Fiscal Policy and Ecological Sustainability: A Post-Keynesian Perspective Yannis Dafermos and Maria Nikolaidi
Fiscal Policy and Ecological Sustainability: A Post-Keynesian Perspective Yannis Dafermos and Maria Nikolaidi
Fiscal Policy and Ecological Sustainability: A Post-Keynesian Perspective Yannis Dafermos and Maria Nikolaidi
a Department of Accounting, Economics and Finance, University of the West of England, Bristol, UK
b Department of International Business and Economics, University of Greenwich, London, UK
Abstract: Fiscal policy has a strong role to play in the transition to an ecologically sustainable economy. This
paper critically discusses the way that green fiscal policy has been analysed in both conventional and post-
Keynesian approaches. It then uses a recently developed post-Keynesian ecological macroeconomic model
in order to provide a comparative evaluation of three different types of green fiscal policy: carbon taxes,
green subsidies and green public investment. We show that (i) carbon taxes reduce global warming but
increase financial risks due to their adverse effects on the profitability of firms and credit availability; (ii)
green subsidies and green public investment improve ecological efficiency, but their positive environmental
impact is partially offset by their macroeconomic rebound effects; and (iii) a green fiscal policy mix derives
better outcomes than isolated policies. Directions for future heterodox macroeconomic research on the links
between fiscal policy and ecological sustainability are suggested.
Keywords: post-Keynesian economics, ecological economics, green fiscal policy, stock-flow consistent
modelling
May 2019*
Acknowledgements: We are grateful to Philip Arestis and the participants of the conference ‘Frontiers of heterodox
macroeconomics’ (Cambridge, March 2019), the 29th Annual PKES Workshop (London, May 2019) and the 16th
International Conference on Developments in Economic Theory and Policy (Bilbao, June 2019) for useful comments
on an earlier version of this paper. Any remaining errors are ours. The paper is forthcoming in Arestis P., Sawyer, M.
(eds.) Frontiers of Heterodox Macroeconomics, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke.
Address for correspondence: Maria Nikolaidi, Senior Lecturer in Economics, Department of International Business
and Economics, University of Greenwich, Old Royal Naval College, Park Row, London, SE10 9LS, email:
[email protected]
Fiscal policy and ecological sustainability:
A post-Keynesian perspective
1. Introduction
Environmental problems are now more pressing than ever in human history. Climate change,
biodiversity loss, ocean acidification, deforestation, ocean plastic pollution and water scarcity are
only some examples of these problems. Human activity is almost entirely responsible for these
environmental pressures. For instance, climate change is directly linked with the build-up of
greenhouse gases (GHGs) in the atmosphere caused by industrial activity over the last decades. The
accumulation of plastics in the oceans is a direct outcome of the inherent tendency of the current
economic system to generate large amounts of non-recyclable hazardous waste, which is disposed
into the environment. Deforestation is the result of urbanisation, cattle ranching, the use of trees
for fuel and other human-related developments and activities.
There is, therefore, an urgent need to change fundamentally the way that our economies and
societies produce and consume. Failure to do so could result in environmental collapse, harming
fundamentally the future of humanity. Fiscal policy is one of the key tools that can be used in this
direction. Green fiscal policy is not confined to the use of taxes as a means to incentivise more
environmentally friendly production and consumption patterns. Green fiscal policy has also to do
with government spending (for example, through subsidies and investment) that affects the use of
renewables, energy efficiency, waste generation, recycling and other aspects of production and
consumption that have an impact on the environment. Green fiscal policy also includes public
investment in research and development of new green technologies.
Post-Keynesian economics has traditionally emphasised the importance of fiscal policy for
achieving macroeconomic stability and high levels of employment (see, for example, Fazzari, 1994-
5; Wray, 2007; Arestis and Sawyer, 2010; Hein and Stockhammer, 2010; Nikolaidi, 2014; Dafermos,
2018). This comes in contrast to the limited role fiscal policy is considered to play in the ‘New
Consensus Macroeconomics’. In this consensus, which continues to play a prominent role in
modern macroeconomics, fiscal policy is not considered to be an effective instrument for regulating
aggregate demand and higher government spending is postulated to have a neutral impact on long-
1
run growth and an adverse effect on budget deficits (see Arestis and Sawyer, 2003; Lavoie, 2006;
Arestis, 2012).
However, despite their emphasis on the positive economic and social effects of fiscal policy, post-
Keynesian economists have not paid enough attention to the way that fiscal policy could be used
to achieve ecological sustainability. This has largely to do with the fact that ecological sustainability
has only very recently incorporated into post-Keynesian approaches (see Fontana and Sawyer, 2013,
2016; Jackson and Victor, 2016; Taylor et al., 2016; Dafermos et al., 2017). Therefore, the
investigation of the environmental effects of fiscal policy from a post-Keynesian perspective is still
at a very preliminary stage.
The aim of this paper is to critically discuss how green fiscal policy has been so far analysed within
both conventional and post-Keynesian frameworks, placing particular emphasis on the assumptions
that have been adopted in different types of models and the implications that these assumptions
have for the results of the analysis. It also intends to explore how green fiscal policy could contribute
to ecological sustainability, using a recently developed post-Keynesian ecological macroeconomic
model that allows us to provide a comparative assessment of different types of green fiscal policies.
Our evaluation, which relies on a scenario analysis, focuses both on the environmental effects of
these policies (primarily climate change), and their key economic and financial implications. The
green fiscal policies that we examine are carbon taxes, green subsidies and green public investment.
We also discuss directions for future heterodox macroeconomic research in this area.
We proceed as follows. In Section 2, we briefly describe the main fiscal policies for ecological
sustainability. In Section 3, we discuss how the effects of green fiscal policies have been analysed in
mainstream and post-Keynesian models and we briefly analyse some key methodological issues. In
Section 4, we outline the model used for our evaluation of green fiscal policies. In Section 5, we
describe our scenario analysis and we present our simulation results. In Section 6, we summarise
our key findings and provide directions for future research.
2
2. Which are the key green fiscal policies?
Carbon taxes remain the most popular green fiscal policy since today. The idea behind this policy
is straightforward: by imposing such taxes on carbon emissions, firms have an economic incentive
to rely less on fossil fuels and invest more in renewables and energy efficiency. Furthermore, carbon
taxes can induce households to choose less carbon-intensive goods. Proponents of carbon taxes
often argue that their beneficial effects are not confined to the reduction of carbon emissions. These
taxes can be a source of significant revenues for the governments, allowing them to spend in areas
that are highly important for the environment (such as low-carbon infrastructures) or reduce taxes
on other economic activities or income sources, via the so-called ‘revenue recycling’ ( High-Level
Commission on Carbon Prices, 2017; OECD, 2017; World Bank, 2019).
However, carbon taxes are likely to have significant distributional effects (Zachmann et al., 2018).
For example, a tax on carbon can lead to a rise in energy prices, which are more likely to hurt much
more significantly poorer households whose electricity and heating costs constitute a significant
proportion of their income. In addition, carbon taxes may affect those who work in carbon-
intensive sectors or small and medium-sized enterprises that rely on carbon-related activities.
Consequently, it is often argued that these policies have to be accompanied by offsetting measures
that attenuate these adverse distributional effects.
Carbon taxes are not the only type of environmental taxes (World Bank, 2019). Environmental
taxes include all the taxes that are imposed on a physical unit that has an adverse impact on the
environment. Examples of other environmental taxes are the taxes on transport (e.g. heavy goods
vehicle taxes), pollution taxes (e.g. air pollution and landfill taxes) and resource taxes (e.g. mineral
resources extraction taxes). The idea behind these taxes is similar to that of carbon taxes: they are
meant to create incentives for more environmentally friendly behaviours and can, at the same time,
raise public revenues that can be used for other beneficial purposes.
Green subsidies are another green fiscal policy. They can take many forms. For example, they can
be tax exemptions (as is the case, for example, with electric vehicles in many countries), feed-in
3
tariffs for renewable energy production1 or grants that fund part of investment projects that intend
to have a positive environmental impact. Quite ironically, subsidies have not overall played a
beneficial environmental role over the last decades. This is because a significant amount of subsidies
has supported – and continues to support – energy consumption and production related to fossil
fuels (High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices, 2017; Monasterolo and Raberto, 2019). The
removal of fossil fuel subsidies is, thus, an essential part of any green fiscal policy mix.
However, green fiscal policies are not restricted to the use of taxes and subsidies. The spending
decisions of governments also have a significant impact on ecological sustainability (Pollin et al.,
2014). For example, instead of trying just to incentivise and fund green private investment,
governments can also invest directly in low-carbon infrastructure (such as electricity transmission
grids and electric vehicle charging facilities), energy efficiency retrofits for publicly-owned buildings
as well as research and development in green technologies (like battery storage technologies and
technologies for the electrification of the industrial sector). This investment can take place within
the context of a mission-oriented approach (Mazzucato and McPherson, 2018). In addition, the
government can employ people to work in the public sector in order to provide environment-
friendly services through a jobs guarantee programme (Forstater, 2003) or via standard public sector
employment contracts.
Carbon taxes constitute the green fiscal policy whose implications have been most extensively
explored in the economic modelling literature. This has largely been done via Integrated Assessment
Models (IAMs). These models include both economic and environmental modules, allowing the
combined assessment of the economic and environmental effects of various types of policies. IAMs
can be classified into two broad categories: (i) the Policy Optimisation Models (POMs) which
identify optimal policies by relying on cost-benefit analysis; and (ii) the Policy Evaluation Models
(PEMs) whose key aim is to identify a least-cost approach to achieve a specific goal; for example, a
specific change in atmospheric temperature (Farmer et al., 2015).
1 Feed-in tariffs are long-term contracts, which allow green energy producers to receive a fixed payment for the
electricity that they generate; these payments are independent of the market price of electricity.
4
The most well-known POM is the Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy (DICE) model, which
has been developed by the Nobel Prize-winning economist, William Nordhaus. The DICE model
(Nordhaus, 2018) uses the standard neoclassical optimal growth framework whereby a social
planner decides about the level of consumption and investment such that the discounted sum of
per capita population-weighted utility is maximised. Within this framework, output is supply-
determined and is affected by the level of investment, which builds up capital stock. Consumption
and investment are substitutable. Lower consumption today leads to higher investment today,
which in turn leads to higher output and higher consumption in the future.
