Broadening Narrow Money Monetary Policy With A Central Bank Digital Currency
Broadening Narrow Money Monetary Policy With A Central Bank Digital Currency
Broadening Narrow Money Monetary Policy With A Central Bank Digital Currency
724
Broadening narrow money: monetary
policy with a central bank digital currency
Jack Meaning, Ben Dyson, James Barker and Emily Clayton
May 2018
Staff Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate.
Any views expressed are solely those of the author(s) and so cannot be taken to represent those of the Bank of England or to state
Bank of England policy. This paper should therefore not be reported as representing the views of the Bank of England or members of
the Monetary Policy Committee, Financial Policy Committee or Prudential Regulation Committee.
Staff Working Paper No. 724
Broadening narrow money: monetary policy with a
central bank digital currency
Jack Meaning,(1) Ben Dyson,(2) James Barker(3) and Emily Clayton(4)
Abstract
This paper discusses central bank digital currency (CBDC) and its potential impact on the monetary
transmission mechanism. We first offer a general definition of CBDC which should make the concept
accessible to a wide range of economists and policy practitioners. We then investigate how CBDC could
affect the various stages of transmission, from markets for central bank money to the real economy. We
conclude that monetary policy would be able to operate much as it does now, by varying the price or
quantity of central bank money, and that transmission may even strengthen for a given change in policy
instruments.
Key words: Central bank digital currency, money, monetary policy, cryptocurrency.
We would like to thank John Barrdear, Tim Boobier, Rashmi Harimohan, Andrew Hauser, Michael Kumhof, Becky Maule and
Matthew Trott for a number of informative discussions, Jamie Walton for help in proofing this draft, and participants at the
CEBRA Annual Conference 2017, particularly Charles Kahn for his insightful discussion, and the ECB workshop on Money Markets,
Monetary Policy Implementation and Central Bank Balance Sheets 2017. We also thank Andrew Levin for his insightful comments
and suggestions as referee. The views here represent those of the authors only and should not be interpreted as an official position
of the Bank of England in any way.
Publications and Design Team, Bank of England, Threadneedle Street, London, EC2R 8AH
Telephone +44 (0)20 7601 4030 email [email protected]
2
They conclude that CBDC could act as a highly effective form of money and promote
true price stability, as the real value of CBDC could be easily held stable over time.
In contrast to the existing literature, this paper approaches the topic of CBDC
from the perspective of its impact on the monetary transmission mechanism (MTM).
More specifically, we consider how CBDC might affect the implementation of monetary
policy decisions and the channels, speed and strength with which those decisions are
transmitted to the real economy. For the most part we focus on a specific form of cen-
tral bank digital currency: universally accessible, account-based and interest-bearing.
Conceptually, this CBDC variant could be thought of as a widening of access to the
existing system of central bank reserve accounts, which are currently only accessible
to a limited subset of economic agents.4 In Section 6 we consider a scenario in which
different types of CBDC account holder are paid different interest rates and show how
this is largely analogous to reserves existing alongside a second CBDC. In Section 7 we
look at an e-cash variant of CBDC.
It is difficult to draw definitive or quantitatively-robust conclusions about the im-
pact of CBDC on the monetary transmission mechanism, due to the large degree of
uncertainty around the ultimate design of CBDC, the economic environment it will be
introduced into, and the structural changes that may accompany it. Rather, this paper
aims to provide a framework for thinking about these issues and begins to populate
that framework with broad brush conclusions based on existing theory and reason-
able, transparent assumptions. These conclusions would need to be reviewed were a
CBDC to be actively introduced. What is more, the impact on the monetary trans-
mission mechanism will need to be balanced by considerations of the other dimensions
of CBDC, such as its effect on payments systems and financial stability. In Section 8
we lay out some of the most pertinent questions that still need to be addressed and
which would be fundamental to the effective implementation of CBDC.
Despite these uncertainties, our analysis leads us to the broad conclusion that a uni-
versally accessible, interest-bearing, account-based CBDC could be used for monetary
policy purposes in much the same way that central bank reserves are now. On the mar-
gin, there may even be reason to believe that the monetary transmission mechanism
would be stronger for a given change in policy instruments.
The rest of the paper is laid out as follows. We begin by elaborating on our general
definition of CBDC and the various sub-characteristics it may exhibit. We then provide
a balance sheet exposition of an economy with universally accessible CBDC and use it to
work through some of the key CBDC-related transactions in the economy. In Section
4 we discuss the likely impact of CBDC on the monetary transmission mechanism,
building from the control of CBDC rates by the central bank, to the channels through
which this impacts the real economy. Section 5 considers quantitative easing under
CBDC, while sections 6 and 7 look at alternative designs for CBDC, respectively a
single CBDC that pays different interest rates dependent on the account holder type,
and e-cash. Finally, we outline some outstanding questions and areas of interest that
follow from our research, before offering some concluding remarks.
4
The Bank of England has recently widened access to central bank reserves to include non-bank Payment
Service Providers and Electronic Money Issuers (Bank of England, 2017a).
3
2 Defining central bank digital currency
The term central bank digital currency is currently used to refer to a wide range of
potential designs and policy choices, with no single commonly agreed definition. This
is, in part, due to the fact that the concept sits at the nexus of a number of different
areas of research and brings together many complex elements, covering topics as di-
verse as computer science, cryptography, payments systems, banking, monetary policy
and financial stability. As a result, the debate around CBDC may at times appear
otherworldly to economists who are not familiar with cryptocurrencies, blockchain and
distributed ledger technology (DLT).
As a response, we offer a general definition that is both an accurate representation
of CBDC, and is stated in terms that will be familiar to any economist with a basic
understanding of the monetary process. It is our hope that this will remove any
perceived mystique around CBDC and promote wider discussion of CBDC among
economists.
To that end, we define a central bank digital currency simply as an electronic, fiat
liability of a central bank that can be used to settle payments or as a store of value. It
is in essence electronic central bank, or ‘narrow’, money.
Within our general definition there exists a wide range of sub-characteristics and
parameters that could be set or varied and which would more precisely define any given
CBDC.
One of the key parameters relates to access to CBDC. A CBDC may be universally
accessible — in other words it can be held by anyone for any purpose — or access may
be restricted to a limited subset of economic agents, or for a limited range of purposes.
This may seem counterintuitive to some monetary economists who take currency to
be something that can be held by anyone i.e. is universally accessible5 . Indeed, Fung
and Halaburda (2016) and Bjerg (2017) identify universal access as a fundamental
characteristic of any CBDC. However, it seems possible that central banks may issue a
CBDC that is available only to a sub-sector of the economy, such as a ‘retail CBDC’ for
households and non-financial businesses only, or a ‘wholesale CBDC’ which can be used
as a settlement asset in financial markets by firms that do not currently have access
to central bank reserves (Bech & Garratt, 2017). The question is then a semantic
one about whether a CBDC that is not universally accessible could still be considered
a central bank digital currency. In fact, the ECB has chosen to use the broader
term “digital base money” (Mersch, 2017), which we find to be more accurate. For
consistency we will stick with the more widely-used term ‘CBDC’, but acknowledge
the potential mild misnomer.
