CH 8
CH 8
To solve this question, firm has to make sure he can sell all he
produces. But this really depends on the demand curve, and its belied
about how other firms in the market will behave, the ease with which
firms can enter and leave the market and the ability of firms to
differentiate their products from those of their rivals. In this
chapter, we look at a competitive market structure.
Textbook example:
There are 40,000 apple farms in the US. One of them charges a
different, higher, price than the others will result in no-sale.
Consumers buy the same apples from others. A farm also has no
incentives to decrease the price since this will not increase profit.
Æ A perfectly competitive firm faces a horizontal demand curve.
Firms are price-takers in the competitive market if
• Identical products (homogeneous product): consumers can substitute
among them perfectly.
• Buyers and sellers know all price charged by all firms → full
information.
• Free entry and exit in the market: who wants to sell can sell.
• Low transaction cost: can easily find other partners to trade.
Also,
MP = ∆(R – C)/∆q
= ∆R/∆q - ∆C/∆q
= MR – MC
So, a firm wants to produce at
MR = MC (Rule 2)
2. In the Short-Run
After figuring out the maximum profit when it stays in business, which
is π* = R* – C* = R* – VC* - FC, a firm will compare the Revenue and
the Variable Cost.
So,
Stay in business or not?
YES (LR: π* > 0; SR: pq∗ > VC (q∗) ) Æ How much to produce? - at MR
= MC
NO (LR: π* < 0; SR: pq∗ < VC (q∗) ) Æ Shut down
From panel (b), we can see that firm chooses its output level to
maximize its total profit rather than the average profit per ton. By
producing 140 thousand tons, where average cost is minimized, firm could
maximize its average profit. If firm produces 284 thousand tons of lime,
although firm loses $0.50 ($6.50-$6) in profit per ton, it gains by
selling more output. And the gain is bigger than the loss, so firm is
maximizing its profit at 284 thousand tons.
Problem 8.1
Solution:
(1) Total cost a =Total cost b + τ q
⇒ MC a = MC b + τ
and
⇒ AC a = AC b + τ
(2) Originally, the firm has MC1 and AC1 and its equilibrium is e1.
The tax will shift both the MC and AC up by $τ . And the new
equilibrium is e2 . In response to tax, firm produces q1 − q2 fewer
units of output.
(3) Since firm sells less output, and average cost has been
increased, the profit it earns now drops. Firms sell less and make
less profit per unit.
Figure 8.4
Practice: If we find the fixed cost is increased twice, will that change
firm’s production decision?
Answer: No. Because firm’s production decision has nothing to do with
Fixed cost. Only depends on Variable cost.
[2] From one firm’s supply curve to the market supply curve
After the shock: demand shifts to left. New market equilibrium is the
intersection of new demand curve and supply curve, i.e., E2 . The new
market equilibrium price is $5, while the market equilibrium quantity is
250. When price is $5, each firm will produce 50 units of output. So,
again, we have 250=5*50.
But for this case, firm doesn’t have a positive profit. Each firm loses
5*50-6.97*50=-1.97*50=-98.5. However, if firm chooses to shut down, he
also loses –98.5. Firm is indifferent in shutting down or producing. We
assume firm will produce if he is indifferent.
Figure 8.12
All potential firms have the same cost curves. There are many potential
firms that may enter the market. Suppose there are a few firms in the
market already and they have the same supply curve S1.
If the price is lower than 10, no one wants to produce Æ leave.
If the price is higher then 10, there is a positive profit Æ attract
new firms → more output will be supplied → price will be driven
down → profit=0 → firms will be indifferent in entering or not.
So, as long as the price is at 10, any quantity can be supplied by
having more firms. This means a horizontal supply curve. Note the
firms all produce at the lowest point of AC.
For example, there are many countries that produce cotton. Each country
has numerous farms with identical cost curves. But the technology and
cost among countries are different. The world cotton supply curve looks
like the one above on page 253 in textbook. It has several steps. Each
step means that all the quantities in the world market is supplied by
farms in one country. At a low price, Pakistan farmers supply cotton
(this price is too low for other countries). The farms are identical, so
this segment is horizontal as in case 1. When all the farms are engaged
in production, Pakistan cannot supply more. As the price increases,
Argentina will join the market and start another horizontal segment.
This depends on whether the industry hires a large portion of the input.
- The computer industry uses steel to make computer cases, the changes
in output will not affect world steel price.
- The construction industry, on the other hand, buys a major portion of
steel. The steel price will go up if more construction is demanded.
Figure 8.13
Originally, free entry makes all firm producing at the lowest part of
AC.
To supply a higher quantity Æ need more inputsÆinput prices up Æ
cost curves up Æ free entry leads to lowest point of new AC Æ
upward sloping market supply curve.
Figure 8.14
The reason is that the input may not be mass-produced. As the output
goes up, the demand for the input increase, mass-production reduced
the input price.
To supply a higher quantity Æ input prices down Æ cost curves down
Æ free entry leads to lowest point of new AC Æ downward sloping
market supply curve.
To sum up the firms’ and market’s supply curves in the SR and LR:
Short-run:
1. Sfirm is the part of MC above AVC.
2. Smarket is the sum of all firms, S curves and number of firms is fixed.
3. The change of market comes from the change in each firm’s production,
not from the number of firms.
Long-run:
1. Sfirm is the part of LRMC above LRAC.
2. When there is free-entry,
(i) firms produce at the lowest point of LRAC, which means zero-
profit,
(ii) Smarket is not the sum of firms’ S curves.
3. In an identical-firm free entry model
(i) Increasing-cost market: upward sloping Smarket
(ii) Constant-cost market: flat Smarket
(iii) Decreasing-cost market: downward sloping Smarket
4. The change in market output can only be caused by the change in the
number of firms.
Since the market supply curve is different in the short run and in the
long run, the equilibrium will also be different for these two. The
relationship between SHORT-RUN Competitive Equilibrium and LONG-RUN
Competitive Equilibrium depends on where the market demand curve crosses
the short-run and long-run market supply curves.
Let’s use the graph below to illustrate the relationship between SR and
LR. We assume that the firm uses the same plant size in SR and LR so
that the minimal average cost is same in both cases.
Figure 8.15
Assume there are 20 firms in the market originally.
Practice:
If government starts collecting a lump-sum franchise tax of τ each year
from each identical firm in a competitive market with free entry and
exit, how do the long-rum market and firm equilibrium change?
Solution:
Step 1: TC A = TC B + τ ⇒ AC A = AC B + τ / q and MC A = MC B
Step 2: put the new MC and AC on the graph.
Step 4: When there is a lump-sum tax, each firm will produce more:
q2 > q1 . But we know that the new market quantity is less than before, so
this implies there is less firms in the market.
n2 = Q2 / q2 < n1 = Q1 / q1
So there are fewer firms remaining in the market, but each firm is
producing more.