Economic activity generates carbon emissions, which are considered a kind of externality. These
emissions enter into the carbon cycle. The part of carbon that is not absorbed by oceans and the
biosphere remains in the atmosphere contributing to climate change. Climate change in turn has
adverse feedback effects on economic activity: the DICE model uses a damage function, which
links atmospheric temperature with economic damages in a non-linear way. These damages reduce
GDP and, thus, consumption and economic welfare. The social cost of carbon represents the decline
in the discounted value of economic welfare caused by an increase in CO2 emissions by 1 tonne.
The rate that is used to discount economic welfare reflects social time preferences. The higher the
discount rate the lower the value assigned to damages that will be experienced by future generations.
Firms can reduce emissions, and thus climate damages, by undertaking mitigation activities.
However, mitigation has a cost: an increase in mitigation reduces the resources that are available
for consumption and conventional investment. Therefore, the social planner weighs off the cost of
mitigation against the benefit of reducing climate damages, and selects the optimal level of
mitigation that equalises the cost with the benefit. At this optimal level, the social cost of carbon is
equal to the incremental cost of mitigation. When the social cost of carbon is derived, based on this
cost-benefit analysis, it is considered to reflect the optimal carbon price and, if a carbon tax is
imposed, its value should be equal to this optimal price.2
2 Note that the carbon price derived by DICE and other IAMs is also compatible with cap-and-trade systems.
5
According to the most recent estimates that rely on the DICE model (Nordhaus, 2017), the optimal
carbon price for 2015 is $31 per tonne of CO2 in 2010 US$.3 Interestingly, such a price for carbon
derives a 3.5 degrees global warming at the end of this century, which is much higher than 1.5 or 2
degrees threshold that has been set by the Paris Agreement. However, within the IAM community
there is no consensus on what the right value for the optimal carbon price is. Many IAMs, which
have modified key assumptions in the DICE model, have estimated different optimal carbon prices,
which in most cases are higher compared to those estimated by Nordhaus. These higher estimates
can, for example, be the result of the incorporation of climate tipping points, the use of a lower
discount rate, the incorporation of a more pessimistic damage function, the assumption for a higher
climate sensitivity to the increase in carbon concentration, or the introduction of intra-region
inequality (see e.g. Botzen and van der Bergh, 2012; Lemoine and Traeger, 2014; Dennig et al.,
2015; Dietz and Stern, 2015; Espagne et al., 2018).
Other well-known POMs that have been used to estimate optimal carbon prices are FUND
(Anthoff and Tol, 2013), PAGE (Hope, 2011) and WITCH (Bosetti et al., 2006). FUND has a very
detailed analysis of damages since it includes damage functions for a variety of effects of climate
change, including the impact on health, agriculture, forestry, migration and water resources. It
analyses a large number of world regions and endogenises many GHG emissions, not only the
carbon dioxide ones, as is the case in DICE. However, the economic module in FUND is relatively
simple and economic growth is exogenous. The social cost of carbon is estimated by monetising
the welfare effects of climate change, including the value of life. PAGE is close to FUND in the
sense that economic growth is exogenous and different type of damages in different regions are
analysed. However, it is less complicated.4
6
explore the combined effects of carbon pricing and innovation policies, showing that innovation
policies can reinforce the positive environmental effects of carbon pricing (Bosetti et al., 2011).
It is important to point out that although the primary aim of POMs is to estimate the social cost of
carbon that corresponds to an optimal path, they have also been used to derive non-optimal paths.
For example, Nordhaus (2017) has himself calculated the social cost of carbon that would result in
no more than 2.5 degrees global warming. As expected, this social cost of carbon is much higher
than the one that is derived based on the optimal path.
Contrary to POMs, PEMS do not use cost-benefit analysis since they do not typically include
monetised damages from the environment. Generally speaking, they have a more detailed sectoral
representation and a more detailed analysis of the energy system and emissions. This allows them
to be employed for exploring how mitigation policies can affect different sectors of the economy,
as well as the use of energy and the generation of GHG emissions in a more comprehensive way.
This is why many PEMs have been used in the scenarios of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change (IPCC) (see Krey et al., 2014). Some well-known PEMs are the Economic Projection Policy
Analysis (EPPA) model (Chen et al., 2016), the Global Change Assessment Model (GCAM) (Shi et
al., 2017) and the Model for Energy Supply Strategy Alternatives and their General Environmental
impact model (MESSAGE) (Riahi et al., 2011).
The economic module of many IAMs (both POMs and PEMs) is often built based on CGE
(Computable General Equilibrium) modelling techniques. CGE models are multi-sector models in
which household and firms are assumed to maximise their utility and profits. In these models
product and factor markets are typically postulated to be competitive and clear through changes in
relative prices; the latter depend on the interaction between supply and demand. General
equilibrium is achieved when all markets are in equilibrium.5
CGE models have been employed to analyse the effects of a wide range of green fiscal policies,
including carbon taxes (e.g. Meng et al., 2013; Guo et al., 2014) and green subsidies or feed-in-tariffs
(e.g. Kalkuhl et al., 2013; Wei et al., 2019). Many studies that rely on CGE models have also paid
5For detailed discussions of the use of CGE models in the analysis of environmental policies, see Bergman (2005) and
Babatunde et al. (2017).
7
particular attention to the distributional effects of carbon taxes (and carbon pricing more general),
whereby a common finding is that carbon taxes are regressive. However, their adverse distributional
effects can be offset if the associated tax revenues are used to compensate poorer households (e.g.
Rausch et al., 2011; Liang and Wei, 2012).
In CGE models employment is determined via the interaction between labour supply and labour
demand. In these models, a policy mix that increases environmental taxes and reduces labour taxes
can increase employment, by raising both labour supply and labour demand, but it can also decrease
it because of the impact of environmental taxes on prices. If the labour market is assumed to be
perfect and no involuntary unemployment exists (which is the case in the vast majority of CGE
models), it is less likely that such a policy mix will have a favourable employment effect. Positive
employment effects become more likely when labour market is imperfect and involuntary
unemployment exists (World Bank, 2019).6
Now, a crucial question arises: can IAMs and CGE models provide an appropriate framework for
analysing environmental economic policies, including green fiscal policies? As the recent literature
on economy-environment modelling has emphasised, these approaches have several limitations.
Let us briefly refer to those of them that are more relevant for our analysis.7
First, in the vast majority of CGE models and IAMs it is assumed that economies function at full
capacity and full employment. This is at odds with reality: modern economies are characterised by
idle resources (see, for example, Chewpreecha et al., 2017), which means that an increase in
aggregate demand always causes an increase in GDP.8 In the standard IAMs and CGE models, this
is not the case: if, for example, public green investment demand increases, the creation of new jobs
should be accompanied by an equivalent reduction in jobs in other sectors of the economy.
Although there are IAMs or CGE models in which involuntary unemployment is introduced (as
mentioned above), aggregate demand still plays a negligible role.
6 For a CGE model that permits imperfections in the labour market, see Capros et al. (2013).
7 For a detailed discussion of additional issues see, among others, Scrieciu et al. (2013), Farmer et al. (2015), van den
Bergh and Botzen (2015) and Pollitt and Mercure (2017).
8 Of course, the magnitude of this effect on GDP depends on some potential capacity constraints that have to do, for
8
The lack of a role for aggregate demand is important for an additional reason. Climate damages are
likely to affect consumption and investment demand significantly and hence GDP (Batten, 2018;
and Dafermos et al., 2017, 2018). For example, in areas in which there will be a secular increase in
the severity and frequency of climate-related events, firms might be less willing to invest is physical
assets and households might increase their propensity to save. Without an explicit analysis of
demand, these effects cannot be examined.
Second, the way that mitigation is modelled in CGE models and IAMs, is problematic. Mitigation
in these models is considered to constitute only a cost. This violates the Keynesian principle that
one person’s spending is another person’s income. For example, if a company buys some solar
panels to reduce its carbon emissions, the spending on these panels will be an inflow for the
company that produces the panels. This spending contributes to GDP and cannot be considered
only as a cost. It is also problematic that green capital that is built via mitigation spending does not
contribute to future GDP. Taking into account that mitigation can have a positive contribution to
GDP would call into question the whole rationale of cost-benefit analysis.
Third, money in these models is not created endogenously as is the case in the real-world financial
systems (see Arestis and Sawyer, 2006; McLeay et al., 2014). The financial system, if it appears in
the models, plays merely an intermediary role. A direct implication is that environment-related
spending (of the private or the public sector) always crowds-out other types of investment spending
or leads to lower consumption. This is because credit cannot expand to support investment; prior
savings can only fund the latter. This means that the possibility that climate policies are
expansionary is ruled out (Pollitt and Mercure, 2017). Moreover, the expansion of green private
investment is restricted since firms cannot acquire credit created out of ‘thin air’. This is highly
important as an assumption, given that credit can be a very crucial source of funding for green
investments, like those linked to renewables, which tend to have high upfront costs.
The way that money and the financial system are treated in CGE models and IAMs has additional
implications. In particular, it makes it very difficult to analyse the financial stability effects of climate
change. As has been extensively discussed in the recent literature on climate-related financial risks
(e.g. Scott et al., 2017), climate policies and climate change can lead to defaults and asset price
deflation, disrupting the credit provision process through interconnected balance sheets. The
9
effects cannot be properly explored in CGE models and IAMs. Moreover, these models are not
suitable for the analysis of the effects of environmental financial policies that have been recently
suggested, and whose aim is to reallocate credit and funds from brown investment towards green
investment (Campiglio, 2016; Volz, 2017; Campiglio et al., 2018; D’Orazio and Popoyan, 2019).
