Appendix A
Eigenvalues and eigenvectors
The AHP is an important field of application of linear algebra, and especially of
its theory regarding positive matrices. This appendix contains an introduction to
eigenvalues and eigenvectors focused on their relevance for the AHP. At present,
there are many ways to work out the AHP without getting dirty with eigenvalues and
eigenvectors. Thus, in a certain sense knowing about them is superfluous. However,
by knowing them the reader will figure out the connection between AHP and linear
algebra and hopefully see the AHP from a higher observation point.
Definition A.1 (Eigenvalues and eigenvectors). Consider an n × n square matrix A
and an n-dimensional vector w. Then, w and λ are an eigenvector and an eigenvalue
of A, respectively, if and only if
Aw = λ w. (A.1)
Example A.1. Consider the matrix and the vector as follows
1 2 2
A= w= .
1/2 1 1
Then, one reckons that w is an eigenvector of A for λ = 2. In fact
1 2 2 2
=2 .
1/2 1 1 1
Note that, if w is an eigenvector of A, then all vectors α w for α ∈ R are also eigen-
vectors of A, we call this set of vectors the eigenspace of A associated to that eigen-
vector (or its respective eigenvalue). Now one natural question arises; how to find
the eigenvalues and the eigenvectors of a given matrix. By considering the identity
c Matteo Brunelli 2015 71
M. Brunelli, Introduction to the Analytic Hierarchy Process,
SpringerBriefs in Operations Research, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-12502-2
72 A Eigenvalues and eigenvectors
matrix I and the null vector 0 = (0, . . . , 0)T , we can rewrite (A.1),
Aw = λ w
Aw − λ w = 0
Aw − λ Iw = 0
(A − λ I)w = 0 (A.2)
Now, from the basics of linear algebra we know that, if det(A − λ I) = 0, then
there is only one solution to (A.2), which is the trivial solution w = (0, . . . , 0)T .
We are instead interested in the case where other solutions exists, then to the case
det (A − λ I) = 0. Hence, by changing notation ρA (λ ) := det (A − λ I), we need to
find the roots of ρA (λ ). Such a polynomial is called the characteristic polynomial
of A.
Example A.2. Reprising the matrix of the previous example
1−λ 2
ρA (λ ) = det
1/2 1 − λ
1
= (1 − λ )(1 − λ ) − 2
2
= λ (λ − 2)
and by imposing λ (λ − 2) = 0 it follows that ρA (λ ) = 0 for λ = 0, 2. Now, consid-
ering for example the eigenvalue λ = 2 the associated eigenvector can be found by
solving
1 2 w1 w1
=2
1/2 1 w2 w2
from which we derive that w1 = 2w2 and that w = (2, 1)T is the eigenvector associ-
ated to λ = 2. Clearly, also all the eigenvectors of the eigenspace spanned by w are
eigenvectors of λ = 2, e.g. (1, 0.5)T .
Note that the eigenvalues can be ordered from the greatest to the smallest accord-
ing to their absolute value. We call maximum eigenvalue the one with the greatest
absolute value and we denote it as λmax . In Example A.2, we have λmax = 2. Going
back to the computational part, with the increasing size of a matrix, things get more
complicated, especially when it comes to find the roots of the characteristic polyno-
mial. However, the idea remains the same.
Example A.3. Consider the following matrix
⎛ ⎞
1 2 8
A = ⎝1/2 1 4⎠ .
1/8 1/4 1
Then, by putting its characteristic polynomial equal to 0, and by skipping the ele-
mentary steps, one recovers
ρA (λ ) = λ 2 (3 − λ ) = 0 (A.3)
A Eigenvalues and eigenvectors 73
The eigenvalues are then λ = 0, 3. In this case we say that the algebraic multiplicity
of λ = 0 is equal to 2. Roughly speaking, with algebraic multiplicity we indicate the
number of times that a solution appears in the equation. In this case the multiplicity
2 of λ = 0 is obvious if we rewrite (A.3) as follows,
ρA (λ ) = λ λ (3 − λ ) = 0 (A.4)
Note that in the previous example one eigenvalue was equal to n, and the other, with
multiplicity (n − 1) was equal to 0. This is not a case, but a more general result.
Proposition A.1. Given a pairwise comparison matrix A, if and only if A is con-
sistent, then one eigenvalue, λmax is equal to n and the other is equal to 0, with
multiplicity (n − 1).
