ECON 3350/7350 Applied Econometrics For Macroeconomics and Finance
ECON 3350/7350 Applied Econometrics For Macroeconomics and Finance
ECON 3350/7350 Applied Econometrics For Macroeconomics and Finance
Fu Ouyang
School of Economics
University of Queensland
April 1, 2019
Cointegration
Recommended readings
Cointegration: I(1) variables are related such that there exists a linear
combination that yields a I(0) process.
Spurious Regression
Let xt = xt−1 + εx,t and yt = yt−1 + εy,t , where εx,t and εy,t are
independent white noise.
So, a t-test will tend to reject H0 incorrectly (i.e. α is not the correct
significance level)..
Spurious Regression
√
In fact, as T −→ ∞, the quantity T (βb1 − β1 ) −→ ∞.
• t-statistic of β1 increases with sample size—more data exacerbates the
problems with t-tests.
• OLS is not consistent, and there is no well-defined sampling
distribution.
Significant t-tests occur because even pure random walks tend to resemble
trends; when two I(1) variables wander in the same direction for a while,
we might mistake this for cointegration.
yt = ξt + νy,t ,
1
xt = ξt + νx,t ,
β
ξt = ξt−1 + ηt ,
1
νy,t = −βε1,t , νx,t = − ε2,t , ηt = βε1,t + ε2,t ,
β
is also I(0).
Cointegration and Common Stochastic Trends
The key component that ties together yt and xt is the common stochastic
trend ξt .
• Both yt and xt actually embody stationary movements around the
non-stationary ξt .
16
12
-4
55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10 15
• GS3: ADF statistic is -2.178 (p-value 0.4995); GS5: ADF statistic is -1.977 (p-value 0.6104)
• SPREAD: ADF statistic is -5.608 (p-value 0.0000)
Definition of Cointegration
Definition.
The components of wt are cointegrated of order d, b, denoted CI(d, b), iff
1. all components of wt are I(d), and
2. there exists a n × 1 vector β 6= 0 such that
zt = B0 wt
Yt = λt Ktθ Nt1−θ ,
ln λt = µλ + ln λt−1 + ξt ,
Slight extension of the Neoclassical Growth Model yields that the great ratios
Ct It
Yt and Yt are stationary stochastic processes.
Therefore, theory implies that ln Ct , ln It , and ln Yt are all I(1) but the
quantities ln Ct − ln Yt and ln It − ln Yt are I(0).
y t = β0 + β1 x t + ε t
will be superconsistent.
Normally, √
b − β) −→ N (0, V).
T (β
√
That is, β
b converges at rate T .
b − β) −→ N (0, V).
T (β
That is, β
b converges at rate T . This implies that when cointegrating
relationships exist, OLS estimates reliably even in small samples; when
they do not exist, OLS leads to spurios relationships.
Income Consumption Example
Define:
• ct : (log) consumption;
• yt : (log) income;
• at : (log) wealth;
and arrange them into a 3 × 1 vector wt = (ct , yt , at )0 .
Use, e.g., Cointegrating ADF with (in this case) two variables–Table C of
Enders.
Cointegration Space
All examples so far assumed cointegrating vectors are either fully known
or partially known.
In the permanent income hypothesis example,
1
B = −1 .
β
In all these cases, the cointegrating vectors are unique and we can
estimate unknown components such as β1 and β2 from data.
Cointegration Space
0
In general, if zt = B wt is stationary, then for any invertible K, B
e = BK is
0 0
another n × r matrix that yields e zt = Be wt = K zt stationary.