Fourth, most IAMs and CGE models rely on the idea that the agents have a common understanding
of the way that the economy works (which is captured by the model that is used by economists)
and they know the data-generating process about the economy, which follows a pre-determined
probability distribution. However, in reality fundamental uncertainty exists (Davidson, 1991, 2002;
Fontana and Gerrard, 2004). The future path of the economy is unknown and unknowable, which
stems from the fact that this path is determined based on the decisions of people today, which
cannot be known by definition.9 Consequently, in their decision-making process, agents follow
norms and rules of thumb in line with the concept of ‘procedural’ rationality (Lavoie, 2014, chapter
2). Within that context, an ‘optimal’ path cannot be by definition identified. Needless to say, the
importance of fundamental uncertainty is reinforced when the uncertainties about environmental
issues are taken into account.10
Fifth, the idea of analysing the environmental problems simply as externalities, whose value can be
priced, raises many questions. In practice, these prices are estimated using methodologies that often
rely on subjective valuations of life and pollution, which cannot reflect the intrinsic value of nature
and the actual social cost of environmental degradation (Neuteleers and Engelen, 2015; Berger,
2017). In addition, according to the tradition of ecological economics, the environmental problems
should not be viewed as side effects of economic activity. Instead, the economy should be analysed
as a sub-system of the wider ecosystem (Daly and Farley, 2011). An implication of this is that the
stability of the ecosystem is a prerequisite for a stable society and economy. If the prices imposed
on ‘externalities’ are not enough to prevent severe ecological disruptions, the economy will be
destabilised as well. IAMs take implicitly that into account when they analyse, for example, how a
higher than 2 degrees global warming can be prevented, instead of using cost-benefit analysis (which
9 This, in particular, relies on the concept of ‘ontological’ uncertainty, which is one of the two forms of fundamental
uncertainty, the other one being ‘epistemological’ uncertainty. For the differences between ontological and
epistemological uncertainty see Lavoie (2014, chapter 2).
10 See, for example, Aldred (2012) on the importance of climate change uncertainty and its links with fundamental
uncertainty à la Keynes.
10
is the case in PEMs). However, IAMs and CGE models do not generally adopt a systems approach
that could explicitly examine how the dynamic interactions between the ecosystem and the
economic system could result in instability and collapse.
Over recent years, alternative models have been developed, which do not suffer from most of the
above-mentioned problems. The majority of these models draw on the post-Keynesian tradition
and they thereby postulate that output is demand-determined, money is created endogenously,
finance plays a non-neutral role, economies do not operate at equilibrium and agents take decisions
based on rules of thumb and norms. A few of these models also rely on agent-based methodologies,
which provide an alternative to the representative agent approach of most IAMs (Lamperti et al.,
2018).
Some of these heterodox macro models have recently been employed to examine the effects of
green fiscal policies. Monasterolo and Raberto (2018) have explored the impact of green subsidies
using a stock-flow consistent (SFC) model.11 Their model does not include an environmental or
climate module, but it has a detailed economic module in which an explicit distinction is made
between green and brown capital. In their scenarios, subsidies are funded via sovereign green bonds
or taxes. Their results show that green subsidies have a positive impact on green investment.
However, the effects on employment and total capital accumulation depend on the type of funding.
If green subsidies are funded via taxes, the economic effects are negative since taxation reduces
disposable income. If, on the other hand, sovereign bonds are issued to finance green subsidies,
employment and capital accumulation increase; however, in this scenario public indebtedness also
increases. Monasterolo and Raberto (2019) have used an extended version of this model to examine
the implications of phasing out fossil fuel subsidies. In their simulations, a smooth phasing out of
these subsidies not only increases green investment, but also improves macroeconomic
performance.
Godin (2012) has developed an SFC model that analyses the implications of a green employer of
last resort (ELR) programme. According to this programme, all those who are unemployed do not
receive unemployment benefits, but work instead in green jobs in the public sector. The simulation
For the stock-flow consistent approach to macroeconomic modelling, see Godley and Lavoie (2012), Caverzasi and
11
11
analysis shows that such a programme can reduce both private unemployment and energy
consumption.
D’Alessandro et al. (2018) have built a post-Keynesian model for the French economy, which is
used to conduct projections for a variety of environmental policies. These policies include a carbon
tax and a jobs guarantee programme that incorporates green jobs. In their simulations, carbon taxes
do not have a very significant environmental effect because only a relatively small amount of
emissions is affected by these taxes. The jobs guarantee programme has a positive effect on
employment, but it also increases the fiscal deficit.
Bovari et al. (2018) have developed an SFC model in which a climate module à la DICE is
incorporated. They analyse the effects of carbon taxes and green subsidies. Although carbon taxes
have a beneficial effect on the path of atmospheric temperature, they decrease corporate profits,
increasing thereby firms’ reliance on private debt. When carbon taxes are implemented in
combination with green subsidies, the reduction in atmospheric temperature is reinforced and the
rise in private indebtedness is less severe. However, green subsidies cause a rise in public
indebtedness.
Mercure et al. (2018) have used a large-scale global post-Keynesian macro-econometric model to
analyse the effects of a wide range of climate policies, including green fiscal policies. They examine
policies such as feed-in tariffs, subsidies for renewables and heating systems, carbon prices and fuel
taxes. Their model also includes a climate module and the role of technology diffusion. Their results
show that the combination of such policies can significantly reduce the pace of global warming.
The economic effects of these policies are both positive and negative. On the one hand, electricity
prices go up, reducing the real disposable income of households and slowing thereby economic
activity. On the other hand, green public investment increases employment and household income.
The impact on fiscal balances is typically positive since revenues from taxes are higher than the
expenditures in each region of the world. The impact on trade balance varies. Regions that produce
fossil fuels are adversely affected since their exports decline, while in regions in which fossil fuels
are imported the impact is positive since their imports go down.
12
Deleidi et al. (2019) have investigated the way that government spending on both green innovation
and green capital can affect ecological sustainability, using an SFC model. Their simulation analysis
shows that this type of spending has positive effects on making the use of energy and matter more
efficient, slowing down climate change and the depletion of energy and material resources.
Although the above-mentioned studies have examined various aspects of green fiscal policies from
a post-Keynesian perspective, they have not systematically compared carbon taxes with other types
of green fiscal policies (including green public investment) with explicit reference to their combined
effects on the economic, financial and environmental variables. In what follows we provide such a
comparative evaluation using the DEFINE (Dynamic Ecosystem-FINance-Economy) model
developed by Dafermos et al. (2017, 2018). This model serves our purposes because it combines
aspects of post-Keynesian and ecological economics and pays particular attention to the interactions
between the ecosystem, the financial system and the macroeconomy. The aim of our analysis is to
open the avenue for a more systematic examination of the links between fiscal policy and ecological
sustainability in heterodox macroeconomics.
The DEFINE model portrays the economy as a subsystem of the broader ecosystem. The economy
uses material and energy resources from the environment on a continuous basis. Production leads
to the generation of waste (such as hazardous solid waste and carbon emissions), which causes the
degradation of the ecosystem. This degradation has feedback effects on humans and the function
of the macroeconomy and the financial system. These negative effects include, for example, (i) the
destruction of capital stock due to climate-related events (like floods and hurricanes); (ii) global
warming-related reductions in labour productivity; (iii) the negative impact of hazardous waste on
the health of the population and the ability of people to work; and (iv) the adverse impact of climate
damages on economic units’ expectations that affect their consumption and investment decisions.
These effects can worsen the financial position of households and firms and can result in financial
instability via a large number of feedback loops related primarily with the process through which
credit is provided via banks and the bond market.
13
The way that energy and matter are analysed draws on the tradition of Georgescu-Roegen (1971).
The model uses material flow analysis, which ensures a consistent representation of material flows
in and out the socio-economic system, in line with the First Law of Thermodynamics (according to
which matter and energy are not created or destroyed). Special emphasis is placed on the interaction
between material extraction, recycling and the generation of waste. The model reports how waste
is accumulated and pays particular attention to the potential emergence of matter depletion
problems. The model also captures a key implication of the Second Law of Thermodynamics: as
fossil fuels are burned, low-entropy energy is transformed into high-entropy energy. The model
shows the dynamic evolution of the stock of fossil-fuel energy in order to capture the depletion of
low-entropy energy.12
Carbon emissions are generated when non-renewable energy is produced. These carbon emissions
contribute to the accumulation of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere. This build-up of carbon leads
to higher radiative forcing, which expresses the difference between the solar energy absorbed by
the Earth and the energy that is radiated back to the outer space. In turn, the rise in radiative forcing
causes an increase in atmospheric temperature.
The way that the macroeconomy and the financial system are analysed is broadly in line with the
SFC literature. For example, (i) all financial inflows correspond to financial outflows and all financial
assets correspond to financial liabilities; (ii) the interaction between financial stocks and flows are
explicitly modelled and the accumulation of private debt can have important negative feedback
effects on macroeconomic and financial stability; and (iii) money is endogenously created when
loans are provided.
Some key features of the model that differentiate it from the majority of previous SFC models are
the following. First, banks do not provide credit in a passive way. There is an explicit credit rationing
procedure: banks reject a proportion of the loan applications or provide a lower amount of loans
than those that are demanded by the potential borrowers. Banks decide about the level of credit
rationing based on both their own financial position and the financial position of their potential
12For a discussion of the First and the Second Law of Thermodynamics and their implications for economics, see Daly
and Farley (2011).
14
borrowers. Lending interest rates are also endogenous; apart from being affected by central bank
decisions, they also tend to increase when banks’ financial position deteriorates.
Second, although output is demand-determined, supply constraints are also taken into account. This
is crucial because environmental degradation, captured for example by climate change, is very likely
to have significant supply-side effects, since it can reduce labour/capital productivity and labour
force, and it can also destroy a large proportion of capital stock. In addition, the model uses a
Leontief-type production function whereby energy and matter are essential for the production
process. Thus, a potential depletion of energy and material reserves can restrict economic activity.
DEFINE consists of two big blocks. The first block is the ecosystem block, which includes
equations about (i) matter, recycling and waste, (ii) energy, (iii) emissions and climate change and
(iv) ecological efficiency and technology. This block is built around a physical flow matrix and a
physical stock-flow matrix that allow us to track explicitly the evolution of material and energy flows
and stocks that play a key role for the stability of the ecosystem. The evolution of these physical
stocks and flows is affected by human activity in both a negative and a positive way. On the one
hand, higher economic activity leads to the accumulation of stocks that degrade the ecosystem (like
carbon concentration and hazardous waste stock) and the depletion of useful resources. On the
other hand, green technical progress can attenuate the adverse environmental impact per unit of
GDP.
