Shelter Fi Nance Strategies For The Poor: Philippines: Gilberto M Llanto
Shelter Fi Nance Strategies For The Poor: Philippines: Gilberto M Llanto
Shelter Fi Nance Strategies For The Poor: Philippines: Gilberto M Llanto
GILBERTO M LLANTO
Gilberto M Llanto holds ABSTRACT In the Philippines, rapid urbanization casts a serious challenge to
a PhD in Economics from providing the urban poor with access to decent shelter. The urban poor lack access
the School of Economics, not only to appropriate housing but also to affordable, tenured, serviced land,
University of the Philippines
(Diliman campus) and is shelter financing, targeted and sustainable subsidies and the means to provide their
currently a Senior Fellow own shelter. This paper focuses on shelter finance strategies for the poor because
at the Philippine Institute it is a key instrument for addressing their shelter problem. The paper critiques the
for Development Studies, current shelter finance innovations that have been developed in the Philippines to
the foremost think tank provide for poor households, especially those in the informal sector, and identifies
in the country. He has
written extensively on
possible areas of improvement in shelter finance for them.
banking and financial
markets, housing finance, KEYWORDS community mortgage programme / finance / informal sector /
local government finance innovations / market-oriented housing strategy / public–private participation /
and microfinance, and his
recent research interests
shelter
include governance
and institutions,
regulatory economics
and infrastructure. He
I. INTRODUCTION
is consultant to the
World Bank, the Asian In the Philippines, rapid urbanization has swelled the ranks of the urban
Development Bank, the poor and created tremendous demand for housing, social services and
Australian Agency for secure land tenure. This has remained unsatisfied. The Housing and
International Development
(AusAID) and various Urban Development Coordinating Council (HUDCC) estimates that
international organizations, the Philippine population will increase from 80 million in 2002 to 98.2
and is Vice-Chairman of million by 2015. The country has one of the highest urban growth rates in
the Board of Directors
of a CARD Bank, the first the world, averaging 5.1 per cent between 1960 and 1995. More than half
microfinance bank in the of the population is in urban areas and this is expected to reach 60 per
country. cent by 2010 if current trends continue. While official data indicate that
Address: Philippine
only about 20 per cent of the 7.5 million urban households fall below the
Institute for Development poverty income line, this indicator alone does not capture the numbers of
Studies, 106 Amorsolo informal settlers living in dire circumstances.
Street, Legaspi Village,
Makati City, Philippines;
Housing and land markets have not kept pace with rapid urban
e-mail: [email protected]. growth. The unmet housing need rose from 2.4 million to 3.6 million
housing units between 2000 and 2004.(1) Over the last decade, the private
1. Ballesteros, Marife (2005), sector provided an annual average of 50,000 housing units, mostly for
“Rethinking institutional
reforms in the Philippine non-poor families. The government-led shelter programme provided on
housing sector”, Philippine average only about 120,000 “units of housing assistance”, many of which
Institute for Development went to employed members of pension funds.(2) The shortfall is primarily
Studies, Makati City.
in low-income housing, where the population is least able to match rising
2. See reference 1. land and house construction costs and where the market has been unable
to provide affordable, conveniently located housing. As a consequence,
Environment & Urbanization Copyright © 2007 International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED). 409
Vol 19(2): 409–423. DOI: 10.1177/0956247807082821 www.sagepublications.com
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 19 No 2 October 2007
five poor urban households has no toilet facility.(4) Rental housing markets 4. See references 1 and 3.
are almost non-existent because of strict rent control laws; and lack of
access to land is a key impediment to house building for the urban poor.
In sum, shelter is simply not affordable for the poor. They lack access
not only to appropriate housing but also to affordable, tenured, serviced
land, shelter financing, targeted and sustainable subsidies and the means
to provide their own shelter.(5) 5. Asian Development
Access to shelter depends to a large extent on efficiencies in production, Bank (2003), Report and
Recommendation of the
finance and regulation. This paper focuses on shelter finance strategies President to the Board of
for the poor because this is a key instrument for addressing their shelter Directors on a Proposed
problem, including access to basic water and sanitation services. Shelter Loan and Technical Assistance
Grant to the Development
finance for middle- and high-income groups is not addressed here because Bank of the Philippines in the
they can easily access the formal financial markets for their housing Republic of the Philippines for
demand. The paper critiques the current shelter finance innovations that the Development of Poor
Urban Communities Sector
have been developed to provide for poor households, especially those
Project, RRP 32499,
in the informal sector, and identifies possible areas of improvement in November.
shelter finance for them.