Proceeding further, another question arises and regards the behavior of λmax when A
is not consistent. As λmax cannot be equal to n, then what else can it be? Eigenvalues
are roots of polynomials and it is natural to suspect that λmax could be a complex
number. Fortunately, this cannot happen for pairwise comparison matrices and we
can restrict the search to real numbers. This is formalized in the following theorem.
Theorem A.1 (Perron-Frobenius). Given a square matrix A, if A is positive, i.e.
ai j > 0 ∀i, j, then its maximum eigenvalue is real, λmax ∈ R.
Example A.4. Consider the following matrix
⎛ ⎞
1 2 8
A = ⎝1/2 1 1/4⎠
1/8 4 1
Using the rule of Sarrus we compute
1 1 1
ρA (λ ) = (1 − λ ) + 2 · ·
3
+ 8 · · 4 − (1 − λ ) − (1 − λ ) − (1 − λ )
4 8 2
2 32
= (1 − λ )3 + + − 3(1 − λ )
32 2
225
= + 3λ 2 − λ 3 .
16
16 + 3λ − λ = 0 we find that λmax ≈ 3.9167. The other two roots are
By solving 225 2 3
conjugate complex and we are not interested in them. Such solution can be easily
found by any mathematical software. Now, with this solution, we need to solve the
equation system ⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞
1 2 8 w1 w1
⎝1/2 1 1/4⎠ ⎝w2 ⎠ = 3.9167 ⎝w2 ⎠ .
1/8 4 1 w3 w3
74 A Eigenvalues and eigenvectors
To aid the process and avoid the problem of infinitely many solutions we add the
condition w1 + w2 + w3 = 1 and solve
⎧
⎪
⎪ w1 + 2w2 + 8w3 = 3.9167w1
⎪
⎨ 1 w + w + 1 w = 3.9167w
2 1 2 4 3 2
⎪
⎪
1
w1 + 4w2 + w3 = 3.9167w3
⎪
⎩8
w1 + w2 + w3 = 1
from which we obtain
w ≈ (0.660761, 0.131112, 0.208127)T .
Note that in the this last example A was inconsistent and λmax > n. The following
proposition clarifies the range of possible values attained by λmax .
Proposition A.2 (Saaty [99]). Let A be a pairwise comparison matrix. Then λmax =
n if and only if A is consistent and strictly greater than n otherwise.
Nowadays, all textbooks on linear algebra cover the theory of eigenvalues and eigen-
vectors. For a less didactic and more involving exposition of eigenvalues and eigen-
vectors with an eye on positive matrices the reader can refer to the book by Horn
and Johnson [70].
Appendix B
Solutions
2.1 Consider that we assumed ai j = wi /w j ∀i, j. Then we write wi and w j as the
respective geometric means and see what happens if we account for the assumption.
1
(∏n aik )1/n ai1 ai2 · · · ain n
ai j = k=1 1/n = .
∏nk=1 a jk a j1 a j2 · · · a jn
Since we assumed that ai j = wi /w j we can substitute these in the equation and
rewrite it as
w w wi
1n ⎛ wn ⎞ 1n
i i
· · · i
w1 w2 ···wn ⎠ wi
w w
ai j = w1j w2j
wn
wj = ⎝ = .
wnj
w1 w2 · · · wn
wj
w1 w2 ···wn
The original assumption is correctly recovered and therefore, when ai j = wi /w j
∀i, j, the geometric mean method returns the correct vector.
2.2 The proof was provided by the Crawford and Williams [43]. See Theorem 3 in
their paper.
3.1 Underbraced are the numbers of independent comparisons for each level of the
hierarchy, starting from the top.
3(3 − 1) 4(4 − 1) 3(3 − 1) 3(3 − 1) 3(3 − 1)
+ + + +9 = 42
2
2 2
2 2
3 12 27
Solution to Problem 3.2: Consider the analytic formula of c3 , that is,
n−2 n−1 n
aik ai j a jk
c3 = ∑ ∑ ∑ 2 − ai j a jk − aik .
i=1 j=i+1 k= j+1
c Matteo Brunelli 2015 75
M. Brunelli, Introduction to the Analytic Hierarchy Process,
SpringerBriefs in Operations Research, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-12502-2
76 B Solutions
At this point, consider the matrix Ȧ with the entry ȧi j missing. The sum contains
four transitivities and we can expand it
ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ ȧ
c3 = 6 8 − 13 − 12 23 − 14 − 12 24 − 14 − 13 34 − 24 − 23 34
ȧ12 ȧ23 ȧ13 ȧ12 ȧ24 ȧ14 ȧ13 ȧ34 ȧ14 ȧ23 ȧ34 ȧ24
− 37
6 −
ȧ14
2 − ȧ 2 −
ȧ14
8
− ȧ 8 − 13
6
14 14
5x 10 1 15ȧ14 60
=6 − − − =− − − 2.