The second block is the macroeconomy and financial system block, which includes equations about
(i) output determination, (ii) firms, (iii) households, (iii) banks, (iv) the government sector and (v)
the central banks. This block is represented by the transactions flow matrix and the balance sheet
matrix, as is the case in SFC models. Firms invest in conventional and green capital by using retained
profits, loans and bonds. Commercial banks accumulate capital and distribute part of their profits
15
to households. Firms can default on these loans. When this happens, there is an adverse effect on
the capital of banks. In addition, firms can receive funding via the bond market. Households receive
labour income, buy durable consumption goods and accumulate wealth in the form of deposits,
corporate bonds and government securities (there are no household loans). Corporate bonds can
be either green or conventional. When the demand for green bonds increases, the price of these
bonds tends to go up, leading to a lower cost of borrowing for green projects.
Central banks determine the base interest rate; they also provide liquidity to commercial banks and
purchase government securities and corporate bonds. The government sector collects taxes
(including carbon taxes), decides about the level of government consumption and government
investment (the latter can be green or conventional) and can implement bailout programmes, if
there are financial problems in the banking sector.
In what follows, we use the new version of the model, DEFINE 1.1. Compared to DEFINE 1.0,
the latter version has various additional features that have to do with the role of fiscal and financial
policies. The new features that are relevant for our analysis here are the following. First, carbon
taxes are explicitly incorporated, which means that firms have to pay taxes based on the carbon
emissions that they generate. The implication of this is that carbon taxes reduce the profitability of
the firm sector. Since investment depends on profits, carbon taxes have an adverse effect on
economic activity and accumulation of capital. Note that the adverse effect on economic activity is
magnified by the fact that lower profitability also reduces loan provision. However, the adverse
effect of carbon taxes on firms’ profitability induces them to replace conventional investment with
green investment. This tends to reduce carbon emissions.
Second, the government sector covers a proportion of green private investment spending via green
subsidies. This has the opposite effect on profitability compared to carbon taxes. This policy also
incentivises firms to invest more in green capital.
Third, the government sector undertakes public investment, which can be either green or
conventional. As a result of this investment, public capital is accumulated. The evolution of green
public capital compared to conventional capital affects ecological efficiency. For example, the
building of public electricity grids can increase the use of renewables and improve energy efficiency.
16
In the model, the decision of the government about the level of green investment is exogenously
determined based on its policy priorities. In addition, the government decides about the level of its
green and conventional investment separately.
We have made the simplifying assumption that the government decides about this spending without
taking into account the potential effects on public debt. We have assumed so because we wish to
focus on the implications of green government spending, instead of exploring the drivers of fiscal
decisions, which are quite complex, differ around the world and depend significantly on political
factors.
Fourth, the firm sector has been disaggregated into four broad sectors (‘mining and utilities’,
‘manufacturing and construction’, ‘transport’ and ‘other sectors’)13 whose conventional capital stock
is assumed to have a different ‘degree of brownness’. This degree of brownness is proxied by the
carbon dioxide emissions that each sector produces compared to its gross value added. Hence, the
higher this value, the higher the brownness of the capital of the sector, and the larger thereby the
adverse environmental effect of the conventional investment of this sector.
A detailed description of these extensions as well as an analysis of all the equations of the model
and its technical details can be found on the website of the model.14 The website also includes
information about the data that has been used to calibrate the model and estimate some of its key
behavioural equations. Our econometric estimations rely on panel data for a large number of
countries and refer to (i) the consumption function, according to which the spending of households
depends on their disposable income and financial wealth; (ii) the investment equation which
portrays the investment of firms as a function of the profit rate, the rate of capacity utilisation and
the unemployment rate; (iii) the labour productivity function whereby labour productivity depends
on the growth rate of output in line with the Kaldor-Verdoorn law; (iv) the credit rationing function,
13 This disaggregation relies on ISIC (International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities) rev.
3.1. The ‘mining and utilities’ sector includes ISIC C (‘mining and quarrying’) and ISIC E (‘electricity, gas and water
supply’), the ‘manufacturing and construction’ sector includes ISIC D (‘manufacturing’) and ISIC F (‘construction’),
the ‘transport’ sector corresponds to ISIC I (‘transport, storage and communications’) and the ‘other sectors’ include
ISIC A, B, G, H and J-P.
14 Available at: www.define-model.org
17
which is indirectly estimated via an econometric equation that refers to the determinants of
corporate loan growth; and (v) the equation about the endogenous spread on corporate loans.
The evaluation of policies in DEFINE does not rely on any cost-benefit analysis, despite the fact
that damages are taken into account. Mitigation, which takes the form of green investment, does
not represent just a cost, as in traditional IAMs. Instead, green investment contributes to GDP and
is not necessarily financed by prior savings; it can also be financed by newly created public or private
debt. This is not in line with the rationale of the cost-benefit analysis used by IAMs.
In DEFINE we, instead, adopt a systems approach. Policies are evaluated based on their ability to
achieve high well-being in a way that does not cause a collapse of the highly interconnected
macroeconomic, financial and ecological systems (in both the short run and the long run). In other
words, when the model is used for policy analysis, the purpose is to identify a mix of policies that
permits the socio-economic system to function within the environmental limits and achieve the
highest possible welfare.
The model is run for the period 2017-2120. The reason why such a long period has been selected
is because we wish to evaluate how green fiscal policy could alter the long-run trends in key
environmental variables (and the feedback effects of these trends on the stability of the economic
and financial systems). We first develop a baseline scenario for this period. In this scenario, the
global economy continues to expand in broad line with recent trends and ecological efficiency
improves slowly, due to green technical progress and some moderate mitigation action. However,
this action is not enough to avoid a significant rise in atmospheric temperature by the end of this
century.
Table 1 describes the main features of this scenario. The economy grows on average at a rate close
to 2.5% until 2050; in other words, we postulate an economic expansion a little bit slower than the
one observed over the last two decades or so. Crucially, economic growth has a declining trend,
partially because of demographic changes. In 2050 population becomes equal to about 9.77 billion
people (based on United Nations, 2017). The unemployment rate remains, on average, slightly lower
18
than 6% until 2050. Moreover, the default rate on corporate loans is assumed to remain, on average,
close to its current level, which is slightly higher than 4%.
Variable Value/trend
Economic growth till 2050 Approximately 2.5% (on average)
Unemployment rate till 2050 Slightly lower than 6% (on average)
Population in 2050 9.77 billion
Labour force-to-population ratio in 2050 0.45
Default rate on corporate loans till 2050 Slightly higher than 4% (on average)
Carbon tax Increases by 3% per year
Green public investment Remains stable as a proportion of GDP
Green subsidies Remain stable as a proportion of green investment
CO2 intensity in 2050 as a ratio of CO 2 intensity in 2017 Around 0.9
Share of renewable energy in total energy in 2050 Around 25%
Energy intensity in 2050 as a ratio of energy intensity in 2017 Around 0.7
Annual total green investment in the period 2017-2050 Around US$ 1.5 trillion
Yield of conventional bonds Quite stable till around 2050
Yield of green bonds Declines slightly in the next decade or so
In terms of environmental policies, the carbon tax is assumed to increase by 3% per year. In our
model, the carbon tax has been calibrated to US$ 1 per tonne of CO2 in 2017. This is derived by
dividing the global total revenue from carbon taxes (available from World Bank, 2018) by the total
industrial carbon emissions. This figure is relatively low since in reality only a small proportion of
carbon emissions (about 20%) is taxed (World Bank, 2018), while in our model all the industrial
emissions are taxed. Thus, the carbon tax should be low enough in our simulations in order for the
value of carbon tax revenues in our model to match the data for 2017.
The subsidy rate on green investment remains unchanged, close to 28% according to our calibration
for 2017. Green public investment increases, but remains constant as a proportion of GDP. For
2017, this has been calibrated at about 0.25%. It is implicitly assumed that environmental regulation
becomes gradually stricter, contributing to the moderate rise in green investment as a proportion
of conventional investment. Overall, annual total (private and public) green investment during the
period 2017-2050 is equal to around US$ 1.5 trillion.15
15Note that in the reference scenario of IRENA (2018, p. 41) the annual investment in renewables and energy efficiency
over the period 2015-2050 is close to US$ 1.3 trillion. Recall that green investment in our model does not only include
19
The accumulation of green capital leads to an improvement in ecological efficiency indicators. The
share of renewable energy increases to about 25% until 2050 (from about 14%, which is the current
level), while energy intensity is assumed to become approximately 30% lower in 2050 compared to
its 2017 level. Material intensity and recycling rate also improve moderately.
We also assume that the yield on conventional bonds remains relatively stable until 2050, while the
yield of green bonds improves in the next decade or so. The latter is a result of an increasing demand
for green bonds that outstrips their supply, in line with recent trends (Climate Bonds Initiative,
2017, 2018a, 2018b).
Figure 1 illustrates how some key variables of the ecosystem, the financial system and the
macroeconomy evolve under our baseline scenario. Since the rise in green investment is moderate
(see Figure 1b, which refers to the desired investment in the ‘mining and utilities’ sector), the share
of renewable energy does not increase sufficiently by the end of the century (Figure 1c). The
improvement in energy efficiency is also moderate (not shown in the figure). This fact, combined
with the continuous rise in GDP (Figure 1a), results in a continuous rise in carbon emissions in the
next 4-5 decades (Figure 1d) that ultimately leads to an increase in atmospheric temperature by
about 3.8oC (compared the pre-industrial levels) in 2100 (Figure 1e).
Global warming has adverse effects on the economy and the financial system. There is a long-run
decline in the profitability of firms (Figure 1f), which is driven both by the climate-related
destruction of capital and the fall in aggregate demand due to climate change. This decline becomes
more pronounced once the 2 degrees threshold is passed, at the mid of this century. The fall in
profitability triggers liquidity problems that cause a rise in the default rate on corporate loans (Figure
1g). Consequently, the capital of banks is hurt and their capital adequacy ratio follows a downward
trend (Figure 1h). At some point, bank capital is not enough in order for banks to comply with the
minimum capital requirements, so the government sector steps in and bailouts the banking sector.
investment in renewables and energy efficiency; it also includes investment that improves material intensity and the
recycling rate.
