “Nichigin Riron ha Machigatte inai” (BOJ Theory Is Not
Wrong). In Shukan Toyo Keizai, October 10.
Otani, Satoshi, Shigenori Shiratsuka, and Masayuki Nakakuki (2004) “Seisan Yoso
Shijo no Yugami to Kokunai Keizai Chosei” (Distortions in Production Factor
Markets and Domestic Economic Adjustments), IMES Discussion Paper No.
20040J-1.
Shinpo, Seiji (2002) “Defure wo Motarashita noha Kozo Yoin ka Kinnyu Seisaku
ka” (Is It a Structural Factor or Monetary Policy That Has Brought about
Deflation?). In Kinnyu seisaku ronso no soten–nichigin hihan to sono hanron
(Issues in Monetary Policy Debates – Criticism of the Bank of Japan and
Counterarguments) edited by Ryutaro Komiya). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2002) “Ryoteki Kanwa Saiyo go 1 nenkan no Keiken” (One
Year of Experience since the Introduction of Quantitative Easing). In Kinnyu
seisaku ronso no soten -nichigin hihan to sono hanron (Issues in Monetary Policy
Debates—Criticism on the BOJ and Counterarguments), edited by Ryutaro
Komiya. Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2008) “Gendai no Kinnyu Seisaku” (Current Monetary
Policy). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2009) “Tokushu Sei ka Ruiji Sei ka? – Kinnyu Seisaku Kenkyu
wo Meguru Nihon no Baburu Hokaigo no Keiken” (Uniqueness or Similarity?
220 K. ARAMAKI
Deflation and the Mechanism
of Corporate Behavior
estimated data for all of the profit-making companies (about 2.7 million
companies) in Japan, such as sales, wages, profits, assets, liabilities, and
capital. The statistics also give breakdowns by sectors and by company size
classified by capital size. All data are in nominal terms. We first look at
profit and loss, then assets and liabilities, and finally net assets. Drawing
on these analyses, we then present our views on the whole mechanism of
stagnation and deflation after the collapse of the bubble, and we further
explore the reason why companies continued to restrain investment and
wages even after the companies had eliminated excesses.
Fig. 6.1 Sales and wages (all industries excluding financial and insurance compa-
nies). Note: Wages = salaries + bonuses + expenses for fringe benefits for employ-
ees. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations
by Industry”
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 223
60 12.0
50 10.0 Operating
profits
40 8.0
Ratio of
30 6.0 wages to
sales
20 4.0 (RHS)
10 2.0
0 0.0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 6.2 Ratio of wages to sales and operating profits. Source: Ministry of
Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
by the mid-1990s. By the first half of the 1990s, however, wages contin-
ued to grow gradually, and they became more or less flat (did not decline)
thereafter.1
Reflecting such developments in sales and wages, the ratio of wages to
sales rose until the late 1990s, and the operating profits stagnated (Fig. 6.2).
With the outbreak of the financial crisis, the ratio started to decline and it
continued to do so until 2007. Then, the ratio jumped due to the sales
collapse after the Global Financial Crisis (GFC), but subsequently started
to decline again. Operating profits, which had been stagnating, started to
rise after entering the 2000s, but drastically fell with the GFC, after which
it resumed its rise. Over a quarter of a century after the burst of the bubble,
the operating profits have not shown a stable rising trend, while develop-
ments in most recent years may show some upward movements.
Different from developments in operating profits, current profits (and net
profits after tax) recovered a rising trend from the end of the 1990s, reflect-
ing improvements in non-operational profits from the early 1990s, which
cover such items as interest and dividends received and interest paid. Since
then, current profits have been rising with substantial fluctuations (Fig. 6.3).
1
Companies in Fig. 6.1 exclude financial and insurance companies. The same applies to all
subsequent figures.
224 K. ARAMAKI
(trillion yen)
80
70
60
50 Operating
profits
40
Non-
30 operational
profits
20
Current
10 profits
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2014
FY2011
-10
-20
Fig. 6.3 Operating profits, non-operational profits, and current profits (all
industries excluding financial and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of
Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
First, sales stopped growing from the beginning of 1990s and started to
decline from around the mid-1990s.
Second, wages continued to grow for some time, but they became flat
before the mid-1990s.
Third, the ratio of wages to sales rose substantially after entering the 1990s
(after the financial crisis, the ratio started to decline but then rose again
significantly, due to the GFC).
Fourth, the operating profits sharply declined and stayed low throughout
the 1990s (they rose in the 2000s but declined due to the GFC).
Fifth, current profits recovered a rising trend from the end of the 1990s,
reflecting improvements in non-operational profits.
Sixth, improvements in current profits, however, have not led to an increase
in wages (improvements in current profits and wages have been
de-linked).
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 225
(trillion yen)
80
70
60
50 Current
profits
40
Changes
30 in wages
20 from
previous
10 year
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2014
FY2011
-10
-20
Fig. 6.4 Current profits and changes in wages from previous year. Source:
Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
(trillion yen)
1800
1600
1400
1200
1000 Assets
800 Liabilities
600
400
200
0 FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
Fig. 6.5 Assets and liabilities of companies (all industries excluding financial and
insurance companies). Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics
of Corporations by Industry”
(trillion yen)
1,800
1,600
1,400
1,200 Assets
1,000 Fixed
assets
800
liquid
600 assets
400
200
0
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
Fig. 6.6 Assets and their breakdown between fixed and liquid assets (all indus-
tries excluding financial and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of Finance,
“Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 227
(trillion yen)
800
700 Liquid assets
600 Cash and deposits
500 Notes and accounts
receivable
400
Inventory assets
300
Securities held for
200 trading purposes or
100 maturing within one
year
0
FY1960
FY1964
FY1968
FY1972
FY1976
FY1980
FY1984
FY1988
FY1992
FY1996
FY2000
FY2004
FY2008
FY2012
FY2016
Fig. 6.7 Liquid assets and their components (all industries excluding financial
and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements
Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
2
Physical assets (excluding land) is the sum of “expenditure for construction that is not
completed” and “other physical assets (excluding land)” in the financial statement statistics
of corporations by industry.
3
The ratio of outstanding FDI (converted to the yen using the year-end exchange rate) to
stocks held for investment purposes has been around between 30% and 40% from the latter
half of 1990s to the beginning of 2010s. It showed a sharp increase since the first half of
2010s, reaching a level above 50% in fiscal 2016.
228 K. ARAMAKI
(trillion yen)
900
800
700 Fixed assets
600 Land
500 Physical
assets
400
(excluding
300 land)
200 Securities
100 held for
investment
0 purposes
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 6.8 Fixed assets and their major components (all industries excluding finan-
cial and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements
Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
(trillion yen)
350
Securities
300 held for
250 investment
purposes
200 Of which stocks
150 Of which bond
Outstanding
100 balance of
50 external
FDI
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 6.9 Investment securities and Foreign Direct Investment. Note: Data for
outstanding balance of external FDI are obtained by multiplying calendar year-end
balance of FDI (in US dollars) by year-end yen–dollar exchange rate. As data for
securities for investment purposes are as of the fiscal year end (that is, end March
of the following year), there is a three-month discrepancy in timing between these
two data. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of
Corporations by Industry,” Japan External Trade Organization (JETRO)
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 229
First, the decline in liquid assets after the collapse of the bubble reflects
stagnation in business activities.
Second, by contrast, fixed assets continued to increase. This is because,
while physical assets including buildings and machinery started to
decline from around the time of the financial crisis, an increase in securi-
ties held for investment purposes more than made up for such a decline.
Third, it is possible that the increase in securities held for investment pur-
poses from around the mid-2000s was substantially accounted for by an
expansion of outward FDI.
(trillion yen)
1,200
1,000
800 Liabilities
Fixed
600 liabilities
Liquid
400 liabilities
200
0
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
Fig. 6.10 Liabilities and their breakdown between liquid and fixed liabilities (all
industries excluding financial and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of
Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
(trillion yen)
700
600 Liquid
liabilities
500
Notes and
400 accounts
payable
300
Borrowing
200 maturing
within one
100 year
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 6.11 Liquid liabilities and their major components (all industries excluding
financial and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial
Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 231
(trillion yen)
600
500
Fixed
liabilities
400
Long-term
borrowing
300
Bond
200
100
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 6.12 Fixed liabilities and their components (all industries excluding finan-
cial and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements
Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
(trillion yen)
800
700
600 Net assets
500 Capital
400 Capital
surplus
300 Earned
200 surplus
100
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 6.13 Net assets and their components (all industries excluding financial and
insurance companies). Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics
of Corporations by Industry”
major factor behind the increase was an increase in earned surplus supported
by an increase in profits, which was substantially supported by improve-
ments in non-operational profits that we have seen in this chapter (Fig. 6.14).
Such a move to strengthen the net assets position can be found also in
developments in the capital/asset ratio. The capital/asset ratio of compa-
nies was on a rising trend from the mid-1970s and throughout the 1980s.
Then, it decelerated after entering the 1990s and almost stopped growing
after the mid-1990s. However, it started to sharply rise after the financial
crisis and has reached a historic high in recent years (Fig. 6.15).
We have looked at developments in profits and losses, assets and liabilities,
and net assets of companies based on combined financial statements. What do
they imply? Developments in these financial statement data indicate that the
financial crisis seems to have fundamentally changed the behaviors of compa-
nies. It appears that priorities in the management of companies changed;
strengthening their balance sheet position was given priority over other objec-
tives. The reason behind this was the drastic change in financial environments.
We have seen in Chap. 4 that the lending attitudes of financial institutions was
sharply tightened at the outbreak of the financial crisis, across companies of all
capital sizes, including small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) that were
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 233
(trillion yen)
350
300
250 Earned surplus
200 Accumulated
profits
150
Earned surplus
100 other than
50 accumulated
profits
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
-50
-100
Fig. 6.14 Earned surplus and its components. Source: Ministry of Finance,
“Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
(%)
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
FY1982
FY1984
FY1986
FY1988
FY1990
FY1992
FY1994
FY1996
FY1998
FY2000
FY2002
FY2004
FY2006
FY2008
FY2010
FY2012
FY2014
FY2016
FY1960
FY1962
FY1964
FY1966
FY1968
FY1970
FY1972
FY1974
FY1976
FY1978
FY1980
Equal or
(No.) (No.)
greater than 1
8000 500,000 bil. yen capital
7000 450,000 size
400,000 Less than 1 bil.
6000
350,000 yen and equal
5000 300,000 or greater than
100 mil. yen
4000 250,000
capital size
3000 200,000
Less than 100
150,000
2000 mil. yen capital
100,000 size (RHS)
1000 50,000
0 0
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
4
Particularly, for small- and medium-sized companies that were highly dependent on bor-
rowing from financial institutions, borrowing from financial institutions had been function-
ing as funding similar to capital contributions for which only interest payments were required
and repayment of principal was not expected. Therefore, faced with curbing of new loans (or
possibly, forcible collection of outstanding loans) by financial institutions after the financial
crisis, these companies had no choice other than trying to defend themselves by, for example,
strengthening their net asset positions.
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 235
First, the size of assets and liabilities started to expand from the mid-1980s at
a much faster pace than indicated by the trend in the preceding periods.
Second, the growth of both assets and liabilities slowed down after enter-
ing the 1990s and then declined from mid-1990s to early 2000s.
Third, after that, while assets resumed growth in early 2000s, liabilities
showed little growth to date.
Fourth, stagnation of assets after entering the 1990s was due to the decline
in liquid assets caused by stagnant business activities.
Fifth, fixed assets continued to grow, albeit at a slower pace even after
entering the 1990s (they are growing even now).
Sixth, however, in the fixed assets, physical assets (excluding land) started
to decline after the financial crisis, and this continued until recent years.
Seventh, on the other hand, in place of physical assets (excluding land), secu-
rities held for investment purposes significantly increased, making up for
the decline in physical assets (excluding land), and became a driving force
of supporting an increase in fixed assets or assets as a whole. Increase in
cash and deposits also supported growth of assets after the GFC in 2008.
Eighth, stagnation of liabilities, after entering the 1990s, also reflected
stagnation of economic activities. At the same time, both short-term
and long-term borrowing continued to increase at least up to the mid-
1990s (this corresponds to the fact that physical assets (excluding land)
were on a rising trend until around the financial crisis).
Ninth, the decline in liabilities from around the mid-1990s reflects a
decline in short-term and long-term borrowing (this has been particu-
larly distinct after the financial crisis).
Tenth, the growth of net assets accelerated in the second half of the 1980s,
slowed down after entering the 1990s, and halted around the mid-1990s.
However, net assets suddenly started a sharp increase, reflecting an
increase in earned surplus supported by an increase in profits.
The problem started with the rapid expansion of the asset size of the
corporate sector from the mid-1980s and the sudden stop of sales growth
and the subsequent fall of sales after the burst of the bubble at the begin-
ning of the 1990s. These developments indicate that the corporate sector
came to have a huge amount of assets for which they could not expect
sufficient sales or demand, that is, excessive (unprofitable) assets. This lay
at the heart of the difficulties of the Japanese economy after the collapse
of the bubble.
Under the circumstances, the corporate sector initially took the follow-
ing responses. First, they restrained investment but did not swiftly remove
excessive assets. Second, they maintained existing employment (regular
employment showed a moderate increase until the second half of the
1990s). Third, they restrained wage increases, but the combined amount
of wages paid by the corporate sector continued to increase for some time
(accordingly, the wage/sales ratio significantly increased in the 1990s).
Fourth, as a result, operating profits stagnated, and companies tried to
secure current profits by improving non-operational profits (interest pay-
ments, etc.). So, current profits started to increase from the end of the
1990s, but different from the pattern than existed until the 1980s; the
improvements in current profits did not lead to an increase in wages (per-
formance of companies and wage increases had become de-linked). Such
response by the corporate sector, in the period from the collapse of the
bubble but before the breakout of the financial crisis, may be regarded as
a passive response in that they did not swiftly dispose of the excess assets
and liabilities, maintained employment, and accepted a wage increase for
some time. If we focus on the corporate behavior, this first stage of the
economic stagnation may be termed “the period of passive response.”
Although the corporate sector employed what may be called a tradi-
tional approach that placed importance on securing employment and took
time to dispose of excessive assets, the costs and risk of holding excessive
(unprofitable) assets started to be shifted to the financial sector, in the
form of increasing non-performing loans (NPLs) and a financial crisis
broke out in late 1990s. Faced with the crisis, the corporate sector
addressed the problem of excessive assets in a dramatically different way,
and with this change, the stagnation entered the second stage.
To explain the process, after the crisis broke out, the lending attitude of
financial institutions was suddenly tightened, including for small- and
medium-sized borrowers for which the tightening of lending was rela-
tively moderate in the period immediately after the burst of the bubble. In
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 237
has been another big issue of the Japanese economy? Our conclusion is
that we should regard deflation as brought about by structuralized demand
shortage under the long-lasting defensive attitude of companies. To
expound, labor cost reduction through nominal wage cuts and replace-
ment of regular employment with non-regular employment placed a
downward pressure on general price levels. At the same time, defensive
behaviors of companies imposed negative impacts on consumption
through stagnant wages. Structuralized demand shortage due to such
downward pressure on consumption and prolonged restraint on invest-
ment must have worked as a chronically depressing pressure on general
price levels. If this is the case, it is likely that deflation is not the cause of
the economic stagnation that Japan suffered for such a long time, but it is
the outcome of the stagnation, or the consequence of the defensive behav-
iors of companies triggered by the financial crisis. This interpretation,
however, does not deny the possibility that deflation may have added an
extra burden on the economy through a mechanism that discouraged
employment and borrowings, making an exit from the low-growth cycle
more difficult.5
5
In addition to such behavioral changes of companies, however, it is possible that external
factors contributed to the nominal wage decline and emergence of deflation. This issue is
examined later in this chapter.
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 239
6
The total asset turnover ratio is usually defined as the value of sales divided by total assets.
In the text, the term, physical assets (excluding land), is used instead of total assets.
240 K. ARAMAKI
sales. The ratio hit a bottom by the beginning of the 1980s, and then fol-
lowed a rising trend. The pace of the rise accelerated after entering the
1990s, but it started to decline from the mid- through the second half of
the 1990s (Fig. 6.17).
With these developments in mind, let us conduct a very rough estimate
of the amount of excessive supply capacity (physical assets).7 We first assume
that a company has some criterion on the desirable physical assets/sales
ratio, or how much physical assets it wishes to hold per unit of expected
sales. As companies usually need physical assets in order to produce goods
or services, it is realistic to assume that a company would wish to strike
some balance between the size of physical assets and the volume of sales. As
Fig. 6.17 shows, this ratio changes over time, and it is difficult to know
what level of the ratio a company regards as appropriate. Figure 6.18 shows
estimates of excess physical assets. Estimates of excess physical assets
(%)
0.35
0.3
All industries
0.25 Manufacturing
0.2 Non-
manufacturing
0.15
0.1
0.05
0
FY1960
FY1963
FY1966
FY1969
FY1972
FY1975
FY1978
FY1981
FY1984
FY1987
FY1990
FY1993
FY1996
FY1999
FY2002
FY2005
FY2008
FY2011
FY2014
Fig. 6.17 Ratio of physical assets (excluding land) to sales. Note: Physical assets
= expenditure for construction that has not been completed + other physical assets
such as structure, machinery, and equipment (excluding land). Source: Ministry of
Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
7
Estimation is conducted as follows. It is assumed that the physical assets/sales ratio was opti-
mum and that there was no excess assets in FY 1990. The optimum size of physical assets is cal-
culated for each of the subsequent years by multiplying the amount of sales in each year by the
physical assets/sales ratio in FY 1990. That part of the actual size of physical assets that is greater
than the estimated “optimum” size of physical assets in each year is regarded as excess assets.
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 241
(trillion yen)
120
100
Excess
80 physical
assets
60 (estimate)
40 Investment
20 Depreciation
Fig. 6.18 Estimated excess physical assets, investment, and depreciation (all
industries excluding financial and insurance companies). Source: Ministry of
Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
decline, with the result that excess supply capacity did not decline, increas-
ing rather until the latter half of the 1990s. The presence of such excess
supply capacity brought about by sales stagnation and the growth of sup-
ply capacity placed a continuous downward pressure on investment, mak-
ing the recovery in the first stage of stagnation weak.
After the financial crisis (or in the second stage of stagnation), compa-
nies’ responses drastically changed, and disposition of excess assets and
liabilities rapidly progressed. In this stage, restraint of investment was fur-
ther strengthened and physical assets started to decline. Investment
restraint in the second stage of stagnation was implemented in order to
carry out disposition of excesses that had been delayed and, therefore, was
an unavoidable process.
(billion yen)
90,000.0
80,000.0
70,000.0
60,000.0
50,000.0
40,000.0
30,000.0
20,000.0
10,000.0
0.0
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2012
2013
2014
2015
2011
60 140
Private
120
50 investment
100 Cash flow
40
80 Private
30 investment
60
/Cash flow
20
40
10 20
0 0
FY1991
FY1994
FY1997
FY2000
FY2003
FY2006
FY2009
FY2012
FY2015
FY1961
FY1964
FY1967
FY1970
FY1973
FY1976
FY1979
FY1982
FY1985
FY1988
Fig. 6.20 Cash flow, private investment, and private investment/cash flow.
Note: Private investment =①Difference from previous year in (a) expenditure for
construction that has not been completed, (b) other physical assets (excluding
land), (c) intangible assets other than software, and (d) software + ②depreciation.