8 x 3 4 ȧ14
Let us inspect the first and second derivatives of c3 in ȧ14 :
∂ c3 60 15
= − ,
∂ ȧ14 (ȧ14 )2 4
∂ c3
2 120
=− .
∂ ȧ14
2
(ȧ14 )3
The second derivative is strictly negative for positive values of ȧ14 , which means
that the function is strictly concave for ȧ14 > 0 and that, if there is a maximum, then
it is unique. By equating the first derivative to zero, we recover that (ȧ14 )2 = 16. Of
the two solutions we take the positive one, which is ȧ14 = 4.
3.3 ⎛ ⎞
3 2 0 0
⎜1/2 1 1/3 1⎟
C=⎜
⎝ 0 3 2 2⎠
⎟
0 1 1/2 2
3.4 ⎛ ⎞
1 2 4 3
⎜1/2 1 2 3/2⎟
A=⎜
⎝1/4 1/2 1 3/4⎠
⎟
1/3 2/3 4/3 1
4.1 If the matrix is consistent, then any column can act as the priority vector. An
alternative method, which is also used to derive the vector from inconsistent matri-
ces, is the arithmetic mean of the rows,
n
1
ui =
n ∑ pi j .
j=1
In the case of consistent matrices, this method returns exactly the correct vector. The
proof is similar to the one used to solve Problem 2.1.
References
1. J. Aczél and T. L. Saaty. Procedures for synthesizing ratio judgments. Journal of Mathemat-
ical Psychology, 27(1):93–102, 1983.
2. J. Aguarón and J. M. Moreno-Jiménez. The geometric consistency index: Approximated
thresholds. European Journal of Operational Research, 147(1):137–145, 2003.
3. J. A. Alonso and M. T. Lamata. Consistency in the analytic hierarchy process: a new
approach. International Journal of Uncertainty, Fuzziness and Knowledge-Based Systems,
14(4):445–459, 2006.
4. S. Anand and A. Sen. Human development index: methodology and measurement. Techni-
cal report, Human Development Report Office (HDRO), United Nations Development Pro-
gramme (UNDP), 1994.
5. A. Arbel. Approximate articulation of preference and priority derivation. European Journal
of Operational Research, 43(3):317–326, 1989.
6. A. Arbel and L. Vargas. Interval judgments and Euclidean centers. Mathematical and Com-
puter Modelling, 46(7):976–984, 2007.
7. C. A. Bana e Costa and J.-C. Vansnick. A critical analysis of the eigenvalue method used
to derive priorities in AHP. European Journal of Operational Research, 187(3):1422–1428,
2008.
8. M. B. Barfod and S. Leleur. Scaling transformation in the REMBRANDT technique: exami-
nation of the progression factor. International Journal of Information Technology & Decision
Making, 12(5):887–903, 2013.
9. J. Barzilai. Deriving weights from pairwise comparison matrices. The Journal of the Oper-
ational Research Society, 48(12):1226–1232, 1997.
10. J. Barzilai. Consistency measures for pairwise comparison matrices. Journal of Multi-
Criteria Decision Analysis, 7(3):123–132, 1998.
11. J. Barzilai, W. D. Cook, and B. Golany. Consistent weights for judgements matrices of the
relative importance of alternatives. Operations Research Letters, 6(3):131–134, 1987.
12. J. Barzilai and B. Golany. AHP rank reversal, normalization and aggregation rules. INFOR-
Information Systems and Operational Research, 32(2):57–64, 1994.
13. L. Basile and L. D’Apuzzo. Weak consistency and quasi-linear means imply the actual
ranking. International Journal of Uncertainty, Fuzziness and Knowledge-Based Systems,
10(3):227–240, 2002.
14. L. Basile and L. D’Apuzzo. Transitive matrices, strict preference order and ordinal evaluation
operators. Soft Computing, 10(10):933–940, 2006.
15. V. Belton and T. Gear. On a short-coming of Saaty’s method of analytic hierarchies. Omega,
11(3):228–230, 1983.