A second key parameter relates to whether CBDC is interest bearing. An interest-
bearing CBDC might pay positive, zero or even negative rates at various points in the
economic cycle. As we will discuss in Section 2.1, this interest rate could be used to
pursue a number of objectives, although not simultaneously. For instance, it could be
used to stabilise inflation and output, as the primary instrument of monetary policy, or
it could be used to regulate demand for CBDC. Alternatively, a non-interest-bearing
CBDC could be considered closer in spirit to central bank notes, and so is often referred
5
Making a CBDC universally accessible to non-residents as well as residents could have implications on
the exchange rate and capital flows. These are complex issues that we do not address in this paper, except
very briefly in Section 4.
4
to as ‘e-cash’.
An important question relates to whether a CBDC trades at par with other cen-
tral bank liabilities. In most existing monetary frameworks, different types of central
bank liabilities can be exchanged with one another 1:1, e.g. one unit of central bank
notes can be exchanged for one unit of reserves. However, a number of authors have
suggested breaking with this convention, particularly in the context of CBDC. Kimball
and Agarwal (2015) for instance outline a framework in which a flexible exchange rate
can be operated between cash and electronic central bank money in order to facilitate
a negative interest rate on cash and overcome the effective lower bound. What such a
system would mean though is that the economy would be operating with two distinct
fiat currencies simultaneously, albeit with a managed exchange rate. We doubt that
this would be plausible in practice. For instance, it would raise significant questions
around which of the two currencies, physical cash or CBDC, would be the unit of ac-
count in the economy. Also, were both currencies to become widely used, the prices
of goods and services would need to be quoted in both, adding an administrative cost
that could be significant. In general, we believe managing two fiat currencies simulta-
neously would pose a significant risk for monetary stability, so while we acknowledge
the theoretical possibility of a CBDC that does not trade at par, for this paper we
assume that all forms of central bank money can be exchanged at par.
Some design choices relate to the technology used to power a CBDC. For instance,
a CBDC could be token-based currency, such as the proposed Fedcoin of Koning (2014)
or BitDollar, proposed by Motamedi (2014). This would mean that once issued, units
of CBDC could be transferred from one agent to another independently of the central
bank, in much the same way that central bank notes are currently. The alternative
would be an account-based CBDC in which agents had an account recorded by the
central bank and transactions were made by the central bank debiting one account and
crediting another.
Perhaps the characteristic that causes the most confusion is whether or not the
CBDC is a cryptocurrency. Cryptocurrencies, such as Bitcoin, Litecoin or Ether,
make use of distributed ledgers that rely on cryptographic techniques to maintain their
veracity. Much of the discussion around CBDC implies, either explicitly or implicitly,
that it would also be a cryptocurrency, but this need not be the case. CBDC could
equally be based on a more mature and established technology, such as that which
powers existing central bank real-time gross-settlement systems.6 This kind of CBDC
would not be a cryptocurrency, but would remain a central bank digital currency.
The optimal setting of each of these parameters will depend on the reason for which
the CBDC is being introduced; a CBDC designed to provide a secure payments service
may look very different to one that is primarily used as an instrument of monetary pol-
icy. However, our general definition provides a framework by which any future research
can define the subset of CBDC to which it refers, and assess how its conclusions may
vary were those parameters to be set differently. We therefore see this as an important
first contribution of our paper. There is a small existing literature seeking to clarify
the terminology around CBDC. Bjerg (2017) offers a taxonomy that is a subset of our
6
Scorer (2017) explains that distributed ledger technology may have other technological advantages over
centralised ledgers — in particular, a higher level of resilience. However, the technology is considered still
too immature to power a critical national payment system such as the Bank of England’s Real-Time Gross
Settlement system (Bank of England, 2017a).
5
more general definition, additionally requiring universal accessibility. Bech and Gar-
ratt (2017) present a taxonomy broadly consistent with our own. Within their money
flower representation, our definition of CBDC is depicted by the four core segments
incorporating both retail and whole central bank crypto-currencies, settlement or re-
serve accounts with the central bank, and deposited currency accounts. The analysis
within Bech and Garratt (2017) goes on to focus on the subset of money that is based
on cryptographic technology, so discusses central bank cryptocurrencies - CBCC rather
than CBDC.
To provide some context to our definition, Table 1 compares CBDC to some common
money-like assets and shows the characteristics they each have. As shown by the first
column, under our general definition, the first two characteristics are both necessary
and sufficient to class an asset as CBDC, while the others may or may not hold. Before
any real-world CBDC could be launched, careful consideration would need to be given
to the setting of these parameters.
a
We have taken Bitcoin and Ether as the best known examples of privately-issued cryptocurrency. The
characteristics shown are also accurate for the majority of cryptocurrencies, although the economic and
technological design of different cryptocurrencies can vary significantly.
b
Trades at par with other central bank liabilities
To give a clear example, under our general definition, one form of central bank dig-
ital currency already exists, and plays a fundamental role in the conduct of monetary
policy: reserves. Reserves are electronic and account-based. They are not a cryp-
tocurrency as they are not based on distributed ledger or other cryptographic system
of account. In many cases they pay a rate of return, either on the total balance held,
or on those parts of the balance deemed excess. However, they are only accessible to
a limited number of participants, mainly banks and other select monetary financial
institutions (MFIs). Their primary objective is as an active instrument for monetary
policy, however, for a small subset of the economy they also provide secure, efficient
payments services, and they can serve as an instrument of financial stability policy. It
should be noted here that under the stricter definition of CBDC suggested by Bjerg
(2017), reserves would not qualify as a CBDC as they fail to meet the universal acces-
sibility requirement. However, a number of studies have either implicitly or explicitly
made the assumption that reserves should be thought of as CBDC, including He et al.
(2017) at the IMF.
6
2.1 CBDC in this paper
For the majority of this paper we will focus on a particular form of CBDC. Following
the conclusions of both Scorer (2017) and Bordo and Levin (2017b) we concentrate on
an account-based CBDC, in which the identity of CBDC account holders is known (in
contrast to a token-based CBDC which could offer truly anonymous payments). We
also begin from an assumption of universal accessibility such that everyone can hold a
CBDC account with the central bank.