Cash flow = current profits × (1/2) + depreciation. Source: Ministry of Finance,
“Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
244 K. ARAMAKI
Fig. 6.21 Dividends received from abroad and their share in non-operational
revenue. Note: Dividends received = “Dividends and withdrawals from income of
quasi-corporations” in Ministry of Finance, “Balance of payments statistics.” Non-
operational revenue is for all industries excluding financial and insurance compa-
nies. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations
by Industry”
8
The shrinking population or the expectation of the population shrinking is sometimes
cited as a cause of the decline of expected growth rate. However, the number of people of
working age in the population started to decline in the mid-1990s, and the total population
started to decline in the latter half of the 2000s. It is probably since about 2010 that the eco-
nomic effects of the population shrinking started to be widely recognized. Developments in
expected growth rate do not seem to be in line with evolution of the demographic facts. Refer
to the supplement to this chapter for information about the demography and the economy.
246 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
7.0
6.0
5.0
Next
4.0 year
Next
3.0 three
2.0 years
Next
1.0 five
years
0.0
FY1973
FY1975
FY1977
FY1979
FY1981
FY1983
FY1985
FY1987
FY1989
FY1991
FY1993
FY1995
FY1997
FY1999
FY2001
FY2003
FY2005
FY2007
FY2009
FY2011
FY2013
FY2015
-1.0
-2.0
Fig. 6.22 Expected growth rate held by companies. Source: Cabinet Office,
“Survey on company behavior”
(%)
7.0
6.0
Foreign subsidiaries
5.0 (all industries
excluding financial
4.0 and insurance)
0.0
Fig. 6.23 Ratio of current profits to sales (%). Source: Ministry of Economy,
Trade and Industry, “Basic survey on overseas business activities”
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 247
(%)
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
Fig. 6.24 Ratio of outstanding Foreign Direct Investment (all sectors) to physical
assets (excluding land) (all industries excluding financial and insurance companies).
Note: Outstanding FDI is obtained by converting the year-end outstanding bal-
ance of outward FDI (all sectors, in US dollars) to yen using the year-end exchange
rate. Physical assets are the sum of “other physical assets (excluding land)” and
changes from the previous year in “expenditure for construction that has not been
completed” (all industries excluding financial and insurance companies). Source:
Ministry of Finance, “Statistics of corporate financial statements,” JETRO)
248 K. ARAMAKI
70
Private
60 investment
(excluding
50 land)
40 Cash flow
30 Private
investment
20 + outward
FDI
10
0
FY2003
FY2006
FY2009
FY2012
FY2015
FY1961
FY1964
FY1967
FY1970
FY1973
FY1976
FY1979
FY1982
FY1985
FY1988
FY1991
FY1994
FY1997
FY2000
Fig. 6.26 Private investment, outward Foreign Direct Investment, and cash flow.
Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by
Industry”; JETRO “Direct Investment Statistics”; IMF, “International Financial
Statistics”
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 249
most recent years, indicating that companies are starting to use their cash
flows almost completely, but with a greater emphasis on overseas investment.
Let us summarize the outcome of the examination of investment
restraint in this chapter:
9
As Fig. 6.7 in this chapter shows, cash and deposits held by companies sharply increased
from the latter half of 2000s. This is partly due to the shock of the GFC, but the fact that it
continues to increase demonstrates the strength of defensive attitude or risk avoidance.
250 K. ARAMAKI
Developments in Wages
Developments in wages indicate that wages have been restrained for nearly
20 years. Year-on-year rate of changes in wages per worker (nominal index,
2015 average = 100) has been negative in 12 out of 19 years from 1998
to 2016 (a simple average of year-on-year rate of change over 19 years is
−0.7%). The level of nominal wage per worker declined by 12.4% from the
peak of 114.8 in 1997 to 100.6 in 2016 (Fig. 6.27).
Developments in real terms are almost the same. Real wages per worker
(yearly average, deflated by CPI, 2015 = 100) have declined by 13.1%
from the peak of 115.8 in 1996 to 100.6 in 2017 (a simple average over
the first to third quarters) (Fig. 6.28).
(%)
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
-1.0
-2.0
-3.0
-4.0
-5.0
Fig. 6.27 Monthly nominal cash earnings per worker (in establishments with
five employees or more, year-on-year change). Source: Ministry of Health, Labor
and Welfare, “Monthly labor survey”
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 251
120.0
115.0
110.0
105.0
100.0
95.0
90.0
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
Fig. 6.28 Monthly real cash earnings per worker (in establishments with five
employees or more [2015 = 100]). Source: Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare,
“Monthly labor survey”
ratio of total wages to total sales significantly increased after entering the
1990s, and the operating profits substantially declined and stagnated (see
Figs. 6.1 and 6.2).
As previously mentioned, response by companies in the period after the
collapse of the bubble but before the financial crisis was passive. During
this period of passive response, companies maintained employment and
wages, and accordingly, a rise in labor costs and reduction in operating
profits resulted.
Figure 6.29 shows developments in real wages and labor productivity
since the 1990s. It shows that the rise in real wages from 1990 exceeded
the rise in labor productivity over the same period throughout the 1990s.
Reflecting such developments, as Fig. 6.30 indicates, the share of labor
income (the labor share) in national income sharply increased in the
1990s.10
10
Labor income share = (labor income in real GDP)/(real GDP) = (real wage per worker
[w]) × (total number of workers [N]) / (real GDP [y]) = w/(y/N). Therefore, the rate of
change in labor income share = the rate of change in real wages − the rate of change in labor
productivity. So, if an increase in real wages exceeds an increase in labor productivity, as is the
case shown in Fig. 6.29, the labor income share rises.
252 K. ARAMAKI
115
110
90
85
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
Fig. 6.29 Real wages and labor productivity (1990 = 100). Note: Real wages =
real wages in Monthly Labor Survey, labor productivity = real GDP (all indus-
tries)/No. of employees in Labor Force Survey. Source: Ministry of Health, Labor,
and Welfare, “Monthly labor survey”; Cabinet Office, Statistics Bureau, Ministry
of Internal Affairs and Communications, “Labor force survey”
The rise in real wages and labor income share depressed return on assets
(ROA) of companies. As we saw in Fig. 4.2, ROA continuously declined
after entering the 1990s until near the end of the 1990s.11
In this way, in the first stage of stagnation until before the financial crisis,
companies not only continued to hold excess (unprofitable) assets, as previ-
ously explained, but also accepted increases in labor costs, and as a result,
incurred a further decline in ROA. However, the situation drastically changed
with the breakout of the financial crisis in the late 1990s. The lending stance
of financial institutions was sharply tightened. With the deterioration of fund-
ing environments, companies started to rapidly strengthen their net asset
positions, as explained before. The “period of crisis response” previously
mentioned then started. With little expectation for sales increase, companies
aimed to strengthen their net asset positions by creating profits through labor
cost reduction, in addition to repayment of debts (interest payment reduc-
tion), and sales of assets (realization of unrealized capital gains).
11
The decline in ROA may have been another factor that contributed to the restraint on
investment.
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 253
(%)
76.0
74.0
72.0 GDP
statistics
70.0 with base
year = 2000
68.0
GDP
66.0 statistics
with base
64.0 year = 2011
62.0
60.0
2010
1984
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2012
2014
1980
1982
1986
1988
1990
1992
Fig. 6.30 Labor income share. Note: Labor income share = labor income/
national income (in factor price base). Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
Labor cost reduction after the financial crisis was pursued basically
through a reduction in wages of regular workers and a reduction in the
number of regular workers and their replacement with non-regular work-
ers. As we saw in Fig. 4.15, the number of regular workers declined by
4.8 million in eight years from 1997 to 2005. It tended to decline beyond
that, but it hit a bottom in 2014 and recovered an upward trend recently.
Also, as we saw in Fig. 4.14, the share of non-regular workers sharply
increased from 20.2% in 1990 and 20.9% in 1995 to 37.9% in 2014, sub-
sequently declined somewhat thereafter.12
12
Expanded use of non-regular workers has been in progress in almost all sectors from
2003 to 2015 (Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications, “Labour Force Survey,
Detailed Tabulation”). The share of non-regular workers is high in restaurants, hotels,
wholesale and retail, real estate, and services, including medical and welfare. Also, the share
of non-regular workers substantially increased in such sectors as transportation, restaurants,
and hotels. At the same time, employment in manufacturing sector has been declining, and
employment has been rising in such sectors as medical care and welfare and restaurants and
hotels, showing a shift in industrial structure toward domestic demand-type services indus-
tries. Among the sectors in which increased employment has been provided, the wage levels
in those sectors, such as medical care, welfare, and wholesale and retail are relatively low and
the wage levels in information and communication are high. The wage levels in regulated
sectors, such as railways and electricity, gas and water supply are high (Ministry of Health,
Labor, and Welfare, “Basic Survey on Wage Structure”).
254 K. ARAMAKI
104
102
100
Normal
98
workers
Part-time
96
workers
94
92
90
Fig. 6.31 Monthly cash earnings per worker for normal workers and for part-
time workers (2015 = 100). Source: Ministry of Health, Labor, and Welfare,
“Monthly labor survey”
13
If we include social security contribution borne by companies, costs of hiring a regular
worker become further high as compared with hiring a non-regular worker.
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 255
(%)
65.0
64.0
63.0
62.0
61.0
60.0
59.0
58.0
57.0
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
62 France
60
58
56
(%)
66
64
62
60
58
56
54
52
FY1999
FY2000
FY2001
FY2002
FY2003
FY2004
FY2005
FY2006
FY2007
FY2008
FY2009
FY2010
FY2011
FY2012
FY2013
FY2014
FY2015
FY2016
FY1990
FY1991
FY1992
FY1993
FY1994
FY1995
FY1996
FY1997
FY1998
Fig. 6.34 Labor cost/value added. Note: Labor cost = wages + bonuses +
expense for fringe benefits. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements
Statistics of Corporations by Industry”
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 257
Fig. 6.35 Value added and ratio of wage increase, dividends, and increase in net
assets to value added. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Financial Statements Statistics
of Corporations by Industry”
258 K. ARAMAKI
added stopped growing following the collapse of the bubble, and, particu-
larly, after the financial crisis, the amount of value added was allocated
differently from the previous pattern—strengthening the net asset position
and dividend payments, and curtailing increases in wages. Companies’ pri-
orities for the allocation of value added changed greatly with the outbreak
of the financial crisis, and the change may have become irreversible.
250.0
200.0
US
150.0 UK
Germany
100.0 France
Japan
50.0
0.0
Fig. 6.36 Annual average wage (1991 = 100). Source: OECD Economic
Outlook Database
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 259
300.0
250.0
200.0
Japan
150.0 US
Germany
100.0 UK
France
50.0
0.0
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
01/01/1970
01/12/1971
01/11/1973
10
15
20
25
0
5
-5
01/10/1975
(%)
01/09/1977 1971
K. ARAMAKI
01/08/1979 1974
01/07/1981
1977
01/06/1983
01/05/1985 1980
01/04/1987 1983
01/03/1989 1986
01/02/1991
1989
01/01/1993
01/12/1994 1992
01/11/1996 1995
01/10/1998 1998
01/09/2000
2001
01/08/2002
Japan
01/05/2008 2010
average
01/04/2010
01/03/2012
01/02/2014
Fig. 6.39 Export price index (yen base) (2015 = 100). Source: Bank of Japan
01/01/2016
Fig. 6.38 Annual rate of increase in CPI (excluding food, energy). Source: OECD
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 261
developments in the export price index (yen base, 2015 = 100). Export price
has been largely on the decline since the 1980s.14
Such a continuous decline in export price (yen base) suggests that, in
addition to the effects of technological progress, the pricing behavior of
export industries focused on restraint of export prices in the situation of
intensifying competitive pressure from emerging market economies and
continuous yen appreciation. Restraint on export prices by export indus-
tries, which are leading industries in Japan, depressed prices of intermedi-
ate inputs and wages.
As we have seen, wage restraint has continued even after excess employ-
ment was eliminated by the mid-2000s. The continuing restraint may
reflect the long-held company goal of maintaining international competi-
tiveness through cost reduction, with labor cost reduction through wage
restraint and replacement of regular with non-regular workers offering a
very effective tool to accomplish this aim.
However, competition through such cost reduction seems to have
placed Japanese economy in a more difficult position. The terms of trade
on domestic production of manufacturers (output deflator / input defla-
tor) has been deteriorating since the 2000s, and this development has
made it more difficult to make profits, further depressing wages (Fig. 6.40).
Such a tendency is most articulated in electric machinery industries, which
suffered significant decline in the output deflator. These developments in
terms of trade were the outcome of companies’ behavior in internationally
competitive environments, but at the same time, worked as an impetus to
expand low cost production abroad and to reduce domestic production. For
the production of goods that can be easily standardized, international com-
petition through cost restraint may have ceased to be an effective strategy, as
Japan is a high-wage economy (Fig. 6.41).
Despite such efforts for exports price restraint, Japan’s export share in
world exports has declined significantly since the 1990s. This reflects
decline in competitiveness and/or a shift of production bases abroad
through foreign direct investment.
However, other industrial countries have also lost their share in world
exports, with the rise of emerging market economies, particularly China,
14
In terms of the rate of change, the average rate of change vis-à-vis previous year of
Japan’s export price index (yen base, monthly) over the period from January 1976 to
December 2013 was −1.2%.
262 K. ARAMAKI
140.0
120.0
100.0
Output
80.0 deflator
60.0 Input
deflator
40.0
20.0
0.0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
Fig. 6.40 Developments in terms of trade (output deflator and input deflator):
manufacturing (2005 = 100). Source: Cabinet Office, GDP Statistics
250.0
200.0
150.0 Output
deflator
Input
100.0 deflator
50.0
0.0
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
Fig. 6.41 Developments in terms of trade (output deflator and input deflator):
electric machinery (2005 = 100). Source: Cabinet Office GDP Statistics
(%)
20
18
16
14
Japan
12
US
10
Germany
8
UK
6 France
4 China
2
0
1950
1953
1956
1959
1962
1965
1968
1971
1974
1977
1980
1983
1986
1989
1992
1995
1998
2001
2004
2007
2010
2013
2016
Fig. 6.42 Share of G5 and China in world exports. Source: IMF, “Direction of
Trade”
(trillion yen)
300.0
250.0
200.0 Base
year = 2000
150.0
Base
100.0 year = 2011
50.0
0.0
FY1980
FY1982
FY1984
FY1986
FY1988
FY1990
FY1992
FY1994
FY1996
FY1998
FY2000
FY2002
FY2004
FY2006
FY2010
FY2014
FY2008
FY2012
Fig. 6.43 Employment income. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
(trillion yen)
20.0000
15.0000
10.0000
Base
5.0000
year = 2000
Base
0.0000
year = 2011
FY1980
FY1982
FY1984
FY1986
FY1988
FY1990
FY1992
FY1994
FY1996
FY1998
FY2000
FY2002
FY2004
FY2006
FY2008
FY2010
FY2012
FY2014
-5.0000
-10.0000
-15.0000
Fig. 6.44 Net interest received by households. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP
statistics
(trillion yen)
350.0000
300.0000
250.0000
Base
200.0000 year = 2000
150.0000 Base
year = 2011
100.0000
50.0000
0.0000 FY1996
FY1998
FY2000
FY2002
FY2004
FY2006
FY2008
FY2010
FY2012
FY2014
FY1980
FY1982
FY1984
FY1986
FY1988
FY1990
FY1992
FY1994
15
The ratio of household consumption to household income is defined as the ratio of final
consumption expenditure of households to the combined amount of nominal income of
households, including employment income, property income such as net interest received,
and operating surplus and mixed income (that is, personal business income).
266 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
100
90
80
70
60 Base
year = 2000
50
Base
40 year = 2011
30
20
10
0
1994
1996
1998
2000
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
2002
300
Fig. 6.47 Export price, import price, and terms of trade (2015 = 100). Source:
Bank of Japan
has been declining since the mid-1980s. By contrast, Japan’s import price
index (yen base) had been stable from mid-1980s but increased substan-
tially from the mid-2000s. Reflecting such developments in export and
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 267
import prices, the terms of trade (export price index/import price index)
followed a declining trend from the beginning of the 1970s. It tended to
be stable from the 1980s but very rapidly deteriorated from the latter half
of 1990s.
A deterioration of the terms of trade may bring about a decline in real
wages, as indicated in the equation here, which is derived from the defini-
tion of the real wages:
Where
Even if the labor share (WN/Y) and the labor productivity (y/N) are
kept unchanged, real wages decline if the GDP deflator declines more than
the CPI. A deterioration in terms of trade (export price/import price) low-
ers the GDP deflator/CPI ratio, because a rise in import prices is reflected
in the CPI but not in GDP deflator, and a decline in export prices is
reflected not in the CPI but in the GDP deflator. A decline in the GDP
deflator/CPI ratio makes an increase in nominal GDP (and, therefore,
nominal wages) smaller than an increase in CPI, thereby reducing real
wages. A stagnation in real wages in the 2000s could have been brought
about by the deterioration in the terms of trade. We saw in Chap. 4 that
the growth contribution of private consumption has been declining since
the 2000s. The consistent decline in real wages due to factors including
deterioration in the terms of trade seems to be among the causes of such
decline.
268 K. ARAMAKI
16
Images of the stagnation mechanism in each of the first, second, and third stages are
given in the supplement to this chapter.
270 K. ARAMAKI
There are two views on the motivation for the continuation of investment
restraint. In one view, it is construed that the investment restraint was
brought about by an irrationally defensive mindset of companies, which had
been deeply ingrained as a result of the long-lasting low growth. From the
other perspective, the investment restraint was viewed as the result of a ratio-
nal choice made by companies to shift the production base to overseas,
reflecting, one, low growth of the domestic economy over an extended
period of time, and, two, a difference in profitability between domestic and
foreign operations.
As for wages, the labor income share rose to an unprecedented high
level in the first stage of stagnation. After the financial crisis, the corpo-
rate sector drastically changed its stance and rapidly proceeded with labor
cost reduction through reduction of nominal wages of regular workers
and their replacement with non-regular workers. As a result, excess
employment was eliminated by the mid-2000s. However, wage restraint
continued. This may have occurred because the labor cost reduction,
through reduction of nominal wages of regular workers and their replace-
ment with non-regular workers who were paid lower wages, could be
utilized as an effective tool in competition through further cost reduc-
tion, even after the excess employment had been eliminated. This corpo-
rate behavior may have been influenced by pricing behavior that is,
long-term restraint on export prices, which has been long employed by
companies during the yen appreciation and faced with international
competition.
With the continued wage restraint and the reduction in interest received
by households under the low-interest policy, the ratio of household con-
sumption to household income continued to rise and the savings ratio of
households became negative. Due to deterioration in the terms of trade
from the 2000s, the real wages further declined, making it difficult to
expect a greater growth contribution from consumption.
The Japanese economy returned to a normal situation from the mid-
2000s, after overcoming the negative legacy of the bubble and shocks of
the financial crisis. Under these circumstances, the corporate sector still
continued to restrain investment and wages. These defensive behaviors,
together with the effects of the resultant decline in nominal wages and
structuralized shortage of domestic demand, seem to have brought about
continued deflation. Deflation itself in turn had depressing effects on the
economy, by lowering sales expectations held by companies for the future
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 271
17
Particularly due to restraint on investment in physical assets over an extended period of
time, it is possible that supply capacity of companies may have been significantly reduced,
leading to a decline of potential growth rate. The potential growth rate of Japanese economy
estimated by the Cabinet Office declined from 4.4% in the 1980s, to 1.9% in the 1990s, and
further, to 0.7% in the 2000s. Thereafter, it has risen somewhat, and it was estimated to be
1.0% as of second quarter of 2017.
