Building Social Cohesion: Family, Friends, and Corruption: Alexandru V. Roman and Hugh T. Miller
Building Social Cohesion: Family, Friends, and Corruption: Alexandru V. Roman and Hugh T. Miller
Building Social Cohesion: Family, Friends, and Corruption: Alexandru V. Roman and Hugh T. Miller
Article
Administration & Society
Building Social
2014, V
ol. 46(7) 775–795
© 2013 SAGE Publications
DOI: 10.1177/0095399712473987
Cohesion: Family, aas.sagepub.com
Abstract
While material gain continues to be a leading motivator for corrupt acts,
this study shows that social status and kinship responsibilities should also
be considered possible precursors to corruption. This finding has important
implications for constructing an appropriate understanding of corruption,
designing anticorruption policies, and achieving ethical governance in devel-
oping democracies.
Keywords
public corruption, corrupt behavior, Eastern Europe, networks of association,
kinship
Corresponding Author:
Alexandru V. Roman, School of Public Administration, Florida Atlantic University, 777 Glades
Road, Boca Raton, FL 33431, USA.
Email: [email protected]
776 Administration & Society 46(7)
Studying Corruption
The study of corruption is haunted by myriad theoretical and contextual dif-
ficulties (Williams, 2000). For example, an ineffective police department can
be both a cause and a consequence of corruption. Jain (1998, 2001) argues
that the fragmentation in the present body of literature on corruption is pri-
marily due to the numerous diverging definitions and understandings associ-
ated with the issue. Alemann (2004) proposes that corruption exists at least
in five dimensions: social decline, deviant behavior, logic of exchange, a
system of measurable perceptions, and “shadow politics.” Pardo (2004)
notes that “in any given society, corruption is a changing phenomenon, some
of its aspects and received morality are culturally specific and its conceptu-
alization is affected by personal interest, cultural values and socio-economic
status” (p. 2). In this sense, Heidenheimer (2004) identifies three social per-
ceptions of corruption—white, gray, and black. White corruption refers to
corrupt acts that are socially accepted whereas black corruption is socially
unacceptable.
Rose-Ackerman (1999), Johnston (2001), and Alemann (2004) each note
that the definitions of corruption are evolving over time, and also assert that
the debate over defining corruption is expected to intensify in the future. This
does not mean that defining corruption is a hopeless endeavor. It simply sug-
gests that the definition of corruption should avoid naive oversimplifications
and should be constructed with room for contextual sensitivity. For the pur-
poses of this study, we understand public corruption as, per Huberts and
Nelen (2005), an act (or failure to act) as a result of receiving personal
rewards from interested outside parties. de Graaf and Huberts (2008) note
two important elements of this definition. First, for an act to be deemed cor-
rupt, an outside interest should be present. That is, if the public official acts
or fails to act, he or she is doing so because the behavior benefits someone
else. The lack of an outside interest renders the act as fraud, theft, or unethical
behavior, but not as corruption. The presence of a clear personal award or
benefit, which would otherwise fall outside the terms of employment,
Roman and Miller 777
Case files were one source of data; interviews with informants were
another source. To capture the cultural dimensions of corruption and to gar-
ner background for the cases, 33 interviews were conducted. There was no
specific reason for conducting this number of interviews. Interviewing ceased
when we believed that a theoretical saturation had been achieved due to the
diminished marginal utility of each successive interview in generating new
information, insights, or themes. Of the 33 informants, 5 were business own-
ers, 4 were anticorruption agencies’ employees, 3 were former employees of
anticorruption agencies, 5 were fiscal/judicial/custom employees, 8 were
journalists, and 8 were public officials not directly related to fiscal, judicial,
custom, or anticorruption entities.
Trust between the researcher and the informant was key to gathering use-
ful information. Given the sensitivity of the issues, the interviews were struc-
tured such that the respondents portrayed their social perceptions and
discussed specifics only if they felt comfortable doing so. Interviewees were
selected using a snowball sampling method. Several months prior to the pos-
sible interview, candidates were contacted about their willingness to partici-
pate. If they accepted, they were asked to refer other potentially willing
participants. Of great importance is the fact that due to the sensitivity of the
topic, many would talk about corruption in detail only if they knew the
researcher through a third party. Trust and familiarity with the interviewer,
even if through a third person, were critical in the interviewees’ acceptance
rate and in the authenticity of the discussion and storytelling. It was common
for the respondents to express the desire to take a glimpse at the researcher’s
notes at the conclusion of the interviews, even if they were enthusiastic and
open during the discussion. The requests were correlated with the amount of
notes the researcher was taking and with the degree of trust the respondent
expressed. The more the notes and the lesser the trust, the higher the probabil-
ity of the interviewee asking to examine the notes.
