Por Qué La Economía Conductual Es Tan Popular?
Por Qué La Economía Conductual Es Tan Popular?
tan popular?
La reciente moda de este campo académico es en parte un triunfo del marketing.
CréditoCréditoMichael DeForge
Esta es tu vista previa de un artículo.
Inicie sesión o cree una cuenta gratuita para leer más artículos cada mes.
What is behavioral economics, and why has it become so popular? The field has
been described by Richard Thaler, one of its founders, as “economics done with
strong injections of good psychology.” Proponents view it as a way to make
economics more accurate by incorporating more realistic assumptions about how
humans behave.
In practice, much of behavioral economics consists in using psychological insights
to influence behavior. These interventions tend to be small, often involving subtle
changes in how choices are presented: for example, whether you have to “opt in” to
a 401(k) savings plan versus having to “opt out.” In this respect, behavioral
economics can be thought of as endorsing the outsize benefits of psychological
“tricks,” rather than as calling for more fundamental behavioral or policy change.
Yet this triumph has come at a cost. In order to appeal to other economists,
behavioral economists are too often concerned with describing how human
behavior deviates from the assumptions of standard economic models, rather than
with understanding why people behave the way they do.
Consider loss aversion. This is the notion that losses have a bigger psychological
impact than gains do — that losing $5, for example, feels worse than gaining $5
feels good. Behavioral economists point to loss aversion as a psychological glitch
that explains a lot of puzzling human conduct. But in an article published this year,
the psychologist Derek D. Rucker and I contend that the behaviors most commonly
attributed to loss aversion are a result of other causes.
But Dr. Rucker and I note that there is an alternative explanation: The participants
may not have had a clearly defined idea of what the mug was worth to them. If that
was the case, there was a range of prices for the mug ($4 to $6) that left the
participants disinclined to either buy or sell it, and therefore mug owners and non-
owners maintained the status quo out of inertia. Only a relatively high price ($7
and up) offered a meaningful incentive for an owner to bother parting with the
mug; correspondingly, only a relatively low price ($3 or below) offered a
meaningful incentive for a non-owner to bother acquiring the mug.
The effects of this kind of intervention are often small. Recent studies have found
that providing households with information on how their electricity usage
compared to that of other households — a classic “nudge” — reduced electricity
consumption by only 2 percent or less.
There is nothing wrong with achieving small victories with minor interventions.
The worry, however, is that the perceived simplicity and efficacy of such tactics will
distract decision makers from more substantive efforts — for example, reducing
electricity consumption by taxing it more heavily or investing in renewable energy
resources.
It is great that behavioral economics is receiving its due; the field has contributed
significantly to our understanding of ourselves. But in all the excitement, it’s
important to keep an eye on its limits.