16. V. Belton and T. Gear. The legitimacy of rank reversal—a comment. Omega, 13(3):143–144,
1985.
c Matteo Brunelli 2015 77
M. Brunelli, Introduction to the Analytic Hierarchy Process,
SpringerBriefs in Operations Research, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-12502-2
78 References
17. M. Bernasconi, C. Choirat, and R. Seri. The analytic hierachy process and the theory of
measurement. Management Science, 56(4):699–711, 2010.
18. M. Bernasconi, C. Choirat, and R. Seri. Empirical properties of group preference aggrega-
tion methods employed in AHP: Theory and evidence. European Journal of Operational
Research, 232(3):584–592, 2014.
19. R. Blanquero, E. Carrizosa, and E. Conde. Inferring weights from pairwise comparison
matrices. Mathematical Methods of Operations Research, 64(2):271–284, 2006.
20. L. Bodin and S. I. Gass. On teaching the analytic hierarchy process. Computers & Operations
Research, 30(10):1487–1497, 2003.
21. L. Bodin and S. I. Gass. Exercises for teaching the analytic hierarchy process. INFORMS
Transactions on Education, 4(2):1–13, 2004.
22. S. P. Boyd and L. Vandenberghe. Convex Optimization. Cambridge University Press, 2004.
23. S. Bozóki. Solution of the least squares method problem of pairwise comparison matrices.
Central European Journal of Operations Research, 16(4):345–358, 2008.
24. S. Bozóki. Inefficient weights from pairwise comparison matrices with arbitrarily small
inconsistency. Optimization: A Journal of Mathematical Programming and Operations
Research, 63(12):1893–1901.
25. S. Bozóki, L. Dezső, A. Poesz, and J. Temesi. Analysis of pairwise comparison matrices: an
empirical research. Annals of Operations Research, 211(1):511–528, 2013.
26. S. Bozóki, J. Fülöp, and L. Rónyai. On optimal completion of incomplete pairwise compar-
ison matrices. Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 52(1):318–333, 2010.
27. M. Brunelli, L. Canal, and M. Fedrizzi. Inconsistency indices for pairwise comparison matri-
ces: a numerical study. Annals of Operations Research, 211(1):493–509, 2013.
28. M. Brunelli, A. Critch, and M. Fedrizzi. A note on the proportionality between some con-
sistency indices in the AHP. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 219(14):7901–7906,
2013.
29. M. Brunelli and M. Fedrizzi. Axiomatic properties of inconsistency indices for pairwise
comparisons. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 2014. (in press).
30. M. Brunelli, M. Fedrizzi, and S. Giove. Reconstruction methods for incomplete fuzzy pref-
erence relations: A numerical comparison. In WILF, pages 86–93, 2007.
31. M. Brunelli and J. Mezei. How different are ranking methods for fuzzy numbers? A numer-
ical study. International Journal of Approximate Reasoning, 54(5):627–639, 2013.
32. J. J. Buckley. Fuzzy hierarchical analysis. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 17(3):233–247, 1985.
33. D.-H. Byun. The AHP approach for selecting an automobile purchase model. Information
& Management, 38(5):289–297, 2001.
34. C. Carlsson and P. Walden. AHP in political group decisions: A study in the art of possibili-
ties. Interfaces, 25(4):14–29, 1995.
35. F. J. Carmone Jr, A. Kara, and S. H. Zanakis. A Monte Carlo investigation of incomplete pair-
wise comparison matrices in AHP. European Journal of Operational Research, 102(3):538–
553, 1997.
36. B. Cavallo and L. D’Apuzzo. A general unified framework for pairwise comparison matrices
in multicriterial methods. International Journal of Intelligent Systems, 24(4):377–398, 2009.
37. B. Cavallo and L. D’Apuzzo. Characterizations of consistent pairwise comparison matri-
ces over Abelian linearly ordered groups. International Journal of Intelligent Systems,
25(10):1035–1059, 2010.
38. D.-Y. Chang. Applications of the extent analysis on fuzzy AHP. European Journal of Oper-
ational Research, 95(3):649–655, 1996.
39. F. Chiclana, E. Herrera-Viedma, S. Alonso, and F. Herrera. Cardinal consistency of reciprocal
preference relations: A characterization of multiplicative transitivity. IEEE Transactions on
Fuzzy Systems, 17(1):14–23, 2009.
40. E. U. Choo and W. C. Wedley. A common framework for deriving preference values from
pairwise comparison matrices. Computers & Operations Research, 31(6):893–908, 2004.