In the course of the investigation, it became apparent that the cases made
available to us might have been biased due to prosecution practices. During
the initial stages of case analysis, it became obvious that of the 28 cases being
studied, none could be classified as “elite” or “political” corruption cases;
and perhaps only 2 cases could have been labeled as “important.” This real-
ization contrasted sharply with what some of the respondents were suggest-
ing. One of the high-ranking officials, during the interview attempted to
explain the discrepancy:
The ones whose files you are looking through represent the ones who
simply did not have enough money to get the accusations dismissed.
780 Administration & Society 46(7)
The anticorruption guys need to show that they are working. That is
why most of your cases are small . . . I will tell you for a fact that one
year off your sentence is 5,000 Euros. So if you are facing a three-year
sentence you’ll have to pay 15,000 Euros to get it dismissed. There will
be a price difference depending on who you will approach. Some just
don’t have that kind of money.
This raises the possibility that the corruption cases that wind up being
investigated are those that fall outside very powerful networks. If so, it would
be more than ironic that in certain ways, the agencies that are supposed to
combat corruption could be the most corrupt. Moreover, several interview
respondents pointed out that a large number of suspected corruption cases
never make it to trial. Among them, the majority are politics-related cases,
whose resolution can drag on for years or they would be eventually dropped
due to a supposed lack of evidence. One investigator claimed that one of his
colleagues lost his job because he initiated an investigation of a powerful
individual. According to the official, there is an unwritten code of “whom
you can and whom you cannot touch.” Thus, within the Eastern context, the
predominance in terms of prosecution record of small corruption cases in
which low-ranking bureaucrats are involved raises the possibility that powerful—
and corrupt—networks dominate the countries.
781
782 Administration & Society 46(7)
Heuristic Findings
The case analysis has yielded five propositions with respect to the correlates
of corruption in Moldova. Knowing the extent to which these propositions
are generalizable requires further research, but we would posit the following
propositions as worthy of further scholarly attention:
The next section will discuss each of the five propositions in more detail.
Discussion
This finding contradicts most prior literature, which typically assumes that
the nature of corruption in developing and poor countries is primarily moti-
vated by material gain (de Graaf & Huberts, 2008). Driven by the assumption
that agents are rational, it is expected that better economic situations would
lead to less corruption (Fishman & Gatti, 2002; Forgues-Puccio & Blackburn,
2010; Gundlach & Paldam, 2009; Paldam, 2001; Rauch & Evans, 2000;
Treisman, 2000). Instead, with higher income and improved economic devel-
opments, the manifestations of corruption may well change, but embedded-
ness of corruption in social relations does not.
Given that more than 50% of the cases in our data set were not motivated
by material gain, it is difficult to uphold the assumption that corruption is
primarily driven by poverty. In only 13 cases was the motivator material gain.
In 6 out of the 13 cases, material gain was coded as high. However, in none
of these cases did the amount at stake exceed US$15,000. In 4 cases, the
financial reward was less than US$250. Meanwhile, kinship relations and
family pressure motivated 10 of the corrupt acts. Status considerations were
the motives behind 5 corruption cases.
In eight of the cases when corruption was kinship-driven, a dominant
theme was the inability to refuse blood relatives. In one of the files, the cor-
rupt official was quoted saying “I could not refuse him; he is my cumătru [a
Romanian term].” A cumătru is someone who becomes a relative either by
blood relation or through receiving the denomination through associations
built by religious customs. From here arose the term cumătrism. Such rela-
tionships are traditionally established for the sole purpose of “having some-
one there.” For example, many young couples would like to become
associated with someone who is already successful and has established a cer-
tain area of influence. This type of an association would allow a young
784 Administration & Society 46(7)
couple to possibly tap into the resources of the association network at some
point in the future. The new relationship, however, also obligates the couple
to be responsive to the cumătru’s suggestions and demands. Such a web of
relations becomes essential to developing a career or getting something done
and will be established within relatively similar income and social levels.
Rarely do individuals within higher socioeconomic status accept entering
into such associations with others who are not part of their approximate status
network. Both parties in the relationship need to feel that they have some-
thing to gain by initiating it.
Status and kinship concerns seem to be important to the process of the pub-
lic official becoming corrupt. In the five cases motivated by status concerns, the
public officials explained their acts as a consequence of the power to undertake
those acts and the desire to make use of their ability to exert influence. In
instances when bribes were present, the accused regularly were quoted in their
files as interpreting their ability “to dictate” bribes as proof of their social sta-
tus. They took pride in the fact that outside parties would approach them and
ask for favors. The interviews suggested that kinship might be even more pow-
erful than material gains in fostering corruption. As one of the interviewees
stated, “Everyone has a cumătru somewhere. Before you know it . . . you can’t
get anything done without going through a cumătru of a cumătru.”