410
S H E LT E R F I N A N C E S T R A T E G I E S F O R T H E P O O R : P H I L I P P I N E S
411
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 19 No 2 October 2007
The expectation was that government should and could pour an in-
determinate amount of funds into the housing sector, notwithstanding
competing public policy goals requiring funding support. The old ap-
proach failed to direct private sector financing to social housing because
of inappropriate incentives for private sector participation. Consequently,
low-cost and social housing became totally dependent on pension funds
and public sector resources, which unfortunately could not adequately meet
the huge demand–supply gap in the housing market. In addition, the
utilization of members’ pension fund contributions to meet a public policy
goal was shown to be detrimental to the interests of those members.
In the late 1990s, the government started to rethink its housing policy
and strategy. The housing finance market worked for middle- and high-
income groups because they were able to obtain mortgage loans from
private commercial banks and the government’s HDMF, more popularly
known as the Pag–IBIG Fund. The main concern was how to make the
housing market work for poor households, particularly the informal
sector, which makes up the majority of the population.
The major change was a strategy to tap the private mortgage market
to finance the housing demand of low-income households and to target
housing subsidies to those households as outlined in the Medium Term
412
S H E LT E R F I N A N C E S T R A T E G I E S F O R T H E P O O R : P H I L I P P I N E S
Philippine Development Plan. The government saw that its main role was
to provide the environment for private sector participation in the housing
market. Subsidies would only be targeted at poor households. The strategy
called for the integration of low-cost housing (for the employed low-
income households) and social housing (for the informal sector) into the
mainstream credit markets. Government realized that it would be unable
to finance all the requirements in the housing sector, especially given the
huge losses under the formula lending approach and the inappropriate
incentives that misdirected housing subsidies. While creating distortions
in the financial markets, subsidies have discouraged the participation of
private lenders who obviously cannot compete with the government’s
subsidized programmes. The social costs of subsidizing housing loans and
10. See reference 8; also misdirecting subsidies to non-poor borrowers had proven quite high.(10)
Llanto, Gilberto M (1999), What are the outcomes of the shift in housing finance strategy?
“Housing policy: developing a
market-based housing finance The HUDCC projects that demand for the plan period 2006–2010 will
system”, PIDS Policy Notes be around 3.76 million housing units:(11) 1.17 million units to address the
99–15, December, Philippine housing backlog and 2.59 million units for new households. Potential
Institute for Development
Studies, Makati City. average annual housing demand is between 751,000 and 805,000
housing units. Around 94,393 total housing units had been produced by
11. Figures in this paragraph June 2005, a slight improvement over the 86,407 housing units produced
are from a presentation by
Gonzalo Bongolan, President in the previous year. Thirty-five per cent of the housing units for 2005
of the Home Guaranty were for social housing, 16 per cent for low-cost housing and the rest for
Corporation. See Bongolan,
middle- and high-income groups, divided among medium-cost housing,
Gonzalo (2007), “Overview of
Philippine housing and housing condominiums and open market housing. The average annual supply
finance”, presentation to the of housing units (social, low-cost and for middle- and high-income
First Philippine Housing Forum,
15 March, Makati City.
groups) for the last 17 years (1990–2007) was 156,813 units; for the
last 10 years, the average has been 216,216 housing units. The primary
mortgage/contract receivables market from 2001 to 2006 indicates that
the government continued to provide the bulk of funds for housing (80
per cent). The private banking sector has remained conservative with a
share of 20 per cent (Table 1).
The actual production of housing units falls short of government
estimates of the housing demand for the plan period. This shows the
great challenge to the new approach for addressing the critical housing
backlog. The huge demand–supply gap will continue in the future unless
TA B L E 1
Primary mortgage/contract receivable market, 2001–2006
Fund contributors Estimated cumulative releases Percentage
(in million pesos) of total
Government home 64,720.51 (US$ 1,261.36 million) 63.1
development mutual fund
Social security system 85.87 (US$ 1.67 million) 0.1
Government service security 16,833.05 (US$ 328.06 million) 16.4
system
Sub-total 81,639.43 (US$ 1,591.10 million) 79.6
Private banks 20,952.00 (US$ 408.34 million) 20.4
Grand total 102,591.43 (US$1,999.43 million) 100.0
US$1 = Pesos 51.31 (exchange rate sourced from the National Economic and
Development Authority).