20
Bank bailouts have an adverse effect on the public debt-to-output ratio (Figure 1i). However, this
is not the only reason why public indebtedness deteriorates. Public indebtedness primarily goes up
because of the decline in economic activity that reduces tax revenues. Note that in our model we
have not incorporated the financing of adaptation measures to climate change. If this were the case,
the adverse impact of climate change on public indebtedness would be magnified.
Climate change is not the only environmental issue. The combination of continuous economic
expansion with an insufficient improvement in material efficiency and recycling leads to a
continuous rise in the waste produced by the socio-economic system (Figure 1l). This has negative
feedback effects on the health of the population since a proportion of this waste is hazardous and
can lead to chronic diseases. These diseases reduce the ability of people to work, inducing a fall in
labour force.
We now examine how the above mentioned trends could be modified if different types of green
fiscal policies are introduced at the global level in 2022. The green fiscal policies that we analyse are
the following:
▪ Carbon tax: The carbon tax increases to US$ 16 per tonne of CO2 in 2022 and grows by 3% per
year thereafter. The increase in carbon tax to US$ 16 per tonne of CO2 in 2022 corresponds to
a carbon tax of US$ 80 per tonne of CO2, if the latter is imposed only on those emissions that
are currently covered by carbon pricing schemes (20% of total emissions). Note that US$ 80 per
tonne of CO2 is the upper limit for the carbon price suggested by High-Level Commission on
Carbon Prices (2017) for 2020.
▪ Green public subsidies: The green subsidies provided by the government increases from 28% to
60% as a proportion of green investment in 2022 and remain constant thereafter.
▪ Green public investment: The green investment of the government increases from 0.25% to 1% (as
a proportion of GDP) in 2022 and remains constant thereafter.
Note that each one of these policies corresponds to US$ 0.6-0.7 trillion. This amount is either the
increase in government revenues (in the case of carbon tax) or the increase in government spending
(in the case of green subsidies or green public investment) after the introduction of the policies.
21
The effects are shown in Figure 1. Let us first focus on the impact of a rise in carbon tax. This rise
has a direct adverse effect on the profitability of firms (Figure 1f): since they cannot directly cut
carbon emissions substantially, they have to pay a significant amount of money in the form of taxes,
which causes a fall in profits. This has various implications for macroeconomic performance and
financial stability.
To begin with, since firms have fewer profits, they cut their desired investment and their access to
finance is distorted. The latter happens because lower profits increase the debt service ratio of firms,
and this makes banks less willing to approve applications for corporate loans. The decline in desired
investment, in conjunction with the increase in credit rationing, triggers an overall decline in private
investment. Consequently, economic activity slows down (Figure 1a) and the unemployment rate
increases significantly (Figure 1j). Moreover, lower profitability deteriorates the liquidity position of
firms, causing a rise in the default rate, which affects adversely the stability of the financial system.
Therefore, in our simulations the increase in carbon tax increases the so-called climate-related
transition financial risks. In the related literature (e.g. Scott et al., 2017), these risks refer, among
others, to the adverse impact that an abrupt implementation of climate policies could have on the
financial system.16
However, these risks are not confined to the direct negative effect of a higher carbon tax on loan
defaults. The interaction between the macroeconomy and the financial system generates second-
round effects that exacerbate these risks and influence the evolution of macroeconomic activity. In
particular, as the default rate remains high, the capital adequacy ratio of banks declines. Since banks
have less capital, the cut in lending is reinforced.17 This keeps economic growth at a low level for a
prolonged period, magnifying financial instability.
16 Other causes of climate-related transition financial risks include rapid green technical progress that might render
carbon-intensive assets unprofitable and abrupt changes in environmental preferences.
17 Note that the effect of bank capital on bank lending, which is incorporated explicitly in our model, is in line with the
recent empirical literature. The latter shows that changes in the capital adequacy ratio affect loan supply (see e.g. Aiyar
et al., 2016; Gambacorta and Shin, 2018).
22
Fig. 1: Effects of carbon tax, green subsidy and green public investment policies, selected variables
(a) Growth rate of output (b) Share of desired green investment in total
investment, mining and utilities
23
(continued from the previous page)
Note: The figure reports across-run averages from 200 Monte Carlo simulations. The values used in the baseline scenario are available
at www.define-model.org. All policy shocks take place in 2022. Under ‘carbon tax’, the tax on total carbon emissions increases to
$16/tCO2 and grows at 3% thereafter. Under ‘green subsidy’, the subsidies as a proportion of green investment increase to 60%. Under
‘green public investment’, green public investment increases to 1%, as a proportion of GDP.
24
This higher financial instability is reflected, more precisely, in two developments. First, the capital
adequacy ratio of banks continues to decline for many years, reaching the minimum level required
by regulatory authorities (which in our simulations is assumed to be 8%). This induces the
government sector to bailout banks. Second, lower macroeconomic activity reduces the financial
wealth of households and, hence, their demand for corporate bonds goes down. The overall result
is that the price of corporate bonds declines, causing an increase in the yield of bonds, which affects
the cost of borrowing for firms (not shown in the figure). Thus, we overall have that in our
simulations the sudden increase in carbon tax brings about a kind of climate Minsky moment that has
prolonged adverse effects on the economy.18
These effects of the rise in carbon tax have an additional important implication. The conventional
wisdom is that such a rise benefits public indebtedness because it increases tax revenues. The
argument is that, if these revenues are not ‘recycled’, the government deficit goes down and this
can improve the financial position of the government. However, this conventional wisdom ignores
the aggregate demand and financial effects of carbon taxes, described above. These effects make
carbon taxes have adverse implications for the long-run financial position of the government. In
particular, in our simulations the increase in the carbon tax initially reduces the public deficit, as
expected by the conventional wisdom (not shown in the figure). However, the reduction in
aggregate demand, amplified by the adverse financial conditions, reduces the revenues that the
government receives from taxes. Hence, the deficit gradually gets back to its initial level. At some
point, the contractionary effects make the public debt-to-output ratio higher than its value in the
baseline scenario (see Figure 1i).
The carbon tax-induced stagnation does not continue forever. The increase in carbon tax
incentivises firms to invest more in green capital and reduce their brown investment. This is
reflected in the rise of the share of desired green investment in total investment. Figure 1b shows
how this share in the ‘mining and utilities’ sector increases due to the increase in the carbon tax. A
similar increase takes place in other sectors, generating an improvement in the use of renewables
(Figure 1c) and a decline in energy efficiency (not shown in the figure).
25
As a result, carbon emissions go down and, hence, firms have gradually to pay less carbon taxes.
This improves their profitability and liquidity position, producing an increase in desired investment
and loan supply. These positive economic developments are reinforced by the fact that the
prolonged stagnation has declined the level of private debt, making firms and banks more willing
to participate in new debt contracts that stimulate economic activity. Hence, although the increase
in carbon tax triggers important contractionary effects, these effects are gradually faded away and
economic growth bounces back.
How about the impact of the increase in carbon taxes on the environment? As alluded to above, an
important implication of this policy is that firms start reducing their carbon emissions since they
now have to pay more for the adverse environmental impact of their activity. However, the decline
in emissions is not only caused by the change in firms’ investment mix. Quite ironically, the
contractionary effects of carbon taxes also drive this decline; this is so since economic activity slows
down, and, thus, the emissions that the economy generates decline too. Hence, a more integrated
approach to the environmental effects of carbon taxes needs to take explicitly into account the
adverse impact that such taxes might have on economic activity.
The reduction in carbon emissions, compared to the baseline scenario, slows down global warming.
However, atmospheric temperature is still high at the end of this century (close to 3.5oC according
to Figure 1e). A higher decline in global warming would be possible by imposing a higher carbon
tax. However, the side effect of doing so would be an even higher decline in economic activity in
the first years after the introduction of a stricter carbon tax policy.
Importantly, other environmental variables are also positively influenced by the rise in carbon tax.
The induced increase in green investment, in combination with the reduction in economic activity,
leads to a lower extraction of matter for production purposes. Hence, the depletion of material
reserves slows down, compared to the baseline scenario (Figure 1k). The waste per capita that is
generated by the socio-economic system is also reduced (Figure 1l).
However, the overall restriction of environmental problems is not sufficient to prevent a new round
of severe economic and financial problems. This time the physical effects of climate change
primarily cause these problems, as it was the case in the baseline scenario. Climate damages increase
26
the default rate of firms (Figure 1g), reinforcing the under-capitalisation of banks (Figure 1h). At
some point, the economy somehow recovers once debt levels have fallen sufficiently and credit
expansion slightly bounces back. However, since this economy is constantly hit by climate shocks,
it is not possible for the default rate to get back to levels that ensure financial stability. Therefore,
climate-induced financial volatility becomes the new norm.
Overall, the increase in carbon tax in our model initiates a process that generates two long cycles in
which climate and financial factors interact. The first cycle is induced by a partial transition to a
low-carbon economy that takes place via the increase in carbon taxes. The carbon tax-related
stagnation lasts until carbon emissions and private debt decline sufficiently. However, relatively
shortly after the recovery of the economy a new cycle begins. This cycle starts because of the
physical effects of climate change that bring the economy into a period of constant volatility.
Next, we turn to the impact of green subsidies. The rise in the green subsidy rate has quite the
opposite effects compared to those of carbon taxes: since firms now receive money from the
government, their profitability and liquidity increases. Hence, all those macrofinancial dynamic
interactions described in the case of carbon taxes now work in the opposite direction, leading to an
increase in economic activity (Figure 1a), a fall in unemployment (Figure 1j), a decline in loan
defaults (Figure 1g) and an improvement in the financial position of banks (Figure 1h). This implies
that green subsidies do not pose transition risks to the financial system. Quite the contrary: they
improve financial stability.
However, do they harm the financial position of the government? As shown in Figure 1i, the public
debt-to-GDP ratio does not increase, compared to the baseline scenario. Actually, after a few years
it becomes lower than what it was the case in the baseline scenario. This is due to the positive
expansionary effects of this policy on growth and thus on tax revenues. Hence, the impact of higher
green subsidies on public indebtedness should not be the primary concern for those policy makers
worrying about the government financial position.