Most of the officials did not think they were doing anything wrong. Only
in three cases did the officials express the concern that one day they might
have to face charges. Such responses are consistent with the prior research
reports (Ashforth & Anand, 2003; Ermann & Lundman, 2002; Grødeland,
2010; Spinei et al., 2008). Corrupt officials denied that they were responsible,
or that they had hurt anyone. Within this theme, there were two dominant
tendencies: (a) the officials thought that there was nothing wrong with what
they did because everyone does it or expects it; they were just the ones who
got caught and (b) the amount involved was trivial and they were simply
“helping to get the job done, push something through.”
For Moldova, like for many other members of the communist bloc, the fall
of the Soviet Union led to a chaotic transition toward a market economy.
Within this environment, the individuals who were charismatic, motivated,
Roman and Miller 785
Current public official (C.P.O.):If you are a business and you need
something done, it could take you 6 months. You will need to stop
by several offices, wait in line, and then wait for a decision. I can get
you through the same process in less than a week. During my lunch,
I go in, get the things signed and accepted, and move on.
Interviewer:Why?
C.P.O.:Money of course. I am not an idiot. But I don’t charge a lot. I
just charge 200 Euros, that’s it. Sometimes I do it for free if we are
talking about someone I know.
Interviewer:Do you think this is OK?
C.P.O:It is probably borderline . . . But it is OK. I wouldn’t be telling
you if I didn’t think it is OK [laughs]. It is not like I am doing some-
thing wrong. I am speeding the process for them by doing it in their
place. The same thing a lawyer does, only because I know everyone
and I work with them already I do it much quicker. I am also using
my time . . . so . . .
Interviewer:Isn’t this part of your job description though?
C.P.O.:Only one step of it is. The other three or five are not. This is
where I come in and get all the signatures collected in 1 week rather
than 6 months. The way I see it, without me, many businesses would
have halted. I could name at least three instances when I helped
someone avoid bankruptcy by saving them time.
This suggests that the slow bureaucratic apparatus juxtaposed with the
needs of the economic players for quick decisions creates a favorable envi-
ronment for public officials who conduct themselves as entrepreneurs. The
idea of entrepreneurship within the bureaucratic apparatus is rather well
developed in the literature (see Kalu, 2003; Kingdon, 2011; Mintrom &
Norman, 2009; Osborne & Gaebler, 1992; Teske, 1994). However, unlike the
entrepreneurship discussed in that literature, here public officials do not pur-
sue policy change or administrative efficiency; they rather pursue personal
and kinship interests. Yet, the entrepreneurial approach and the ability to
manipulate what otherwise is a rigid bureaucratic system “gets the job done.”
786 Administration & Society 46(7)
In all the cases, the supervision of corrupt officials was poor, nonexis-
tent, or there were indications of financial kickbacks for superiors (in 30%
of the cases, a bribe was shared). In 75% of the cases, the hierarchy was not
well established and the corrupt official was rarely reported or evaluated.
None of the organizations put strong emphasis on political or professional
integrity. Corrupt officials were only vaguely aware of organizational ethi-
cal expectations.
The accused argued that “when working in the field” they had little guidance
or supervision. More than 90% of the cases involved street-level public officials
who were in direct contact with the citizens. The officials either blamed superi-
ors and the organization or claimed that they “simply made a mistake” and that
they were not aware that “it is not all right” to do what they did.
When corrupt officials attempted to justify themselves by saying “every-
body else does it,” they were figuratively correct. The density of corrupt
occurrences per type of public organization is relatively high in Moldova.
These acts take place in well-established networks of association. Compared
with the de Graaf and Huberts (2008) study, in the case of Moldova, there are
a higher number of cases involving more than one official; corrupt acts often
utilized stable intermediaries. While all the officials with corruption files
attempted to justify their behavior with “everyone else is doing it” responses,
no one offered to “rat out” a colleague. The interviews and content analysis
suggested three main reasons for the unwillingness of the incriminated offi-
cials to betray others within their networks. (a) There were no gains from it,
as in many instances even the investigators assigned to the corruption case
were happy to put a “check mark” on the case as “done,” showing no interest
in pursuing further ramifications. Moreover, the corrupt administrator did not
believe that anyone would actually do anything. (b) The corrupt public ser-
vants were more concerned about “burning bridges” than about receiving a
sentence. From the 11 cases in which the officials had a previous criminal
offense, in two cases they were eventually reemployed by the same institu-
tion. (c) The corrupt individuals were afraid that others have someone within
the anticorruption investigation department and that “ratting out” would have
serious repercussions for them.