41. W. D. Cook and M. Kress. Deriving weights from pairwise comparison ratio matrices: An
axiomatic approach. European Journal of Operational Research, 37(3):355–362, 1988.
References 79
42. G. Crawford. The geometric mean procedure for estimating the scale of a judgment matrix.
Mathematical Modelling, 9(3-5):327–334, 1989.
43. G. Crawford and C. Williams. A note on the analysis of subjective judgment matrices.
Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 29(4):387–405, 1985.
44. B. De Baets, H. De Meyer, B. De Schuymer, and S. Jenei. Cyclic evaluation of transitivity
of reciprocal relations. Social Choice and Welfare, 26(2):217–238, 2006.
45. D. Dubois. The role of fuzzy sets in decision sciences: Old techniques and new directions.
Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 184(1):3–28, 2011.
46. D. Dubois and H. Prade. Operations on fuzzy numbers. International Journal of Systems
Science, 9(6):613–626, 1978.
47. D. Dubois and H. Prade. Fuzzy Sets and Systems: Theory and Applications, volume 144 of
Mathematics in Science and Engineering. Academic Press, 1980.
48. Z. Duszak and W. W. Koczkodaj. Generalization of a new definition of consistency for
pairwise comparisons. Information Processing Letters, 52(5):273–276, 1994.
49. J. S. Dyer. Remarks on the analytic hierarchy process. Management Science, 36(3):249–258,
1990.
50. R. F. Dyer and E. H. Forman. Group decision support with the analytic hierarchy process.
Decision Support Systems, 8(2):99–124, 1992.
51. M. Fedrizzi and M. Brunelli. On the priority vector associated with a reciprocal relation and
with a pairwise comparison matrix. Soft Computing, 14(6):639–645, 2010.
52. M. Fedrizzi and S. Giove. Optimal sequencing in incomplete pairwise comparisons for large-
dimensional problems. International Journal of General Systems, 42(4):366–375, 2013.
53. J. Fichtner. On deriving priority vectors from matrices of pairwise comparisons. Socio-
Economic Planning Sciences, 20(6):341–345, 1986.
54. J. Figueira, S. Greco, and M. Ehrgott. Multiple Criteria Decision Analysis: State of the Art
Surveys, volume 78 of International Series in Operations Research & Management Science.
Springer, 2005.
55. P. C. Fishburn. Utility Theory for Decision Making. R. E. Krieger Pub. Co., 1979.
56. P. C. Fishburn. Preference relations and their numerical representations. Theoretical Com-
puter Science, 217(2):359–383, 1999.
57. E. Forman and K. Peniwati. Aggregating individual judgments and priorities with the ana-
lytic hierarchy process. European Journal of Operational Research, 108(1):165–169, 1998.
58. J. B. Fraleigh. A First Course in Abstract Algebra. Pearson, 7th edition, 2002.
59. S. French and D.-L. Xu. Comparison study of multi-attribute decision analytic software.
Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 13(2-3):65–80, 2005.
60. F. Galton. Vox populi. Nature, 75:450–451, 1907.
61. S. I. Gass. Model world: The great debate — MAUT versus AHP. Interfaces, 35(4):308–312,
2005.
62. S. I. Gass and T. Rapcsák. Singular value decomposition in AHP. European Journal of
Operational Research, 154(3):573–584, 2004.
63. B. L. Golden and Q. Wang. An alternate measure of consistency. In B. L. Golden, E. A.
Wasil, and P. T. Harker, editors, The Analytic Hierarchy Process: Applications and Studies,
pages 68–81. Springer-Verlag, 1989.
64. B. L. Golden, E. A. Wasil, and D. E. Levy. Applications of the analytic hierarchy process:
A categorized, annotated bibliography. In The Analytic Hierarchy Process: Applications and
Studies, pages 37–58. Springer-Verlag, 1989.
65. R. Hämäläinen. Decisionarium—aiding decisions, negotiating and collecting opinions on
the web. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 12(2-3):101–110, 2003.
66. R. P. Hämäläinen and T. O. Seppäläinen. The analytic network process in energy policy
planning. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 20(6):399–405, 1986.
67. P. T. Harker. Derivatives of the Perron root of a positive reciprocal matrix: with application
to the analytic hierarchy process. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 22(2):217–232,
1987.
68. P. T. Harker. Incomplete pairwise comparisons in the analytic hierarchy process. Mathemat-
ical Modelling, 9(11):837–848, 1987.