Beyond assuming that a CBDC is technologically feasible, we abstract away from
questions over the precise nature of the underlying technology, remaining agnostic over
whether the accounts are managed on a distributed ledger, a form of RTGS or some
other means.7 However, we feel that the most plausible method of implementation
would be that the central bank would provide the underlying payments platform for
CBDC, but would not deal directly with members of the public. Instead, it would
allow private sector firms, such as financial technology firms, payment institutions or
banks, to identify customers, register CBDC accounts on their behalf and provide
the customer interface and customer services related to CBDC accounts. These firms
would be responsible for administering CBDC accounts, but would not take custody
of the CBDC itself, ensuring that CBDC remained a liability of the central bank to
the end user rather than to an intermediary. We assume that the payment services
available to CBDC account holders would be comparable to those available to holders
of bank deposits, and that the CBDC and deposit-based payment systems would be
interoperable (so that any deposit account could make a payment to any CBDC account
and vice versa). This means that CBDC would serve as a close — but not perfect —
substitute for bank deposits. This point is crucial: as discussed by Broadbent (2016),
if CBDC only serves as a substitute for central bank notes, then the monetary policy
implications are negligible, but once CBDC starts to offer payment services similar
to bank deposits, there will be an impact on the quantity and price of bank funding,
with interesting implications for monetary policy. Importantly, we assume that CBDC
accounts would not offer credit facilities, such as overdrafts, to the vast majority of
users.8
Lastly, in the main we will be working on the assumption that CBDC pays a rate
of interest and, more specifically, that this interest rate is used as an instrument of
monetary policy. The arguments in favour of paying interest on short-term central
bank liabilities have their origins in Friedman (1960), who argued that they should pay
a rate of interest equivalent to the risk-free rate. As we will expand upon in Section 4,
in our benchmark framework the rate of interest paid on CBDC balances is the main
instrument of monetary policy, and would be set in order to guide the macroeconomy.
However, an alternative approach would be to set the interest rate paid on CBDC
with a different objective in mind, for instance to guide the quantity of CBDC in
response to changes in demand. This would require a different formulation of CBDC
to the one considered in our benchmark. Primarily it would require a distinction
between CBDC held by banks, and CBDC held by non-banks, including the public
more broadly. The rate paid on the CBDC held by MFIs could then be used to set
the stance of monetary policy (just as the rate on reserves is used today), while the
7
See Scorer (2017) on the relative merits of DLT or other delivery methods.
8
As discussed in Section 4, we do assume CBDC credit can be lent to certain financial institutions at a
discount window facility.
7
rate paid on the broader CBDC could be used to regulate demand for CBDC through
the price mechanism. In Section 6 we will discuss a variant of our benchmark that
approximates this by allowing the central bank to pay differentiated rates of interest to
different account holder types. Barrdear and Kumhof (2016) go further and explicitly
differentiate reserves and a broader CBDC as distinct assets. But as we will show, the
two frameworks are largely equivalent except under specific conditions.
Conceptually, one way to think about the CBDC discussed in this paper is simply
as a widening of access to the existing system of reserve accounts offered by central
banks. Since the financial crisis of 2007-09 the Bank of England, like a numberof
other central banks, has undertaken projects to widen access to central bank money to
broker-dealers and central counterparties (CCPs), although these firms still make up
a relatively small subset of the economy. The universally accessible CBDC discussed
below takes that process to its extreme conclusion of access being granted to all agents
within the economy.
8
Figure 1: Balance sheets without and with CBDC
9
Goodfriend (2016), Kimball and Agarwal (2015) and Rogoff (2016) all suggest that
replacing cash with a CBDC could make it easier to set a negative rate on central bank
money and thus alleviate the lower bound on interest rates. However, as recognised by
these authors, the removal of cash is not a necessary consequence of CBDC and while
one may have a bearing on the other, the two policies should be assessed on their own
merits.
The most obvious difference between the left and right panels is that non-banks can
now hold electronic central bank money, in the form of CBDC. Our example assumes
that non-banks partly substitute from bonds, deposits and banknotes into CBDC. The
impact on the size and composition of the different sectors’ balance sheets depends on
the type of substitution from each asset to CBDC.
Substitution by non-banks from central bank notes into CBDC simply changes
the composition of central bank liabilities and private sector assets. This has limited
impact beyond some minor implications for seigniorage.12 However, substitution by
non-banks from either deposits or bonds into CBDC will have more significant impacts
on the balance sheets, through the transactions described below.
10
Figure 2: Varying the aggregate supply of CBDC through asset purchases
11
level of government debt is very low but the majority of transactions are carried out
using electronic payments, it may be necessary to accept a wider range of collateral
than in an economy with a large government debt market and little latent demand for
CBDC.
12
Figure 3: Balance sheets without and with CBDC
13
3.2.2 Risk of runs to CBDC
A related concern is the possibility of a very rapid substitution from deposits to CBDC
— in other words, a bank run. In this extreme case, the contraction in bank funding
and the withdrawal of liquidity (in the form of CBDC) may put the central bank in
the position of having to replace the funding that commercial banks had lost.14
These risks have been highlighted by policymakers (Broadbent, 2016; Carney,
2018), and pose a genuine challenge to the feasibility of CBDC. However, we sug-
gest that such risks can be managed. One approach would be to artificially introduce
some of the frictions that currently discourage large-scale runs to cash, for example
by introducing a notice period for large CBDC withdrawals, not paying interest on
balances held above a given limit, or imposing fees on unusually large balances that
could approximate the storage costs of cash. Alternatively, CBDC accounts might have
a daily transfer limit. Such design features are within the control of the central bank,
and would affect the attractiveness of CBDC, limiting the extent to which it was a
substitute for bank deposits. A key challenge is to find the optimal trade-off between
encouraging uptake of CBDC in order to have a monetary policy impact, and limiting
the creation of new financial stability risks.
It is also not certain that run-risk would necessarily be increased under a CBDC.
It is certainly true that the speed of a run could be quicker, and that the cost and
frictions of running could be less. However, it is also possible that those who have the
highest sensitivity to the (real or perceived) credit risk of bank deposits are those most
likely to substitute from deposits to CBDC over a period of time after CBDC has first
been introduced. Therefore, the marginal impact of a change in the perceived level of
risk in the banking sector could conceivably be less, as the most ‘flighty’ depositors
would have already substituted into a safe asset. Thus the probability of a run, for a
given level of risk, may be lower when a safe outside option such as CBDC has already
been provided.
Theoretically, run risks could also be mitigated by removing the requirement for
banks to convert deposits to CBDC.15 In our view, the ability of depositors to exchange
commercial bank money for central bank money on demand is fundamental in main-
taining the confidence in bank deposits, and many of the activities of the monetary
authority (such as lender of last resort, liquidity regulations, and deposit insurance) are
geared towards ensuring that this is always possible. In fact, many would consider it a
necessary part of establishing a stable monetary framework in which CBDC and bank
deposits coexisted and exchanged at parity (i.e. 1:1). Preventing depositors from with-
drawing CBDC as a fundamental design feature of the system would therefore seem to
be a significant and potentially risky departure from usual central bank practice.
14
to a change in the path of the real economy. In the analysis that follows we will discuss
three broad stages of the monetary transmission mechanism. The first is the setting
of the policy instrument - either the interest rate on, or quantity of, electronic central
bank money in the secondary market. Second is the pass-through of changes in the
price and interest rate on CBDC to the interest rates and prices of other assets in the
economy. Lastly there is the pass-through from these financial market movements to
the real economy. This final stage can itself be subdivided into a range of transmission
channels including the real interest rate channel, the bank lending channel and the
expectations/signalling channel, among others.