788 Administration & Society 46(7)
The officials would join the organization open to the idea of income outside
of salary. Within organizational and social context open to corrupt behavior,
the public officials would initially start timidly, until they became comfort-
able enough with the process to achieve stable opportunities. In 11 cases, this
was not the first criminal offense for the public official. In 5 of the 11 cases,
the previous sentence was a result of abuse of power or a corruption charge.
One of the case files revealed the following exchange:
Investigator:It says here that you didn’t have a job for 4 years after the
university? Why?
Suspected official (S.O.):I only wanted to work for [name of institution
removed].
Investigator:Really? So you didn’t do anything for 4 years . . . you
waited to get in with them? Why?
S.O.:I am not going somewhere and work on salary. There I could make
good money . . . and I could be someone. People respect you if you
work there. Guys don’t go there because they want to help anyone.
If you get in, you have connections and you are guaranteed money.
Investigator:What did you do for money for 4 years?
Suspected official:My wife worked.
Conclusion
Aside from material gain, de Graaf and Huberts (2008) hypothesize that
friendship, love, status, and need to impress others were important motives
to commit corrupt acts. In our study, although status is identified as a motiva-
tor in five instances, kinship considerations predominated. Our original defi-
nition of corruption followed the lead of de Graaf and Huberts, which
required the presence of a clear personal award or benefit to count as corrup-
tion. We no longer regard this definition as adequate in light of the diffuse
beneficiaries of corrupt acts. Personal reward cannot be ruled out, but in
some social contexts, especially in nonindividualistic cultures, the instru-
mental logic of personal benefits does not reflect the complexities of the
networks of social obligations faced by the corrupt officials.
In other respects, too, the relationship between material considerations and
corruption might not be as powerful as is often assumed to be the case for low-
income societies. Rather than slipping down a slope once in office, officials in
the post-Soviet bloc are coming into government positions with the expecta-
tion of corrupt acts as a normal aspect of their job and a “supplement” to
income. Cultural and social environments sustain the beliefs that such consid-
erations are normal for public servants. One of the respondents put it this way:
The bureaucracies in Eastern Europe do not neatly fit with the Weberian
model.
Funding
The author(s) received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or pub-
lication of this article.
Note
1. In 2011, Moldova received a Corruption Perception Index (CPI) score of only
2.9 out of 10, where the lower the score, the more corrupt the country is per-
ceived (Transparency International, 2011). It shared the 112th place with Algeria,
Egypt, Kosovo, Senegal, and Vietnam, among 178 countries that were ranked.
The CPI score for 2010 was 2.9 (similar to Argentina, Algeria, Kazakhstan, and
Senegal, ranked 105th) while the 2009 score was 3.3 (ranked 89th and tied with
Lesotho, Malawi, Mexico, Morocco, and Rwanda).
References
Acemoglu, D., & Verdier, T. (2000). The choice between market failures and corrup-
tion. American Economic Review, 90, 194-211.
Aidt, T. (2003). Economic analysis of corruption: A survey. Economic Journal, 113,
F632-F652.
Akçay, S. (2006).Corruption and human development. Cato Journal, 26, 29-48.
Alemann, U. (2004). The unknown depths of political theory: The case for a multi-
dimensional concept of corruption. Crime, Law and Social Change, 42, 25-34.
Ashforth, B. E., & Anand, V. (2003). The normalization of corruption in organiza-
tions. Research in Organizational Behavior, 25, 1-52.
Barsukova, S. (2009). Corruption. Russian Politics & Law, 47(4), 8-27.
Bayley, D. (1966). The effects of corruption in a developing nation. Western Political
Quarterly, 19, 719-732.
Brovkin, V. (2003). Corruption in the 20th century Russia. Crime, Law and Social
Change, 40, 195-230.
de Graaf, G., & Huberts, L. W. J. C. (2008). Portraying the nature of corruption using
an explorative case study design. Public Administration Review, 68, 640-653.
Doig, A. (2011). Numbers, words and KYC: Knowing your country and knowing
your corruption. Critical Perspectives on International Business, 7, 142-158.
Earle, B. (2000). Bribery and corruption in Eastern Europe, the Baltic states, and the
Commonwealth of Independent States: What is to be done? Cornell International
Law Journal, 33, 483-513.