413
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 19 No 2 October 2007
414
S H E LT E R F I N A N C E S T R A T E G I E S F O R T H E P O O R : P H I L I P P I N E S
415
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 19 No 2 October 2007
of land that may have been illegally occupied. It is difficult for urban 18. Research in housing
markets shows the critical
poor households to go beyond the first stage loan unless land tenure or role played by secure tenure
ownership is secure. and title for those in the
Performance. It is primarily informal settlers wanting to access lots informal sector. See Jimenez,
and legal titles who have used the CMP. During the period 1993–1998, Emmanuel (1984), “Tenure
security and urban squatting”,
the CMP accounted for an estimated 60 per cent of “completed units Review of Economics and
of assistance” targeted by the NSP.(19) Karaos(20) observed that of all the Statistics Vol 66, pages
government housing programmes, the CMP had the lowest cost per unit 556–567; also Friedman,
Joseph, Emmanuel Jimenez
of assistance and had a higher repayment rate than the UHLP. and Stephen Mayo (1988), “The
The CMP seems to be a successful housing programme for urban poor demand for tenure security
households in terms of reach and affordability.(21) It has the potential to in developing countries”,
Journal of Development
provide informal settlers with land tenure security and decent housing Economics Vol 29, pages
sites. While there are cases of beneficiaries selling their lots to others, 185–198; and Follain, James
many more hold on to the lots awarded to them. Once awarded their lots, and Emmanuel Jimenez (1985),
“Estimating the demand for
they begin to save and slowly make improvements to their dwelling units. housing characteristics: a
Available data indicate that from 1989 to August 2001, the CMP helped survey and critique”, Regional
fund 883 community projects, benefiting 110,632 families, at a total cost Science and Urban Economics
Vol 15, pages 77–107.
of Pesos 3.14 billion.(22) The projects were distributed among 14 of the
country’s 15 regions. Compared to other government housing programmes, 19. See reference 5, Asian
the CMP assisted the greatest number of families in the shortest period Development Bank (2003).
of time with the smallest loan fund utilization. It is cost effective in that
20. Karaos, Anna Marie (2001),
a relatively small loan amount can provide urban poor households with “Decentralization, local
land tenure security and ownership of a small piece of land. According governance and urban poverty
to the NHMFC, the average loan amount under the CMP from 1989 to in four Philippine cities”, Ateneo
University Institute on Church
2000 was Pesos 28,039 per beneficiary, 15 per cent of the average loan and Social Issues, Quezon City.
per beneficiary in other government housing programmes. Moreover, the
CMP’s average monthly amortization of Pesos 185(23) makes it affordable 21. See reference 14, Cacnio
(2001); also see reference 14,
to poor households. Between 1993 and 1998, the CMP performed better Ballesteros and Vertido (2004);
than the UHLP and other government housing programmes in terms and see reference 8, Llanto and
of collection efficiency rate, computed as a cumulative percentage of Orbeta, Jr (2001).
total loan collections over total billing, excluding penalty charges. The
22. US$ 0.06 billion at
CMP’s average loan collection rate during the period stood at 77 per cent US$1 = Pesos 51.31 in 2006.
compared to a 63.3 per cent average for the UHLP.
However, despite its better than average collection rates, the CMP 23. US$ 3.60 per month at
US$1 = Pesos 51.31 in 2006.
faces a sustainability problem. Loan repayment rates are highly variable
across community associations. The most recent assessment of the CMP(24) 24. See reference 14,
showed that from 1989 to 2003, it financed 1,109 projects nationwide, Ballesteros and Vertido (2004);
also see reference 14, Cacnio
benefiting 138,871 households. The total loan released in mortgage (2001).
take-out amounted to Pesos 4.3 billion(25) and the average loan size per
household was about Pesos 30,000.(26) The overall collection efficiency 25. US$ 0.08 billion at
US$1 = Pesos 51.31 in 2006.
ratio was 80.2 per cent as of the end of 2002 and 78.2 per cent as of the
end of 2003, and the general trend shows repayments below 80 per cent 26. US$ 584.68 at US$1 = Pesos
in most years of the review period. The government, which has problems 51.31 in 2006.
with its huge fiscal deficit, would be hard pressed to continue allocating a
huge budgetary appropriation annually to the CMP. A viable CMP would
have to become more self-sustaining as a revolving fund, whereby the re-
flows coming from loan repayments could be used in other CMP sites.