For the most part we will focus on the marginal impact of a change in a given policy
instrument. CBDC would likely bring with it a host of changes to the steady state
structure of the economy, such as changes to the equilibrium interest rate or steady
state credit spreads. For a fuller analysis of such issues, we refer the reader to Barrdear
and Kumhof (2016) and Bordo and Levin (2017b). We will also focus on the most
common existing instruments of policy, namely (1) the short-term nominal interest rate
and (2) quantitative easing. This provides a clearer lens through which to view the
marginal change to the policy transmission mechanism that is purely a consequence of
a universally accessible CBDC, rather than a discussion of more unconventional policies
which would represent an innovation to the monetary framework in and of themselves.
15
Figure 4: Secondary market for central bank money under corridor and floor systems
16
secondary market activity has notably diminished in frameworks where a floor system
has been introduced. In practice it has been found that the floor created by paying
interest on reserves is far from fully binding. This is largely attributed to the tiered
nature of access to electronic central bank money.
How would this change with the existence of a universally-accessible CBDC? First,
the demand curve for electronic central bank money would shift to the right, as in
Figure 5, as there would be increased demand from non-banks who previously could
not access CBDC. The extent of this rightward shift would depend on the attractiveness
of CBDC and ultimately the whole range of design features it offered, as well as other
determinants including whether a credible deposit guarantee scheme applied to bank
deposits, and the balance between electronic and cash payments in the economy. The
impact on interest rates would depend on the response of the central bank. If they
accomodated the increase in demand by expanding supply sufficiently then they would
be able to keep the prevailing interest rate at the floor. However, if they were to fail
to fully accommodate the increase in demand, then the interest rate in the secondary
market would rise in a fashion more akin to a corridor. If the central bank were to
maintain the initial solid supply curve in Figure 5, not only would the interest rate rise,
but there would also be a redistribution of CBDC within the economy. Banks would
divest themselves of CBDC to the point of inflection in the original demand curve,
something they are unable to do in the current framework. Non-banks would acquire
these excess CBDC holdings from the banks to partially satiate their demand. Any
increases in supply would lead to a larger central bank balance sheet, consistent with
the balance sheet diagrams in Section 1.
Beyond this shift in the demand curve there would be a fundamental change in the
nature of the overnight market for central bank money. Currently that market is an
interbank market as only certain banks can participate. This means that there are a
relatively small, homogenous set of agents trading for a relatively homogenous set of
purposes, predominantly to smooth liquidity and payments shocks. With universally-
accessible CBDC, banks could still trade central bank money with each other in this
way, but this interbank lending would now only represent one possible segment of the
market for CBDC. A bank requiring central bank money to meet liquidity needs at the
end of the day could potentially borrow those funds from a non-bank as much as it
could borrow them from a bank. This increased access to the market would be likely
to increase both liquidity and competition.18 Similarly, banks with excess CBDC at
the end of the day would be able to lend it to a wider range of agents than they can
currently, as they could now lend it outside of the banking sector, although demand
for such short-term funding is likely to be limited in the real economy.
Non-banks would now have the option to hold funds at the central bank, in the
form of CBDC, and earn the CBDC rate. This would increase the efficacy of the floor
and make it more binding. If anyone can earn the central bank policy rate, then there
is no incentive for them to put their money on deposit or lend it to someone else for
less than the rate they can earn risk-free from the central bank.
Crucially, the central bank could control the rate on CBDC — the first stage of
the monetary transmission mechanism — in much the same way as it does now. By
18
In practice, it may not be feasible for banks to borrow the amount of funds they require at such short
notice from multiple non-banks, and so they may stick to existing relationships with other banks, which may
limit any impact of CBDC on the interbank market.
17
expanding the quantity of CBDC such that the market clears at the floor, the central
bank could use the rate of interest paid on CBDC balances, and the expectation thereof,
to guide rates in the rest of the economy. It could also vary the aggregate quantity
of CBDC as an (operationally) independent instrument to stimulate the economy.
Goodfriend (2002) shows how both the quantity and price of central bank money can
be varied independently in a floor system based on the existing reserves framework.
It would also be possible for the central bank to operate a corridor system with
a universal CBDC, by reducing the supply such that a more developed secondary
market evolves that clears at a rate above the central bank deposit rate. This would,
however, require more active management of the central bank’s balance sheet, perhaps
with significant and regular open market operations, and it would not allow for the
independent adjustment of both the price and supply of CBDC.19
R C = R − φC (1)
19
Advanced economy central banks have not yet specified whether they will maintain a floor system once
their post-crisis asset purchases are unwound.
20
It may also be a positive function of the cost of administering accounts, or the underlying payments
system. φC could therefore be thought of as a more complex, composite premium of factors that drive a
wedge between the risk-free rate and the rate on CBDC.
18
This transactional service can be motivated in a number of ways and need not be
constant, but could vary through time and, as posited by Friedman (1960), it could be
a function of the stock of CBDC itself.21
The rates of interest on other assets in the economy can then be written in the
general form by
R x = R c + φx (2)
where φx is a premium for asset x that could be a function of a wide range of factors.
These could include the relative probability of default compared with CBDC,22 the
relative transactional utility provided by the asset and the relative utility provided by
the asset for liquidity management or regulatory purposes. For instance, government
bonds would have little to no default risk, so that element of the premium would be
low, but they also provide little to no transactional utility, which would cause a positive
spread against the CBDC rate to occur. Deposits with commercial banks could provide
transactional services similar to CBDC, and so would see an equivalent premium along
that dimension, but do inherently contain risk of default, and so would see a spread
occur over the CBDC rate.
An initial consequence of a universally-accessible CBDC is likely to be that deposit
rates offered by commercial banks would be higher than the interest rate paid on
CBDC. Prior to the 2008 financial crisis, deposit rates consistently cleared at below the
policy rate (Figure 6). This could be explained by two phenomena. First, banks had a
monopoly on the creation of electronic money that could be used to make transactions
in the wider economy, and non-banks had no outside alternative. Banks could make
use of this monopoly to lower the rate that they paid on deposits. In terms of equation
2 this meant that the transactional utility for non-banks of reserves was zero, while
the transactional utility of commercial bank deposits was high, and so the latter rate
naturally fell below the former. What is more, state backstops, implicit or otherwise,
essentially gave the perception that bank deposits were risk-free and so there was no
default premium built into deposit rates. Second, banks offered a bundling of services,
such as overdrafts and preferential mortgage or lending rates, which provided a utility
to holding deposits with the banking sector and which were reflected in a negative
premium, lowering the rate at which the deposit market cleared. With a universally-
accessible CBDC, central banks would be making available to non-banks an outside,
competitive option for the provision of a means of payment (although unlike some bank
deposits, this would not be bundled with other services such as overdrafts). With such
an outside option, were a commercial bank to try and pay less than the policy rate
on funds, the non-bank depositor could withdraw CBDC in return for a reduction in
their deposit balances. This would constitute a large structural change for the banking
sector which could have consequences for credit provision and banks’ funding models.