80 References
69. E. Herrera-Viedma, F. Herrera, F. Chiclana, and M. Luque. Some issues on consistency
of fuzzy preference relations. European Journal of Operational Research, 154(1):98–109,
2004.
70. R. A. Horn and C. R. Johnson. Matrix Analysis. Cambridge University Press, 1985.
71. A. Ishizaka, D. Balkenborg, and T. Kaplan. Does AHP help us make a choice? An experi-
mental evaluation. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 62(10):1801–1812, 2011.
72. A. Ishizaka and A. Labib. Analytic hierarchy process and expert choice: Benefits and limi-
tations. OR Insight, 22(4):201–220, 2002.
73. A. Ishizaka and M. Lusti. How to derive priorities in AHP: a comparative study. Central
European Journal of Operations Research, 14(4):387–400, 2006.
74. A. Ishizaka and P. Nemery. Multi-criteria Decision Analysis: Methods and Software. Wiley,
2013.
75. P. Ji and R. Jiang. Scale transitivity in the AHP. Journal of the Operational Research Society,
54(8):896–905, 2003.
76. R. L. Keeney and H. Raiffa. Decisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value
Tradeoffs. Wiley, New York, 1976.
77. G. J. Klir. Uncertainty in economics: The heritage of G.L.S. Shackle. Fuzzy Economic
Review, 7(2):3–21, 2002.
78. G. J. Klir. Uncertainty and Information: Foundations of Generalized Information Theory.
Wiley, 2005.
79. G. J. Klir and B. Yuan. Fuzzy Sets and Fuzzy Logic: Theory and Applications. Pretience
Hall, 1995.
80. W. W. Koczkodaj. A new definition of consistency of pairwise comparisons. Mathematical
and Computer Modelling, 18(7):79–84, 1993.
81. W. W. Koczkodaj and M. Orlowski. An orthogonal basis for computing a consistent approx-
imation to a pairwise comparisons matrix. Computers & Mathematics with Applications,
34(10):41–47, 1997.
82. C.-C. Lin. A revised framework for deriving preference values from pairwise comparison
matrices. European Journal of Operational Research, 176(2):1145–1150, 2007.
83. C. S. Lin and S. L. Harris. A unified framework for the prioritization of organ transplant
patients: Analytic hierarchy process, sensitivity and multifactor robustness study. Journal of
Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 20(3-4):157–172, 2013.
84. H. A. Linstone and M. Turoff. The Delphi Method: Techniques and Applications, volume 29.
Addison-Wesley Massachussets, 1979.
85. F. A. Lootsma. Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis via Ratio and Difference Judgement, vol-
ume 29 of Applied Optimization. Springer, 1999.
86. R. D. Luce and H. Raiffa. Games and Decisions. John Wiley and Sons, 1957.
87. R. D. Luce and P. Suppes. Preference, utility, and subjective probability. Handbook of
Mathematical Psychology, 3:249–410, 1965.
88. H. Maleki and S. Zahir. A comprehensive literature review of the rank reversal phenomenon
in the analytic hierarchy process. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 20(3-4):141–
155, 2013.
89. J. Mingers. Soft OR comes of age—but not everywhere! Omega, 39(6):729–741, 2011.
90. S. Nikou and J. Mezei. Evaluation of mobile services and substantial adoption factors with
analytic hierarchy process (AHP). Telecommunications Policy, 37(10):915–929, 2013.
91. D. L. Olson, G. Fliedner, and K. Currie. Comparison of the REMBRANDT system with ana-
lytic hierarchy process. European Journal of Operational Research, 82(3):522–539, 1995.
92. W. Pedrycz. Why triangular membership functions? Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 64(1):21–30,
1994.
93. J. I. Peláez and M. T. Lamata. A new measure of consistency for positive reciprocal matrices.
Computers & Mathematics with Applications, 46(12):1839–1845, 2003.
94. K. Peniwati. Criteria for evaluating group decision-making methods. Mathematical and
Computer Modelling, 46(7-8):935–947, 2007.
95. K. Peniwati and T. Hsiao. Ranking countries according to economics, social and political
indicators. Mathematical Modelling, 9(3-5):203–209, 1987.
References 81
96. M. A. Pöhjönen, R. P. Hämäläinen, and A. A. Salo. An experiment on the numerical mod-
elling of verbal ratio statements. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 6(1):1–10,
1997.
97. J. Ramı́k and P. Korviny. Inconsistency of pair-wise comparison matrix with fuzzy elements
based on geometric mean. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 161(11):1604–1613, 2010.
