Chapter 16 Solution Manual Microeconomic Theory
Chapter 16 Solution Manual Microeconomic Theory
Labor Markets
Because the subject of labor demand was extensively treated in Chapter 11, the problems in this
chapter focus primarily on labor supply and on equilibrium in the labor market. Most of the labor
supply problems (16.1–16.3) start with the specification of a utility function and then ask
students to explore the labor supply behavior implied by the function. The primary focus of most
of the problems that concern labor market equilibrium is on monopsony and the marginal
expense concept (problems 16.5–16.7). Analytical problems are concerned with generalizing the
labor supply problems to consider risk, family labor supply, and intertemporal labor supply.
Comments on Problems
16.1 This problem is an algebraic example of labor supply that is based on a CobbDouglas
(constant budget shares) utility function. Part (b) shows in a simple context the work
disincentive effects of a lump-sum transfer. Three-fourths of the extra 4,000 is “spent” on
leisure which, at a price of $5 per hour, implies a 600-hour reduction in labor supply. Part
(c) then illustrates a positive labor supply response to a higher wage since the $3,000
spent on leisure will now only buy 300 hours. Notice that a change in the wage would not
affect the solution to part (a), because, in the absence of nonlabor income, the constant
share assumption assures that the individual will always choose to consume 6,000 hours
(=3/4 of 8,000) of leisure.
16.2 This problem uses the expenditure function approach to study labor supply. It shows why
income and substitution effects are precisely off-setting in the Cobb–Douglas case.
16.3 This problem is an application of labor supply theory to the case of means-tested income
transfer programs. The problem results in a kinked budget constraint. Reducing the
implicit tax rate on earnings (parts (f) and (g)) has an ambiguous effect on H since
income and substitution effects work in opposite directions.
16.4 This problem is a simple supply–demand example that asks students to compute various
equilibrium outcomes.
16.5 This problem is an illustration of marginal expense calculation. The problem also shows
that imposition of a minimum wage may actually raise employment in the monopsony
case.
16.7 This is a bilateral monopoly problem for an input (here, pelts). Students may get confused
on what is required here, so they should be encouraged first to take an a priori graphical
approach and then try to add numbers to their graph. In that way, they can identify the
relevant intersections that require numerical solutions.
16.8 This problem is a numerical example of the union–employer game illustrated in Example
16.5.
Analytical Problems
16.9 Compensating wage differentials for risk. This problem develops the idea of a
certainty-equivalent wage rate.
16.10 Family labor supply. This problem introduces (in part (b)) the concept of “home
production.” The functional forms specified here are so general that this problem should
be regarded primarily as a descriptive one that provides students with a general
framework for discussing various possibilities.
16.11 A few results from demand theory. This problem shows how many problems in labor
supply theory can be addressed using demand theory concepts from Part 2 of the text.
16.12 Intertemporal labor supply. This problem is an introduction to some general concepts
in the theory of multiperiod labor supply. Because time has not yet been explicitly
introduced, however, the results pertain only to a situation with no discounting.
Solutions
b. Full income is now $44,000, so this person will devote $33,000 to leisure. This
will buy 6,600 hours of leisure, so labor supply will fall to 1,400 hours.
c. With the higher wage, full income is $84,000, $63,000 of which will be devoted
to leisure. Hence, leisure time is 6,300 hours and work time is 1,700 hours. In this
case, therefore the higher wage promotes a greater labor supply even in the
presence of nonlabor income.
Leisure = 6,300 hours; work = 1,700 hours. Hence, higher wage leads to
more labor supply. Note that in part (a) labor supply is perfectly inelastic at 2,000
hours.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.
186 Chapter 16: Labor Markets
16.2
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.
187 Chapter 16: Labor Markets
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.
188 Chapter 16: Labor Markets
e.
g. Income and substitution effects of law change work in opposite directions (see
graph). Substitution effect favors more work (new budget constraint is steeper);
income effect favors less work (person has more income for h 5, 000 ).
c. With a minimum wage of w 4, labor demand = 250, labor supply = 400, and
unemployment = 150.
d.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.
