46 Sample Chapter
46 Sample Chapter
46 Sample Chapter
Classical Macroeconomics
as old industries shutting down and new ones coming up or unemployment that
occurs during business cycles (recessions or depression).
Full employment will, then, occur only in the long run. So, long run
perspective is implicit in all these postulates. The classicals generally ignore
short run problems however serious they may be. In the long run, total demand
for labour will always be equal to total supply of labour and total output (of
goods and services) will be at its full potential level.
Lapses from full employment, classicals suggest, may be corrected by
appropriate wage cut given sufficient flexibility in the wage system. Thus,
classical economists viewed unemployment as a passing phase in the development
of capitalist economy while full employment being a normal phenomenon.
sector is known as absolute price level or nominal price level or simply ‘level
of prices’. On the other hand, the price level determined in the real sector is
known as relative price level (price of one product in terms of other product). For
understanding the underlying meaning of this classical dichotomy, we take an
example. Let us suppose there are two goods: wheat and potato whose nominal
prices are ` 10.00 per kg and ` 15.00 per kg respectively (or, their real price
ratio is 1.5 units of wheat: 1 unit of potato). If, for some reason, the supply of
money in the economy suddenly doubles, the prices of wheat and potato also
double to ` 20 per kg and ` 30 per kg. But their relative price ratio remains
the same, i.e., 1.5 units of wheat : 1 unit of potato. This is because the relative
price level is something determined by factors such as, relative factor supplies
of goods services and technology of production which are independent of the
factors affecting the monetary sector.
Surprisingly, however, the reverse causation is not true, so that changes in
the real sector do influence the monetary sector.
or national income version. The latter version has become more popular and
convenient expression of quantity theory.
The Fisherian version of quantity theory is expressed in terms of the following
equation:
MV=PT (2.1)
where M = Supply of money used for purchase-sale of goods, V = velocity of
circulation of money, T = Total volume of transactions of all goods, P = Average
price level.
Equation (2.1) is an expression that simply equates two sides of transactions
(purchase and sale) of all goods in the economy, with the help of money, during
a certain period of time. The right hand side of equation (2.1) shows the total
quantity of goods sold valued at their average price level while the left hand
side shows the total amount of money required for goods bought. This seems
to be an obvious fact and shows the equilibrium condition of the economy. The
explanation of the terms (M, V, P and T) is as follows:
M, the supply of money, refers to the money in circulation (notes and coins)
as also bank money (demand deposits). M is supposed to be exogenously given.
At the time when quantity theory was originally developed, M was supposed
to constitute only the currency in circulation. However, when transactions by
individuals and businesses included operations through banks, bank deposits
were also included in M.
V, the velocity of circulation of M, stands for the average number of times
money is used up in the process of transaction of goods during the specified
period of time. In other words, individual units of money (for instance, individual
coins or notes of different denominations) may be used up different number of
times, but V stands only for their average number.
T refers to the total volume of goods transacted. It includes all goods –
intermediate (goods used as inputs to industries) as well as final goods.
P is the average price-level, i.e., money prices of all goods taken at their
average value.
Referring back to equation (2.1), T is assumed given and constant and is
also independent of M and V. Recalling the dichotomy postulate which states
that goods sector (or, real sector) is independent of monetary sector, the
constancy of T can be better understood. T, representing the total outputs of
goods is determined by the factor supplies and technology. The total volume of T
signifying total output of the economy, is constant at its maximum feasible level.
In other words, full use of available technology and resources (including labour)
is assumed to have been made to produce total volume of T (or, supply of goods)
at full employment. V is a significant factor in the equation. It is also constant
and unrelated to either M or T. It is determined by institutional and structural
Classical Macroeconomics 29
factors of the economy and society such as payment system (payment habits and
patterns) as also the structure of the economy. For instance, if the receipt and
payment pattern of either an individual or business is once a week as against
once a month, the velocity of money in the case of the former will be greater
than in the latter. Similarly, if the structure of the economy requires that most
payments are made in cash than in any other form, the velocity will be higher.
Now, V is not only constant but its value will be maximum, given the assumption
that money is meant only for transaction purposes, and hence, people would
hold money for minimum period necessary. Constancy of V is also obvious from
the fact that it is the ratio between PT and M (V = PT/M) and while T part
is independent, M is exogenously determined and P, of course, is calculated
part depending on measurement yardsticks. Thus, if V is constant (at maximum
value), T is also constant, it is easy to establish that P varies proportionately
(and, of course, directly) with M. If M increases (decreases) by say 100 per cent,
P also increases (decreases) by 100 per cent.