272 K. ARAMAKI
SUPPLEMENT
Mechanism of the Three Stages
of Stagnation Collapse of the bubble
(1) Mechanism of the first stage Cessation of sale
of stagnation (from the collapse Formation of increase and
excess assets subsequent
of the bubble until just before decline of sales
the financial crisis: 1991–1997)
Lengthening of
Initial acceptance
disposition of
of wage increase
excess assets
Japanese–US
trade disputes
Yen Increase in
appreciation excess
assets
Lengthening of
Drag on exports investment
restraint
Lengthening of
stagnation
Decline in
debt service
capacity
Decline in profitability of
land, decline in land
prices, decline in
collateral value of land
Shift of cost of excess
assets to financial sector
(worsening of NPL
problems)
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 273
Deterioration of
economic Tightening of lending
conditions stance
Wage Replacement
reduction by non-regular
workers
Investment
restraint Decline in
growth
contribution of
consumption
Deflation
and low
growth
274 K. ARAMAKI
Continued low
growth
Low growth
expectations
Population decline
Continued defensive
attitude of companies
High Competition
profitability Investment Labor cost through cost
of overseas restraint restraint reduction
business
Replacement
Wage
Decline in growth by non-regular
restraint workers
potential and
export
competitiveness
Decline
Decline in in
growth Future
Deterioration concern of marriage
in terms Decline in contribution of and
consumption households
of trade, interest received birth
decline in rates
real wages
Monetary
policy
relaxation
Structuralized
Continuation
domestic demand
of deflation
Fiscal shortage
and low
stimulus growth
Deterioration
in fiscal
position
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 275
Demographic Interpretation
Another interpretation of stagnation relates to demography. In 2010, a
small book entitled The True Origin of Deflation (Motani 2010) became
a bestseller. Motani’s contention is that the demographic change, in
particular, the absolute decrease in the working age population, which
(%)
6
cash
-2 earnings per
worker
(change from
-4 previous
year)
-6
-8
Fig. 6.48 GDP gap and changes of monthly cash earnings per worker from pre-
vious year. Source: Cabinet Office, Ministry of Health, Labor, and Welfare,
“Monthly Employment Survey”
276 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
6
CPI (excluding
4 fresh food)
(change
from
2 previous
year)
0 Monthly
cash
Jan-91
Jan-94
Jan-97
Jan-00
Jan-03
Jan-06
Jan-09
Jan-12
Jan-15
Jul-92
Jul-95
Jul-98
Jul-01
Jul-04
Jul-07
Jul-10
Jul-13
Jul-16
earnings
-2 (change from
previous
year [five-year
-4 moving
average])
-6
Fig. 6.49 Nominal wage and Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food)
(changes from previous year). Note: Nominal wage = total cash earning per
employee (in the establishments with five or more employees). Source: Statistics
Bureau of Japan, Ministry of Health, Labor, and Welfare, “Monthly labor survey”
18
Motani (2010, 140) wrote, “As the working age population continues to decline, the
domestic demand-type industries, which account for a large part of employment, constantly
suffer from excess supply and their business performance will never improve.” Examples of
demand stagnation in terms of quantity that Motani indicated include the following:
–– The number of new cars sold domestically hit a peak in 2000, decreasing thereafter.
–– The number of books and magazines sold domestically hit a peak in 1997.
–– The quantity of goods transported domestically (weight × distance) hit a peak in fiscal
year 2000.
–– The quantity of alcoholic beverages sold domestically started to decrease from fiscal year
2002.
–– The quantity of tap water used per one person hit a peak in 1997.
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 277
(%)
15 2.5
2
10
-10 -0.5
Fig. 6.50 Real GDP growth and population growth (Japan). Source: IMF, OECD
rate and the aging population] and to globalization ... are the fundamental
causes of low growth and deflation” (Shirakawa 2012b).19
We look next at Fig. 6.50. The GDP growth rate may look like this,
generally, following population developments in Japan. Does demography
determine our future?
However, such a pattern does not seem to be universal. A similar but
less clear pattern has been observed in France and the United States
(Figs. 6.51 and 6.52), but not in the United Kingdom or in Germany
(Figs. 6.53 and 6.54).
A fundamental rebuttal of Motani’s argument, or any other arguments
that relates demography to the two decade-long stagnation, is that demo-
graphic changes proceed only gradually and, therefore, would not be able
to produce such an abrupt change as shown by the nominal GDP
developments since 1990s in Fig. 6.55. Structural headwinds may be with
us, but demographic changes do not wholly explain the long stagnation
over two decades from the 1990s. Although it is an issue that warrants
thorough examination—how long- term and structural factors such as
demography were related to the long stagnation and the current condi-
19
Shirakawa (2012a) further states, “In the 1990s, low growth was mainly brought about
by the deleveraging associated with the unprecedented bursting of the bubble. In the 2000s
and thereafter, the major causes of low growth in Japan have been rapid population aging
and population decline.”
278 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
10 1.6
8 1.4
1.2
6 Real GDP
growth rate
1
4 5-year moving
average
0.8
growth rate
2
0.6 Population
growth rate
0 (RHS)
0.4
1952
1956
1960
1964
1968
1972
1976
1980
1984
1988
1992
1996
2000
2004
2008
2012
-2 0.2
-4 0
Fig. 6.51 Real GDP growth and population growth (France). Source: IMF, OECD
(%)
10 2
1.8
8
1.6
6 1.4
Growth rate
1.2
4 5-year moving
1 average
growth rate
2
0.8
Population
0.6 growth rate
0 (RHS)
1952
1956
1960
1964
1968
1972
1976
1980
1984
1988
1992
1996
2000
2004
2008
2012
0.4
-2
0.2
-4 0
Fig. 6.52 Real GDP growth and population growth (US). Source: IMF, OECD
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 279
(%)
8 0.8
6 0.7
Real
0.6 GDP
4
growth
0.5 5-year
2 moving
0.4 average
0 growth
0.3 rate
1952
1956
1960
1964
1968
1972
1976
1980
1984
1988
1992
1996
2000
2004
2008
2012
-2 Population
0.2 growth
-4 0.1
-6 0
Fig. 6.53 Real GDP growth and population growth (United Kingdom). Source:
IMF, OECD
(%)
15 1.2
1
10
0.8 Real GDP
growth
0.6 rate
5
5-year moving
0.4 average
growth
0 0.2 rate
1961
1964
1967
1970
1973
1976
1979
1982
1985
1988
1991
1994
1997
2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
Population
0 growth
-5 rate (RHS)
-0.2
-10 -0.4
Fig. 6.54 Real GDP growth and population growth (Germany). Source: IMF,
OECD
280 K. ARAMAKI
600.0 14000
12000 Nominal
500.0
GDP (base
10000 year = 1990)
400.0 Nominal
8000 GDP (base
300.0 year = 2000)
6000
Nominal
200.0 GDP (base
4000
year = 2011)
100.0 2000 Population
(RHS)
0.0 0
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
Fig. 6.55 Nominal GDP and population. Source: Ministry of Health, Labor,
and Welfare, “Vital Statistics Report”; Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
Bibliography
English References
IMF (2014) “Japan 2014 Article IV Consultation- Staff Report; and Press
Release,” July.
Kang, Joong Shik (2014) “Balance Sheet Repair and Corporate Investment in
Japan” IMF Working Paper WP/14/141, International Monetary Fund, Asian
and Pacific Department.
Katz, Richard (1998) Japan: The System that Soured: The Rise and Fall of the
Japanese Economic Miracle. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Shirai, Sayuri (2012) “Jinko Dotai no Henka ha Wagakuni no Makuro Keizai ni
Eikyo wo Ataete Irunoka?” (Have Demographic Changes Affected Japan’s
Macroeconomic Performance?) September 7.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012a) “Deleveraging and Growth: Is the Developed World
Following Japan’s Long and Winding Road?” Lecture at the London School of
Economics and Political Science, co-hosted by the Asia Research Center and
STICERD, LSE, January 10.
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 281
Japanese References
Aoshima, Yaichi, Akira Takeishi, and Michael A. Cusumano (2010) Meido in
Japan ha Owaru noka (Is Made in Japan to End?) Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Economic Planning Agency (1993) Heisei 5 nen Nenji Keizai Hokoku (1993
Annual Economic Report).
Bank of Japan (1994) “Heisei 5 nendo no Kinnyu oyobi Keizai no Doko” (Financial
and Economic Developments in FY 1993). In Chosa Geppo, BOJ, June.
Bank of Japan (1998) “Change of the Guideline for Money Market Operations,”
September 9, Bank of Japan.
Bank of Japan (2001) “Saikin no Ginko Kashidashi Shijo no Doko nituite” (Recent
Developments in Bank Credit Markets) October, Market Review 2001-J-10.
Bank of Japan (2003a) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment) April.
Bank of Japan (2003b) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment) October.
Bank of Japan (2004a) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment) April.
Bank of Japan (2004b) “Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka” (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment) October.
Bank of Japan (2005a) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment) April.
Bank of Japan (2005b) “Wagakuni Kigyo niyoru Yurishi Fusai no Asshuku to Rieki
Bunpai Saku” (Reduction of Interest-bearing Debt by Japanese Companies and
Profit Distribution Policy) May, Nichigin Review 2005-J-7.
Bank of Japan (2005c) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Price and Risk Assessment) October.
Bank of Japan (2009a) Kinnyu Keizai Geppo (Monthly Financial and Economic
Report) February.
Bank of Japan (2009b) “Kigyo Shueki no Kaizen to sono Nihon Keizai heno
Ganni” (Improvements in Corporate Profits and Its Implications to Japanese
Economy), September 20, Research and Statistics Department.
Bank of Japan (2012) “Nihon no Jinko Dotai to Chuchoki tekina Seichoryoku: Jijitsu
to Ronten no Seiri” (Japan’s Demography and Medium and Long-term Growth
Potential: Facts and Issues), August, Research and Statistics Department.
Cabinet Office (2014) “Senzai Seichoritsu ni tuite (Chuchoki, Makuroteki Kanten
karano Bunseki ①)” (On the potential growth rate (Analysis from mid- to long-
term and macro economic viewpoints [1]), February 14, Heisei 26 http://
www5.cao.go.jp/keizai-shimon/kaigi/special/future/0214/shiryou_02.pdf
(viewed December 11, 2017).
282 K. ARAMAKI
Cabinet Office (2005) Heisei 17 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku (Annual Report
on the Japanese Economy and Public Finance FY 2005).
Cabinet Office (2008) Heisei 20 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku (Annual Report
on the Japanese Economy and Public Finance FY 2008).
Cabinet Office (2010) Heisei 22 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku (Annual Report
on the Japanese Economy and Public Finance FY 2010).
Cabinet Office (2012) Heisei 24 nenban Kodomo Kosodate Hakusho (White Paper
on Children and Child-Rearing 2012).
Fukao, Kyoji (2012) Usinawareta 20 nen’ to Nihon Keizai – Kozoteki Yoin to Saisei
heno Gendoryoku no Kaimei (‘Lost 20 years’ and the Japanese economy -
Identifying structural factors and the momentum for its revival). Nihon Keizai
Shimbun Shuppan Sha.
Fukuda, Shin-ichi (2015) “Ushinawareta 20 nen wo Koete” (Beyond ‘Lost Two
Decades’). NTT Shuppan.
Itami, Takayuki (2006) Nichi Bei Kigyo no Rieki Ritsu Kakusa (Discrepancy in
Profitability between Japanese and US Companies). Yuhi Kaku.
Kato, Hisakazu (2001) Jinko Keizaigaku Nyumon (Introduction to Demographic
Economics). Nihon Keizai Hyoron Sha.
Kaufmann, Franz-Xaver (2011) Shukugen suru Shakai – Jinko Gensho to sono
Kiketsu (Shrinking Society – Population Decline and Its Consequences). Hara
Shobo.
Komine, Takao (2007) Jinko Gen Shoshika Shakai no Mirai (Future of the Society
with Population Shrinkage and the Declining Birth Rate). Akashi Shobo.
Komine, Takao (2010) Jinko Fuka Shakai (Society with Demographic Burden).
Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Koo, Richard (2007) ‘In’ to ‘Yo’ no Keizai Gaku (Economics of ‘The Sunny Side’
and ‘The Shadow Side’). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Koo, Richard (2008) Nihon Keizai wo Oou Futatsu no Nami (Two Waves Hanging
over the Japanese Economy). Tokuma Shoten.
Kumon, Takashi (2006) Jinko Defure ha Hajimatte iru (Demographic Deflation
Has Already Set in). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Matsutani, Akihiko (2004) ‘Jinko Gensho Keizai’ no Atarashii Koshiki (A New
Formula for ‘the Economy with a Shrinking Population’). Nihon Keizai
Shimbun Sha.
Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare (2012) Heisei 24 nenban Koreika Shakai
Hakusho (2012 White Paper on Ageing Society).
Motani, Kosuke (2010) Defure no Shotai –Keizai ha Jinko no nami de Ugoku (True
Origin of Deflation: The Economy Moves by the Demographic Waves),
Kadokawa One Tema 21.
Nukaga, Makoto (2005) “Juyo Shukusho no Kiki” (Crisis of Demand Shrinkage).
NTT Shuppan.
Obuchi, Hiroshi (1997) Shosika Jidai no Nihon Keizai (Japanese Economy in the
Era of Declining Birth Rate). Nihon Hoso Kyokai.
DEFLATION AND THE MECHANISM OF CORPORATE BEHAVIOR 283
Obuchi, Hiroshi and Hitoshi Morioka (1981) Keizai Jinko Gaku (Economic
Demography). Shin Hyoron.
Obuchi, Hiroshi and Hiroyuki Kanekiyo (2005) Shoshika no Shakai Keizaigaku
(Socioeconomics of the Declining Birth Rate). Hara Shobo.
Obuchi, Hiroshi and Hitoshi Morioka (2006) Jinko Gensho Jidai no Nihon Keizai
(Japanese Economy in the Era of the Shrinking Population). Hara Shobo.
Ogawa, Kazuo (2009) Baransu Shito no Kison to Jitsubutsu Keizai – 1990 nendai
ikono Nihon Keizai no Jissho Bunseki (Damages to the Balance Sheet and the
Real Economy – Empirical Analysis of the Japanese Economy since the 1990s).
In Furyo Saiken to Kinnyu Kiki, (Non-Performing Loans and the Financial
Crisis), edited by Kazuto Ikeo, (Cabinet Office “Baburu/defure kino Nihon
Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 4” (Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in the
Period of Bubble and Deflation 4)). Economic and Social Research Institute,
Cabinet Office.
Shimizudani, Satoshi (2005) Kitai to Fukakujitsu Sei no Keizai Gaku (Economics
of Expectation and Uncertainty). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2010a) “Nihon Keizai to Inobeshon” (Japan’s Economy and
Innovation) May 31.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2010b) “Tokushu Sei ka Ruiji Sei ka? –Kinnyu Seisaku
Kenkyu wo Meguru Nihon no Baburu Hokaigo no Keiken” (Uniqueness or
Similarity?, Japan’s Post-Bubble Experience in Monetary Policy Studies),
September 16, Bank Of Japan.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2011) “Kodo Seicho kara Antei Seicho he – Nihon no Keiken
to Sinkokoku Keizai heno Ganni” (The Transition from High Growth to Stable
Growth: Japan’s Experience and Implications for Emerging Economies) May 5.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012a) “Derebarejji to Keizai Seicho – Senshinkoku ha
Kakoni Nihon ga Ayunda ‘Nagaku Magari Kunetta Michi’ wo Tadotte
Ikunoka” (Deleveraging and Growth: Is the Developed World Following
Japan’s Long and Winding Road?), January 10.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012b) “Saikin no Kinnyu Josei to Kinnyu Seisaku Unnei”
(Recent Financial and Economic Developments and Monetary Policy
Management) June 4, Bank of Japan.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012c) “Jinko Dotai no Henka to Makuro Keizai Pafomansu :
Nihon no Keiken kara” (Demographic Changes and Macroeconomic Performance:
Japanese Experience) May 30.
Sugihara, Shigeru, and Satoshi Ota (2002) “Shisan Kakaku no Geraku to Kigyo no
Baransu Shito Chosei” (Decline in Asset prices and Balance Sheet Adjustments
of Corporations). In Defure no Jissho Bunseki, (Empirical Analysis of Deflation),
edited by Yutaka Harada and Kikuo Iwata, Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Takayama, Noriyuki, and Osamu Saito (2006) “Shoshika no Keizaigaku”
(Economics of the Declining Birth Rate). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
284 K. ARAMAKI
Tsutani, Noriko, and Yoshio Higuchi (2009) “Jinko Gensho to Nihon Keizai”
(Population Decline and the Japanese Economy). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Yashiro, Naohiro (2004) Shoshi Koreika no Keizaigaku (Economics of the
Declining Birth Rate and Aging). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi (2011) “Shoshi Koreika to Keizai Seicho” (The Declining
Birth Rate and Aging and Economic Growth). In Shoshi Koreika no moto deno
Keizai Katsuryoku, (Economic Vitality under the Declining Birth Rate and
Aging), edited by Masahisa Fujita and Hiroshi Yoshikawa, Nihon Hyoron Sha.
CHAPTER 7
Abenomics and Challenges
for the Japanese Economy
1 Abenomics
Start of Abenomics
On November 14, 2012, then Prime Minister (PM) Noda of the Democratic
Party (DP) declared in the Parliamentary discussion with Mr. Abe, presi-
dent of the LDP, that he would dissolve the House of Representatives in
two days, that is, on November 16. In the election on December 16, the
LDP had won a landslide victory, gaining 294 seats from the pre-election
level of 119, out of the total 480 seats, while the DP suffered a crushing
defeat of reducing its seats by three-fourths from 230 to 57.
On December 26, 2012, the second Abe administration started and
adopted its “Basic Policy” in the first cabinet meeting, in which it was
stated about the economy:
A strong economy is the source of Japan’s strength. Without its revival,
there is no restoration of fiscal soundness nor Japan’s future.
Through “three arrows” of bold monetary policy, flexible fiscal policy,
and growth strategy that promote private investment, we overcome pro-
longed deflation, and aim to increase employment.
This is the declaration of the start of Abenomics.
Thoughts behind “three Arrows” are explained as follows:1
1
Refer to materials on Abenomics published on the home page of the Prime Minister’s
office including the manuscript of the press conference by Prime Minister Abe on January
11, 2013 (https://www.kantei.go.jp/).
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 287
companies and people for the future and raise private investment
(growth strategy).
The BOJ introduced the price stability target of 2% in terms of the year-
on-year rate of change in the Consumer Price Index (CPI) (excluding
fresh food) and committed to achieve the target in the earliest possible
time, with a time horizon of about two years.3
2
Governor Kuroda is reported to have said in his inaugural speech to BOJ staff that the
BOJ is the only central bank in the world that does not achieve its mission to realize price
stability. Governor Kuroda is also reported to have said in his first meeting with BOJ execu-
tive staff, “First, you have to believe that you can do it.”
3
The BOJ under the former Governor Shirakawa had already introduced a price stability
target of 2% in January 2013. The difference is that the QQE under Governor Kuroda set a
time limit for its realization.
288 K. ARAMAKI
he Continuation of the QQE
T
The bank will continue with the QQE, as long as it is necessary to achieve
the price stability target of 2% and maintain that target in a stable manner.
