Optimal Monetary Rules: The Case of Brazil: TÞ 1 1 T 2 T 3 T TÞ 1
Optimal Monetary Rules: The Case of Brazil: TÞ 1 1 T 2 T 3 T TÞ 1
Within a dynamic programming approach, an optimal rule for the central bank to
attain its inflation targeting goals is derived. The short-run nominal interest rate is
used as an instrument to achieve monetary objectives. The model is tested for the
Brazilian economy and compared with results found for other countries. Evidence
for the estimated feedback interest rule for the Central Bank suggests that the cost of
reducing inflation in an open economy is lower than that of a closed economy.
Applied Economics Letters ISSN 1350–4851 print/ISSN 1466–4291 online ß 2003 Taylor & Francis Ltd 299
http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals
DOI: 10.1080/0003684032000066804
300 Charles Lima De Almeida et al.
where yt denotes the output gap, it is the real interest rate, Solving problem (2.11) with respect to t gives the first-
et is the real exchange rate, and ut is a demand shock, order condition:
assumed to be normally distributed.
The supply curve is represented by the traditional t þ Vz Et ðztþ1 Þ ¼ 0 ð2:12Þ
Phillips curve:
Applying the envelope theorem with respect to zt gives:
tþ1 ¼ t þ yt þ ð"t "t1 Þ þ tþ1 ð2:2Þ
Vz ðzt Þ ¼ zt þ Vz Et ðztþ1 Þ ð2:13Þ
where t is the inflation rate, "t is the depreciation rate in
Multiplying Equation 2.13 by , substituting in Equation
the nominal exchange rate and tþ1 the supply shock not
2.12, taking this expression one-step forward and
correlated with utþ1.
expectations:
The policy maker chooses in instant t the interest rate it,
and the state variable in instant t is
Et Vz ðztþ1 Þ ¼ zt þ t Et ðtþ1 Þ ð2:14Þ
zt ¼ yt þ t þ ð"t "t1 Þ ð2:3Þ
Inserting Equation 2.14 in Equation 2.12:
The optimal feedback rule will be given by
t ¼ Xzt ð2:4Þ t ¼ zt þ Et ðtþ1 Þ ð2:15Þ
þ 2 þ 2
where When the policy is established in instant t, zt is the state
variable and thus the optimal policy rule has a quadratic
t ¼ a1 ytt þ a2 it þ et ð2:5Þ form t ¼ Xzt. Therefore
Equations 2.1 and 2.2 can be rewritten as Etþ1 ðtþ1 Þ ¼ XEt ðztþ1 Þ ¼ X ð1 þ X Þzt ð2:16Þ
ytþ1 ¼ t þ utþ1 ð2:6Þ Inserting this expression in Equation 2.15 gives the
following quadratic form:
and
X 2 þ 2 X þ ¼ 0 ð2:17Þ
tþ1 ¼ zt þ tþ1 ð2:7Þ
Define the value function as After some algebraic operations the product of the roots is
1 1
Vðzt Þ ¼ minEt ð y2tþ1 þ 2tþ1 Þ þ Vðztþ1 Þ ð2:10Þ X1 X2 ¼ < 0 ð2:20Þ
2
replacing Equations 2.6, 2.7 and 2.9 in the value function The root of interest is the one that satisfies the stability
we obtain: condition, that is the negative root X2. Finally, replacing
X2 in Equation 2.4 gives
1 1 qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
Vðzt Þ ¼ min Et ðt þ utþ1 Þ2 þ Et ðzt þ tþ1 Þ2
t 2 2 ð þ 2 Þ ð þ 2 Þ2 þ 4ð 2 2 Þ
ð2:11Þ t ¼ zt
2
þEt Vðzt þ t þ utþ1 þ tþ1 Þ
ð2:21Þ
Optimal monetary rules: the case of Brazil 301
We can derive the optimal rule for the interest rate Applying Augmented Dickey and Fuller tests, the null of
a unit root for the output gap, interest rates and inflation is
a1 X2 a3 X2 X2 rejected. Results for these unit roots are available upon
it ¼ yt þ et þ t þ et ð2:22Þ
a2 a2 a2 a2 request from the authors.
In order to derive the optimal policy rule for the
Brazilian economy, ¼ 0.7 and ¼ 1 were assumed, which
are the intertemporal discount factor and the relative
III. EMPIRICAL RESULTS weight of output gap in the loss function. After replacing
these parameters and coefficients in Table 1 and Table 2
For the econometric analysis we have used quarterly data one obtains
and the sample begins in the first quarter of 1994 and ends
in the last quarter of 2001. All variables are in natural logs. it ¼ 5; 5yt þ 4; 2t ð3:1Þ
As a proxy for the output gap we have estimated a
Hodrick–Prescott filter and used the difference between These results are quite different from those found in Taylor
observed GDP and the filtered series. The inflation rate is (1993) and Ball (1998) and are more in line with those
given by IPCA. The interest rate is given by SELIC, which found in Walsh (1997) (see Table 3).
is the instrument that the central bank uses to achieve it’s The coefficient on the output gap is similar to that found
price stability goals. in Ball (1998), while the coefficient on inflation is much
According to the results, shown in Table 1, both the lag higher than that found previously, which suggests that the
of the output gap and lagged interest rate are significant central bank of Brazil has to increase its interest rates much
in explaining current output gap, and the sign of the more than developed countries in order to counterbalance
coefficients are in line with the expected sign. As an increase in inflation.
instruments, a dummy for the Russian crisis, three lags Table 4 and Table 5 present results for an open economy.
for the interest rate and four lags for government spending Replacing the results one obtains the optimal rule:
were used.
Table 2 presents empirical results for the Phillips it ¼ 5:2yt þ 0:3t þ 0:6"t1 þ 0:2et ð3:2Þ
equation. Both lagged output gap and inflation are
significant in explaining current inflation. As instruments, To the best of our knowledge, most research on developed
a dummy for the Russian crisis, six lags for the inflation countries has estimated different optimal feedback rules,
rate and two lags for government spending have been used. making comparisons more difficult. As can be seen, the
coefficient on inflation has decreased to 0.3. Thus, the
Table 1. IS equation – closed economy
Standard errors are given in parentheses. Rejection of the null Standard errors are given in parentheses. Rejection of the null
with 99% confidence. Rejection of the null with 95% with 99% confidence. Rejection of the null with 95%
confidence. confidence.
302 Charles Lima De Almeida et al.
Table 5. Phillips equation – open economy derived using a dynamic programming approach and a
dynamic loss function. IS-AS equations have been esti-
Variables Coefficients p-value mated using two-stage least squares and an optimal
yt1 0.08 0.02 feedback rule has been fitted for short run interest rates
(0.05) for both closed and open economies.
"t 0.07 0.03 It has been found that the feedback rule behaves
(0.01) differently from similar rules estimated for developed
t1 0.65 0.00 countries. For the open economy evidence suggests that
(0.038)
interest rates needs to rise less than one-to-one with inflation
Adjusted R2 ¼ 64%
(while the contrary happens within a closed economy).
Standard errors are given in parentheses. Rejection of the null Thus, it is found that within an open economy the central
with 99% confidence. Rejection of the null with 95% bank has much more power to reduce inflation than within a
confidence. closed economy. This issue will be left for further research.