Another version of the classical quantity theory, known as Income Version
has gained popularity on account of aggregation and of problem of measurement
of large number of physical goods under the volume of transactions (T) and the
problem of measurement of price levels of all such goods. The income version,
instead, can be stated as:
MW = P0Y (2.2)
where, M = money supply, W = income velocity of money, Y = real national
income or product P0 = average price level of Y. P0 can be defined as GNP
deflator also (an index number used to obtain real GNP – from GNP at current
prices to GNP at constant prices), see Chapter 1 page 7)
In equation (2.2), W is the average number of times M (or, units of money) is
used for transaction of final goods and services only, i.e., Y or GNP. Obviously,
the value of W is less than V since volume of Y is less than T.
In the present formulation also, the earlier conditions and implications of
equation (2.1) hold, viz., the constancy of W and Y, both being at their maximum
feasible levels as also both being independent of M or P0 for reasons explained
in the context of equation (2.1). Thus, the utilimate conclusion – M and P0 are
directly and proportionately related hold equally truly.
One significant implication of equation (2.2) is that now W, the velocity, can
be expressed as a ratio of nominal GNP (P0Y) and money supply (M). If both P0Y
and M change proportionately W remains constant. If, by assumption, Y is at full
employment level and hence constant, proportionate change in M will produce
proportionate change in P0.1
1
The constant velocity characteristic will further be discussed in the Theory of Demand for Money by
Milton Friedman in Chapter 6.
30 A Textbook of Modern Macroeconomics
fi P = 225/75 = 3.00
So, P increases from 2.667 to 3.00, i.e., by 12.5%.
Thus, an increase in money supply raises price level by the same extent.
Therefore, the relationship between money supply and price level is
direct and proportionate. Let us examine if this change has any impact
on money wage rate.
The real wage rate, W/P is now W/3 = 5; giving W = 15.
But, W/P = 15/3 = 5.
W has now increased from 13.335 to 15.00, i.e., by 12.4859% or, 12.5%.
Thus, money wage rate has also increased by the same extent as the
price-level and money wage rate has changed by the same extent and in
the same direction but real wage rate remains the same.
(b) Secondly, we can analyse the impact of change in real sector variables
on the monetary sector in the following manner:
Let the supply curve of labour change from
15 + 2W/P to 20 + 2 W/P (a shift of the supply curve to the right)
The labour market equilibrium will now be solved by equating the
demand curve with the new supply curve of labour:
50 – 5W/P = 20 + 2W/P which gives W/P = 4.2857.
The corresponding demand and supply of labour will be 28.5714.
Substituting this value in eqn. (1) we obtain,
Y = 10 × 28.574 – 0.1 (28.5714)2
= 285.714 – 81.6325 = 204.0815
Thus output increases from 187.5 to 204.08, i.e., by 8.84 per cent. The
employment of labour increases from 25 to 28.57, i.e., by 3.57 units or,
by 14.28 per cent.
Now money supply remaining the same, i.e.,
200 = 0.4 PY,
and Y being higher now at 204.0815, by substituting we obtain,
200 = 0.4P (204.0815)
fi 200 = 81.6325 P
giving the value of P = 2.45.
Thus, price level is now lower as compared to 2.667 earlier. In percentage
terms, P has fallen by 8.14 per cent.
However, we have seen earlier that the real wage rate has already fallen
to 4.2857. Hence, money wage rate now is solved as 4.2857 = W/2.45
= 10.4999.
Classical Macroeconomics 39
Thus, W has decreased from 13.335 to 10.4999, i.e., by 21.26 per cent
which is larger percentage fall than fall the price level.
Thus, the shift in the supply curve of labour to the right results in:
(a) Increase in output, (b) increase in employment, (c) fall in real wage
rate, (d) fall in price level and (e) fall in money wage rate.
In the similar vein, we can analyze the effect of change in technology
(shift in production function) on the real sector as well as monetary
sector variables (shift in production function upward means better and
improved technology)1
SUMMARY
1. Classical macroeconomics is based on a set of postulates/assumptions
such as long period, Say’s law of market, full employment, flexibility
of wages and prices, neutrality of money, absence of money illusion
and dichotomy between real and monetary sectors. If these postulates
are accepted, classical macroeconomics produces a neat systematic and
logical theory to explain the working of the economy.
2. Long period is the key assumption which allow economic agents to
sufficiently adjust and revise their decisions and attain the new level of
equilibrium. Even though they do consider changes occurring during
short period, but such changes are not important for the classicals.
1
In this case the production function might be: Y = 16N – 0.1N2 or any higher value of the intercept.
Classical Macroeconomics 41