The Economic Problem: Professor Mikal Skuterud ECON 101 - FALL 2019 University of Waterloo
This document provides an overview of key economic concepts including:
1) It introduces the production possibilities frontier (PPF) to show the tradeoffs between producing different goods given limited resources.
2) It defines opportunity cost and shows how opportunity cost increases as production moves along the outward-bowing PPF.
3) It explains how specialization according to comparative advantage allows individuals and economies to gain from trade and expand their combined PPF.
4) Technological progress and capital accumulation can shift and expand the PPF over time, allowing higher levels of production and economic growth.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0 ratings0% found this document useful (0 votes)
40 views27 pages
The Economic Problem: Professor Mikal Skuterud ECON 101 - FALL 2019 University of Waterloo
This document provides an overview of key economic concepts including:
1) It introduces the production possibilities frontier (PPF) to show the tradeoffs between producing different goods given limited resources.
2) It defines opportunity cost and shows how opportunity cost increases as production moves along the outward-bowing PPF.
3) It explains how specialization according to comparative advantage allows individuals and economies to gain from trade and expand their combined PPF.
4) Technological progress and capital accumulation can shift and expand the PPF over time, allowing higher levels of production and economic growth.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 27
Chapter 2:
The Economic Problem
P ROF ESSO R M I K A L S KU T ERU D ECO N 1 0 1 – FA L L 2 0 1 9 U N I V ERSITY O F WAT ER LO O Production possibilities frontier (PPF) • The PPF shows the total amount of cola and pizza that can be produced in Canada in a month given total resources (land, labour and capital) and technology available to produce them. The PPF reflects scarcity. • We can produce any combination of cola and pizza on or within the PPF, but not outside it. Production on the PPF (combination D) is efficient, while production inside the PPF (combination Z) is inefficient. • Moving along the PPF involves making tradeoffs. For example, moving from D to E provides 1 million more pizzas, but at the cost of 4 million fewer cans of cola. Opportunity cost • The opportunity cost of producing an additional pizza are the cans of cola we must forego. For example, going from C to D, we gain 1 million pizzas (3 instead of 2 million) at the cost of 3 million cans of cola (9 instead of 12 million). Expressed as a ratio, the cost of a pizza in moving from C to D is 3 cans of cola. • Notice that the opportunity cost of producing pizza increases as the production of pizzas increases. From A to B, the opportunity cost of pizza is 1 can of cola, but from E to F, the opportunity cost of pizza is 5 cans of cola. The outward-shape of the of the PPF reflects the increasing opportunity cost. Opportunity cost • Convince yourself that the opportunity of a pizza is constant when the PPF is linear. • What is the opportunity cost of pizza in this figure? The PPF and marginal cost • The marginal cost of pizza, in terms of foregone cola, is equal to the slope of the PPF. • Going from C to D, we gain 1 million pizzas, but forego 3 million cans of cola. This means that the average slope of the PPF between C and D is 3. In fact, at 2.5 million pizzas, the slope of the PPF is exactly 3. • This means that the marginal cost of producing an additional pizza, when you are already producing 2.5 million pizzas, is 3 cans of cola. The PPF and marginal cost
• Rather than draw the PPF, we can
alternatively plot the marginal cost of pizza measured in cans of foregone cola. • The increasing opportunity cost of pizza means an increasing marginal cost of pizza. Using resources efficiently • We achieve production efficiency at every point on the PPF. But what amount of cola and pizza is “best” for society? This depends on people’s relative preferences for cola and pizza. • The answer is the point on the PPF where production provides the greatest benefit to society. When goods and services are provided at the lowest possible cost in quantities that provide the greatest social benefit, we have achieved allocative efficiency. Preferences and marginal benefit At A, Canadians are consuming 0.5 million pizzas. At this level of pizza consumption they are willing to give up 5 cans of cola for one additional pizza. Preferences and marginal benefit At B, Canadians are consuming 1.5 million pizzas. At this higher level of pizza consumption they are willing to give up only 4 cans of cola for one additional pizza. Preferences and marginal benefit At E, Canadians are consuming 4.5 million pizzas. At this high level of pizza consumption they are willing to give up only 1 can of cola for one additional pizza. Marginal benefit curve • The line through the points shows the marginal benefit to society of pizza. • The downward slope reflects the idea that as pizza becomes relatively plentiful and cola becomes relatively scarce, consumers are less willing to forego cola to obtain additional pizza. This is the principle of decreasing marginal benefit, which reflects our tendency to prefer variety as overconsumption of any single good leads to satiation. Allocative efficiency At a production level of 1.5 million pizzas, we can produce one more pizza at a cost of 2 cans of cola. However, consumers are willing to forego 4 cans of cola for one additional pizza. Allocative efficiency At a production level of 3.5 million pizzas, we can produce one more pizza at a cost of 4 cans of cola. However, consumers are only willing to forego 2 cans of cola for one additional pizza. Allocative efficiency At a production level of 2.5 million pizzas, the marginal