Of particular interest are the environmental effects of green subsidies. As in the case of carbon
taxes, green subsidies motivate firms to invest more in green capital. Hence, there is a reduction in
atmospheric temperature (see Figure 1e). This improvement in temperature is higher in comparison
27
with the carbon taxes scenario. This is so basically because the green subsidy policy (i) affects green
investment in all sectors (not only in the sectors that produce the majority of carbon emissions) and
(ii) has a positive impact on green credit availability.
One would might expect an even higher reduction in atmospheric temperature. However, this is
not the case because of the macroeconomic rebound effect that refers to the adverse environmental
impact of the increase in macroeconomic activity.19 In other words, although green subsidies reduce
the carbon emissions per GDP, the rise in GDP weakens the decline in these emissions. Moreover,
the rise in green subsidies leads to a higher material depletion ratio and a higher generation of waste
in the long run, compared to the baseline scenario (see Figures 1k and 1l, respectively).
We now consider the impact of an increase in public green investment. As in the case of green
subsidies, such an increase leads to more economic activity (Figure 1a). Note that green public
investment affects directly GDP; the government sector builds infrastructure by demanding directly
investment goods produced by the private sector. On the contrary, when green subsidies are
provided, the impact on investment is indirect (via the profitability of firms). Moreover, ecological
efficiency now improves without observing an increase in the share of desired green private
investment in total private investment (Figure 1b). This improvement in ecological efficiency stems
now directly from the increase in green public capital. Actually, it is interesting that the share of
desired green investment in the ‘mining and utilities’ sector goes down. This happens because the
reduction in overall carbon emissions (due to green public infrastructure) makes this sector pay less
carbon taxes, and thus disincentivises it to undertake more green investment.
As in the scenario of green subsidies, the increase in economic activity is not beneficial to the
environment. The decline in atmospheric temperature is less impressive than one would might
expect (Figure 1e). In addition, as shown in Figure 1k and Figure 1l, the high economic growth
caused by the increase in public green investment amplifies the material depletion and waste
generation problems. Therefore, although an increase in public investment appears to be an
19For a description of the rebound effects, see Barker et al. (2009). Our analysis captures the macroeconomic aspects
of these rebound effects since a rise in investment induced by a climate policy leads to higher economic activity that
results in a rise in carbon emissions, waste and the use of energy and matter.
28
attractive policy in terms of economic and employment effects, it does not have very strong effects
on improving environmental sustainability, when it is implemented in isolation.
As is clear from Figure 1, the rebound effects on green public investment should be of a much
larger concern than any effects on public indebtedness. Actually, the higher economic growth
caused by the rise in green public investment reduces after some years the public debt-to-GDP
ratio, compared to the baseline scenario (similarly to what happens when the green subsidies
increase).
Table 2 summarises the main similarities and differences between the effects of all green fiscal
policies described above. A common feature of all these policies is that they reduce global warming.
In the case of green subsidies and green public investment, this happens primarily because of the
rise in green investment compared to conventional investment. In the case of carbon taxes, the
reduction in global warming is also caused by the slowdown that it causes to the global economy.
Since all these policies reduce the pace of climate change, they also reduce the climate-related
physical financial risks.
Table 2: Key similarities and differences between the effects of the three green fiscal policies
Both green subsidies and green public investment policies stimulate economic activity. This is
beneficial to the economy, but has adverse effects on the environment due to the macroeconomic
rebound effects described above. On the contrary, the carbon tax policy hits the profitability of
firms and, thus, the transition to a low-carbon economy is accompanied by financial instability and
29
a deterioration in macroeconomic performance. A side effect of this is that public indebtedness
increases. This is not the case under the policies of green subsidies and green public investment:
their positive economic and financial effects cause a decline in public indebtedness, compared to
the baseline scenario.
We now ask what the effects are of a combined implementation of all the above-mentioned policies.
Figure 2 shows that this fiscal policy mix has several advantages. First, the combined
implementation of the three policies represents a very large positive economic shock, which affects
the economy on a constant basis. The contractionary effects of a higher carbon tax are
overcompensated by the expansionary effects of the green subsidy and green public investment
policies. Thus, economic growth increases (Figure 2a) and unemployment declines substantially
(Figure 2j). Note that the stimulating effect of the shock continuously increases since, as time passes,
private green investment goes up (and thus green subsidies) and carbon emissions go down (and
thus carbon taxes). Second, the boost in green investment is now much stronger, producing a
pronounced improvement of ecological efficiency indicators. For example, the share of renewable
energy increases much more rapidly by the mid of this century (Figure 2c). Consequently, there is a
significant decline in carbon emissions (Figure 2d) that restricts the rise in atmospheric temperature
to about 2.6oC by the end of this century (Figure 2e). Third, the lower pace of climate change makes
the climate damages much less pronounced. This, in conjunction with the rise in economic activity,
improves substantially firm profitability compared to the baseline scenario (Figure 2f); the same
holds for the default rate (Figure 2g), the capital adequacy ratio (Figure 2h) and the public debt-to-
GDP ratio (Figure 2i).
30
Fig.2: Effects of a green fiscal policy mix, selected variables
(a) Growth rate of output (b) Share of desired green investment in total
investment, mining and utilities
31
(continued from the previous page)
Note: The figure reports across-run averages from 200 Monte Carlo simulations. The values used in the baseline scenario are available
at www.define-model.org. The ‘green fiscal policy mix’ is implemented in 2022. It combines a ‘carbon tax’, a ‘green subsidy’ and a ‘green
public investment’ policy. Under ‘carbon tax’, the tax on total carbon emissions increases to $16/tCO 2 and grows at 3% thereafter.
Under ‘green subsidy’, the subsidies as a proportion of green investment increase to 60%. Under ‘green public investment’, green public
investment increases to 1%, as a proportion of GDP.
32
However, the high level of economic activity comes at an environmental cost. Although green
investment reduces material intensity and increases recycling, this is not sufficient to prevent an
increase in the waste per capita generated by the socio-economic system (Figure 2l). Moreover,
there is a substantial rise in the material depletion ratio (Figure 2k). This happens, in particular, at
the beginning of the next century and poses a significant challenge to macroeconomic stability.
Actually, with the values that we have used in our simulations for the parameters and variables that
refer to material flows and stocks, it turns out that the economy exhausts most of its material
reserves until 2110. This results in severe economic instability.20
Regarding the global warming effects of the green fiscal policy mix, several additional points are
worth mentioning. First, the path of atmospheric temperature shown in our simulations is
significantly affected by the assumptions made about the climate system. Our assumptions follow
those that Nordhaus (2018) has made in the recent version of the DICE model. Two key parameters
of the climate system are the climate sensitivity and the carbon absorption capacity of the upper
ocean and the biosphere. The climate sensitivity shows how much the equilibrium temperature of
the atmosphere increases when carbon concentration doubles compared to pre-industrial levels.
The carbon absorption capacity of the upper ocean and the biosphere reflects how much carbon is
absorbed by these reservoirs. The lower the value of climate sensitivity and the higher the value of
the carbon absorption capacity, the lower the adverse effects of carbon emissions on global
warming. Under more optimistic assumptions about the value of these parameters, our green fiscal
policy mix could produce a temperature path closer to 2 degrees.
Second, our analysis does not consider the case of ‘negative emissions’ technologies, like the carbon
capture and storage ones. The inclusion of such technologies could significantly affect the path of
atmospheric temperature in our scenarios. Note that these technologies play a key role in the IPCC
scenarios that produce 1.5 or 2 degrees (IPCC, 2018).
Third, even if optimistic assumptions about the reaction of the climate system are adopted and
‘negative emissions’ technologies are introduced, it might well still be the case that our green fiscal
policy mix, or more aggressive versions of it, are insufficient to keep climate change close to the
targets set by the Paris Agreement. This means that many other policies need to accompany our
green fiscal policy mix. These could include stricter environmental regulation, policies that reduce
the growth of carbon-intensive consumption and financial policies that support actively the
20 This is why we do not report the value of variables after 2110 in Figure 2.
33
transition to a low-carbon economy. Actually, a key message of our analysis is that the complex
interactions between the ecosystem, the macroeconomy and the financial system make it almost
impossible for isolated policies to achieve stability in all systems simultaneously. The environmental
and social challenges facing humanity in the next decades will require an innovative combination of
different types of policies, as well as a fundamental change in our consumption patterns.
Fiscal policy has a crucial role to play in the fight against environmental problems. Contrary to
conventional wisdom, this role moves beyond environment-related taxation; the spending decisions
of the government can also have important implications for ecological sustainability. The main
purpose of this paper has been to provide a comparative evaluation of different types of green fiscal
policies, drawing on some recent developments in post-Keynesian ecological macroeconomic
modelling. In our assessment, we focused on the role of carbon taxes, green subsidies and green
public investment.
Our analysis has produced various interesting results. We have shown that carbon taxes can reduce
global warming, as is the case in conventional environment-economy models. However, the explicit
incorporation of the financial system in our model has allowed us to pay particular attention to an
additional aspect of this policy, which has so far been neglected in conventional approaches: the
implications of carbon taxes for the stability of the financial system. In particular, we have illustrated
that the adverse effect of carbon taxes on the profitability of firms can give rise to a type of climate
Minsky moment whereby the default rate of firms increases, with negative effects on the capital
position of banks and the availability of credit. The rise in financial instability exacerbates the
negative effects of carbon taxes on economic growth and employment. However, quite ironically,
these economic and financial adverse effects of higher carbon taxes reinforce their positive
environmental impact, since lower economic activity leads to less carbon emissions.
Green subsidies and green public investment also have positive environmental effects since they
increase green capital compared to conventional capital. However, their positive impact on
economic activity has as a result that their beneficial environmental effects are partially offset by
macroeconomic rebound effects. The latter refer to the fact that the rise in green private and public
investment leads to higher use of natural resources. This does not only have a negative impact on
the dynamics of atmospheric temperature. It also causes some quite significant matter depletion
34
problems at the beginning of the next century and it places upward pressures on the waste generated
by the socio-economic system. Another interesting result is that, quite paradoxically from a
conventional point of view, higher spending on public green investment and green subsidies reduces
public indebtedness. This happens because of the positive effects of higher growth on tax revenues,
but also because these policies reduce climate damages, which have an adverse impact on public
indebtedness.
Combined implementation of higher carbon taxes, green subsidies and green public investment
turns out to be more beneficial compared to the case in which these policies take place in isolation.