In Section 6 we will suggest an extension of the framework outlined here that could
ameliorate any negative impact of such a change.
It may be argued that deposit guarantee schemes make bank deposits essentially
risk-free, so that there is no significant difference in default risk between deposits and
21
Bordo and Levin (2017a) develop the ideas of Friedman in the context of CBDC. They suggest that if
φ = f (Qc ) and the creation of CBDC is costless then the supply of CBDC should be expanded to the point
c
where φc = 0 and the rate of return on CBDC equals the risk-free rate, R = Rc .
22
We assume CBDC has zero default risk.
19
Figure 6: Sight deposit rates vs policy rates in the UK
20
4.2 MTM Stage 2: transmission to financial markets
As well as potentially changing the structure of interest rates in the economy, there are
a number of features of the model of CBDC outlined earlier that could affect the speed
and extent of pass-through between changes in the policy rate and other rates. Most
notably, the central bank is now offering an outside option to those who want to hold
electronic money balances and who previously could only do so via deposits with a
commercial bank. To explore the effect of this, we abstract from the steady state shift
that might occur as a result of this outside option, and also from the transitional period
as any new steady state is achieved. The existence of a competitive money alternative
to bank deposits is likely to mean that if the interest rate on that alternative changes,
but deposit rates do not move by an equal amount, then people may reallocate their
portfolio to take advantage of the relatively higher return that has opened up. This
would create flows between the two assets. If the policy rate which is paid on CBDC
is increased then this could result in a fall in demand for bank deposits, while if the
policy rate is cut, this could drive demand from CBDC into bank deposits. This will
be particularly acute when it is easier to convert between CBDC and deposits. To
the extent that pass-through from policy rates to deposit and wholesale rates has been
estimated to be less than one, CBDC is likely to strengthen this stage of transmission.
We agree with Bordo and Levin (2017b) that deposit-taking institutions that engage
in customer-focussed relationship banking are likely to be less vulnerable to the outflows
of deposits than the areas of the market that compete purely on price terms. We also
acknowledge that evidence for the UK shows that deposits are sticky — depositors do
not often switch banks — and so have low price elasticity (Chiu & Hill, 2015). The
extent to which this remains the case once the central bank offers an outside option,
and in the face of structural changes that will make it easier to switch accounts (such
as the EU’s Second Payment Services Directive), remains to be seen.
Ultimately, whether there is a change in the speed of pass-through from changes in
the policy rate to changes in deposit rates will depend on how banks react. We could
assume that technology is likely to mean that depositors can more easily and costlessly
move between deposits and CBDC, so banks would have to respond quickly to stem
deposit flows. However, banks may react to the increased flightiness of deposits by
changing their funding models to rely more on term funding, to ‘lock in’ deposits. This
would mean that pass-through to rates paid on deposits would ultimately be slower.
The strength of pass-through to lending rates for commercial bank money would
likely be affected along two avenues. First, larger changes in deposits and wholesale
rates for a given change in the policy rate would also mean a larger impact on banks’
funding costs, all else equal. For a given mark-up on these funding costs, this would
have a larger impact on loan rates. Second, a universally accessible CBDC might also
enable greater competition in the provision of credit. CBDC could allow non-banks to
make loans more easily. For instance, peer-to-peer lenders would no longer have to clear
settlements through their competitors in the banking sector, as is currently necessary
in the existing system of tiered access to central bank money. This process incurs a
cost which CBDC could potentially eliminate, putting non-bank credit providers on a
more equal footing with their banking sector counterparts and would limit the extent
to which banks could vary margins in light of changes in funding costs. This increased
sensitivity of both funding costs and lending rates to changes in the policy rate could
act to strengthen the bank lending channel which we discuss further in the next section.
21
4.3 MTM stage 3: transmission to the real economy
Being able to influence interest rates is only an intermediary step in the monetary
transmission mechanism; the ultimate goal of changes in policy is to guide the real
economy. The process by which this is achieved can be characterised by various chan-
nels, for which there is a wide range of taxonomies.23
A number of the channels by which the monetary transmission mechanism leads to
the real economy begin with the change in interest rates we have discussed previously.
The most obvious of these is the real interest rate channel, but the cash-flow channel
and bank lending channel are also dependent on changes in either nominal or real
interest rates.
Given that our previous analysis suggests that universally accessible CBDC is likely
to increase the extent of changes in interest rates for a given change in the policy rate,
all else equal, this will serve to amplify the strength of all of these channels, for a given
change in the policy rate. Beyond this however, it is hard to pin down any structural
reason why a CBDC would influence the strength of, for example, the real interest rate
channel. At its heart, this channel is based on the deep parameters determining the
intertemporal preferences and decision making of economic agents. These are unlikely
to be influenced by whether or not agents are fulfilling their intertemporal allocation
through a CBDC, bank deposits, or some other asset.24 Similarly, the cash-flow channel
is based on the marginal propensities to consume of various agents, which there is little
reason to believe would change as a result of CBDC becoming universally accessible.
The process by which agents form expectations would also appear to be largely
independent of the introduction or otherwise of a universally accessible CBDC. There-
fore one may expect the expectations/signalling channel to be affected only insofar as
CBDC adds or detracts from the clarity and credibility of central bank communications
of the policy stance. This effect seems unlikely to be large, but if the pass-through
from policy rates to wider rates were to become fuller then the potential for policy
becoming constrained would be reduced, all else equal
The exchange rate channel could become more sensitive to a change in the policy
rate, as international differentials in market interest rates would widen by more. For
the logical argument behind this, think of an uncovered interest rate parity (UIP)
condition in which the two rates of interest that matter are the bond rate in each
currency. If a given change in the domestic policy rate leads to a greater change in
the bond rate, then the exchange rate will have to move by more to clear the market
consistent with UIP.
Perhaps the channel of transmission that would be most affected by the introduc-
tion of a universally accessible CBDC would be the bank lending channel. As discussed
previously, the funding costs of banks would likely become more sensitive to changes in
policy rates. This should strengthen the bank lending channel. What is more, the ad-
ditional competition in credit provision may make pass-through to lending rates more
complete. However, this picture has the potential to be complicated by a number of
features of an economy with universally accessible CBDC. First, the fact that deposit
23
The interested reader should see Mishkin (1995) which provides a broad coverage and forms the basis of
the characterisation in this paper.
24
The caveat to this may be that if CBDC is a truly risk-free asset, then this may lower the risk of
transferring wealth between periods and increase the amount of intertemporal allocation that occurs, but
this would predominantly be a level change rather than a change in the extent of transmission.
