0% found this document useful (0 votes)
38 views36 pages

Lecture 4 Ec 106 Preferences

The document provides an outline and overview of key concepts related to consumer preferences and choice in economics, including: (1) Preference relations are used to model how consumers compare and rank different bundles of goods, using notions of strict preference, weak preference, and indifference. (2) Utility functions provide a formal way to represent preferences in terms of increasing or decreasing levels of satisfaction. (3) Indifference curves illustrate bundles that provide equal levels of utility or satisfaction. (4) Marginal utility and marginal rates of substitution are important concepts for understanding consumer optimization. (5) Specific utility functions like Cobb-Douglas are discussed as examples.

Uploaded by

Eileen
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
38 views36 pages

Lecture 4 Ec 106 Preferences

The document provides an outline and overview of key concepts related to consumer preferences and choice in economics, including: (1) Preference relations are used to model how consumers compare and rank different bundles of goods, using notions of strict preference, weak preference, and indifference. (2) Utility functions provide a formal way to represent preferences in terms of increasing or decreasing levels of satisfaction. (3) Indifference curves illustrate bundles that provide equal levels of utility or satisfaction. (4) Marginal utility and marginal rates of substitution are important concepts for understanding consumer optimization. (5) Specific utility functions like Cobb-Douglas are discussed as examples.

Uploaded by

Eileen
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 36

Topic

Outline

§  Budget Sets and Budget Constraints


§  Consumer Preferences
§  The best feasible choice of consumption
§  Applications
Consumer Choice II
PREFERENCES:UTILITY
Rationality in Economics

§  Behavioral Postulate:
A decisionmaker always chooses its most
preferred alternative from its set of
available alternatives.
§  So to model choice we must model
decisionmakers preferences.
Preference Relations
§  Comparing two different consumption
bundles, x and y:
ú  strict preference: x is more preferred than is y.
ú  weak preference: x is as at least as preferred as
is y.
ú  indifference: x is exactly as preferred as is y.
Preference Relations

§  Strict preference, weak preference and


indifference are all preference relations.
§  Particularly, they are ordinal relations; i.e.
they state only the order in which bundles
are preferred.
Preference Relations
≺"
§  denotes strict preference;
≺"
x y means that bundle x is preferred
strictly to bundle y.
Preference Relations
≺"
§  denotes strict preference;
≺"
x y means bundle x is preferred strictly to
bundle y.
§  ∼ denotes indifference; x ∼ y means x and y
are equally preferred.
Preference Relations
≺"
§  denotes strict preference so
≺"
x y means that bundle x is preferred
strictly to bundle y.
§  ∼ denotes indifference; x ∼ y means x and y
are equally preferred.
§  ≻" denotes weak preference;
~
§  x ≻" y means x is preferred at least as much
~
as is y.
Preference Relations

§  x ≻" y and y ≻" x imply x ∼ y.


~ ~
Preference Relations

§  x≻" y and y ≻" x imply x ∼ y.


~ ~
Assumptions about Preference
Relations
§  Completeness: For any two bundles x
and y it is always possible to make the
statement that either
x ≻" y
or ~
y ≻" x.
~
Assumptions about Preference
Relations
§  Reflexivity: Any bundle x is always at
least as preferred as itself; i.e.

x ≻"
~
x.
Assumptions about Preference
Relations
§  Transitivity: If
x is at least as preferred as y, and
y is at least as preferred as z, then
x is at least as preferred as z; i.e.

x≻" y and y ≻" z x ≻"


z.
~ ~ ~
Utility Functions
§  Formal way to represent preferences
§  A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation
if and only if:
≺"
x x U(x ) > U(x )

≺"
x x U(x ) < U(x )

x ∼ x U(x ) = U(x ).
§  Utility is an ordinal (i.e. ordering) concept, i.e. if U(x) =
6 and U(y) = 2 then bundle x is strictly preferred to
bundle y, but not necessarily preferred three times as
much as is y.
Indifference Curves

§  Take a reference bundle x . The set of all


bundles equally preferred to x is the
indifference curve containing x ; the set of
all bundles y ∼ x .
§  Since an indifference curve is not
always a curve a better name might be an
indifference set .
Indifference Curves

x2 x ∼x ∼x
x

x1
Indifference Curves

x2
≺" ≺"
z x y
x

x1
Indifference Curves
I1 All bundles in I1 are
x2
x strictly preferred to
all in I2.
z
I2

All bundles in I2 are


y strictly preferred to
I3
all in I3.
x1
Indifference Curves

x2
WP(x), the set of
x bundles weakly
preferred to x.

I(x) I(x )

x1
Utility Functions & ICs

x2 ≺"
(2,3) (2,2) ∼ (4,1)

Is U(x1,x2) = x1x2 a suitable


utility function to represent
these bundles?