Strengthening of the QQE
The QQE has been strengthened as follows:
On October 31, 2014, the BOJ announced an expansion of the QQE,
which included an increase of the targeted annual increase in base money
from the previous amount of 60–70 trillion to 80 trillion yen.
4
The BOJ adopted a three-tier system: (1) an interest rate of +0.1% is applied to the aver-
age balance of the current account (less required reserves) during 2015, as before; (2) an
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 289
interest rate of 0% is applied to the sum of the amount of reserves required and the outstand-
ing amount of certain credit from the BOJ; and (3) a negative interest rate of −0.1% is
applied to the outstanding balance in excess of the outstanding balance on (1) and (2) com-
bined. The BOJ estimated that, as of the start of the new system, (1) would be about 210
trillion yen, (2) would be about 40 trillion yen, and if the outstanding balance of the current
account increased to 260 trillion yen in February, then the negative interest rate of −0.1%
would be applied to 10 trillion yen.
5
At the start of the QQE, the BOJ stated in the “Outlook for Economic Activity and
Prices” (April 26, 2013) that the 2% price stability target would be reached toward the latter
half of the projection period (FY 2013–FY2015). Its outlook for the timing of the achieve-
ment of the target had been postponed six times before the wording itself was deleted in
April 2018. In the monetary policy statement released on September 21, 2016, which intro-
duced the yield curve control, objectives were stated as achieving the price stability target of
2% at the earliest possible time, with no mention of the specific timing of the achievement.
The only occasion where the time limit for the achievement of 2% target was mentioned in
the policy statement was when the original QQE was introduced on April 4, 2013.
290 K. ARAMAKI
vis-à-vis the previous year was 2.5% and 3.5% for fiscal years 2013 and
2014, respectively, but it has been contained to a level less than 1% for
subsequent years. By contrast, during the period of less than five years,
economic stimulus packages were compiled four times. Outlines of the
packages are described here.6
On January 11, 2013, the government decided on “the Emergency
Economic Measures for the Revival of Japan’s Economy,” with the central
government expenditure amounting to 10.3 trillion yen and the expected
impact on real GDP at about 2%. The focus is placed on the quickness of
effects and demand creating impacts such as public work, including recov-
ery from the Great Earthquake.
On December 5, 2013, the government decided on “The Economic
Measures for Realization of Virtuous Cycles,” with the central govern-
ment expenditure amounting to 5.5 trillion yen and the expected impact
on real GDP at around 1%.
On December 27, 2014, the government adopted “the Immediate
Economic Measures for Extending Virtuous Cycles to Local Economies,”
with additional central government expenditure amounting to 3.5 trillion
yen and expected contribution to real GDP growth at about 0.7%.
On August 2, 2016, the government adopted “Economic Measures for
Realizing Investment for the Future,” with additional central government
expenditure of 13.5 trillion yen and expected short-term contribution to
real GDP growth at about 1.3%.
6
On the settlement basis, which includes supplementary budgets, after the size increased
by 3.2% from 97.1 trillion yen in fiscal 2012 to 100.0 trillion yen in fiscal 2013, it declined
somewhat. It was 97.5 trillion yen in fiscal 2016, slightly greater by 0.5% from fiscal 2012.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 291
the size of primary balance7 deficit (in GDP) of the central and local gov-
ernments by fiscal 2015, as compared with fiscal 2010, to make the primary
balance in surplus by fiscal 2020, and to aim at reducing steadily the size of
outstanding debt (in GDP) thereafter.” The primary balance deficit of cen-
tral and local governments (in GDP) declined to −3.0%, achieving the tar-
get of halving the deficits from the level of fiscal 2010 (−6.6%).
Furthermore, Japan included the aforementioned fiscal consolidation
goals in the “St. Petersburg Action Plan,” adopted at the G20 summit
meeting held in St. Petersburg, Russia, in September 2013.
On October 1, 2013, the government decided to raise the consumption tax
rate from current 5% to 8% from April 1, 2014, as scheduled, which was the first
increase of the rate in last 17 years. At the same time, the government decided
to compile an economic package (“The Economic Measures for Realization of
Virtuous Cycles”) to cope with the risk of economic downturn caused by a
reactionary fall in demand after the last minute surge before the rate increase.
On April 1, 2014, the consumption tax rate was increased from 5% to
8%. Then, the economy recorded negative growth in the second and third
quarters consecutively, due to factors including reactionary demand fall
after the last minute surge.
In November 2014, Prime Minister Abe announced that the consump-
tion tax rate hike from 8% to 10% scheduled for October 2015 would be
postponed by 18 months to April 2017, and that he would dissolve the
lower house to ask for the people’s judgment on Abenomics.
In “Basic Policy on Economic and Fiscal Management and Reform
2015” adopted by the Cabinet on June 30, 2015, previous goals were
maintained that the government is to achieve surplus in the primary balance
in fiscal 2020, and to this end, reduce the size of the primary balance deficit
and that the government is to steadily reduce the level of outstanding debt
(in GDP) in the medium and long term.
However, on June 1, 2016, Prime Minister Abe announced another
postponement of the planned increase in consumption tax rate from 8% to
10% by 2 years and a half from April 1, 2017, to October 1, 2019.
7
Primary balance is the balance between, on the one hand, revenues arising from taxes and
other means of revenue, excluding assumption of debts through, for example, issuing gov-
ernment bonds, and; on the other hand, expenditures excluding interest and principal repay-
ments for the debts such as government bonds that were issued in the past. Primary balance
is a criterion to measure whether expenditures necessary to implement policies for the year
are financed by taxes and other means of revenue, excluding debt assumption. We should
note that, even if primary balance is in balance, the outstanding balance of government debt
will increase by the amount of interest payable to the debts assumed in the past.
292 K. ARAMAKI
2013
June The government decided on the “Japan Revitalization Strategy—
Japan is Back” and for “A New Decade of Revival,” after the 20 years of
stagnation; the strategy set as its goal to aim at achieving around 3% nomi-
nal and 2% real GDP growth, on average, over the coming 10 years (there-
after, the growth strategy is revised in June of each year up to 2016).8
September “The Trilateral Forum for Realization of Virtuous Cycles
among the Government, Companies, and Employees” was established, so
as to form a common understanding on such issues as wage increases and
to pass through the increase in cost of inputs onto the prices paid to sub-
contractors through participation by relevant ministers and representatives
from business and labor.
8
The growth strategy, revised in June 2014, included the following reforms: ① Aiming to
reduce the effective corporate tax rate to a level below 30% (the effective corporate tax rate was
reduced to a level below 30% beginning April 2016); ② Revising the basic asset allocation
policy of the Government Pension Investment Fund (GPIF), the world largest pension fund
(the basic asset allocation policy was revised on October 2014, as described in the text, and the
share of risk assets has been increased); ③ Strengthening corporate governance (as described in
the text, the amendment to the Company Act placed into force on May 1, 2015, held account-
able certain companies, including listed companies, if they did not hire directors of their
boards from the outside); ④ Other reforms including deregulation in vital areas such as agri-
culture, healthcare, energy, and the introduction of national strategic zone, where further
deregulation will be applied in such areas as medical care, employment, education, redevelop-
ment of cities, agriculture, and utilization of historic buildings.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 293
2013
June Japan revitalization strategy—Japan is back and a new decade of revival: aim
of 2% GDP growth over coming 10 years.
September “Trilateral forum for realization of virtuous cycles among the government,
companies, and employees” formed.
2014
February The Financial Services Agency formulated a stewardship code, under which
institutional investors are required, on a “comply or explain” basis, for
example, to have clear guidelines on such issues as execution of the voting
rights they have and publication of their voting decisions.
June The Company Act was amended (implemented in May 2015) to make certain
companies, including listed companies, accountable for non-hiring of directors
on their board from the outside, on a “comply or explain” basis.
October The basic asset allocation policy of GPIF (the world largest pension fund) was
changed as below:
Domestic bond 60%→35%
Domestic equity 12%→25%
Foreign bond 11%→15%
Foreign equity 12%→25%
2015
June The Tokyo Stock Exchange formulated and put into force a corporate
governance code by revising listing rules, under which listed companies are
required to hire more than one independent director on their board on a
“comply or explain” basis.
September Prime Minister Abe proposed “Three new arrows,” composed of “Robust
economy (nominal GDP to be 600 trillion yen in 2020),” “Childcare
supports (desirable birth rate of 1.8 targeted),” and “Social care that provides
reassurance (no one forced to leave their job for nursing care of elderlies),”
and also set a policy goal to maintain population of 100 million even 50 years
later.
October Basic agreement reached for the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)
A forum between government and the private sector for investment for the
future was established (meetings were held for five times from October 2015
to April 2016 with participation by the Prime Minister, relevant ministers,
chairman of Keidanren (Japan Business Federation), and others to discuss
challenges to address in order for the expansion of private investment)
November Outline of comprehensive TPP-related policy measures adopted
December Outline of tax reform approved by cabinet (effective corporate tax rate to be
reduced to a level below 30% (29.27%) from fiscal 2016)
294 K. ARAMAKI
2016
June Plan for dynamic engagement of all citizens adopted, incorporating
work-style reform (a principle of “equal pay for equal work,” correcting long
working hours, promotion of employment of the aged) and provision of
favorable environments for child care and nursing
September The implementation meeting for work-style reform established to discuss an
implementation plan for work-style reform, with participation by Prime
Minister, relevant ministers, representatives from business and labor, and
experts
2017
March The implementation meeting for work-style reform adopted an
implementation plan for work-style reform (incorporating guidelines for
“equal pay for equal work” prepared by the government, and the
introduction of a regulation with a penalty for violation to impose an upper
limit on overtime work)
July A framework agreement reached for Japan–European Union economic
partnership agreement
November Basic agreement reached for TPP 119
9
In addition to these measures, the administration has been continuing its efforts to
reform and strengthen the economy through such actions as below:
Adoption of an enforcement plan of regulation reform (June 2014, June 2015, June 2016,
and June 2017)
Adoption of an enforcement plan for the strengthening of industrial competitiveness
(February 2013 and February 2016)
Adoption of five commitments for the encouragement of inward foreign direct investment
(March 2015)
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 295
started to depreciate sharply from the end of 2012 and fell by 20.6% from
79.91 yen to the dollar on November 14, 2012, to 100.63 yen at the end
of May 2013. However, subsequent developments were not one-sided or
dramatic as in the initial period, but mixed, consisting of positive develop-
ments and stagnation.
While it is a very rough grouping, we may be able to classify develop-
ments in stock and foreign exchange markets under the Abenomics into
five periods: ① dramatic change, ② deceleration, ③ re-acceleration, ④
adverse developments, and ⑤ stabilization.
To explain Fig. 7.1, making use of Table 7.1, in about half a year from
November 2012 when dissolution of the House was declared to May
2013, the most dramatic changes occurred; the yen rate (monthly aver-
age) depreciated by 19.2%, and the stock price index (end of month) rose
by 45.8%. In the following year and a half, while depreciation of the yen
and stock price increase continued, the pace significantly decelerated and
became somewhat stagnant. After the BOJ introduced the QQE expan-
sion measures at the end of October 2014, the yen rate depreciated fur-
(yen) (yen)
140 QQE 25,000
QQE strengthened Yield curve control (2016.9.21)
(2013.4.4) (2014.10.31)
120
20,000
100
Supplementary 15,000
80
measure (2015.12.28)
60 Negative interest
rate (2016.1.29) 10,000
40
Yen = dollar exchange rate (monthly
average) 5,000
20 Nikkei225 (end of month[RHS])
0 0
May-12
May-13
May-14
May-15
May-16
May-17
Sep-12
Sep-13
Sep-14
Sep-15
Sep-16
Sep-17
Jan-12
Jan-13
Jan-14
Jan-15
Jan-16
Jan-17
Fig. 7.1 Developments in the stock and foreign exchange market: Five subperi-
ods under Abenomics. Source: Bank of Japan, Yahoo Finance. https://stocks.
finance.yahoo.co.jp/stocks/history/?code=998407.O DL accessed on November
18, 2017
296 K. ARAMAKI
Table 7.1 Five periods in relation to developments in stock price and the yen
rate under Abenomics
Periods Events Changes in foreign Changes in
exchange rate stock price
Note: Yen/dollar rate is the monthly average of the rate at 5 p.m. in the Tokyo market, and the stock price
is end-month Nikkei 225
Source: BOJ, Yahoo Finance
ther to around 120 yen to the dollar. The stock price, which had been on a
rising trend from around the summer of that year, continued to rise further.
However, from end-2015, together with a recurrence of the sharp fall in
crude oil prices, the yen rate substantially appreciated close to 100 yen to
the dollar and the stock price also fell. Subsequently, after the BOJ changed
its policy from the base money targeting to the yield curve control, based
on the comprehensive assessment of the QQE, the yen depreciated and the
stock price rose, partly helped by the US stock price surge and dollar appre-
ciation after the victory of Mr. Trump in the US presidential election.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 297
(billion yen)
20000
15000
-5000
-10000
Fig. 7.2 Trading amounts by investor type in Tokyo, 1st section. Source: Japan
Exchange Group, “Trading amounts by investor type in Tokyo Stock Exchange,
1st section”
298 K. ARAMAKI
Fig. 7.3 Accumulated change of Nikkei 225 (October 31, 2012 = 100). Source:
Fukuda (2015)
tended that the dramatic stock market boom under Abenomics happened
only in time zones when foreign investors were active and concluded that
foreign investors’ responses to the new regime played a leading role in
improving the market sentiments.
Figure 7.4 shows, as in the previous figure, accumulated yen–dollar
exchange rate changes for Japan daytime (9:00–17:00) and Japan night-
time (I = 17:00–9:00, II = 17:00–7:00) from October 31, 2018 (= 0).10
In the same way as the stock price, yen depreciation took place in the
Japan nighttime when foreign investors were active.11
10
Depreciation of the yen rate is indicated by a vertical upward movement.
11
Japan nighttime II excludes Japan’s morning hours when the Sydney market starts trad-
ing from the definition of Japan nighttime. While, under this alternative nighttime definition
(from 5 p.m. in Tokyo to 7 a.m. in Tokyo in the following business day), the yen’s deprecia-
tion in nighttime was less dramatic, the basic feature is maintained.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 299
(yen/dollar)
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
2013/9/6
2014/5/7
2014/6/3
2013/8/12
2013/10/3
2014/1/21
2014/2/17
2014/3/14
2014/4/10
2014/6/30
2014/7/25
2014/8/21
2014/9/17
2012/10/31
2012/11/28
2012/12/26
2013/01/29
2013/02/26
2013/03/26
2013/04/22
2013/05/22
2013/06/18
2013/07/16
2013/10/31
2013/11/27
2013/12/24
2014/10/15
-5.0
-10.0
Fig. 7.4 Accumulated change of yen = dollar exchange rate (October 31,
2012 = 0). Source: Fukuda (2015)
(yen) (%)
140 6
120 4
100 2
80 0
60 -2
Yen = dollar exchange rate
40 -4
Real GDP growth rate
20 -6
0 -8
2012Q1
2012Q2
2012Q3
2012Q4
2013Q1
2013Q2
2013Q4
2014.Q1
2014Q2
2014Q3
2014Q4
2015Q1
2015Q2
2015Q3
2015Q4
2016Q1
2016Q2
2016Q3
2016Q4
2017Q1
2017Q2
2017Q3
2013Q3
Fig. 7.5 Yen = dollar exchange rate and real GDP growth rate. Source: Bank of
Japan, Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
300 K. ARAMAKI
rate (period average) and the development in real GDP growth rate (quar-
ter-to-quarter rate of change, annualized). While the yen–dollar exchange
rate substantially changed, there has not been a significant change in real
GDP growth rate.
Figure 7.6 shows developments in stock prices and the real GDP. Here,
again, the rise in stock prices has not been accompanied by any significant
changes in the real GDP growth rate.
(yen) (%)
25000 6
4
20000
2
15000 0
10000 -2
Nikkei 225
-4
Real GDP growth rate
5000
-6
0 -8
2012Q1
2012Q2
2012Q3
2012Q4
2013Q1
2013Q2
2013Q3
2013Q4
2014.Q1
2014Q2
2014Q3
2014Q4
2015Q1
2015Q2
2015Q3
2015Q4
2016Q1
2016Q2
2016Q3
2016Q4
2017Q1
2017Q2
2017Q3
Fig. 7.6 Nikkei 225 and real GDP growth rate. Source: Yahoo Finance, Cabinet
Office GDP statistics
12
As the outcome of the two-period comparison significantly changes depending on how
we define the preceding period, we need to cautiously assess analysis in this part. In the text,
we excluded the year of 2009 that includes the period of sharp contraction of the economy
immediately after the Lehman shock (−18.2% annualized quarter-to-quarter rate of change
in 2009Q1) and subsequent substantial recovery (8.7% annualized quarter-to-quarter rate of
change in 2009Q3) and accordingly, defined the preceding period as starting from 2010Q1.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 301
(%)
2
Net export
1.5
Government expenditure
1 Inventory
Housing investment
0
10Q1-12Q4 13Q1-18Q1 Consumption
-0.5
Real GDP growth rate
(quarter-to-quarter,
-1 annualized)
Fig. 7.7 Real growth rate and growth contribution by demand components:
Preceding period (2010Q1–2012Q4) and Abenomics period (2013Q1–2018Q1).
Note: The figures show a simple average of quarter-to-quarter growth rates (annual-
ized) and the average growth contribution by each demand component, and the line
shows real GDP growth rate. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics, Bank of Japan
The average real GDP growth rate stayed the same from 1.3% in the
preceding period to 1.3% in the Abenomics period. If we define the pre-
ceding period as covering 2009Q2 or 2009Q3 to 2012Q4, the average
growth rate in the Abenomics period was marginally lower than that in the
preceding period. Therefore, it may be duly said that there has not been a
significant change in GDP growth under Abenomics.
By contrast, there has been a significant change in the composition of
growth contribution by demand components. Growth contribution of net
exports increased by 0.8 point from −0.5 point to 0.3 point. Government
expenditure nearly doubled its growth contribution from 0.1 point (more
precisely, 0.14 point) to 0.3 point (more precisely, 0.25 point), but con-
sumption reduced its growth contribution to a level smaller than half of
the level in the preceding period from 0.7 point to 0.2 point. There has
not been a big change in growth contribution of private investment.
What is characteristic of the Abenomics period is that, as the impedi-
ments to exports, arising from sharp appreciation of the yen in the preced-
302 K. ARAMAKI
ing period, were removed, net export recovered its growth contribution
and government expenditure supported growth, while private investment
did not increase significantly and consumption substantially reduced its
growth contribution.
Investment
As we saw in the preceding subsection, private investment has not shown
a large increase. Is it that the very eased monetary policy under Abenomics
has not been effective? Figure 7.8 shows developments in the interest rate
on Japanese government bonds by maturity. The interest rate on the gov-
ernment bonds has declined since Abenomics started across the maturi-
ties. Bold monetary policy has been effective in this respect.13
Both the interest rate on government bonds and the lending rate were
on a declining trend from 2006 and from 2008, respectively. As Figs. 7.8
(%)
2.5
1.5 13-Nov-12
2-Apr-13
10-Oct-14
1
17-Dec-15
28-Jan-16
0.5 20-Sep-16
22-Nov-17
0
1 year
2 year
3 year
4 year
5 year
6 year
7 year
8 year
9 year
10 year
15 year
20 year
25 year
30 year
40 year
-0.5
13
Fig. 7.8 shows interest rates across maturity one day before the day when major policy
action was taken mainly in the field of monetary policy.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 303
and 7.9 show, the rates continued to decline further from 2013, and bank
lending continued to increase after bottoming out in 2010.