22
rates are now above policy rates could squeeze the net interest margins of the bank-
ing sector, which, among other things could result in lower profits; this would mean
bank capital grows at a slower rate, constraining banks’ ability to lend and therefore
weakening the bank lending channel.25
Perhaps more fundamentally, were a CBDC to disintermediate the banking sector
and significantly reduce the size of its aggregate balance sheet, as discussed in Section
3, this would reduce the importance and traction of the bank lending channel. This
disintermediation is more likely when a CBDC is a close substitute for bank deposits
that fully or partially dominates them in some aspects. This would be precisely when
the benefits to the monetary transmission mechanism discussed above would be at
their greatest. It is therefore apparent that a trade-off exists between the two forces
CBDC would exert on transmission through the banking sector, which would need to
be managed.
What is more, banks are crucially involved in money creation, a key part of the
impact of the bank lending channel. Currently banks lend by issuing new deposits,
in effect creating new money and purchasing power (McLeay et al., 2014; Jakab &
Kumhof, 2015). In contrast, non-bank lenders transfer existing purchasing power (ei-
ther deposits or CBDC) from savers to borrowers, but do not create any new purchasing
power in the process. With the introduction of CBDC, banks can continue to lend by is-
suing deposits, but they could alternatively choose to ‘lend CBDC’. In practical terms,
this would require that they ask the borrower to nominate a CBDC account into which
the lent funds could be transferred.
In practice, there are a number of reasons why banks would continue to prefer to
lend by issuing new deposits. Firstly, there is unlikely to be demand for borrowing in
CBDC specifically: as long as the sellers of goods, services or assets are able to substi-
tute freely between deposits and CBDC (which we assume they can), then they should
be neutral between receiving payments in CBDC or deposits, and should not offer any
incentive for buyers to pay by one medium over the other. This means borrowers them-
selves should be neutral between borrowing CBDC and borrowing deposits — they will
borrow from whichever lender offers them the best borrowing rate. Consequently, the
interest rate on loans for a given level of risk and term should be the same whether it
is CBDC or deposits that are borrowed. For this reason, banks are unlikely to receive
requests to borrow in CBDC specifically. Secondly, for a bank, lending CBDC will have
a much more negative impact on current regulatory ratios (specifically the Liquidity
Coverage Ratio and Net Stable Funding Ratio) than lending via issuing deposits, be-
cause lending CBDC ensures that the bank will lose £100 of liquidity for every £100
lent. In contrast, while lending by issuing deposits could still lead to some outflow of
CBDC, it is likely to be less, on average, than 100% of the amount lent.
All taken together, this analysis suggests that a universally accessible CBDC would
most likely strengthen the impact of changes in the policy rate on the real economy,
predominantly through increased pass-through from policy rates to other interest rates
in the economy. To the extent that this were the case, a CBDC would imply that
policy rates needed to vary by less over the cycle to stabilise the economy, conditioned
on the same shocks afflicting the economy.
25
We suggest a partial solution to this in Section 6 based on paying different rates of interest on CBDC
held by banks and on CBDC held by other agents.
23
5 Quantitative Easing with CBDC
In recent years central banks have purchased assets fom the private sector and funded
these purchases with newly created central bank money, a policy known as quantitative
easing. However, as non-banks cannot currently hold electronic central bank money,
and purchasing large amounts of assets by printing central bank notes is neither practi-
cal nor desirable, non-banks must use commercial banks as intermediaries to sell assets
to the central bank. The commercial bank sells the asset to the central bank on behalf
of the non-bank and receives an increased balance of electronic central bank money in
its reserve account. It simultaneously generates a new deposit on the liability side of its
own balance sheet, which it credits to the ultimate seller – the non-bank. Crucially, a
universally accessible CBDC would remove the need for this intermediated interaction:
QE could be carried out directly with non-bank participants. This process is shown in
Figure 2. The central bank can purchase an asset from a non-bank and simply increase
the balance on the seller’s CBDC account. In this way, QE can be more targeted, as
the central bank can choose to alter the balance sheet of the non-bank or banking sec-
tor independently, as it sees fit. It also has consequences for the onward transmission
of QE.
One of the main theoretical transmission mechanisms of asset purchases is the
portfolio rebalancing channel. This has its basis in work by Tobin (1969) and others,
who show that if assets are imperfect substitutes for one another, and there are market
frictions, then changes in the relative supplies of assets in the privately held portfolio
will have consequences for prices and yields. Empirical literature on the recent asset
purchase programmes of the Federal Reserve, Bank of England, European Central
Bank and Bank of Japan shows significant incidences of this channel of transmission.
See Bhattarai and Neely (2016) for a survey of the literature on the U.S. experience,
or Joyce, Liu, and Tonks (2014) for the UK, as well as Meaning and Zhu (2011, 2012).
As stated above, a consequence of the current system is that central bank asset
purchases from the non-bank private sector increase in the size of the banking sector’s
aggregate balance sheet, and change its composition, for instance average duration and
liquidity ratios. This will lead banks to rebalance their portfolios. They can do this in
two ways, each of which would have different consequences for the transmission of QE,
and for the impact of a universally accessible CBDC. If banks react to the enforced
additional holding of reserves by divesting themselves of similar, safe, liquid assets,
they may sell government bonds back to the non-bank private sector. This would
offset the reduction in the publicly-available supply of government bonds and counter
some of the intended policy impact. In this case a universally accessible CBDC would
strengthen the impact and monetary transmission of QE. Alternatively, banks could
choose to rebalance their portfolios by increasing the size of their balance sheets by
extending loans and thus arrive back at the same relative portfolio mix. Christensen
and Krogstrup (2017) develop a theoretical model along these lines in which QE induces
an unwanted change in the duration of banks’ portfolios and leads to an amplification
of the traditional portfolio rebalancing channel. Were this to be the dominant reaction
of banks then a universally accessible CBDC would remove this secondary rebalancing
effect and reduce the strength of QE. In the case of the UK, there is some empirical
evidence that banks behaved more in the former fashion than the latter (Butt, Churm,
& McMahon, 2015), and so we believe that the most likely case is that CBDC would
lead to more effective QE.
24
6 Differentiated rates of interest on CBDC
CBDC as envisioned in the majority of this paper pays a single interest rate, regardless
of the type of account holder. However, this need not be the case and it may even be
beneficial to pay different rates on CBDC depending on who holds it. For instance,
perhaps the most logical way to differentiate CBDC holdings would be between those
held by banks26 and those held by non-banks. This could be motivated by the special
role that banks play in monetary transmission and the economy more widely. For
instance, banks create money and purchasing power in the economy (McLeay et al.,
2014), and we would expect them to continue to create the marginal unit of money even
with a universally accessible CBDC. Paying differentiated rates would allow monetary
policy to influence banks — and therefore credit and money creation — differently to
non-banks.
One constraint faced by banks is that, due to regulation and as a result of the
maturity transformation which they undertake, they must hold some fraction of their
balance sheet in the form of liquid assets, such as central bank money (currently as
reserves) or similar. There is an opportunity cost to holding these assets, as liquid
assets usually pay a lower rate of return than other, less liquid alternatives such as
loans. Banks could increase their interest income by minimising the amount of liquid
assets they hold, but this increases the risk that they will run into liquidity problems
in the future.