98. T. L. Saaty. Mathematical Methods of Operational Research. McGraw Hill, 1959.
99. T. L. Saaty. A scaling method for priorities in hierarchical structures. Journal of Mathemat-
ical Psychology, 15(3):234–281, 1977.
100. T. L. Saaty. The Analytic Hierarchy Process: Planning, Priority Setting, Resource Allocation.
McGraw-Hill, New York, 1980.
101. T. L. Saaty. The Logic of Priorities: Applications in Business, Energy, Health and Trans-
portation. Kluwer-Nijhoff, Boston, 1982.
102. T. L. Saaty. Absolute and relative measurement with the AHP. The most livable cities in the
United States. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 20(6):327–331, 1986.
103. T. L. Saaty. Axiomatic foundation of the analytic hierarchy process. Management Science,
32(7):841–855, 1986.
104. T. L. Saaty. Decision Making for Leaders. The Analytic Hierarchy Process for Decisions in
a Complex World. University of Pittsburgh Press, 1988.
105. T. L. Saaty. Eigenvector and logarithmic least squares. European Journal of Operational
Research, 48(1):156–160, 1990.
106. T. L. Saaty. What is relative measurement? The ratio scale phantom. Mathematical and
Computer Modelling, 17(4-5):1–12, 1993.
107. T. L. Saaty. Relative measurement and its generalization in decision making why pairwise
comparisons are central in mathematics for the measurement of intangible factors the analytic
hierarchy/network process. RACSAM-Revista de la Real Academia de Ciencias Exactas,
Fisicas y Naturales. Serie A. Matematicas, 102(2):251–318, 2008.
108. T. L. Saaty and C. Alsina. On synthesis of judgements. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences,
20(6):333–339, 1986.
109. T. L. Saaty and G. Hu. Ranking by eigenvector versus other methods in the analytic hierarchy
process. Applied Mathematics Letters, 11(4):121–125, 1998.
110. T. L. Saaty and M. S. Ozdemir. Why the magic number seven plus or minus two. Mathemat-
ical and Computer Modelling, 38(3):233–244, 2003.
111. T. L. Saaty and M. Sagir. Global awareness, future city design and decision making. Journal
of Systems Science and Systems Engineering, 21(3):337–355, 2012.
112. T. L. Saaty and M. Sodenkamp. The analytic hierarchy and analytic network measurement
processes: the measurement of intangibles. In Handbook of Multicriteria Analysis, pages
91–166. Springer, 2010.
113. T. L. Saaty and L. T. Tran. On the invalidity of fuzzifying numerical judgements in the
analytic hierarchy process. Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 46(7-8):962–975, 2007.
114. T. L. Saaty and L. G. Vargas. Hierarchical analysis of behavior in competition: Prediction in
chess. Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 25(3):180–191, 1980.
115. T. L. Saaty and L. G. Vargas. Comparison of the eigenvalue, logarithmic least squares and
least squares methods in estimating ratios. Mathematical Modelling, 5(5):309–324, 1984.
116. T. L. Saaty and L. G. Vargas. Modeling behavior in competition: The analytic hierarchy
process. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 16(1):49–92, 1985.
117. T. L. Saaty and L. G. Vargas. Uncertainty and rank order in the analytic hierarchy process.
European Journal of Operational Research, 32(1):107–117, 1987.
118. T. L. Saaty and L. G. Vargas. Decision Making with the Analytic Network Process: Eco-
nomic, Political, Social and Technological Applications with Benefits, Opportunities, Costs
and Risks, volume 195 of International Series in Operations Research & Management Sci-
ence. Springer, 2nd edition, 2013.
119. A. A. Salo and R. Hämäläinen. Preference programming through approximate ratio compar-
isons. European Journal of Operational Research, 82(3):458–475, 1995.
120. A. A. Salo and R. Hämäläinen. On the measurement of preferences in the analytic hierarchy
process. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 6(6):309–319, 1997.
82 References
121. M. Shimura. Fuzzy sets concept in rank-ordering objects. Journal of Mathematical Analysis
and Applications, 43(3):717–733, 1973.
122. S. Shiraishi and T. Obata. On a maximization problem arising from a positive reciprocal
matrix in the AHP. Bulletin of Informatics and Cybernetics, 34(2):91–96, 2002.
123. S. Shiraishi, T. Obata, and M. Daigo. Properties of a positive reciprocal matrix and their
application to AHP. Journal of the Operations Research Society of Japan, 41(3):404–414,
1998.