U≡6
U≡4

x1
Perfect Substitution Indifference
Curves
x2
x1 + x 2 = 5
13
x1 + x 2 = 9
9
x1 + x2 = 13
5
V(x1,x2) = x1 + x2.

5 9 13 x1
All are linear and parallel.
Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves;
Perfect Complements
x2
45o Each of (5,5), (5,9)
and (9,5) contains
5 pairs so each is
equally preferred.
9
5 I1

5 9 x1
Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves;
Perfect Complements
x2
45o Since each of (5,5),
(5,9) and (9,5)
contains 5 pairs,
each is less
9 I2 preferred than the
bundle (9,9) which
5 I1 contains 9 pairs.

5 9 x1
Perfect Complementarity
Indifference Curves
x2
45o
W(x1,x2) = min{x1,x2}

8 min{x1,x2} = 8

5 min{x1,x2} = 5
3 min{x1,x2} = 3

3 5 8 x1
All are right-angled with vertices on a ray
from the origin.
Indifference Curves for Discrete
Commodities
§  A commodity is infinitely divisible if it can
be acquired in any quantity; e.g. water or
cheese.
§  A commodity is discrete if it comes in unit
lumps of 1, 2, 3, … and so on; e.g.
aircraft, ships and refrigerators.
Indifference Curves for Discrete
Commodities
§  Suppose commodity 2 is an infinitely
divisible good (gasoline) while commodity
1 is a discrete good (aircraft). What do
indifference curves look like?
Indifference Curves With a Discrete
Good
Gas-
oline Indifference curves
are collections of
discrete points.

0 1 2 3 4 Aircraft
Well-Behaved Preferences

§  A preference relation is well-behaved if


it is
ú  monotonic and convex.
§  Monotonicity: More of any commodity is
always preferred (i.e. no satiation and
every commodity is a good).

§  Convex: “mixtures” of goods preferred to


extremes
Cobb-Douglas Utility Functions
§  Any utility function of the form
U(x1,x2) = x1a x2b

with a > 0 and b > 0


§  Have we seen this one before?
ú  U(x1,x2) = x1x2 (i.e., a= 1 and b = 1)
§  Other examples
ú  U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x21/2 (a = b = 1/2)
ú  V(x1,x2) = x1 x23 (a = 1, b = 3)
ú  Note: a & b tell you much goods 1 and 2 respectively
matter for your satisfaction
Cobb-Douglas Indifference Curves
x2

U(x1,x2) : x1a x2b = k


Curves are hyperbolic,
asymptoting to, but never
touching any axis.

x1
Marginal Utility
§  Marginal means incremental .
§  The marginal utility of a good i (say a donut)
is the rate at which your total utility changes
when you have one more unit, i.e.
∂U
MU i =
∂xi
§  Example: U(x1,x2) = x1 x22
ú  MU1 = x22
ú  MU2 = 2x1 x2



Marginal Rate of Substitution
§  The general equation for an indifference curve is
U(x1,x2) ≡ k, where k is a utility level (constant)
§  Totally differentiating this identity gives
∂U ∂U
dx1 + dx2 = 0
∂ x1 ∂ x2
§  What does this give us (in plain English)?


§  MRS: Rate at which a consumer is willing to
“trade-off” one good for another.

Marginal Rate of Substitution
§  The general equation for an indifference curve is
U(x1,x2) ≡ k, where k is a utility level (constant)
§  Totally differentiating this identity gives
∂U ∂U
dx1 + dx2 = 0
∂ x1 ∂ x2
§  How do we get MRS (hint: it is the slope of IC)?

dx2 ∂U / ∂ x1
=−
dx1 ∂U / ∂ x 2
§  i.e. MRS = -MU1/MU2

Optimal Bundle: ‘Well-behaved’ pref.
•  At A(x1*,x2*), we know that:
x2 Slope(IC) = Slope of BC

•  -MU1/MU2 = -p1/p2

A •  ...or, at A: MU1/p1 = MU2/p2


x 2*
•  In plain English, the ‘bang for
the buck’ from the last penny
spent on each good must be
the same
x 1* x1
• What if that’s not true? Say
MU1/p1 < MU2/p2
•  Spend less on 1 and more on 2
Perfect Substitutes
Optimal bundle is a
x2 ‘Corner’ Solution. Why?
MRS = -1
(MU1/p1)< (MU2/-/p2) for
all quantities of goods 1
and 2
Slope = -p1/p2 >1 with p1 > p2

x1
Summary: Finding Optimal Bundle
§  Check to see if the preferences are one of the
special cases.
§  If yes, figure out the optimal bundle on a
case-by case basis.
§  If they are well-behaved, then figure out
ú  MRS
ú  Price ratio
ú  Find Bundle for which MRS=Price ratio( good 1 : 2)

You might also like