Paying a single rate on a universally-accessible CBDC may exacerbate this prob-
lem. Historically, the return on central bank money has at least been in excess of the
rates banks have to pay on short-term liabilities such as sight deposits (see Figure 6).
However, as discussed above, CBDC would mean that deposit rates were higher than
the rate paid on CBDC, so banks would be making a net loss on all CBDC held. This
could reduce their overall net interest margins and profitability, and strengthen the
incentive to hold the minimum amount of central bank money.
Differentiating the interest rates paid to banks and non-banks offers a solution to
this problem. If the rate paid on CBDC balances held by banks were greater than the
rate paid to non-banks, then this would increase the return banks receive on the asset
side of their balance sheet without necessarily increasing the cost of deposits on the
liability side, thus lowering the overall cost of holding liquidity. From the depositor
side, if the return on CBDC (the risk-free rate) has not changed, then the return they
require to hold deposits, adjusting for risk and other factors would also not need to
change.
The spread between the rates paid to banks and non-banks could be set as a positive,
but fixed, level with the two rates moving together. In this case there would be a
steady-state impact on banks’ balance sheets, but the consequences for monetary policy
beyond our benchmark case would be limited. Alternatively, the spread itself could be
varied through time; this would have implications for monetary policy, and potentially
financial stability. An increase in the spread could lower the cost of holding a given
level of liquidity for a bank, which in turn would improve its balance sheet position.
There would therefore be a monetary stimulus through the bank balance sheet channel,
or through the bank lending channel. Even if banks passed some or all of the increase
26
This would also include building societies and other firms that are classified as Monetary Financial
Institutions (MFIs).
25
in the return on their assets to depositors in the form of higher deposit rates, this would
be stimulative through a cash-flow channel.27 The spread between the banking sector
CBDC rate and the non-bank CBDC rate would therefore provide an extra dimension
to the stance of monetary policy.
It should be noted that banks already benefit from a form of differentiation similar
to that described here: they have access to the central bank’s balance sheet on different
terms to those of the general public. In fact, the difference is even starker under the
current paradigm: not only do banks receive interest on their central bank money
(reserves) while non-banks do not (on cash), but the functionality and utility of the
two forms of central bank money is different. Although paying different rates to banks
and non-banks may assist in implementing monetary policy, there is the potential
that a system that explicitly pays more to banks than to the public at large could
be objectionable due to concerns around equity and fairness, These debates may be
especially acute in times of financial crisis.
26
Under these conditions the only difference between the reserves and CBDC from a
bank’s point of view would be the rate of interest each paid. Banks would not need
to simultaneously hold buffer stocks of both reserves and CBDC, since they could
freely convert between them on demand, for example converting reserves to CBDC at
the point at which depositors request to withdraw CBDC. This means banks would
exclusively hold whichever of the two assets paid them the highest rate of interest. If
the rate paid on reserves is greater than the rate paid on CBDC, this results in banks
only holding reserves (at the higher rate) and non-banks only holding CBDC. This
outcome is practically identical to the scenario above in which banks are paid one rate
on the CBDC they hold, whilst non-banks pay a different rate. If the rate paid on
reserves is lower than the rate paid on CBDC, banks and non-banks alike will only
hold CBDC, which is equivalent to our earlier scenario in which a single rate is paid
to banks and non-banks alike.
Consequently, in this dual asset regime, assuming free convertibility for different
types of central bank money, then for a non-zero quantity of reserves to exist, the rate
on reserves must be greater than the rate on CBDC. This limitation would not exist in
a framework of differentiated rates on a single CBDC, in which banks receive the rate
determined by the central bank, and have no option to earn the rate paid to non-banks.
Under what circumstances would the two assumptions above not hold? One plau-
sible possibility is if reserves and CBDC had different functionality. For instance, in
the UK, reserves are currently the accepted means of settlement for most interbank
and national payment systems, and we assume they would continue to serve that pur-
pose. However, perhaps CBDC is introduced as a cryptographic token on a distributed
ledger platform with a specific usage, such as settling securities trades in specific fi-
nancial markets. In this case, banks would have an incentive to hold both reserves and
CBDC. However, if the rate on reserves were higher than the rate on CBDC, banks
would still prefer to hold the minimum possible stock of CBDC, and convert reserves to
CBDC at the point at which they are needed for settlement of securities. Consequently,
the second assumption, that reserves and CBDC are freely convertible at the central
bank, must also be false in order to make it worthwhile considering CBDC and reserves
as two distinct assets. Kumhof and Noone (2018) explore scenarios where neither of
these assumptions hold.
7 E-cash
Although the primary focus of this paper is a single, universally accessible CBDC used
for monetary policy purposes, an alternative formulation is to introduce multiple forms
of electronic central bank money and use them for different objectives. The simplest
of these is the introduction of a digital, non-interest bearing, ‘e-cash’ alongside central
bank reserves. To be clear, such a framework amounts to the central bank issuing two
forms of CBDC simultaneously and differentiating them in terms of access. In this
world, reserves (the first form of CBDC) would continue to function as they currently
do, being used to settle between banks but could not be used to pay for goods, services
and assets in the wider economy. They would also continue to be at the heart of setting
monetary policy (Boel, 2016). E-cash (the second form of CBDC) would not be used
in setting monetary policy, but rather as a means of establishing an efficient and safe
payments system.
27
Consideration needs to be given to how the two assets would interact. As we have
noted before, it is common practice for central banks to allow free convertibility, at
par, between their different types of liability (e.g. £10 of reserves for £10 of cash). It
seems unlikely that they would break from this practice if they were to introduce a
third type of liability — CBDC — to their balance sheet. Therefore, an e-cash CBDC
would need to be provided perfectly elastically to meet demand at an interest rate that
is fixed at zero. This means that agents must be able to freely substitute between cash,
CBDC, and reserves (for banks). In this set-up the central bank can set the overall size
of the monetary base, but not directly the composition of liabilities within it. This is a
central feature of the par-convertibility of central bank liabilities even now: the central
bank can choose to inject reserves into the banking system, but if there is a surge in
demand for central bank notes then they must allow the stock of notes to increase while
the stock of reserves falls, or else inject additional reserves, expanding the monetary
base. The alternative is that the increased demand for notes goes unmet and the price
of a note changes relative to the price of reserves, breaking parity between different
types of central bank money and undermining monetary stability.