Reasons for low repayment rates. There are several reasons for
these low repayment rates:
• in off-site projects, it was difficult to organize heterogeneous house-
holds. In on-site projects, problems were related to group size and
maintenance of cohesion and cooperation among group members;
416
S H E LT E R F I N A N C E S T R A T E G I E S F O R T H E P O O R : P H I L I P P I N E S
417
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 19 No 2 October 2007
418
S H E LT E R F I N A N C E S T R A T E G I E S F O R T H E P O O R : P H I L I P P I N E S
419
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 19 No 2 October 2007
421
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 19 No 2 October 2007
422
S H E LT E R F I N A N C E S T R A T E G I E S F O R T H E P O O R : P H I L I P P I N E S
REFERENCES
Asian Development Bank (2003), Report and Recom- in developing countries”, Journal of Development
mendation of the President to the Board of Directors Economics Vol 29, pages 185–198.
on a Proposed Loan and Technical Assistance Grant Jimenez, Emmanuel (1984), “Tenure security and
to the Development Bank of the Philippines in the urban squatting”, Review of Economics and Statistics
Republic of the Philippines for the Development of Vol 66, pages 556–567.
Poor Urban Communities Sector Project, RRP 32499, Karaos, Anna Marie (2001), “Decentralization, local
November. governance and urban poverty in four Philippine
Ball, Michael (2003), “Improving housing markets”, cities”, Ateneo University Institute on Church and
RICS Leading Edge Series, accessible at http:// Social Issues, Quezon City.
www.rics.org. Llanto, Gilberto M (1999), “Housing policy: developing
Ballesteros, Marife (2005), “Rethinking institutional re- a market-based housing finance system”, PIDS
forms in the Philippine housing sector”, Philippine Policy Notes 99–15, December, Philippine Institute
Institute for Development Studies, Makati City. for Development Studies, Makati City.
Ballesteros, Marife and Dam Vertido (2004), “Can group Llanto, Gilberto M (2005), “Infrastructure development:
credit work for housing loans? Some evidence from experience and policy options for the future”,
CMP”, PIDS Policy Notes No 2004–05, Philippine Philippine Institute for Development Studies,
Institute for Development Studies, Makati City. Makati City.
Bongolan, Gonzalo (2007), “Overview of Philippine Llanto, Gilberto M and Marife Ballesteros (2002), “Inte-
housing and housing finance”, Presentation to the grating land issues in poverty reduction strategies
First Philippine Housing Forum, 15 March, Makati and the development agenda: Philippines”, Paper
City. presented at the Regional Workshop on Land Issues
Buckley, Robert and Robert Vogel (1999), “The World in Asia, organized by the World Bank, Phnom Penh,
Bank and microenterprise finance: from concept Cambodia, June 4–6.
to practice”, Report No 19895, World Bank, Llanto, Gilberto M and Leilanie Basilio (1999), “Housing
Washington DC. policy, strategy and recent developments in
Buckley, Robert and Jerry Kalarickal (2004), “Shelter market-based housing finance”, PIDS Discussion
strategies for the urban poor: idiosyncratic and Paper Series No 99–20, Philippine Institute for
successful but hardly mysterious”, World Bank Development Studies, Makati City.
Policy Research Working Paper 3247, World Bank, Llanto, Gilberto M and Eduardo Gonzalez (2006),
Washington DC, October. “Policy reforms and institutional weaknesses:
Cacnio, Faith (2001), “Microfinance approach to hous- closing the gap”, Paper presented at the Conference
ing: the Community Mortgage Programme”, PIDS on Advancing East Asian Economic Integration:
Discussion Paper Series No 2001–28, Philippine Microeconomic Foundations of Economic
Institute for Development Studies, Makati City. Performance in East Asia, Philippine Plaza Hotel,
Campos, J Edgardo (editor) (2001), The Boom and Bust Manila, November 23–24.
of East Asia Corruption, Ateneo de Manila Univer- Llanto, Gilberto M and Aniceto Orbeta Jr (2001), “The
sity Press, Manila. state of Philippine housing programmes: a critical
De Dios, Emmanuel and Hadi Salehi Esfahani (2001), look at how Philippine housing subsidies work”,
“Centralization, political turnover and investment Philippine Institute for Development Studies,
in the Philippines”, in J Edgardo Campos (editor), Makati City.
The Boom and Bust of East Asia Corruption, Ateneo National Economic and Development Authority (2005),
de Manila University Press, Manila. Medium Term Philippine Development Plan: 2005–
Follain, James and Emmanuel Jimenez (1985), “Esti- 2010, Pasig City.
mating the demand for housing characteristics: Strassman, P and A Blunt (1993), “Land, income and
a survey and critique”, Regional Science and Urban mobility: the case of Metro Manila”, Journal of
Economics Vol 15, pages 77–107. Philippine Development Vol 20, No 1, pages
Friedman, Joseph, Emmanuel Jimenez and Stephen 79–115.
Mayo (1988), “The demand for tenure security
423