Ermann, M. D., & Lundman, R. J. (2002). Corporate and governmental deviance:
Problems of organizational behavior in contemporary society. Oxford, NY:
Oxford University Press.
Fijnaut, C., & Huberts, L. W. J. C. (Eds.). (2002). Corruption, integrity and law
enforcement. The Hague, Netherlands: Kluwer Law International.
Roman and Miller 793
Fishman, R., & Gatti, R. (2002). Decentralization and corruption: Evidence across
countries. Journal of Public Economics, 83, 325-345.
Forgues-Puccio, G., & Blackburn, K. (2010). Financial liberalization, bureaucratic
corruption and economic development. Journal of International Money and
Finance, 29, 1321-1339.
Grødeland, A. (2010). Elite perceptions of anti-corruption efforts in Ukraine. Global
Crime, 11, 237-260.
Gundlach, E., & Paldam, M. (2009). The transition of corruption: From poverty to
honesty. Economics Letters, 103, 146-148.
Haberfeld, M. R., Ivkovic, S., & Klockars, C. (2006). Enhancing police integrity. AA
Dordrecht, Netherlands: Springer.
Haller, D., & Shore, C. (2005). Corruption: Anthropological perspectives. London,
England: Pluto Press.
Heidenheimer, A. J. (2004). Disjunctions between corruption and democracy? A qual-
itative exploration. Crime, Law and Social Change, 42, 99-109.
Hofstede, G. H. (1980). Culture’s consequences: International differences in work-
related values. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Hofstede, G. H. (2001). Culture’s consequences: Comparing values, behaviors, insti-
tutions, and organizations across nations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Huberts, L. W. J. C., & Nelen, J. M. (2005). Corruptie in het Nederlandse openbaar
bestuur: Omvang, aard en afdoening [Corruption in government in the Netherlands:
Extent, nature and prosecution]. Utrecht, Netherlands: Lemma.
Ivkovic, S., & Shelley, T. O. (2010). The code of silence and disciplinary fairness.
Policing, 33, 548-574.
Jain, A. K. (1998). Economics of corruption. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Jain, A. K. (2001). Corruption: A review. Journal of Economic Surveys, 15, 71-121.
Johnston, M. (2001). The definitions debate: Good politics, governance, and the con-
cept of corruption. In J. K. Avring (Ed.), Political economy of corruption (pp.
11-32). London, England: Routledge.
Kalu, K. (2003). Entrepreneurs or conservators? Contractarian principles of bureau-
cratic performance. Administration & Society, 35, 539-563.
Karklins, R. (2005). The system made me do it: Corruption in post-communist societ-
ies. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Kingdon, J. W. (2011). Agendas, alternatives, and public policies. New York, NY:
Longman.
Kopits, G., & Craig, J. D. (1998). Transparency in government operations. Washington,
DC: International Monetary Fund.
Ledeneva, A. (2009). From Russia with blat: Can informal networks help modernize
Russia? Social Research, 76, 257-288.
794 Administration & Society 46(7)
Skolnick, J. (2002). Corruption and the blue code of silence. Police Practice &
Research, 3, 7-19.
Spinei, I., Carasciuc, L., Obreia, E., & Lazari, C. (2008). Masuram coruptia: De la
sondaj la sondaj [Measuring corruption: From survey to survey]. Chisinau, Moldova:
Transparency International. Retrieved form http://www.transparency.md/content/
blogcategory/16/48/4/8/lang,en/
Teske, P. (1994). The bureaucratic entrepreneur: The case of city managers. Public
Administration Review, 54, 331-340.
Thai, K. V. (Ed.). (2008). International handbook of public procurement. Boca Raton,
FL: Taylor & Francis.
Transparency International. (2011). Corruption Perception Index 2011. Retrieved
from http://cpi.transparency.org/cpi2011/
Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of
Public Economics, 76, 399-457.
Tumarkin, N. (2000). Russia’s moral rearmament. Wilson Quarterly, 24(2), 48-49.
Uslaner, E. M. (2002). The moral foundations of trust. New York, NY: Cambridge
University Press.
Uslaner, E. M., & Conley, R. S. (2003). Civic engagement and particularized trust:
The ties that bind people to their ethnic communities. American Politics Research,
31, 331-360.
Weber, M. (1978). Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology (G. Roth
& C. Wittich, Ed.). Berkeley: University of California Press.
Williams, R. (2000). Explaining corruption. Cheltenham, UK: Northampton.
Author Biographies
Alexandru V. Roman is a PhD candidate at the School of Public Administration at
Florida Atlantic University. He currently serves as the director of research for the
Public Procurement Research Center at Florida Atlantic University.