189 Chapter 16: Labor Markets
16.5 Given the supply curve for labor, marginal expense is computed as
l 80w,
w l 80,
l2
wl ,
80
d ( wl ) l
MEl .
dl 40
b. For Carl, the marginal expense of labor now equals the minimum wage, and in
equilibrium the marginal expense of labor will equal the marginal revenue
product of labor.
l
MEl wmin 4 MRPi 10 ,
40
implying l 240. With this wage, supply will be 320. Hence there will be
unemployment of 80. But employment has increased from 200 to 240.
c.
d. Under perfect competition, a minimum wage means higher wages but fewer
workers employed. Under monopsony, a minimum wage may result in higher
wages and more workers employed.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.
190 Chapter 16: Labor Markets
wm l m 9
2
3/2
lm
w ml m
3
0.5
lm
MElm = = MRPl 10,
2
implies lm 400 and wm 20 / 3.
For females, the calculation is
l
wf f
100
l 2f
wf l f
100
l
MEl f f 10,
50
l f 500 w 5.
implies and f The profit per hour on machinery equals
9, 000 5(500) 6.66(400) 3,833.
If same wage must be paid to men and women, w MRPl 10,
l lm l f 900 1, 000 1,900.
Furthermore,
1,900(10) 900(10) 1, 000(10) 0.
b. From Dan’s perspective, demand for pelts equals MRPx 1, 200 20 x px .
Hence,
TR p x x 1, 200 x 20 x 2 ,
implying
dTR
MR 1, 200 40 x.
dx
For profit maximization, use marginal revenue equals marginal cost:
1, 200 40 x 20 x,
implying x 20 and px 800.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.
191 Chapter 16: Labor Markets
c. From UF’s perspective, the supply of pelts is reflected in the marginal cost curve
MC 20 x px . Total cost is given by C px x 20 x 2 .
MEx dC dx 40 x.
For profit maximization set MEx 40 x MRPx 1, 200 20 x, implying x 20
and px 400.
d. Both the monopolist and monopsonist agree on x 20, but they differ widely on
price to be paid (800 vs. 400). Bargaining will determine the result.
c. For sustainability, one needs to focus on the employer who has incentive to cheat
if union chooses w 4 (profit maximizing l is 3, not 4). Since (l 3) 9, the
condition for sustainability is
8 6.25
9
1 1
implying 1 2.75 , or 1 2.75 0.36.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.
192 Chapter 16: Labor Markets
Analytical Problems
Considering the first (riskless) job, U ( y ) 100 y 0.5 y and y wl with w 5 and
2
c1 f (h1 ), so, optimal choice would be to choose h1 so that f w1. This would
b.
probably lead person 1 to work less in the market. That may in turn lead person 2
to choose a lower level of h2 on the assumption that h1 and h2 are substitutes in
the utility function. If they were complements, the effect could go the other way.
Clearly, one can greatly elaborate on this theory by working out all of the first-
order conditions and comparative statics results.
n
V ( w, n) ( w n) 1 .
w
Therefore,
1
V ( w, n) 1 n n
( w n) 1 2
w w w
(1 n w) ( w n) 1
1
1
V ( w, n) n
1
( w n) 1 1
n w w
(1 n w) ( w n) 1 .
1
Dividing the first equation by the second yields (after some manipulation)
n
l (1 ) .
w
This is the labor supply function given in Equation 16.24.
b. Using the logic of the development of the Slutsky equation, for any consumption
good
xi xi x
h i .
w w U I
Hence, for any normal good, the income effect in this expression will be positive.
This positive effect will be reinforced for goods that are Hicksian complements
with labor (substitutes for leisure). The substitution effect will be negative,
however, for goods that are Hicksian substitutes for labor (complementary with
leisure), which is probably the case for most ordinary consumption goods. Hence,
it seems that in most cases the sign of this derivative will be ambiguous.
c. Marginal expense is the change in total labor costs for a change in hiring:
wl w l w 1
MEl w l w 1 w 1 .
l l w l
el , w
e ,
is likely to be positive, MEl w. If l , w then MEl w.
el , w
Notice that since
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.
194 Chapter 16: Labor Markets
L c1 U c1 0,
L h1 U h1 w1 0,
Lc2 E (U c2 ) 0,
L h2 E (U h2 ) E ( w2 ) 0,
L W0 w1 (1 h1 ) c1 E ( w2 )(1 h2 ) c2 0.
Combining the first two equations yields the familiar condition for a maximum:
Uh
MRS 1 w1.
U c1
An increase in initial wealth should increase both leisure and consumption
assuming they are normal goods.
b. The equation just says that second-period indirect utility is a function of the
wealth available at the start of that period and the second-period wage (which is
uncertain).
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly
accessible website, in whole or in part.