Since green public investment and green subsidies boost the profitability of firms and growth, the
financial instability effects of higher carbon taxes do not materialise. At the same time, the
contractionary effect of higher carbon taxes counterbalances to some extent the adverse impact of
the macroeconomic rebound effect on carbon emissions and other environmental variables.
Therefore, a green fiscal policy mix is more effective from both an environmental and an
economic/financial point view. This, however, does not mean that such a policy mix solves the
environmental problems: the rise in atmospheric temperature is not so pronounced and high
economic growth causes some material depletion and waste generation problems in the very long
run. Hence, a green fiscal policy mix should be viewed as only one of the tools of a broader set of
policies that are essential for achieving ecological sustainability.
There are various aspects of green fiscal policies that have not been accounted for in our model
and can be the subject of future research. First, we have not explored the distributional effects of
carbon taxes. These effects can be investigated by disaggregating the household sector into different
types of households (see e.g. Dafermos and Papatheodorou, 2015) or by using agent-based
techniques (e.g. Dosi et al., 2013; Russo et al., 2015). This needs to be accompanied by an analysis
of the pricing policies of the carbon-intensive sectors in order to study how income distribution is
affected by different pricing policies, depending on whether higher carbon taxes are passed on to
consumers or not. This would provide some additional insights into our transition-related climate
Minsky moment. For example, one could expect that if carbon taxes are passed on to consumers,
such a moment could be triggered not by higher firm financial fragility, but by higher household
financial fragility. For a preliminary analysis of the distributional effects of carbon taxes within a
post-Keynesian framework, see Monasterolo and Raberto (2018).
35
Second, we have not analysed green public R&D expenditures. Nowadays, the risk of investing in
innovative green technologies is relatively high and the private sector does not seem sufficiently
willing to take that risk. Therefore, future research should investigate how public spending on
innovative research in green technologies could facilitate the transition to a low-carbon economy
and accelerate the change in the technological paradigm. Deleidi et al. (2019) have conducted a
preliminary investigation of the impact of green public spending on green innovation.
Third, public green employment has not been incorporated into our model. This is a crucial aspect
of green fiscal policy. By hiring public sector employees to work in green jobs, the government can
both support environmental targets and reduce the unemployment rate. Nonetheless, higher green
public employment can have macroeconomic rebound effects, as it was the case with green
subsidies and green public investment in our model. The implications of these rebound effects need
to be explored in detail.
Fourth, we have adopted a global perspective for the analysis of the implications of green fiscal
policies. However, regional- and country-level approaches are a prerequisite for a well-informed
implementation of such policies. Although some post-Keynesian analyses have been conducted in
along these lines (e.g. Barker et al., 2012; Pollin et al., 2014), a deeper look into the financial aspects
and implications of green fiscal policies is in order. The incorporation of environmental aspects
into the recently developed country-specific empirical SFC models (see Burgess et al., 2016; Zezza
and Zezza, 2019) would be a significant step in this direction.
Finally, in our analysis we have restricted our attention to a small subset of environmental problems:
climate change, material/energy depletion and waste generation. However, fiscal policy can also
affect many other aspects of the environment, including biodiversity, forests, fisheries and oceans.
A broad research programme on green fiscal policy needs to pay attention to these aspects of the
environment as well. This is particularly important due to the highly interconnected ecological sub-
systems of the global ecosystem. The systems approach adopted in our analysis would be the natural
starting point for such an interdisciplinary research programme.
36
References
Aiyar, S., Calomiris, C.W. and Wieladek, T. (2016), “How does credit supply respond to monetary
policy and bank minimum capital requirements?”. European Economic Review, 82, 142-165.
Aldred, J. (2012), “Climate change uncertainty, irreversibility and the precautionary principle”.
Cambridge Journal of Economics, 36 (5), 1051-1072.
Anthoff, D. and Tol, R.S. (2013), “The uncertainty about the social cost of carbon: A
decomposition analysis using fund”. Climatic Change, 117 (3), 515-530.
Arestis, P. (2012), “Fiscal policy: a strong macroeconomic role”. Review of Keynesian Economics, 1, 93-
108.
Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. (2003), “Reinventing fiscal policy”. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 26
(1), 3-25.
Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. (2006), “The nature and role of monetary policy when money is
endogenous”. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30 (6), 847-860.
Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. (2010), “The return of fiscal policy”. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 32
(3), 327-346.
Babatunde, K.A., Begum, R.A. and Said, F.F. (2017), “Application of computable general
equilibrium (CGE) to climate change mitigation policy: a systematic review”. Renewable and
Sustainable Energy Reviews, 78, 61-71.
Barker, T., Dagoumas, A. and Rubin, J. (2009), “The macroeconomic rebound effect and the world
economy”. Energy Efficiency, 2, 411-427.
Barker, T., Anger, A., Chewpreecha, U. and Pollitt, H. (2012), “A new economics approach to
modelling policies to achieve global 2020 targets for climate stabilisation”. International Review of
Applied Economics, 26 (2), 205-221.
Batten, S. (2018), “Climate change and the macro-economy: a critical review”. Bank of England
Staff Working Paper No. 706.
Berger, S. (2017), The Social Costs of Neoliberalism: Essays on the Economics of K. William Kapp.
Spokesman, Nottingham.
Bergman, L. (2005), “CGE modeling of environmental policy and resource management”, in: Mäler,
K.-G. and Vincent, J.R. (eds.), Handbook of Environmental Economics, Vol. 3, 1273-1306.
Bonen, A., Semmler, W. and Klasen, S. (2014), “Economic damages from climate change: a review
of modeling approaches”. Schwartz Center for Economic Policy Analysis, The New School,
Working Paper No. 3.
37
Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., Galeotti, M., Massetti, E. and Tavoni, M. (2006), “WITCH a world induced
technical change hybrid model”. The Energy Journal, 13-37.
Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., Duval, R. and Tavoni, M. (2011), “What should we expect from innovation?
a model-based assessment of the environmental and mitigation cost implications of climate-
related R&D”. Energy Economics, 33 (6), 1313-1320.
Botzen, W.W. and van den Bergh, J.C. (2012), “How sensitive is Nordhaus to Weitzman? Climate
policy in DICE with an alternative damage function”. Economics Letters, 117 (1), 372-374.
Bovari, E., Giraud, G. and Mc Isaac, F. (2018), “Coping with collapse: a stock-flow consistent
monetary macrodynamics of global warming”. Ecological Economics. 147, 383-398.
Burgess, S., Burrows, O., Godin, A., Kinsella, S. and Millard, S. (2016), “A dynamic model of
financial balances for the United Kingdom”. Bank of England Staff Working Paper No. 614.
Campiglio, E. (2016), “Beyond carbon pricing: the role of banking and monetary policy in financing
the transition to a low-carbon economy”. Ecological Economics, 121, 220-230.
Campiglio, E., Dafermos, Y., Monnin, P., Ryan-Collins, J., Schotten, G. and Tanaka, M. (2018),
“Climate change challenges for central banks and financial regulators”. Nature Climate Change, 8
(6), 462-468.
Capros, P., Van Regemorter, D., Paroussos, L., Karkatsoulis, P., Fragkiadakis, C., Tsani, S.,
Charalampidis, I. and Revesz, T. (2013), “GEM-E3 model documentation”. JRC Scientific and
Policy Reports, European Commission No. 26034.
Carney, M. (2015), “Breaking the Tragedy of the Horizon - Climate Change and Financial Stability”.
Speech given at Lloyd’s of London, London, Bank of England.
Caverzasi, E. and Godin, A. (2015), “Financialisation and the sub-prime crisis: a stock-flow
consistent model”. European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention, 12 (1), 73-92.
Climate Bonds Initiative (2017), “Green bonds highlights 2016”. CBI, London.
Climate Bonds Initiative (2018a), “Green bonds highlights 2017”. CBI, London.
Climate Bonds Initiative (2018b), “Green bond pricing in the primary market: January - June 2018”.
CBI, London.
Chen, Y.H.H., Paltsev, S., Reilly, J.M., Morris, J.F. and Babiker, M.H. (2016), “Long-term economic
modeling for climate change assessment”. Economic Modelling, 52, 867-883.
Chewpreecha, U., Fragkiadakis, K., Fragkos, P., Goldman, M., Lewney, R., Paroussos, L., Pollitt,
H. and Stenning, J. (2017), “Case study - technical analysis on capacity constraints and
macroeconomic performance: technical study on the macroeconomics of climate and energy
policies”. European Commission.
38
Dafermos, Y. (2018), “Debt cycles, instability and fiscal rules: a Godley-Minsky synthesis”.
Cambridge Journal of Economics, 42 (5), 1277-1313.
Dafermos, Y. and Papatheodorou, C. (2015), “Linking functional with personal income
distribution: a stock-flow consistent approach”, International Review of Applied Economics, 29 (6),
787-815.
Dafermos, Y., Nikolaidi, M. and Galanis, G. (2017), “A stock-flow-fund ecological macroeconomic
model”. Ecological Economics, 131, 191-207.
Dafermos, Y., Nikolaidi, M. and Galanis, G. (2018), “Climate change, financial stability and
monetary policy”. Ecological Economics, 152, 219-234.
D’Alessandro, S., Dittmer, K., Distefanol, T. and Cieplinski, A. (2018), “Eurogreen model of job
creation in a post-growth economy”, Greens-EFA.
Daly, H.E. and Farley, J. (2011), Ecological Economics: Principles and Applications. Island Press,
Washington DC.
Davidson, P. (1991), “Is probability theory relevant for uncertainty? A post Keynesian perspective”.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5 (1), 129-143.
Davidson, P. (2002), Financial Markets, Money, and the real World. Edward Elgar Publishing.
Deleidi, M., Pariboni, R. and Passarella, M.V. (2019), “Supermultiplier, innovation and the
ecosystem: a stock-flow dynamic model”. IIPP Working Paper 2019-01, Institute for Innovation
and Public Purpose, UCL.
Dennig, F., Budolfson, M.B., Fleurbaey, M., Siebert, A. and Socolow, R.H. (2015), “Inequality,
climate impacts on the future poor, and carbon prices”. Proceedings of the National Academy
of Sciences, 112 (52), 15827-15832.