The amount of real private investment dropped with the Lehman shock,
hit the bottom of 65.4 trillion yen in 2009Q4, then started to increase and
became 85.2 trillion yen in 2017Q4, exceeding the peak that had been
reached before the Lehman shock. However, the pace of increase has not
shown a big difference between before and after Abenomics started.
Furthermore, as we saw previously, private investment has not increased
much relative to the amount of cash flow (see Fig. 6.20 in Chap. 6).
While companies are in possession of a large amount of cash and deposits,
as we see in the next subsection (Fig. 7.21), private investment by compa-
nies has not shown a large increase and its growth contribution has not
significantly increased either (Figs. 7.7 and 7.10).
4.00
500
3.50
3.00 Outstanding
400 balance of
2.50 bank lending
Interest rate
300 2.00
on
government
1.50
bond (RHS)
200
1.00 Lending rate
0.50
100
0.00
0 -0.50
Fig. 7.9 Interest rate on government bonds, lending rate, and outstanding bal-
ance of bank lending. Source: Bank of Japan; IMF, IFS
304 K. ARAMAKI
(trillion yen)
90.00
80.00
70.00
60.00
50.00
40.00
30.00
20.00
10.00
0.00
Fig. 7.10 Real private investment. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
Consumption
Consumption has reduced its growth contribution, as we have seen.
Developments in the amount of real private consumption since 2007, that
is, the peak year before the Lehman shock, shows that, after it dropped
with the Lehman shock, it began a recovery. Then, due to factors including
a reactionary fall, after a last minute surge in demand preceding the increase
in consumption tax rate in April 2014, private consumption significantly
declined. Thereafter, it started to recover, but the pace of recovery is slow.
This is what the figure may indicate. However, if we look at the develop-
ments in real consumption more closely, we can see that the amount of real
consumption became almost flat from 2013Q2, two quarters before
2014Q1, when the last minute surge in demand before the consumption tax
increase was observed (Fig. 7.11). Behind this stagnation of consumption
lies a fact that, as we saw in the preceding chapter, consumer prices started
to increase from mid-2013 and the pace of the decline in real wages acceler-
ated (for example, real wage index [2015 = 100] declined by 2.9% in half a
year from 105.2 in June 2013 to 102.2 in December 2013) (Fig. 6.28).
Exports
Exports were flat after recovering from the fall following the Lehman
shock, and even under Abenomics, the recovery was relatively slow and
stagnant on a real-term basis, despite sharp depreciation of the yen–dollar
exchange rate. From around the latter half of 2016, exports started to
show a mild increase. By contrast, imports have been stagnant (Fig. 7.12).
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 305
(trillion yen)
310.00
305.00
300.00
295.00
290.00
285.00
280.00
275.00
270.00
265.00
260.00
2011/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2012/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2013/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2014/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2015/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2016/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2017/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2007/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2008/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2009/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
2010/ 1- 3.
7- 9.
Fig. 7.11 Real private consumption. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
(trillion yen)
100.00
80.00
60.00
0.00
2000/ 1- 3.
2001/ 1- 3.
2002/ 1- 3.
2003/ 1- 3.
2004/ 1- 3.
2005/ 1- 3.
2006/ 1- 3.
2007/ 1- 3.
2008/ 1- 3.
2009/ 1- 3.
2010/ 1- 3.
2011/ 1- 3.
2012/ 1- 3.
2013/ 1- 3.
2014/ 1- 3.
2015/ 1- 3.
2016/ 1- 3.
2017/ 1- 3.
-20.00
-40.00
Fig. 7.12 Real exports, real imports, and real net exports. Source: Cabinet
Office, GDP statistics
306 K. ARAMAKI
Government Expenditure
Real government expenditure mostly declined in the 2000s. However,
due to the fiscal stimulus adopted after the Lehman shock, it turned to
follow a rising trend. Thereafter, real government expenditure continued
rising, even after the real GDP became 508.4 trillion yen in 2013Q2,
exceeding the peak of 507.3 trillion yen in 2008Q1 before the Lehman
shock. Injection of public demand seems to have become a normal aspect
of the economy (Fig. 7.13).
evelopments in Prices
D
In January 2013, the government and the BOJ issued a joint statement, in
which the BOJ stated that it set a price stability target of 2% and aimed to
achieve the target at the earliest possible time. Under the QQE in April
2013, the BOJ committed to achieve 2% price stability target at the earliest
time, with a time horizon of about two years (inflation targeting with time
limit). The price stability target of 2% was defined in terms of the year-on-
year rate of change in the CPI (excluding fresh food). While this indicator
tended to become negative from 2012 to the beginning of 2013, it started
to show a clear positive trend from May 2013. However, it then fell into a
negative territory again from August 2015. It became positive from
January 2017. While the pace of increase is constantly positive, it stays at
0.8% year-on-year, that is, less than 1%, as of July 2018 (Fig. 7.14).
Meantime, while the BOJ stated in the initial period after the introduction
(trillion yen)
135
130
125
120
115
110
105
2009/ 1- 3.
4- 6.
2000/ 1- 3.
10-12.
2012/ 1- 3.
10-12.
2015/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
10-12.
2003/ 1- 3.
10-12.
2006/ 1- 3.
10-12.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
7- 9.
4- 6.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
Fig. 7.13 Real government expenditure. Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 307
(%)
4
0
01/01/2012
01/05/2012
01/09/2012
01/01/2013
01/05/2013
01/09/2013
01/01/2014
01/05/2014
01/09/2014
01/01/2015
01/05/2015
01/09/2015
01/01/2016
01/05/2016
01/09/2016
01/01/2017
01/05/2017
01/09/2017
-1
-2
Fig. 7.14 Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food) (year-on-year change).
Source: Statistics Bureau, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications
of the QQE that the price stability target of 2% would likely be reached
toward the latter half of the three-year period from FY 2013 to FY 2015,
that their projection covered. However, the projected timing of achieving
the price target has been postponed six times. In the Monetary Policy
Meeting held on April 27, 2018, the Bank of Japan deleted the wording
on the timing when the 2% target is reached from “The outlook of eco-
nomic activities and price (April 2018).”
Under the initial QQE, it was considered an important policy transmis-
sion channel to raise inflation expectation through measures, including
expansion of base money, reducing the real interest rate (nominal interest
rate – expected rate of inflation), and thereby, stimulating real economy.14
The expected inflation rate (average) held by private sector economists
substantially rose from 2012 to 2013, became flat in mid-2014, started to
decline from the end of 2015, and recently, has stayed around 1%. Expected
inflation rate held by companies, which the Tankan survey of the BOJ
began to collect in April 2014, also started to decline from mid-2014 and
became flat at around 1% since the latter half of 2016 (Figs. 7.15 and 7.16).
14
See Iwata (2013).
308 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
1.6
1.4
1.2
0.2
0
2014.06
2014.12
2015.06
2015.12
2016.06
2016.12
2017.06
2017.12
2009.06
2009.12
2010.06
2010.12
2011.06
2011.12
2012.06
2012.12
2013.06
2013.12
Fig. 7.15 Expected inflation rate held by private sector economists (average).
Source: Tabulated drawing on data provided on website of the Japan Center for
Economic Research
(%)
1.8
1.6
1.4
1.2
In 1 year
1
In 3 years
0.8
In 5 years
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
Mar-16
Jun-16
Sep-16
Dec-16
Mar-17
Jun-17
Sep-17
Dec-17
Mar-14
Jun-14
Sep-14
Dec-14
Mar-15
Jun-15
Sep-15
Dec-15
Fig. 7.16 Expected inflation rate held by companies (all industries). Source:
Bank of Japan, “Tankan survey”
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 309
1.5 120
Consumer price index
(excluding fresh food)
100 year-on-year change
1
(excluding effects of
80 consumption tax
0.5 increase)
60 Yen–dollar exchange
rate (RHS)
0
40 Crude oil price (in
01/01/2012
01/07/2012
01/01/2013
01/07/2013
01/01/2014
01/07/2014
01/01/2015
01/07/2015
01/01/2016
01/07/2016
01/01/2017
01/07/2017
-1 0
Fig. 7.17 Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food) (year-on-year change,
excluding effects of consumption tax increase), yen–dollar rate, and crude oil
price. Source: Cabinet Office, Bank of Japan, IMF
310 K. ARAMAKI
Figure 7.18 shows developments in the rate of change in the CPI, which
excludes, in addition to fresh food, oil products, and other special factors
(also excluding effects of increase in consumption tax rate). Different from
the previous figure, the rate of change in the CPI (excluding fresh food, oil
products, and other special factors) continued to be positive even after the
crude oil price fell sharply from autumn 2014. When the appreciation of
the yen rate proceeded in 2016, the CPI turned steeply downward. As the
CPI excludes oil products, effects of the sharp fall of crude oil price do not
seem to be reflected in the CPI. We can see that developments in the CPI
are significantly influenced by the changes in yen–dollar rate.
On the whole, the CPI (excluding fresh food) seems to have been
strongly influenced by the yen rate and crude oil price, and the increase in
the CPI (excluding fresh food) for more than two years from mid-2013
does not seem to be the outcome of tightening of demand-supply condi-
tions under economic recovery. From around the end of 2016, the rate of
increase in the CPI (excluding fresh food) is almost constantly positive.
60 (RHS)
-0.5 Crude oil price (in dollars
40 per barrel) (RHS)
-1
20
-1.5 0
Fig. 7.18 Consumer Price Index (excluding fresh food, oil products and other
special factors), yen–dollar exchange rate, and crude oil price. Source: Cabinet
Office, Bank of Japan, IMF
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 311
Figures 7.19 and 7.20 indicate that combined current profits of all the
profit-making companies have been increasing as the yen rate depreciated
and the stock prices rose.
Figure 7.21 shows developments in current profits, investment, and
cash and deposit holding. Current profits have been recording a historic
high. Under these circumstances, while investment has increased, cash and
deposits that companies hold has increased more sharply. Although com-
panies are making large amounts of profits, they have not increased invest-
ment significantly, but have substantially increased cash and deposit
holdings.
120
20
100
Yen–dollar
15 rate (period
80
average)
60 10 Current
profits (RHS)
40
5
20
0 0
Fig. 7.19 Yen–dollar exchange rate, and current profits. Source: Ministry of
Finance, “Statistics of financial statement of companies,” Bank of Japan
312 K. ARAMAKI
20000 20
5000 5
0 0
Fig. 7.20 Nikkei 225 and current profits. Source: Ministry of Finance, “Statistics
of financial statement of companies,” Yahoo Finance
70
200 Current
60
profits
50 150 Private
40 investment
(excluding
30 100
software)
20 Cash and
50 deposits
10 (RHS)
0 0
FY1960
FY1964
FY1968
FY1972
FY1976
FY1980
FY1984
FY1988
FY1992
FY1996
FY2000
FY2004
FY2008
FY2012
FY2016
Fig. 7.21 Current profits, investment, cash, and deposits. Source: Ministry of
Finance, “Statistics of financial statement of companies”
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 313
(%)
76.0
74.0
72.0 GDP
statistics
70.0 with base
year = 2000
68.0
GDP
66.0 statistics
with base
64.0 year = 2011
62.0
60.0
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
Fig. 7.22 Labor income share. Note: Labor income share = compensation for
employee/national income (factor price base). Source: Cabinet Office, GDP statistics
in the last 25 years since August 1993. However, as Fig. 7.23 shows, the
improvement started in 2010, and the improvement in the Abenomics
period is the continuation of this trend.
Despite such a tightening in the labor markets, the rate of increase in
wages per worker has been low, as we have seen before. This partly reflects
the fact that the tightening of labor market is not so strong for regular
workers who have by far higher wages, compared with non-regular
workers.
The effective ratio of job offers to job seekers indicates that improve-
ments in labor market conditions are more substantial for part-timers, par-
ticularly, those part-time workers who are not permanent, as compared
with regular workers. While the effective ratio of job offers to job seekers
for regular workers has been improving, the ratio is around 1, recording
1.02 in April 2018 (it was 1.70 for part-timers at that time) (Fig. 7.24).
Reflecting difference in the degree of tightening of labor market condi-
tions, the rate of increase in hourly wage of non-regular workers is higher
than that for regular workers in recent years (Fig. 7.25). The labor market
tightening has been influencing non-regular workers more favorably than
regular workers.
314 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
6.0
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
Apr-94
Nov-95
Jun-97
Jan-99
Aug-00
Mar-02
Oct-03
May-05
Dec-06
Jul-08
Feb-10
Sep-11
Apr-13
Nov-14
Jun-16
Jan-80
Aug-81
Mar-83
Oct-84
May-86
Dec-87
Jul-89
Feb-91
Sep-92
Fig. 7.23 Unemployment rate. Source: Statistics Bureau of Japan, “Labor force
survey”
1.80
1.60
1.40 Permanent
1.20 (regular
worker)
1.00 Permanent
0.80 (part-
timer)
0.60 Part-
0.40 timer
0.20
0.00
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
Fig. 7.24 Ratio of jobs offers to job seekers. Source: Ministry of Health, Labor,
and Welfare, “Employment stabilization operation statistics”
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 315
(%)
3
2.5
2
1.5
Regular
1 worker
0.5 Non-
regular
0
worker
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
-0.5
-1
-1.5
-2
Fig. 7.25 Hourly wages for regular and non-regular workers (year-on-year
change). Note: Hourly wage = contractual wage (i.e., excluding overtime payment
and bonuses) paid in June of each surveyed year, divided by the total contractual
hours worked in June of that year. Source: Ministry of Health, Labor, and Welfare,
“Basic wage structure survey”
Assessment of the Abenomics
Let us make an assessment of Abenomics, drawing on the examination we
have made so far.
(%)
7.0
6.0
Expected
5.0 growth rate
held by
4.0 companies
for coming 3
3.0 years
-1.0
-2.0
Fig. 7.26 Real GDP growth rate and expected growth rate held by companies.
Source: Cabinet Office, “Survey on company behavior”
318 K. ARAMAKI
fulfilling way. Furthermore, due to the need to make up for lack of self-
sustained high growth, the economy cannot lower its dependence on
government expenditure. High dependence on government expenditure,
together with wage restraint, may raise concerns for the future for house-
holds, thus strengthening the mechanism of low growth through its
dampening effects on consumption. The Japanese economy does not
seem to have exited from such a vicious circle yet. Stimulating demand
through the promotion of lending with low interest rates is a policy that
focuses on the cost side of investment activity. It has become clear by the
implementation of bold monetary easing under Abenomics that unless a
sales increase is expected, the effects of cost lowering on investment activ-
ity are limited.
What seems to have started to impose significant effects on growth
expectation of domestic economy, particularly, from around 2010, is
population decline. The total fertility rate, which dropped lower than the
population replacement level of 2.07 in 1974, has been at the 1% level for
more than 40 years. However, it is only recently that population decline
was recognized as a serious problem by the general public. It is probably
since the 2010 publication by Hiroshi Motani of “Defure no Shotai:
Keizai ha jinko no nami de ugoku” (True origin of deflation—The econ-
omy moves by the demographic waves).15,16 To be sure, as Fig. 7.27
shows, the magnitude of expected population decline in Japan is very
15
The Bank of Japan has conducted very extensive research on the effects of the popula-
tion on the economy since the publication of Motani’s book. The executive members of the
BOJ, including then Governor Shirakawa, started to frequently mention effects of popula-
tion decline in their public communication.
16
Motani’s (2010) book is important, as it directed the attention of the public to the issue
of population decline, particularly to its impacts on the demand side of the economy.
Although there are many books on population decline, there are only a handful of books
focusing on the demand side, to the author’s knowledge, examples of which include Nukaga,
Makoto (2005) “Juyo Shukusho no Kiki-Jinko Gensho Shaki no Keizaigaku” (Demand
shrinkage crisis—Economics of population decline) NTT Publication; and Adachi, Makiko
“Shoshi Koreika ga Kakei Bumon ni Ataeru Eikyo” (Impacts of declining birth rate and
aging population on household sector) (Mizuho Soken Ronshu (2004 I), pp. 1–35. Mizuho
Sogo Kenkyujo). Although there were very few reactions from researchers and scholars to
Motani’s arguments, very limited exceptions include Yoshikawa, Hiroshi (2011) “Shoshi
Koreika to Keizai Seicho” (The declining birth rate and aging population and economic
growth), RIETI Discussion Paper Series 11-P-006 January 2011; and Yoshikawa, Hiroshi
(2016) “Jinko to Nihon Keizai” (Population and the Japanese economy), Chu Ko Shinsho.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 319
(thousand)
140,000
120,000
100,000
0
1920
1940
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
2020
2030
2040
2050
Fig. 7.27 Population of Japan and its future estimates. Source: National Institute 2060
of Population and Social Security Research, “Population statistics [2017 revision]”
17
“Population statistics data (2017, revised version)” (Medium fertility assumption
[medium mortality assumption]) by the National Institute of Population and Social Security
Research indicates that Japan’s population is projected to decline by 39.018 million (30.7%)
in 50 years from 127.095 million in 2015 to 88.077 million in 2065. This corresponds to a
decline of 0.780 million per year. It means that one prefectural capital city, such as Niigata
(0.81 million population), Hamamatsu (0.8 million population), or Kumamoto (0.74 mil-
lion population) is projected to disappear each year.
320 K. ARAMAKI
by companies that had been deeply embedded during the prolonged low-
growth performance. It is difficult to judge whether the low-growth expec-
tation of companies at this time is due to an irrational defensive mindset, or
due to rational consideration of factors such as population decline and rela-
tively high profitability of overseas operation. Still, companies seem to be at
least partly constrained by the negative legacy of the 15-year-long low-
growth performance that the corporate sector had brought about.
If the low-growth expectation is due to the defensive mindset, it should
be effective, although seemingly paradoxical, to realize a higher growth
performance than in the past through promotion of economic activities in
such areas where activities were not constrained by low growth in the past
(for example, exports and alteration of foreign demand into domestic
demand through tourism, including medical tourism, promotion of
inward foreign direct investment, and utilization of special economic
zones). Furthermore, it is necessary to encourage more positive behaviors
by companies through, for example, governance reform to promote par-
ticipation of outside people in their management. At the same time, how-
ever, it is necessary to cope with substantive issues for the future. In
particular, it is critically important to mitigate the population decline,
which poses the biggest restraint on growth expectation for the future.
Most importantly to that end is introducing such measures that will enable
women to have and raise children without having their careers interrupted
and negatively affected.
In relation to impacts of population decline on growth, there is a view
that contends that, while Japan’s economy has been behind other advanced
countries in terms of GDP growth, it has not been so in terms of the rate of
growth of GDP per capita or the rate of growth of GDP per working-age
population.18 Figure 7.28 shows the rate of GDP growth of five advanced
countries, including Japan, in every five years. Japan’s growth performance
has been low as compared with other countries since the 1990s.
Figure 7.29 shows the rate of growth of GDP per capita for every five
years. The figure indicates Japan’s performance stagnated in the 1990s,
but it has been neither on the high side nor on the very low side since the
2000s.