benefit equals the marginal cost of pizzas. This allocation between pizza and cola is efficient. Joe’s smoothie bar • Joe operates a smoothie bar, where he produces and sells smoothies and salads. • In one hour, he can produce 6 smoothies or 30 salads. His opportunity cost of producing 1 salad is 1/5 smoothies and his opportunity cost of producing 1 smoothie is 5 salads. • Joe’s customers always order one smoothie for every salad, so Joe spends 10 minutes making 5 salads and 50 minutes making 5 smoothies. Liz’s smoothie bar • Liz also operates a smoothie bar, but she has uses a higher quality blender. • In one hour, she can produce 30 smoothies or 30 salads. Her opportunity cost of producing 1 salad is 1 smoothie and her opportunity cost of producing 1 smoothie is 1 salad. • Liz’s customers also always order one smoothie for every salad, so she spends 30 minutes making 15 salads and 30 minutes making 15 smoothies. Production possibility frontiers Comparative and absolute advantage • A person who is more productive than another person in producing a good or service has an absolute advantage. Liz has an absolute advantage in producing smoothies, since she can produce 30 per hour, while Joe can only produce 6 per hour. Joe has an absolute advantage in nothing. • A person has a comparative advantage in producing a good or service if the opportunity cost of their production is lower than someone else. Liz has a comparative advantage in producing smoothies, but Joe has a comparative advantage in producing salads. • A person who has an absolute advantage in an activity, does not necessarily have a comparative advantage in that activity. Gains from trade • Gains from trade can be achieved if factors of production (land, labour, capital, entrepreneurship) specialize in the production of the goods and services in which they have a comparative advantage. Gains from trade • The gains from trade from specialization are 5 smoothies and 5 salads for both Liz and Joe. The Joe-Liz economy and its PPF • Through specialization, Joe and Liz are able to expand their combined PPF. • When Canada’s millions of workers, acres of land, machines and entrepreneurs are put to the uses in which they have a comparative advantage, Canada’s productive capacity is able to reach its full potential. In other words, its PPF is able to expand outwards as much as possible. • Although Joe and Liz have linear individual PPFs, their combined PPF is bowed outward. In a country with millions of factors of production specializing, the economy’s PPF is smoothly outward-bowed. Economic growth • Economic growth comes from technological change and capital accumulation. • Technological change is the development of new goods and services and more efficient ways of producing existing goods and resources using available resources. • Capital accumulation is the growth of capital resources, including human capital (the skills of people). • By foregoing pizzas today to produce more pizza ovens, we can expand our PPF outward in the future. Hong Kong overtakes Canada • In 1996, production possibilities per person were three times bigger in Canada than in Hong Kong. Canada was devoting one-fifth of national production to capital goods and Hong Kong one-third. They were both at A. • Because Hong Kong invested more in capital accumulation, by 2016 its production possibilities per person had overtaken Canada’s. Hong Kong went from A to B, while Canada went from A to C. • If Hong Kong decreases its capital accumulation (moves to point D), its economic growth will slow. Economic growth and what we produce (1) • When a country is very poor, people’s marginal benefit of food is extremely high so production is highly concentrated in agriculture. • As countries invest in capital and technology, its PPF expands and they can easily satisfy the food demands of its population, so growth in production is concentrated in industry (manufactured goods). • In China, where production per person is 7 times that of Ethiopia, agriculture is only 9 percent of total production, compared to 36 in Ethiopia. Economic growth and what we produce (2) • As China continues to invest in capital and technology, its PPF will approach that of Canada, where production per person is 4 times its level in China. • As society’s needs for manufactured goods are satisfied, labour is released from industry to service production. The share of production in agriculture now drops to only 29%. • The shift from manufacturing to service jobs creates hardship for many workers who lack the skills needed for the new jobs. Economic coordination • For 7.5 billion people in the world to specialize and produce millions of different goods in a socially efficient way, their productive activities must somehow be coordinated. Who is responsible for this coordination? • Coordination in a capitalist market economy relies on four complementary social institutions: 1. Firms: an economic unit that employs factors of production to produce goods and services. 2. Markets: any arrangement that allows buyers and sellers to get information and do business with each other. 3. Property rights: regulations which govern the ownership, use and disposal of the good, services and resources that people value. 4. Money: any commodity or token that is accepted as a means of payment. Circular flows through the economy • Households and firms make choices and markets coordinate their choices. • Households make two types of choices: 1. How much labour, land, capital, and entrepreneurship to sell to firms. 2. What and how many goods and services to consume. • Firms also make two types of choices: 1. How much labour, land, capital, and entrepreneurship to employ; and 2. What and how many goods and services to produce. • The green flows are the payments for the red flows. Markets coordinate these exchanges through price adjustments.