Dietz, S. and Stern, N. (2015), “Endogenous growth, convexity of damage and climate risk: how
Nordhaus’ framework supports deep cuts in carbon emissions”. The Economic Journal, 125 (583),
574-620.
D’Orazio, P. and Popoyan, L. (2019), “Fostering green investments and tackling climate-related
financial risks: which role for macroprudential policies?”. Ecological Economics, 160, 25-37.
Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., Napoletano, M. and Roventini, A. (2013), “Income distribution, credit and
fiscal policies in an agent-based Keynesian model”. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37
(8), 1598-1625.
Espagne, E., Pottier, A., Fabert, B.P., Nadaud, F. and Dumas, P. (2018), “SCCs and the use of
IAMs: let’s separate the wheat from the chaff”. International Economics, 155, 29-47.
Fazzari, S.M. (1994-95), “Why doubt the effectiveness of Keynesian fiscal policy?”. Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics, 17 (2), 231-248.
39
Farmer, J.D., Hepburn, C., Mealy, P. and Teytelboym, A. (2015), “A third wave in the economics
of climate change”. Environmental and Resource Economics, 62 (2), 329-357.
Fontana, G. and Gerrard, B. (2004), “A Post Keynesian theory of decision making under
uncertainty”. Journal of Economic Psychology, 25 (5), 619-637.
Fontana, G. and Sawyer, M.C. (2013), “Post-Keynesian and Kaleckian thoughts on ecological
macroeconomics”. European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention, 10 (2), 256-267.
Fontana, G. and Sawyer, M. (2016), “Towards post-Keynesian ecological macroeconomics”.
Ecological Economics, 121, 186-195.
Forstater, M. (2003), “Public employment and environmental sustainability”. Journal of Post Keynesian
Economics, 25 (3), 385-406.
Gambacorta, L. and Shin, H.S. (2018), “Why bank capital matters for monetary policy”. Journal of
Financial Intermediation, 35, 17-29.
Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1971), The Entropy Law and the Economic Process. Harvard University Press,
Cambridge.
Godin, A. (2012), “Guaranteed green jobs: sustainable full employment”, Levy Economics Institute
Working Paper No. 722.
Godley, W. and Lavoie, M. (2012), Monetary Economics: An Integrated Approach to Credit, Money, Income,
Production and Wealth. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke.
Guo, Z., Zhang, X., Zheng, Y. and Rao, R. (2014), “Exploring the impacts of a carbon tax on the
Chinese economy using a CGE model with a detailed disaggregation of energy sectors”. Energy
Economics, 45, 455-462.
Hein, E. and Stockhammer, E. (2010), “Macroeconomic policy mix, employment and inflation in a
Post-Keynesian alternative to the New Consensus model”. Review of Political Economy, 22 (3), 317-
354.
High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices (2017), “Report of the high-level commission on carbon
prices”. International Bank for Reconstruction and Development and International
Development Association-The World Bank.
Hope, C. (2011), “The social cost of CO2 from the PAGE09 model”. University of Cambridge
Judge Business School Working Paper Series No. 5/2011.
Jackson, T. and Victor, P.A. (2016), “Does slow growth lead to rising inequality? Some theoretical
reflections and numerical simulations”. Ecological Economics, 121, 206-219.
IPCC (2018), “Special report: global warming of 1.5ºC”. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change.
40
IRENA (2018), “Global energy transformation: a roadmap to 2050”. International Renewable
Energy Transformation.
Kalkuhl, M., Edenhofer, O. and Lessmann, K. (2013), “Renewable energy subsidies: second-best
policy or fatal aberration for mitigation?”. Resource and Energy Economics, 35 (3), 217-234.
Krey, V., Masera, O., Blanford, G., Bruckner, T., Cooke, R., Fisher-Vanden, K., Haberl, H.,
Hertwich, E., Kriegler, E., Mueller, D., Paltsev, S., Price, L., Schlömer, S., Ürge-Vorsatz, D., van
Vuuren, D. and Zwickel, T. (2014), “Annex II: metrics and methodology”. In: Edenhofer, O.,
Pichs-Madruga, R., Sokona, Y., Farahani, E., Kadner, S., Seyboth, K., Adler, A., Baum, I.,
Brunner, S., Eickemeier, P., Kriemann, B., Savolainen, J., Schlömer, S., von Stechow, C.,
Zwickel, T. and Minx, J.C. (eds.) Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of
Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Lavoie, M. (2006), “A post‐Keynesian amendment to the new consensus on monetary policy”.
Metroeconomica, 57 (2), 165-192.
Lavoie, M. (2014), Post-Keynesian Economics: New Foundations. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA, USA.
Lamperti, F., Dosi, G., Napoletano, M., Roventini, A. and Sapio, A. (2018), “Faraway, so close:
coupled climate and economic dynamics in an agent-based integrated assessment model”.
Ecological Economics, 150, 315-339.
Lemoine, D. and Traeger, C. (2014), “Watch your step: optimal policy in a tipping climate”. American
Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 6 (1), 137-66.
Liang, Q.M. and Wei, Y.M. (2012), “Distributional impacts of taxing carbon in China: results from
the CEEPA model”. Applied Energy, 92, 545-551.
Mazzucato, M. and McPherson, M. (2018), “The Green New Deal: a bold mission-oriented
approach”. IIPP Policy Brief (December 2018), Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose,
UCL.
McLeay, M., Radia, A. and Thomas, R. (2014), “Money creation in the modern economy”, Bank of
England Quarterly Bulletin, 54 (1), 14–27.
Meng, S., Siriwardana, M. and McNeill, J. (2013), “The environmental and economic impact of the
carbon tax in Australia”. Environmental and Resource Economics, 54 (3), 313-332.
Mercure, J.F., Pollitt, H., Viñuales, J.E., Edwards, N.R., Holden, P.B., Chewpreecha, U., Salas, P.,
Sognnaes, I., Lam, A. and Knobloch, F. (2018), “Macroeconomic impact of stranded fossil fuel
assets”. Nature Climate Change, 8 (7), 588-593.
41
Monasterolo, I. and Raberto, M. (2018), “The EIRIN flow-of-funds behavioural model of green
fiscal policies and green sovereign bonds”. Ecological Economics, 144, 228-243.
Monasterolo, I. and Raberto, M. (2019), “The impact of phasing out fossil fuel subsidies on the
low-carbon transition”. Energy Policy, 124, 355-370.
Nikiforos, M. and Zezza, G. (2017), “Stock‐flow consistent macroeconomic models: a survey”.
Journal of Economic Surveys, 31 (5), 1204-1239.
Nikolaidi, M. (2014), “Margins of safety and instability in a macrodynamic model with Minskyan
insights”. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 31, 1-16.
Neuteleers, S. and Engelen, B. (2015), “Talking money: how market-based valuation can undermine
environmental protection”. Ecological Economics, 117, 253-260.
Nordhaus, W.D. (2017), “Revisiting the social cost of carbon”. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences, 114 (7), 1518-1523.
Nordhaus, W.D. (2018), “Projections and uncertainties about climate change in an era of minimal
climate policies”. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 10 (3), 333-60.
OECD (2017), “Environmental fiscal reform: progress, prospects and pitfalls”. OECD Report for
the G7 Environment Ministers.
Pollin, R., Garrett-Peltier, H., Heintz, J. and Hendricks, B. (2014), “Green growth: a U.S. program
for controlling climate change and expanding job opportunities”. PERI.
Pollitt, H. and Mercure, J.F. (2017), “The role of money and the financial sector in energy-economy
models used for assessing climate and energy policy”. Climate Policy, 18 (2), 184-197.
Rausch, S., Metcalf, G.E. and Reilly, J.M. (2011), “Distributional impacts of carbon pricing: a
general equilibrium approach with micro-data for households”. Energy Economics, 33, S20-S33.
Riahi, K., Rao, S., Krey, V., Cho, C., Chirkov, V., Fischer, G., Kindermann, G., Nakicenovic, N.
and Rafaj, P. (2011), “RCP 8.5 A scenario of comparatively high greenhouse gas emissions”.
Climatic Change, 109 (1-2), 33-57.
Russo, A., Riccetti, L. and Gallegati, M. (2015), “Increasing inequality, consumer credit and financial
fragility in an agent based macroeconomic model”. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 26 (1), 25-47.
Scott, M., van Huizen, J. and Jung, C. (2017), “The Bank of England’s response to climate change”.
Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 2017 Q2, 98-109.
Scrieciu, S.Ş., Barker, T. and Ackerman, F. (2013), “Pushing the boundaries of climate economics:
critical issues to consider in climate policy analysis”. Ecological Economics, 85, 155-165.
Shi, W., Ou, Y., Smith, S.J., Ledna, C.M., Nolte, C.G. and Loughlin, D.H. (2017), “Projecting state-
level air pollutant emissions using an integrated assessment model: GCAM-USA”. Applied Energy,
208, 511-521.
42
Taylor, L., Rezai, A. and Foley, D.K. (2016), “An integrated approach to climate change, income
distribution, employment, and economic growth”. Ecological Economics, 121, 196-205.
United Nations (2017), “World population prospects: key findings and advance tables”. United
Nations, New York.
van den Bergh, J.C. and Botzen, W.J.W. (2015), “Monetary valuation of the social cost of CO2
emissions: a critical survey”. Ecological Economics, 114, 33-46.
Volz, U. (2017), “On the role of central banks in enhancing green financing”. UN Environment
Inquiry Working Paper No. 17/01, Geneva.
Wei, W., Zhao, Y., Wang, J. and Song, M. (2019), “The environmental benefits and economic
impacts of Fit-in-Tariff in China”. Renewable Energy, 133, 401-410.
World Bank (2018), “State and trends of carbon pricing 2018”. World Bank Group.
World Bank (2019), “Fiscal policies for development and climate action”. International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development-The World Bank. World Bank Group.
Wray, L.R. (2007), “The employer of last resort programme: could it work for developing
countries?”. Geneva: ILO.
Zachmann, G., Fredriksson, G. and Claeys, G. (2018), “The distributional effects of climate
policies”. Bruegel. Blueprint Series No. 28.
Zezza, G. and Zezza, F. (2019), “On the design of empirical stock-flow-consistent models”. Levy
Economics Institute of Bard College, Working Paper No. 919.
43