For example, see Masaaki Shirakawa (2012a) “Deleveraging and growth: Is the devel-
18
oped world following Japan’s long and winding road?”, a lecture by the then governor of the
London School of Economics and Political Science on January 10, 2012.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 321
(%)
30
25
20
Japan
15
US
10 Germany
France
5 UK
Fig. 7.28 Five-year real GDP growth rate. Source: United Nations, IMF
(%)
30
25
20
Japan
15
US
Germany
10
France
5 UK
-5
Fig. 7.29 Five-year growth rate of real GDP per capita. Source: United Nations,
IMF
322 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
25
20
15 Japan
US
10 Germany
France
5 UK
-5
Fig. 7.30 Five-year growth rate of real GDP per working-age population
(15–64). Source: United Nations, IMF
19
For example, while the rate of increase in the working-age population from 2010 to
2015 is −5.2%, the number of actual employment increased over the same five-year period
by 1.6%, indicating that an increase in the labor force participation ratio has been making up
for the decline in the working-age population.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 323
costs for economic infrastructure that accrue regardless of the size of pop-
ulation. Therefore, it is difficult to maintain the stable management of a
society if the economy grows only in terms of per capita GDP or per
working-age population GDP and not in terms of total GDP. So, it is nec-
essary to aim for a certain growth of total GDP while attempting to trans-
form the society into a compact one, which can economize on overhead
common costs in line with population decline.
However, the working-age population is expected to decline further,
and it is not possible to indefinitely raise the labor force participation rate.
So, given future demographic change that is expected, it is difficult to
expect the growth rate of total GDP to substantially increase in the future,
without technological progress or other factors significantly raising the
growth rate of GDP per working-age population beyond the level experi-
enced in recent years.
Figure 7.31 shows the GDP gap ([actual GDP − potential GDP]/
potential GDP), which was frequently negative after the collapse of the
bubble, narrowed in the Abenomics period, and has been positive recently.
Demand shortages that the Japanese economy has long suffered from the
collapse of the bubble may have been finally resolved.
(%)
6.0
4.0
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
10-12.
10-12.
10-12.
10-12.
10-12.
10-12.
1980/ 1- 3.
1987/ 1- 3.
1994/ 1- 3.
2001/ 1- 3.
2008/ 1- 3.
2015/ 1- 3.
1991-2012
-2.0 average
2013-17Q2
-4.0 average
-6.0
-8.0
(%)
6.0
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
10-12.
1984/ 1- 3.
10-12.
1989/ 1- 3.
10-12.
1994/ 1- 3.
10-12.
1999/ 1- 3.
10-12.
2014/ 1- 3.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
10-12.
2004/ 1- 3.
10-12.
2009/ 1- 3.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
4- 6.
7- 9.
-1.0
Fig. 7.32 Potential growth rate. Source: Tabulated using data provided from the
Cabinet Office website. (http://www5.cao.go.jp/keizai3/getsurei/getsurei-
index.html)
20
The “2017 White paper on small and medium enterprise in Japan” (pp. 12) notes the
average age of equipment and machinery as of 2016 was 1.5 times older for large companies
and about 2.0 times older for small and medium companies, as compared with 1990, indicat-
ing increased aging of equipment and machinery. Prolonged investment restraint has
imposed negative impacts on competitiveness and growth potential of companies.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 325
(%)
2.5
Net export
2
Government
expenditure
1.5
Inventory
1
Housing investment
0.5
Private investment in
plant and equipment
0
Consumption
-0.5
Real GDP growth rate
-1
each of the five subperiods, covering about 24 years since 1994.21 Growth
contribution of consumption has consistently declined from 0.8 point in
1994–1997 to 0.3 point in the Abenomics period. In the background is the
decline in real wages, as we saw previously. There has not been a big change
in the corporate attitudes toward restraining labor costs. Although labor
market conditions has been tightening, it is tighter in the market for non-
regular workers. Duality in the labor market between regular and non-reg-
ular workers, and the existence of differences in wages and other working
conditions between them, provide companies with an opportunity to con-
tain labor costs through increased use of non-regular workers. In other
words, duality in the labor market offers an effective tool for international
competition through cost reduction. However, there is a limit for high-
wage countries in how far they can compete internationally through cost-
cutting. Restraint on wages contains consumption, and contributes to low
growth, creating a vicious cycle of low growth. Also, duality of the labor
market without rational basis seems to have produced external diseconomies
to the society, by, for example, contributing to the falling marriage rate,
21
Twenty-four years are divided into five subperiods, that is, four subperiods that broadly
correspond to subdivision of the period of stagnation described in Chap. 3 plus the
Abenomics period.
326 K. ARAMAKI
22
According to The Japan Institute for Labor Policy and Training, “Jakunensha no shugyo
jokyo kyaria shokugyo noryoku kaihatu no genjo ② heisei 24 nen ban ‘shugyou kozo kihon
chosa’ yori (‘Current status of employment, career and work capacity development of young
people ② based on ‘basic survey of employment structure 2012’),” JILP document series
No. 144 September 2014, the share of those having a spouse at ages 30 to 34 is 57.8% for
regular workers, and 23.3% for non-regular workers, such as part-timers. The share at the
ages 35 to 39 is 68.6% for regular workers and 28.1% for non-regular workers. In short, the
share of those having a spouse for non-regular workers is lower than half of that for regular
workers.
23
The Japanese government is currently pressing forward with “work style reform.” This
reform effort has positive elements such as regulation of long work hours and realization of
the principle of “equal pay for equal work.” However, how to achieve productivity increase
that this reform aims at by labor market reform is an issue that needs cautious examination
and thought through formulation of appropriate framework based on scientific and objective
evidence. The most important premise when considering labor market reform is the fact that
workers and companies do not stand on an even ground. Workers enter, and work under, an
employment contract in an overwhelmingly disadvantageous (weak) position. As an indi-
vidual, a worker is normally not in a position to choose the work style. In this sense, what is
needed is not the “work style reform” but a reform of “humane resource development and
utilization” under which the way companies or our society in general develop and utilize our
human resources is examined and reformed where necessary and appropriate.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 327
40 40 Construction
bond
20 20
Government
0 0 bond/GDP
(RHS)
FY1965
FY1968
FY1971
FY1974
FY1977
FY1980
FY1983
FY1986
FY1989
FY1992
FY1995
FY1998
FY2001
FY2004
FY2007
FY2010
FY2013
FY2016
24
FILP (Fiscal Investment and Loan Program) represents investment and lending operations
by the government. The FILP bond is a type of government bond that the government issues
as a low-interest fundraising tool based on sovereign credit for the operation of the program.
328 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
45.0
40.0
0.0
Apr-09
Sep-10
Feb-12
Jul-13
Dec-14
May-16
Dec-97
May-99
Oct-00
Mar-02
Aug-03
Jan-05
Jun-06
Nov-07
Fig. 7.35 Share in outstanding government bonds and FILP bonds held by
major holders. Note: FILP bond is a government bond issued by the government
on account of, and registered with, the FILP account of the government. As a
financial product, it is the same as an ordinary government bond (see Footnote 24).
Source: Tabulated data provided on the website of the Bank of Japan.
with the BOJ indicates that the financial position of banks will significantly
depend on the financial soundness not of the government but of the
BOJ. Therefore, in the process of exiting from the current condition of
extremely eased monetary policy, it will become important for the stability
of the financial system to maintain soundness of the BOJ. In other words,
in order for the continued dependence of economic growth on govern-
ment expenditure, coupled with eased monetary policy, not to raise risk to
the financial system, it is becoming increasingly important to accomplish
as soon as possible a private sector-led economic growth structure.
Under the declining strength of consumption, it is sometimes argued
that we need to further strengthen the social security system because con-
sumption has been contained by concern about the future among young
people under the wage restraint and replacement of regular by non-regular
workers. However, judging from the projections of population decline and
further aging in the years to come, it is inevitable for social security expen-
diture, which currently accounts for one-third of expenditures in the gov-
ernment budget, to further increase. Therefore, what is necessary for
maintaining fiscal capability to respond to such policy needs as national
defense and security or maintenance of minimum infrastructure is to raise
taxes and to reduce social security expenditure. In order to alleviate con-
cerns for the future held by young people, it is important to raise the share
of expenditures targeted at young people in such expenditures as social
security. However, if such a shift in focus is accompanied by further deterio-
ration of fiscal position, then it could have negative impacts on the concerns
for the future of young people. Figure 7.36 shows, for each age group of
respondents, the share, among all respondents with concern for the future,
of those who listed deterioration in fiscal, employment, or economic condi-
tions as a factor causing their concern. The share of respondents who listed
any of these three factors is larger for the younger age groups.
Considering the need to alleviate concern for the future, while pressing
forward with restraint on total social security expenditure and also with a
shift of focus toward the younger generation and strengthening education
and job training, it is important to implement such reforms of the social
system that would not raise the fiscal burden. In other words, it is neces-
sary not only for individuals but also for companies and local communities
to move to a society that is based on a principle of “self-help and self-reli-
ance.” We need individuals who do not depend on public support, compa-
nies that do not depend on economic stimulus or subsidies from the
government, and local communities that do not depend on fiscal support
330 K. ARAMAKI
(%)
60
Deterioration in
fiscal position of
50 central and local
government
40
Deterioration in
30 employment
conditions
20 Stagnation and
decline of
10 Japanese
economy
0
(age)
Fig. 7.36 Share of respondents for each age group who listed deterioration in fiscal,
employment, or economic conditions as the cause of their concern for the future.
Note: The figure shows the share of respondents for each age group who listed dete-
rioration in fiscal conditions, employment conditions, or economic stagnation as a
cause of their concern for the future. Respondents are those who had previously
answered that they had concern for the future. Source: Cabinet Office, “Opinion
survey on future image of Japan related to population, economy, and society,” 2012
from the central government such as local distribution tax and subsidies. It
will be inevitable for policies under Abenomics and subsequent policy
developments to shift to the ones that encourage self-reliance of economic
agents and promote their self-help.
formance in the past, but at the same time, we cannot deny that it has a
rational basis such as expectation of quantitative shrinkage of the domestic
markets due to population decline.
In order to exit from this vicious cycle, companies need an expectation
of sales increase, and households need an expectation of stable increase in
income. As we have already touched on the immediately needed measures
such as transformation of foreign demand to domestic demand and gover-
nance reform, we will briefly list medium- and long-term measures in con-
cluding this book.
First, in order to achieve sales increase, while it may appear to be a
roundabout way, it seems most important to reform the way companies
utilize human resources. Presently, an option is open to companies to con-
duct a price-cut competition through reduction of labor costs by long
work hours by regular workers and a shift to non-regular workers.
However, effectiveness of such price-cut competition is limited for
advanced countries that have relatively higher wages. Also, competition
through labor cost reduction by shifting to non-regular workers has
brought about social costs, including significantly lower marriage rates
among non-regular workers. Therefore, it is necessary to encourage com-
panies to move away from a competition through labor cost-cutting
toward a competition through sales increase, by appropriately regulating
long work hours and correcting irrationally differentiated treatments
between regular and non-regular workers. Together with removing irra-
tionally differentiated treatments between regular and non-regular work-
ers, it seems necessary to separate stability of employment and stability of
wages. No matter whether the worker is regular or non-regular, it is
important to provide stable employment where possible, based on a prin-
ciple of “equal pay for equal work.”25 At the same time, it is necessary to
link wages to performance of the company and also introduce competition
among workers for higher wages. If employment security for regular work-
ers is combined with wage security, it is difficult to expect productivity
increase. A system is in order where both regular and non-regular workers
compete for higher productivity on a level paying field. Although cautious
25
With a view to reducing duality between regular and non-regular workers in the Japanese
labor market, Aoyagi and Ganelli (2013) proposed to introduce a Single Open Ended
Contract (SOEC) for all new hires, in which employment protection, including severance
pay, will increase with tenure. The SOEC would imply lower job security compared to cur-
rent regular employment, but higher job security compared to current non-regular employ-
ment. In this regard, the paper refers to the Danish flexicurity model, which is composed of
332 K. ARAMAKI
(1) flexibility in the labor market (including reduction of protection of regular workers),
combined with (2) social security protection through unemployment benefits, and (3) an
active labor market policy. The main idea of flexicurity is that of protecting workers rather
than jobs. However, the authors pointed out that the most difficult part for Japan is the high
fiscal cost of the flexicurity model.
26
As stated before, how to enhance labor productivity under any given framework is an
issue that needs cautious examination based on scientific evidence.
27
The mandatory age-limit retirement system, while a logical consequence of lifetime long
employment coupled with a seniority-based wage system, is a system that can bring about enor-
mous waste of human resources that is beyond imagination under a productivity-based employ-
ment and wage system. When we hear anecdotally about retired highly skilled workers being
employed by foreign competitor companies and contributing to the strengthening of their
competitiveness, we feel deeply how insensitive our society has been to the social losses that
arise from a system of strong job security coupled with a seniority-based wage system. Intrinsic
to current age-based system are, one, objectives to encourage employees to stay longer with the
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 333
company, and, two, difficulty to introduce and operate a wage system that is based on company
performance and assessment of productivity of each employee. As a result, companies continue
to pay wages that may be higher than the productivity of the employees up to the retirement
age and dismiss those employees who can produce more than their wages because they have
reached the retirement age, together with those who cannot. We need to wholly review the
current employment system including the mandatory age-limit retirement system.
334 K. ARAMAKI
28
This is easily seen by looking at the gigantic and stately building of the Tokyo metropoli-
tan government and the lavish, high-rise local government offices of central wards in Tokyo.
The problem with current local government finance is exemplified by the fact that local
assemblies of these local governments do not examine the balance between such expendi-
tures and tax burden borne by local residents, and do not consider tax cuts.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 335
Supplement
Chronology of Abenomics
2012
November 14 Then Prime Minister Noda of the Democratic Party (DP) declared in
the Parliamentary discussion with Mr. Abe, president of LDP that he
would dissolve the House of Representatives in two days, that is, on
November 16.
November 15 Mr. Abe publicly stated that, once the LDP returned to the power, the
government and the BOJ would set an inflation target of 2~3%, and
implement limitless monetary easing.
December 16 In the election on December 16, the LDP had a landslide victory,
gaining 294 seats from the pre-election level of 119, out of the total 480
seats, while the DP suffered a crushing defeat, reducing its seats by
three-fourths from 230 to 57.
December 18 Governor Shirakawa of BOJ visited President Abe in the LDP
headquarters.
December 26 The second Abe administration started and adopted its “Basic Policy” in
the first cabinet meeting, which listed four focused areas (economy,
foreign and security policy, education, and people’s living) in addition to
the recovery from the Great Earthquake and nuclear plant accident, and,
in the area of the economy, stated:
A strong economy is the source of Japan’s strength. Without its revival,
there is no restoration of fiscal soundness nor of Japan’s future.
Through the “three arrows” of bold monetary policy, flexible fiscal
policy, and growth strategy that promote private investment, we
overcome prolonged deflation, and aim to increase employment.
2013
January 11 The government decided on “the Emergency Economic Measures for
the Revival of Japan’s Economy,” with the central government
expenditure amounting to 10.3 trillion yen and the expected impact on
real GDP of about 2%,
January 22 The Cabinet Office, Ministry of Finance, and the Bank of Japan issued a
joint statement on policy coordination between the government and the
BOJ to get out of deflation and achieve sustainable economic growth, in
which the BOJ committed to the establishment of a price stability target
of 2%, in terms of year-on-year change of the CPI and aimed to achieve
this target as soon as possible.
On the same day, the BOJ made public the changes in monetary policy.
March 20 Mr. Haruhiko Kuroda, former president of ADB, became governor of
the BOJ.
336 K. ARAMAKI
April 4 The BOJ introduced the QQE in its first Monetary Policy Committee
meeting after the change of the governor (from Shirakawa to Kuroda)
and deputy governors (new deputies included Professor Iwata of
Gakushuin University, a long-time outspoken critic of the BOJ).
June 14 The government decided on the “Basic Principles for Economic and
Fiscal Management and Reform,” which presents the directions of
economic and fiscal policy management and the basic strategy for
achieving Japan’s revival, including the promotion of the “three arrows”
in an integrated manner.
June 14 The government decided on the “Japan Revitalization Strategy,” which
is composed of three action plans, that is, plans for the revitalization of
Japanese industry, strategic market creation, and a strategy of global
outreach.
August 8 The government approved the medium-term fiscal program, which
includes the following three goals:
To halve the primary balance deficit of central and local governments
combined from the level in FY 2010 (6.6% of GDP) by FY2015;
To change the combined primary balance of central and local
governments into surplus by FY 2020; and
To reduce steadily the debt-to-GDP ratio thereafter.
September 1 The government decided to set up a forum between relevant ministers
and representatives from both companies and employees, so that they
could exchange views and form common understanding necessary to
cope with challenges for achieving virtuous economic cycles.
October 1 The government decided to raise the consumption tax rate from the
current 5% to 8% from April 1, 2014, which is the first increase of the
rate in the last 17 years.
At the same time, the government decided to compile an economic
package to cope with the risk of economic downturn caused by reactionary
fall in demand after the last minute surge before the rate increase.
December 5 The government decided on “The Economic Measures for Realization of
Virtuous Cycles,” with the central government expenditure amounting
to 5.5 trillion yen and the expected impact on real GDP around 1%.
December 20 The forum of ministers and representatives from companies and
employees issued a statement that, under the policy efforts for the
virtuous cycles by the government, companies and employees will, based
on performances of respective companies, let an increase in profits lead
to an increase in wages.
2014
April 1 Consumption tax rate was raised for the first time in 17 years from 5% to 8%.
April 1 Effective corporate tax rate was reduced by 2.4%.
June 24 The revised “Japan Revitalization Strategy” was released (aimed at
reducing effective corporate tax rate to below 30% in a few years,
enhancing corporate governance, enhancing women’s participation,
enabling flexible working practices, attracting foreign talent, reforming
agricultural policy, etc.).
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 337
August 13 Real GDP was estimated to have declined from the previous quarter at
an annualized rate of 6.8% in Q2 2014.
October 31 The BOJ announced an expansion of QQE (increase of the targeted
annual increase in base money from the previous 60–70 to 80 trillion
yen, etc.).
November 17 Real GDP was estimated to have declined from the previous quarter at
an annualized rate of 1.6% in Q3 2014.
November 18 Prime Minister Abe announced that the increase in consumption tax
rate, from 8% to 10% scheduled for October 2015, would be postponed
by 18 months to April 2017, and that he would dissolve the lower house
to ask for the people’s judgment on Abenomics.
November 21 The Lower House dissolved (election on December 14, 2014).
December 14 In the general election on December 14, 2014, the LDP won 291 seats,
just 2 seat less than before the election, and the coalition government
with the Komeito, which obtained 35 seats, maintained the
overwhelming majority of 326, which accounts for more than two-thirds
of the total 475 seats.
December 24 The third Abe cabinet was formed.
December 27 The government decided on “The economic package for the spread of
virtuous cycles to local areas” with additional budget expenditure of 3.5
trillion yen and expected contribution to real GDP growth of about
0.7%.
2015
September 24 Prime Minister Abe declared the Abenomics shift to the second stage
and announced new three arrows (targets), that is, strong economy
(GDP of 600 trillion yen targeted), support for child-rearing (desirable
birth rate of 1.8 targeted), and sound social security (no job departure
due to nursing care of elderlies), and a target of maintaining a
population of 100 million half a century into the future.
December 18 The BOJ adopted supplementary measures for the QQE, including some
lengthening of average remaining maturities of JGB purchased.
2016
January 29 The BOJ decided to introduce a negative interest rate of −0.1% to be
applied to part of the outstanding balance of financial institutions’
current account at BOJ (implemented from February 16) and declared
that it would cut the interest rate further if necessary.