124. S. Shiraishi, T. Obata, M. Daigo, and N. Nakajima. Assessment for an incomplete compari-
son matrix and improvement of an inconsistent comparison: computational experiments. In
ISAHP, pages 200–205, 1999.
125. W. E. Stein and P. J. Mizzi. The harmonic consistency index for the analytic hierarchy
process. European Journal of Operational Research, 177(1):488–497, 2007.
126. J. Surowiecki. The Wisdom of Crowds. Random House LLC, 2005.
127. T. Tanino. Fuzzy preference orderings in group decision making. Fuzzy Sets and Systems,
12(2):117–131, 1984.
128. P. J. M. van Laarhoven and W. Pedrycz. A fuzzy extension of Saaty’s priority theory. Fuzzy
Sets and Systems, 11(1-3):229–241, 1983.
129. L. G. Vargas. An overview of the analytic hierarchy process and its applications. European
Journal of Operational Research, 48(1):2–8, 1990.
130. L. G. Vargas. Comments on Barzilai and Lootsma: Why the multiplicative AHP is invalid: A
practical counterexample. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 6(3):169–170, 1997.
131. J. von Neumann and O. Morgenstern. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton
University Press, 1944.
132. J. Wallenius, J. S. Dyer, P. C. Fishburn, R. E. Steuer, S. Zionts, and K. Deb. Multiple criteria
decision making, multiattribute utility theory: Recent accomplishments and what lies ahead.
Management Science, 54(7):1336–1349, 2008.
133. X. Wang and E. E. Kerre. Reasonable properties for the ordering of fuzzy quantities (i).
Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 118(3):375–385, 2001.
134. Y.-M. Wang, Y. Luo, and Z. Hua. On the extent analysis for fuzzy AHP and its applications.
European Journal of Operational Research, 186(2):735–747, 2008.
135. Z. Xu. A survey of preference relations. International Journal of General Systems,
36(2):179–203, 2007.
136. R. R. Yager. An eigenvalue method of obtaining subjective probabilities. Systems Research
and Behavioral Science, 24(6):382–387, 1979.
137. L. A. Zadeh. Fuzzy sets. Information and Control, 8:338–353, 1965.
138. L. A. Zadeh. Similarity relations and fuzzy orderings. Information Sciences, 3(2):177–200,
1971.
139. L. A. Zadeh. Fuzzy sets as a basis for a theory of possibility. Fuzzy Sets and Systems,
1(1):3–28, 1978.
140. F. Zahedi. The analytic hierarchy process—A survey of the method and its applications.
Interfaces, 16(4):96–108, 1986.
141. K. Zhü. Fuzzy analytic hierarchy process: Fallacies of the popular methods. European
Journal of Operational Research, 236(1):209–217, 2014.
Index
Abstract algebra, 50 Group isomorphisms, 50
Additive pairwise comparison matrices, 46 Group theory, 50
Aggregation of individual judgments, 39
Aggregation of individual priorities, 40 Harmonic consistency index, 28
Ambiguity index, 28 Hierarchy, 7
Analytic Network Process (ANP), 65
Applications, 10 Incomplete pairwise comparison matrix, 33
Inconsistency indices, 24
Chebyshev center, 54 Interval AHP, 51
Coefficient c3 , 26, 34
Compatibility index, 42 Least squares method, 21
Condition of order preservation, 22 Linear space, 46
Consistency, 22
Consistency conditions, 24 Multi-attribute value theory, 66
Consistency index, 24
Consistency ratio, 25 Normalized columns method, 21
Delphi method, 39 Pareto efficiency, 22
Perron-Frobenius theorem, 18
Eigenvalues, 71 Priority vector, 17
Eigenvector method, 18
Eigenvectors, 71 Random index, 25
ELECTRE, 67 Rank reversal, 13
Equivalent representations, 45 Reciprocal relations, 47
Euclidean center, 54 Relative measurement theory, 14
Extent analysis, 60 Revised geometric mean method, 36
Functional analysis, 40 Sensitivity analysis, 68
Fuzzy AHP, 56 Software, 68
Fuzzy number, 56 Subjective probability, 12
Geometric consistency index, 27 Triangular fuzzy number, 57
Geometric mean method, 19
Group decisions, 38 Weak consistency condition, 31
c Matteo Brunelli 2015 83
M. Brunelli, Introduction to the Analytic Hierarchy Process,
SpringerBriefs in Operations Research, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-12502-2