June 1 Prime Minister Abe announced that the increase in consumption tax rate
scheduled for April 1, 2017 would be postponed again by 2 years and a
half to October 1, 2019.
August 2 The government adopted “Economic measures for realizing investment
for the future” with additional central government expenditure of 13.5
trillion yen and expected contribution to real GDP growth of about 1.3%.
338 K. ARAMAKI
September 21 The BOJ released the results of the comprehensive assessment of the
developments under “Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing
(QQE)” and “QQE with a Negative Interest Rate,” and a new policy
called “yield curve control” was announced, in which the policy target
was changed from the previous increase in base money to the control of
both short-term and long-term interest rates (as for the short-term
interest rate, a negative interest rate of −0.1% is applied to a part of the
outstanding balance held by financial institutions in the current account
with the BOJ, and as for the long-term interest rate, the BOJ will
purchase JGBs so that 10-year JGB yields will remain more or less at the
current level around 0%).
October 22 In the election of the Lower House, which was called by Prime Minister
Abe on the grounds that he had changed his policy as to how to use
additional revenue arising from the consumption tax increase, the LDP
had a sweeping victory gaining 284 seats, which is well over half of the
total 465 seats.
Bibliography
English References
Aoyagi, Chie, and Giovanni Ganelli (2013) “The Path to Higher Growth: Does
Revamping Japan’s Dual Labor Market Matter?” IMF Working Paper No. 13/202,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Fukuda, Shin-ichi (2015) “Abenomics: Why was it so successful in changing mar-
ket expectations?” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies vol 37,
1–20.
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2014) “Japan 2014 Article IV Consultation—
Staff Report; and Press Release.” July, IMF Country Report 14/236, IMF,
Washington, DC.
Iwata, Kikuo (2013) “Quantitative and qualitative monetary easing and its trans-
mission mechanism: Logic behind the first arrow.” August 28, 2013, Bank of
Japan.
Kuroda, Haruhiko (2013) “Public policy study and monetary policy manage-
ment.” December 7, 2013, Bank of Japan.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012a) “Deleveraging and Growth: Is the Developed World
Following Japan’s Long and Winding Road?” A Lecture by the Then Governor
at the London School of Economics and Political Science on January 10.
Small and Medium Enterprise Agency (2017) 2017 White paper on small and
medium enterprise in Japan.
ABENOMICS AND CHALLENGES FOR THE JAPANESE ECONOMY 339
Japanese References
Adachi, Makiko (2014) “Shoshi Koreika ga Kakei Bumon ni Ataeru Eikyo (Impacts
of Declining Birth Rate and Aging Population on Household Sector)” (Mizuho
Soken Ronshu (2004 I), pp. 1–35. Mizuho Sogo Kenkyujo.
Bank of Japan (1997) “Kozo Chosei ka no Setsubi Toshi Kaifuku ni tsuite” (On
the Recovery of Plant and Equipment Investment under Structural Adjustments)
February 26, Research and Statistics Department.
Bank of Japan (1999) “90 nendai niokeru Hi-seizogyo no Shueki Teimei no
Haikeinitsite” (On the Background of Profit Stagnation of Non-manufacturing
Industry in the 1990s) February 2, Research and Statistics Department.
Bank of Japan (2006) “Kinnen no Seizogyo no Setsubi Toshi Zoka nitsuite” (On
the Recent Increase in Plant and Equipment Investment of Manufacturing
Industry) Bank of Japan Review 2006-J-17.
Dai-Ichi Seimei Keizai Kenkyu Jo (2003) Shisan Defure de Yomitoku Nihon Keizai
(Understanding Japanese Economy Through Asset Price Deflation) 2003.
Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Hayakawa, Hideo (2016) Kinnyu Seisaku no ‘Gokai’ – ‘Sodai na Jikken’ no Seika
(“Misunderstanding” of monetary policy—Outcome of a “spectacular experi-
ment”). Keio Gijuku Daigaku Shuppan Kai.
Japan Institute for Labor Policy and Training (Rodo Seisaku Kenkyu Kenshu
Kiko) (2014) “Jakunensha no shugyo jokyo, kyaria, shokugyo noryoku kaihatu
no genjo ② heisei 24 nen ban ‘shugyo kozo kihon chosa’ yori” (Current status
of employment, career and work capacity development of young people ②
based on ‘basic survey of employment structure’ 2012), JILP Document Series
No. 144, September 2014.
Kaizuka, Keimei (2006) Keizai Kakusa no Kenkyu (A Study of Economic
Inequality). Chuo Keizai Sha.
Nakao, Takehiko (2008) “Amerika no Keizai Seisaku : Tsuyosa ha Jizoku Dekiru
noka” (Economic Policy in the United States: Can the Strength be Sustained?).
Nukaga, Makoto (2005) “Juyo Shukusho no Kiki-Jinko Gensho Shaki no
Keizaigaku- (Demand shrinkage crisis-Economics of population decline)” NTT
Publication.
Ogawa, Kazuo (2009) “Baransu Shito no Kison to Jitsubutsu Keizai – 1990 nen-
dai ikono Nihon Keizai no Jissho Bunseki” (Damages to the Balance Sheet and
the Real Economy – Empirical Analysis of the Japanese Economy since the
1990s). In Furyo Saiken to Kinnyu Kiki (Non-performing loans and the finan-
cial crisis), edited by Kazuto Ikeo, Cabinet Office, “Baburu/defure kino Nihon
Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 4” (Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in the
Period of the Bubble and Deflation 4), Economic and Social Research Institute,
Cabinet Office.
340 K. ARAMAKI
Oshio, Takashi (2005) Jinko Gensho Jidai no Shakai Hosho Kaikaku (Social Security
System Reform in the Era of Declining Population). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Ota, Kiyoshi (2005) “Furita no Zoka to Rodo Shotoku Kakusa no Kakudai”
(Increase in “Freeter” and Expanding Inequality of Earned Income). ESRI
Discussion Paper Series No.140, May.
Otake Fumio (2005) Nihon no Fubyodo (Inequality in Japan). Nihon Keizai
Shimbun Sha.
Sato, Toshiki (2000) Fubyodo Shakai Nippon : Sayonara So Churyu (Japan An
Unequal Society: Goodbye All Middle Class Society). Chuko Shinsho.
Shimizudani, Satoshi (2005) Kitai to Fukakujitu Sei no Keizai Gaku (Economics
of Expectation and Uncertainty). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Sugihara, Shigeru, and Satoshi Ota (2002) “Shisan Kakaku no Geraku to Kigyo no
Baransu Shito Chosei” (Decline in Asset Prices and Balance Sheet Adjustments
of Corporations). In Defure no Jissho Bunseki (Empirical Analysis of Deflation).,
edited by Yutaka Harada and Kikuo Iwata, Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Tachibanaki, Toshiaki (1998) Nihon no Keizai Kakusa (Economic Inequality in
Japan). Iwanami Shinsho.
Tachibanaki, Toshiaki (2006) Kakusa Shakai: Nani ga Mondai Nanoka (Unequal
Society: What is the Problem?). Iwanami Shinsho.
Yamada, Masahiro (2004) Kibo Kakusa Shakai: ‘Makegumi’ no Zetsubo Kan ga
Nihon wo Hikisaku (Society of Unequal Hope: Despair of “the Failed” will
divide Japan). Chikuma Shobo.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi (2011) “Shoshi Koreika to Keizai Seicho” (The declining
birth rate and aging population and economic growth) RIETI Discussion
Paper Series 11-P-006 January.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi (2016) “Jinko to Nihon Keizai” (Population and the Japanese
economy). Chu Ko Shinsho.
Yugami, Kazufumi (2003) “Nihon no Shotoku Kakusa wo Do Miruka” (How to
Assess Income Disparity in Japan?) JIL Rodo Seisaku Report 2003.3.
Bibliography
Reference in English
Ahearne, Alan, J. Gagnon, J. Haltmaier, and S. Kamin (2002) “Preventing deflation:
Lessons from Japan’s experience in the 1990s.” International Finance Discussion
Paper Number 729, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Washington, DC.
Aoyagi, Chie, and Giovanni Ganelli (2013) “The Path to Higher Growth: Does
Revamping Japan’s Dual Labor Market Matter?” IMF Working Paper No.
13/202, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
BOJ (Bank of Japan) (1998) “Change of the Guideline for Money Market
Operations,” September 9, Bank of Japan.
Bernanke, Ben (2000) “Japanese monetary policy: A case of self-induced paraly-
sis?” In Japan’s Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to U.S. Experience, edited by
Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam. S. Posen. 149–66. Washington, DC: Institute for
International Economy.
Cabinet Office, Government of Japan (2001) Annual Report on the Japanese
Economy and Public Finance 2000—No Gains Without Reform, December.
Flath, David (2005) The Japanese Economy, 2nd edn., Chapter 8. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Fujiki, Hiroshi, Kunio Okina, and Shigenori Shiratsuka (2001) “Monetary Policy
under Zero Interest Rate: Viewpoints of Central Bank Economists” Monetary
and Economic Studies/February 2001, Bank of Japan.
Fukuda, Shin-ichi (2015) “Abenomics: Why Was It So Successful in Changing
Market Expectations?” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies
37: 1–20.
Hayashi, Fumio, and Edward C. Prescott (2002) “The 1990s in Japan: A Lost
Decade.” Review of Economic Dynamics 5 (1): 206–35.
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (1995) “The Nordic Banking Crises: Pitfalls
in Financial Liberalization?” IMF Working Paper WP/95/61, IMF, Washington,
DC.
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2003) World Economic Outlook, April , IMF,
Washington, DC.
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2014) “Japan 2014 Article IV Consultation—
Staff Report and Press Release,” July 2014.
Iwata, Kikuo (2013) “Quantitative and qualitative monetary easing and its trans-
mission mechanism: Logic behind the first arrow,” August 28, Bank of Japan.
Jinushi, Toshiki, Yoshihiro Kuroki, and Ryuzo Miyao (2000) “Monetary policy in
Japan since the late 1980s: Delayed policy actions and some explanations.” In
Japan’s Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to U.S. Experience, edited by Mikitani
Ryoichi, and A. S. Posen, 115–48. Washington, DC: Institute for International
Economy.
Kang, Joong Shik (2014) “Balance Sheet Repair and Corporate Investment in
Japan.” IMF Working Paper WP/14/141, International Monetary Fund,
Asian and Pacific Department.
Katz, Richard (1998) Japan: The System that Soured: The Rise and Fall of the
Japanese Economic Miracle. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.
Kosai, Yutaka (1986) The Era of High-Speed Growth – Notes on the Postwar
Japanese Economy. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.
Krugman, Paul (1998) “It’s baaack: Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity
Trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 137–205.
Krugman, Paul (2000) “Thinking about the liquidity trap” Journal of the Japanese
and International Economies 14: 221–37(2000).
Kuroda, Haruhiko (2013) “Public policy study and monetary policy manage-
ment,” December 7, Bank of Japan.
Mori, Naruki, Shiratsuka Shigenori, and Hiroo Taguchi (2001) “Policy Responses
to the Post-bubble Adjustments in Japan: A Tentative Review.” Monetary and
Economic Studies 19 (S1): 53–112, Institute for Monetary and Economic
Studies, Bank of Japan.
Motonishi, Taizo, and Hiroshi Yoshikawa (1999) “Causes of the Long Stagnation
of Japan During the 1990s: Financial or Real?” NBER Working Paper No.
7351, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Nakao, Takehiko (2002) “Japan’s experience with fiscal policy in the 1990s in the
aftermath of the bubble economy.” Presentation at the 4th Banca d’Italia
Workshops on Public Finances, “The Impact of Fiscal Policy,” March 21–23.
Nakaso, Hiroshi (2001) “The financial crisis in Japan during the 1990s: How the
Bank of Japan responded and the lessons learnt.” BIS Papers No. 6, BIS, Basel.
Nakaso, Hiroshi (2014) “What the lost decades left for the future.” Keynote
speech, 2014 International Conference of the International Association of
Deposit Insurers, Asia–Pacific Regional Committee, Bank of Japan, April 23.
BIBLIOGRAPHY 343
Nishizaki, Kenji, Toshitake Sekine, and Yuichi Ueno (2012) “Chronic deflation in
Japan.” Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, No. 12-E-6, Bank of Japan.
Okina, Kunio and Nobuyuki Oda (2000) “Additional Monetary Easing Options
under the Non-negative Constraint of Interest Rate: Issues Drawing on Japan’s
experience.” Kinnyu Kenkyu 2000.12, Institute for Monetary and Economic
Studies, Bank of Japan.
Okina, Kunio, Masaaki Shirakawa, and Shigenori Shiratsuka (2001) “Asset price
bubbles and monetary policy: Japan’s experience in the late 1980s and the les-
sons: Background Paper.” Monetary and Economic Studies 19 (S1): 395–450.
Okina, Kunio, and Shigenori Shiratsuka (2002) “Asset Price Bubbles, Price
Stability, and Monetary Policy: Japan’s Experience” Monetary and Economic
Studies Vol.20, No3/October 2002, Bank of Japan.
Sakakibara, Eisuke (2000) “US-Japanese economic policy conflicts and coordina-
tion during the 1990s).” In Japan’s Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to
U.S. Experience, edited by Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam S. Posen. Washington,
DC: Institute for International Economy.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2010) “Japan’s economy and monetary policy,” January 29,
Bank of Japan.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012a) “Deleveraging and Growth: Is the World Following
Japan’s Long and Winding Road?” Lecture at the London School of Economics
(LSE) and Political Science (Co, co-hosted by the Asia Research Center and
Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related
Disciplines (STICARD), LSE), January 10, 2012, Bank of Japan.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2012b) “Japan’s economy and monetary policy.” June 4,
Bank of Japan.
Small and Medium Enterprise Agency (2017) 2017 White paper on small and
medium enterprise in Japan.
Swenson, Lars E. (2003) “Escaping from a Liquidity Trap and Deflation: Foolproof
Way and Others.” NBER Working Paper 10195, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, MA.
Ugai, Hiroshi (2007) “Effects of the Quantitative Easing Policy: A Survey of
Empirical Analysis.” Monetary and Economic Studies/March 2007, BOJ.
Yamaguchi, Yutaka (1999) “Monetary Policy and Structural Policy: A Japanese
Perspective.” Remarks by Yutaka Yamaguchi, Deputy Governor of the Bank of
Japan, before Colloque Montaire International at Banque de France, October 8–9.
Reference in Japanese
Adachi, Makiko (2014) “Shoshi Koreika ga Kakei Bumon ni Ataeru Eikyo (Impacts
of Declining Birth Rate and Aging Population on Household Sector)” (Mizuho
Soken Ronshu (2004 I), pp. 1–35. Mizuho Sogo Kenkyujo.
Adachi, Seiji, (2013) “Kinnyu seisaku kettei purosesu to kinnyu seisaku ronso no
keifu” (Process of Monetary Policy Determination and Developments in
344 BIBLIOGRAPHY
Bank of Japan (2003b) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Prices and Risk Assessment), October.
Bank of Japan (2004a) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Prices and Risk Assessment), April.
Bank of Japan (2004b) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Prices and Risk Assessment), October.
Bank of Japan (2005a) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Prices and Risk Assessment), April.
Bank of Japan (2005b) “Wagakuni Kigyo niyoru Yurishi Fusai no Asshuku to Rieki
Bunpai Saku” (Reduction of Interest-bearing Debt by Japanese Companies and
Profit Distribution Policy), May, Nichigin Review 2005-J-7.
Bank of Japan (2005c) Keizai Bukka no Shorai Tenbo to Risuku Hyoka (Future
Outlook of the Economy and Prices and Risk Assessment), October.
Bank of Japan (2006) “Kinnen no Seizogyo no Setsubi Toshi Zoka nitsuite” (On
the Recent Increase in Plant and Equipment Investment of Manufacturing
Industry).
Bank of Japan (2009a) Kinnyu Keizai Geppo (Monthly Financial and Economic
Report) February.
Bank of Japan (2009b) “Kigyo Shueki no Kaizen to sono Nihon Keizai heno
Ganni” (Improvements in Corporate Profits and Its Implications to Japanese
Economy), September 20, Research and Statistics Department.
Bank of Japan (2012) “Nihon no Jinko Dotai to Chuchoki tekina Seichoryoku:
Jijitsu to Ronten no Seiri” (Japan’s Demography and Medium and Long-term
Growth Potential: Facts and Issues), August, Research and Statistics
Department.
Bernanke, Ben (2001) “Mizukara Kino Mahi ni Ochitta Nihon no Kinnyu Seisaku”
(Japanese Monetary Policy—A Case of Self-induced Paralysis?). In Nihon no
Kinyu Kiki—Beikoku no Keiken to Nihon heno Kyokun (Monetary Policy in
Japan—US Experiences and Their Lessons for Japan), edited by Ryoichi
Mikitani and Adam A. Posen, Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Cabinet Office (2001) Heisei 13 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku—Kaikaku
Nakushite Seicho Nashi (Annual Report on the Japanese Economy and Public
Finance FY 2001—No Gains without Reforms), December.
Cabinet Office (2005) Heisei 17 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku (Annual Report
on the Japanese Economy and Public Finance FY 2005), July.
Cabinet Office (2008a) Heisei 20 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku (Annual
Report on the Japanese Economy and Public Finance FY 2008).
Cabinet Office (2008b) Nihon Keizai 2008–2009 (Japanese Economy 2008–
2009), December.
Cabinet Office (2010) Heisei 22 nendo Nenji Keizai Zaisei Hokoku (Annual Report
on the Japanese Economy and Public Finance FY 2010).
Cabinet Office (2012a) Heisei 24 nenban Kodomo Kosodate Hakusho (White Paper
on Children and Child-rearing 2012).
346 BIBLIOGRAPHY
Iwata, Kikuo (1993) Kinnyu Seisaku no Keizai Gaku —‘Nichigin Riron’ no Kensho
(Economics of Monetary Policy—Examination of the “BOJ Theory”). Nihon
Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Iwata, Kikuo, ed. (2000) Kinnyu Seisaku no Ronten (Issues on Monetary Policy).
Toyo Keizai Shinpo Sha.
Iwata, Kikuo (2001) Defure no Keizaigaku (Economics of Deflation). Toyo Keizai
Shimpo Sha.
Iwata, Kikuo (2009) Nihon Ginko ha Shinnyo Dekiruka (Is the Bank of Japan
Trustworthy?). Kodansha Gendai Shinsho.
Iwata, Kikuo (2011) Defure to Cho Endaka (Deflation and Super High Yen).
Kodansha Shinsho.
Iwata, Kikuo, ed. (2013a) Mazu defure wo tomeyo (Stop Deflation, First). Nihon
Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Iwata, Kikuo (2013b) Refure ha Tadasii (Reflation is Right). PHP Kenkyu Jo.
Iwata, Kikuo, and Miyagawa Tsutomu, eds. (2003) Ushinawareta 10 nen no
Shin-in ha Nanika (What is the Real Cause of the Lost Decade?), Economics
Series. Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Japan Institute for Labor Policy and Training (Rodo Seisaku Kenkyu Kenshu
Kiko) (2014) “Jakunensha no shugyo jokyo, kyaria, shokugyo noryoku kaihatu
no genjo ② heisei 24 nen ban ‘shugyo kozo kihon chosa’ yori” (Current status
of employment, career and work capacity development of young people ②
based on ‘basic survey of employment structure’ 2012), JILP Document Series
No. 144, September 2014.
Japan–US Joint Working Group of Special Meeting on Yen–Dollar Exchange Rate
and Financial and Capital Markets (1984) “Nichi Bei Kyodo En-doru Reto
Kinnyu Shihon Shijo Tokubetsu Kaigo Sagyo Bukai Hokoku Sho.” (Report of
the Japan–US Joint Working Group of Special Meeting on Yen–Dollar
Exchange Rate and Financial and Capital Markets) (Report of the Yen–Dollar
Committee), May.
Jinushi, Toshiki, Yoshihiro Kuroki, and Ryuzo Miyao (2001) “1980 nendai Kohan
iko no Nihon no Kinnyu Seisaku- Seisaku Taio no Okure to sono Riyu”
(Monetary Policy in Japan from the Latter Half of the 1980s—Delay in Policy
Response and its Background). In Nihon no Kinnyu Kiki – Beikoku no Keiken
to Nihon heno Kyokun (Monetary Policy in Japan—US Experience and Their
Lessons for Japan), edited by Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam A. Posen, . Tokyo:
Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Kaizuka, Keimei (2006) Keizai Kakusa no Kenkyu (A Study of Economic
Inequality). Chuo Keizai Sha.
Kanagawa, Toru (1987) Boeki Masatsu to Kokusai Keizai no Shomondai-Nihon to
Amerika no Boeki Masatsu wo Chusin ni (Trade Frictions and Issues in
International Economy—Centering on Trade Frictions between Japan and the
US). Keibun Sha.
350 Bibliography
Komine, Takao (2005) Nihon Keizai no Shin Kyokumen (New Phase of the
Japanese Economy). Chuo Koron Sha.
Komine, Takao (2007) Jinko Gen Shoshika Shakai no Mirai (Future of the Society
with Population Shrinkage and the Declining Birth Rate). Akashi Shobo.
Komine, Takao (2010) Jinko Fuka Shakai (Society with Demographic Burden).
Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Komine, Takeo, ed.(2011a) Nihon Keizai no Kiroku—Dai Niji Sekiyu Kiki heno
Taio kara Baburu Hokai made (1970 nendai~1996 nen) (Record of Japanese
Economy from Responses to the 2nd Oil Shock and the Collapse of the Bubble,
1970s to 1996), (“Baburu/defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku Rekisi
hen dai 1 kan”), (Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in the Period of
Bubble and Deflation—History, Vol. 1)), Economic and Social Research
Institute, Cabinet Office, Japanese Government.
Komine, Takao, ed. (2011b) Nihon Keizai no Kiroku—Kinnyu Kiki, Defure to
Kaifuku Katei (1997 nen~2006 nen) (Record of Japanese Economy—
Financial crisis, Deflation and Recovery Process [1997 to 2006]), (“Baburu/
defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku Rekisi hen dai 2 kan” (Japanese
Economy and Economic Policy in the Period of Bubble and Deflation —
History, Vol. 2)), Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office,
Japanese Government.
Komiya, Ryutaro, ed. (2002) “Kinnyu Seisaku no Soten—Nichign Hihan to Sono
Hanron” (Issues in Monetary Policy Debates—Criticism of BOJ and
Counterarguments). Nihon Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Kondo, Takehiko (1999) Puraza Goi no Kenkyu (A Study of the Plaza Accord).
Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Koo, Richard (2007) ‘In’ to ‘Yo’ no Keizai Gaku (Economics of “The Sunny Side”
and “The Shadow Side.”). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Koo, Richard (2008) Nihon Keizai wo Oou Futatsu no Nami (Two Waves Hanging
over the Japanese Economy). Tokuma Shoten.
Kosai, Yutaka, Osamu Ito, and Ritsuko Arioka (2001) “Baburuki no Kinnyu
Seisaku to sono Hansei” (Monetary Policy in the Bubble Era and Its
Reconsideration). In Baburu to Kinnyu Seisaku—Nihon no Keiken to Kyokun,
(Bubble and Monetary Policy—Japan’s Experience and Lessons), edited by
Yutaka Kosai, Masaaki Shirakawa, and Kunio Okina, . Nihon Keizai Shimbun
Sha.
Kubota, Isao (2008) Shogen: Miyazawa Daiichiji [1986–1988] Tsuka Gaiko
(Testimony—First Currency Diplomacy [1986–1988] by Miyazawa). Nishi
Nihon Shimbun Sha.
Kumon, Takashi (2006) Jinko Defure ha Hajimatte iru (Demographic Deflation
Has Already Set In). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Kuroda, Haruhiko (2005) Zaisei Kinnyu Seisaku no Seiko to Shippai (Success and
Failure of Fiscal and Monetary Policy). Nihon Hyoron Sha.
352 Bibliography
Kusano, Atsushi (1998) Yamaichi Shoken Hatan to Kiki Kanri—1965 and 1998
(Failure of Yamaichi Securities and Crisis Management: Years of 1965 and
1997. Asahi Shimbun Sha.
Kusu, Toshiharu (2005) “Baburu no Gennin Saiko (jo)” (Re-examining Causes of
the Bubble [1]). In Yokin Hoken Kiko (Deposit Insurance Corporation) Yokin
Hoken Kenkyu, October.
Kusu, Toshiharu (2006) “Baburu no Gennin Saiko (ge)” (Re-examining Causes of
the Bubble [2]). In Yokin Hoken Kiko (Deposit Insurance Corporation) Yokin
Hoken Kenkyu, November.
Land Economy and Construction Industries Bureau, Ministry of Land,
Infrastructure, Transport and Tourism (2012) “Fudosan Shijo niokeru Shisan
Kakaku Hendo ni kansuru Kenkyu Kai Hokoku Sho” (Report of the Study
Group on Asset Price Developments in Real Estate Markets).
Matsushima, Shigeru, and Harukata Takenaka, eds. (2011) Nihon Keizai no
Kiroku—Jidai Shogen Shu (oraru Hisutori) (Record of Japanese Economy—
Collection of Testimonies of the Period [Oral History]), “(Baburu/Defure ki
no Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku—Rekishi Hen dai 3 kan” (Japanese Economy
and Economic Policies in the Period of Bubble and Deflation, History, Vol. 3)),
Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office. Japanese Government.
Matsutani, Akihiko (2004) ‘Jinko Gensho Keizai’ no Atarasii Koshiki (A New
Formula for “the Economy with a Shrinking Population”). Nihon Keizai
Shimbun Sha.
Matsuzaki, Masahiro (1988) Nichi Bei Masatsu no Seiji Keizai Gaku (Political
Economy of Japan–US Frictions). Yachiyo Shuppan.
Mieno, Yasushi (2000) Ri wo Mite Gi wo Omou (When Seeing Profits, Thinking
about Justice). Chuo Koron Sha.
Mikitani, Ryoichi, and Adam A. Posen, eds. Nihon no Kinyu Kiki—Beikoku no
Keiken to Nihon heno Kyokun (Monetary Policy in Japan—US Experiences and
Their Lessons for Japan). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Ministry of Finance (1984) “Kinnyu no Jiyuka oyobi En no Kokusaika nitsuiteno
Genjo to Tenbo” (Current Conditions and Future Prospects of Financial
Liberalization and Internationalization of the Yen), May.
Ministry of Finance (1992) “Kinnyu Gyosei no Tomen no Unnyo Hoshin”
(Current Policy of Financial Administration), August 18, 1992. In Banking
Bureau, Ministry of Finance, “dai 42 kai Ginko kyoku Kinnyu Nenpo Heisei 5
nen ban” (42nd Annual Report of Banking Bureau Heisei 5).
Ministry of Finance (1993) “Shisan kakaku hendo no mekanizumu to sono keizai
koka” (The Mechanism of Asset Price Movements and its Economic Impacts),
November, Finansharu Rebyu, Fiscal and Monetary Research Institute,
Ministry of Finance, Japan.
Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare (2012) Heisei 24 nenban Koreika Shakai
Hakusho (2012 White Paper on Ageing Society).
Bibliography 353
Otake, Fumio, and Noriyuki Yanagawa (2004) Heisei Fukyo no Ronten (Issues in
Heisei Recession). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Otsuka, Satoshi, Shigenori Shiratsuka, and Masayuki Nakakuki (2004) “Seisansei
Shijo no Yugami to Kokunai Keizai Chosei” (Distortions in Production Factor
Markets and Domestic Economic Adjustments), IMES Discussion Paper No.
20040J-1.
Sakuragawa, Masaya (2003) “Furyo Saiken Mondai ga Nihon Keizai ni Ataeta
Dageki” (Damage to Japanese Economy by Non-Performing Loan Problems).
In Ushinawareta 10 nen no Shinn-in ha Nanika (What is the Real Cause of the
Lost Decade?), edited by Kikuo Iwata and Tsutomu Miyagawa, Economics
Series. Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Sakurai, Ryoji (1993) Baburu Keizai no Hokai to Nihon Keizai no Honshitsu
(Collapse of the Bubble Economy and the Real Nature of the Japanese
Economy). Hokei Ronshu Dai 71 Go.
Sato, Takafumi (2003) Sinnyo Chitsujo Seisaku no Saihen—Wakugumi Ikoki toshi-
teno 1990 nendai (Reorganization of Policies for the Maintenance of Stable
Financial System—1990s as a Period of Framework Transition). Nihon Tosho
Center.
Sato, Takafumi (2010) Kinnyu Gyosei no Zahyo Jiku—Heiji to Yuji wo Koete
(Coordinate Axis for Financial Administration—Beyond Times of Peace and
Crisis). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Sato, Toshiki (2000) Fubyodo Shakai Nippon: Sayonara So Churyu (Japan, An
Unequal Society: Goodbye to All Middle Class Society). Chuko Shinsho.
Shimizu, Hironori (2001) “Goso Sendan Kisei, Ginko Keiei to Nihon no Kinnyu
Kiki” (Convoy-based Regulations, Management of Banks, and Financial Crisis
in Japan). In Nihon no Kinnyu Kiki—Beikoku no Keiken to Nihon heno Kyokun
(Monetary Policy in Japan—US Experiences and Their Lessons for Japan),
edited by Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam A. Posen, Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Shimizudani, Satoshi (2005) Kitai to Fukakujitsu Sei no Keizai Gaku (Economics
of Expectation and Uncertainty). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Shimpo, Seiji (2002) “Defure wo Motarashita noha Kozo Yoin ka Kinnyu Seisaku
ka” (Is It a Structural Factor or Monetary Policy That Has Brought about
Deflation?). In Kinnyu seisaku ronso no soten—nichigin hihan to sono hanron,
(Issues in Monetary Policy Debates—Criticism of the Bank of Japan and
Counterarguments) edited by Ryutaro Komiya. Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Shirai, Sayuri (2012) “Jinko Dotai no Henka ha Wagakuni no Makuro Keizai ni
Eikyo wo Ataete Irunoka?” (Have Demographic Changes Affected Japan’s
Macroeconomic Performance?) September 7.
Shirakawa, Masaaki (2002) “Ryoteki Kanwa Saiyo go 1 nenkan no Keiken” (1-Year
Experience since the Introduction of Quantitative Easing). In Kinnyu seisaku
ronso no soten—nichigin hihan to sono hanron (Issues in Monetary Policy
Debates—Criticism of the Bank of Japan and Counterarguments), edited by
Ryutaro Komiya. Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Bibliography 357
Takenaka, Harukata (2005) “Chika Baburu heno Taio ha Naze Okureta ka—
Tokyo no Mondai ga Nihon no Mondai ni Naru made” (Why Was the Response
to the Land Price Bubble Delayed?—When the Problem in Tokyo Became the
Problem of Japan). In Heisei Baburu—Saki Okuri no Kenkyu, (Heisei
Bubble—A Study of Forbearance), edited by Michio Muramatsu. Toyo Keizai
Shimpo Sha.
Takita, Yoichi (2002) Nihon Keizai Fusakui no Tsumi (Japanese Economy: A
Crime of Omission). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Takita, Yoichi (2006) Nichibei Tsuka Kosho —20 nenme no Shinjitsu (Japan–US
Currency Negotiations—Real Story after 20 Years) Nihon Keizai Shimubun
Sha.
Tanaka, Hideomi, and Seiji Adachi (2003) Heisei Dai Fukyo to Showa Kyoko
—Purakutyikaru Keizaigaku Nyumon (Heisei Great Stagnation and Showa
Depression—Introduction to Practical Economics). Nihon Hoso Shuppan Kai.
Tanaka, Takayuki (2002) Gendai Nihon Keizai—Baburu to Posuto Baburu no
Kiseki (Current Japanese Economy—Trajectory of the Bubble and Post-
Bubble). Nihon Hyoron Sha.
Tanaka, Takayuki (2008) Ushinawareta 15 nen to Kinnyu Seisaku—Nichigin ha
Naniwo Okonai Naniwo Okonawa nakatta noka (“Lost 15 Years” and Monetary
Policy—What Did BOJ Do and Not Do?). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Tanaka, Takayuki (2009) Kinnyu Kiki ni Do Tachi Mukau ka —Ushinawareta 15
nen’ no Kyokun (How to Cope with Financial Crises? Lessons from “the Lost
15 Years”). Chikuma Shobo.
Tatebe, Masayoshi (2010) “Kinnyu Kikika no Nichigin no Kinnyu Seisaku” (BOJ’s
Monetary Policy under the Financial Crisis). Chuo Daigaku Shuppan Bu.
Tsutani, Noriko, and Yoshio Higuchi (2009) Jinko Gensho to Nihon Keizai
(Population Decline and the Japanese Economy). Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Ueda, Kazuo (2001) “1990 nendai niokeru Nihon no Furyo Saiken Mondai no
Gennin” (Cause of Non-Performing Loan Problems in the 1990s in Japan). In
“Nihon Kinnyu Shisutemu no Kiki to Henbo,” (Crisis in Japan’s Financial System
and Its Transition), edited by Takeo Hoshi and Hugh Patrick,. Nihon Keizai
Shimbun Sha.
Ueda, Kazuo (2005) Zero Kinri tono Tatakai (Battle against Zero Interest Rate).
Nihon Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Umeda, Masanobu (2011) Nichigin no Seisaku Keisei ‘Gijiroku’ nado ni Miru
Seisaku Handan no Doki to Seigosei (Policy Formation of the BOJ—Motives of
Policy Determination and Their Coherence in Light of Committee Minutes).
Toyo Keizai Shimbun Sha.
Uemura Shuichi, and Sato Yoshiko (2000) “Saikin no Chika Keisei no Tokucho
nituite” (On the Characteristics of Recent Land Price Formation), October,
BOJ, Chosa Geppo.
Bibliography 359
Volker, Paul, and Toyoo Gyoten (1992) “Tomi no Kobo—En to Doru no Rekishi”
(Rise and Fall of Wealth—History of the Yen and the Dollar). Toyo Keizai
Shimpo Sha.
Wakatabe, Masazumi (2013) Keizai Gakusha Tachino Tatakai—Datsu Defure wo
Meguru Ronso no Rekishi (Battle of the Economists—History of Debates over
Exit from Deflation). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Watanabe, Takashi (2001) Furyo Saiken ha Naze Kienai (Why Have Non-
Performing Loans not Disappeared?). Nikkei BP Sha.
Watanabe, Tsutomu (2009) “Shihan Seiki no Bukka Hendo” (Price Developments
over a Quarter of a Century). In Defure Keizai to Kinnyu Seisaku, (Deflationary
Economy and Monetary Policy), edited by Hiroshi Yoshikawa, (“Baburu/
defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 7” (Japanese Economy and
Economic Policy in the Period of Bubble and Deflation 7)), Economic and
Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office.
Watanabe, Tsutomu (2012) “Zero Kinri kano Choki Defure” (Chronic Deflation
under the Zero Interest Rate), BOJ Working Paper Series No.12 ~J~3, March.
Watanabe, Tsutomu (2013) “Defure Dakkyaku no Joken” (Conditions for Exit
from Deflation) March 26, Canon Institute for Global Studies, http://www.
canon-igs.org/research_papers/macroeconomics/20130326_1816.html
(accessed August 17, 2018).
Yamada, Masahiro (2004) Kibo Kakusa Shakai: ‘Makegumi’ no Zetsubo Kan ga
Nihon wo Hikisaku’ (Society of Unequal Hope: Despair of “the Failed” Will
Divide Japan). Chikuma Shobo.
Yashiro, Naohiro (2004) Shoshi Koreika no Keizaigaku (Economics of the
Declining Birth Rate and Aging). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi (1992) Nihon Keizai to Makuro Keizai Gaku (Japanese
Economy and Macroeconomics). Toyo Keizai Shimpo Sha.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi (1997) Kodo Seicho—Nihon wo Kaeta 6000 Nichi (High Speed
Growth—6000 days that Changed Japan). Yomiuri Shimbun Sha.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi(1999)Tenkanki no Nihon Keizai (The Japanese Economy at a
Turning Point). Iwanami Shoten.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi (2009a) “Defureshon to Kinnyu Seisaku” (Deflation and
Monetary Policy). In Defure Keizai to Kinnyu Seisaku (Deflationary Economy
and Monetary Policy), edited by Hiroshi Yoshikawa, (“Baburu/defure kino
Nihon Keizai to Keizai Seisaku 7”(Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in
the Period of Bubble and Deflation 7)), Economic and Social Research
Institute, Cabinet Office.
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi, ed. (2009b) Defure Keizai to Kinnyu Seisaku (Deflationary
Economy and Monetary Policy), (“Baburu/defure kino Nihon Keizai to Keizai
Seisaku 7”(Japanese Economy and Economic Policy in the Period of Bubble
and Deflation 7)), Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office.
360 Bibliography
Period IV (2008–2012), 20 S
Physical assets, 227n2 “St. Petersburg Action Plan,” 291
ratio of, 240 Sanyo Securities, 129, 137
Population decline, 332 Savings Bank of Finland
“Population statistics data (2017 (SBF), 151
revised version),” 319n17 Second World War, 130
Postwar history, 130 Shimpo, Seiji, 192
Potential growth rate, 324 Shirakawa, Masaaki, 29, 211, 276,
Price, 306–310 277n19, 287n3
Price stability target, 287, 306 Single Open Ended Contract (SOEC),
Primary balance, 291n7 331n25
Private investment, 105–116, 243 Small and medium enterprises (SMEs),
growth contribution of, 97–98 143, 155
Profits of companies, 222–224 Small-sized banks, 136
Public funds, 139 Stagnation of wages, 143
Stagnation period, 14, 83, 96, 101
characteristics of, 96–97
Q Stagnation, three stages mechanism of,
QQE, see Quantitative and Qualitative 271–274
Monetary Easing Stock adjustments, 16, 106–109, 111,
“QQE with a Negative Interest Rate,” 162, 241, 269
289 Stock price, 30, 34, 39–41, 79, 85,
“QQE with yield curve control,” 289 104, 112, 133, 139n15, 141n20,
Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary 147, 201, 295–298, 300, 311,
Easing (QQE), 29, 189, 288, 289 315
adoption of, 198–199 Supply-side
Quantitative easing policy (QEP), 189 factor, 14
by BOJ, 210–211 views, 89–93
Quantity theory of money, 196n4 “Sustained defensiveness,” 5
“Sustained defensiveness period,” 26
Sweden, 151
R
Reagan administration, 12
Real economy, 211, 317, 3258 T
abenomics and, 298–315 Takenaka Plan, 169
Reconstruction Law, 137, 138 Taxation areas, 84
Resona Bank, 139n15 Taylor rule, 200, 202, 203
Resona Group, 139 Terms of trade, 261, 266, 267
Return on asset (ROA), 27n8, 131, “Three arrows,” 29
132, 252, 252n11 “Three excesses” argument, 162
INDEX 367