The demand for e-cash is likely to be a function of, inter alia, other interest rates in
the economy as changes in the rate paid on other assets change the relative return on
e-cash. These shifts in demand could drive flows between deposits and e-cash. In this
way demand for e-cash is likely to be counter-cyclical to policy rates. In the case of a
tightening of monetary policy, an increase in the rate paid on reserves would lead to
an increase in rates paid on bank deposits and thus a decrease in the relative return of
e-cash. This would make e-cash less attractive to hold and lead to a substitution from
CBDC into bank deposits. In contrast, a monetary policy expansion would have the
opposite effect, making e-cash relatively more attractive and leading to a substitution
from deposits into CBDC. These flows in and out of an e-cash CBDC could be a
source of instability in the banking sector. They could also affect the level of liquidity
on banks’ balance sheets and the cost/availability of bank funding, which may in turn
act as an unintentional dampener of the desired change in policy, loosening credit
conditions, all else equal, when policy is aiming to tighten, and vice versa.
28
Relatedly, it is important to find ways to mitigate against any financial stability
risks of CBDC. Critically, research should explore how CBDC can be introduced in an
orderly manner, without having a destabilising impact on the banking sector. Mecha-
nisms need to be designed to allow interoperability between deposits and CBDC whilst
creating incentives to discourage a run from deposits to CBDC in a panic scenario.
If the financial stability risks of CBDC can be reduced, this may tip the cost-benefit
balance in favour of CBDC, from the point of view of central banks.
Another area in which progress might tip the balance on the cost-benefit analysis
of CBDC is technology. Questions on this topic are far from resolved, but, currently,
many consider that distributed ledger technology is too immature and energy intensive
to represent a viable replacement to existing large-scale payments systems. However,
developments in this field are moving at such a rapid pace that what may currently seem
infeasible may be perfectly possible, or even obsolete, by the time a widely accessible
CBDC is introduced.
As well as influencing the functioning of the existing monetary toolkit, CBDC
also has the potential to enable more significant change in the toolkit itself. This
paper has deliberately considered the impact of CBDC on widely-used monetary policy,
namely changes in the central bank’s policy rate, and asset purchases (quantitative
easing). However, CBDC has also been discussed in the context of less conventional
monetary policy, such as the use of negative rates (Kimball & Agarwal, 2015) or direct
distributions of newly issued CBDC to citizens — so-called ‘helicopter money’ (Turner,
2015). These policies do not necessarily require a CBDC to be implemented, but the
existence of CBDC may affect their feasibility and impact. It may even be that CBDC
and future technological progress give rise to monetary instruments that have not yet
been considered.
Spanning all of these areas is the need for robust quantitative insights into CBDC.
Obviously this is complicated by a lack of data and a lack of good proxies for CBDC
— a problem that would be resolved with time once a CBDC had been introduced, but
that is hard to deal with ex-ante. High on the list of empirical questions that will need
to be answered are: What would be the size of demand for a CBDC? How volatile would
this demand be? What would be the interest rate elasticity of substitution between
CBDC and bank deposits? And what would CBDC do to steady state of interest rates
and credit spreads?
9 Concluding remarks
At its simplest, a central bank digital currency can be thought of as electronic narrow
money and so in many ways it should feel familiar to economists and policymakers.
Within this general definition there exist a number of dimensions along which any
specific CBDC could be varied: access, whether it is interest-bearing, the objective it
is designed to achieve, and the underlying technology on which it is based, to name
a few. Careful consideration will need to be given to these parameters both in future
research and also in order for a central bank to effectively introduce CBDC.
The main conclusion of this paper is that under a universally accessible, account-
based CBDC, monetary policy could operate in much the same way as it currently does,
guiding the economy through varying the rate of interest paid on balances of electronic
central bank money and the aggregate quantity of that money. The untested nature
29
of such a CBDC means that the impact on the monetary transmission mechanism is
uncertain, but we believe the most likely consequence would be that CBDC would
strengthen the monetary transmission mechanism, for a given change in policy instru-
ments.
This paper is intended as an early step in the development of the literature on
central bank digital currencies, and many fundamental questions remain unanswered.
These relate to, among other things, the impact on the wider financial sector, the
implications for financial stability, steady state changes in the economy resulting from
CBDC, and how CBDC would affect the balance sheet management of central banks.
Significant work, both theoretical and eventually empirical, will be required to inform
any policy decision to introduce CBDC.
References
Bank of Canada. (2017). Digital Currencies and Fintech. Retrieved from www
.bankofcanada.ca/research/digital-currencies-and-fintech/
Bank of England. (2017a). A blueprint for a new RTGS service for the United
Kingdom.
Bank of England. (2017b). Digital currencies. Retrieved from http://www
.bankofengland.co.uk/research/Pages/onebank/cbdc.aspx
Barrdear, J., & Kumhof, M. (2016). Staff Working Paper No. 605 The macroe-
conomics of central bank issued digital currencies. Bank of England.
Bech, M. L., & Garratt, R. (2017). Central Bank Cryptocurrencies. Bank for
International Settlements.
Benos, E., Garratt, R., & Gurrola-Perez, P. (2017). The Economics of Dis-
tributed Ledger Technology for Securities Settlement. Bank of England
Staff Working Paper No 670 .
Bhattarai, S., & Neely, C. J. (2016). A Survey of the Empirical Literature on
US Unconventional Monetary Policy. Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis.
Bjerg, O. (2017). Designing New Money: the policy trilemma of central bank
digital currency. Copenhagen Business School.
Boel, P. (2016). Thinking about the Future of Money and Potential Implications
for Central Banks. Sveriges Riksbank.
Bordo, M. D., & Levin, A. T. (2017a). Central Bank Digital Currency and the
Future of Monetary Policy. Hoover Institution.
Bordo, M. D., & Levin, A. T. (2017b). Central Bank Digital Currency and the
Future of Monetary Policy. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Broadbent, B. (2016). Central banks and digital currencies (speech). Bank of
England.
Butt, N., Churm, R., & McMahon, M. (2015). Did Quantitative Easing boost
bank lending? Bank Underground.
Carney, M. (2018). The future of money. Speech to the Inaugual Scottish
Economics Conference.
30
Chiu, J., & Hill, J. (2015). Staff Working Paper No. 540 The rate elasticity
of retail deposits in the United Kingdom: a macroeconomic investigation.
Bank of England.
Christensen, J., & Krogstrup, S. (2017). A Portfolio Model of Quantiative Eas-
ing. Presented at the European Central Bank Workshop on money markets,
monetary policy implementation and central bank balance sheets.
Danezis, G., & Meiklejohn, S. (2016). Centrally Banked Cryptocurrencies. Uni-
versity College London.
Dyson, B., & Hodgson, G. (2016). Digital Cash: Why Central Banks Should
Start Issuing Electronic Money. Positive Money.
FirstRand Bank. (2016). The Advent of Crypto Banking: A New Paradigm for
Central and Commercial Banking. FirstRand Bank.
Friedman, M. (1960). A Program for Monetary Stability. Fordham University
Press.
Fung, B. S., & Halaburda, H. (2016). Central Bank Digital Currencies: A
Framework for Assessing Why and How. Bank of Canada Staff Discussion
Paper .
Gagnon, J. E., & Sack, B. (2014). Monetary Policy with Abundant Liquidity: A
New Operating Framework for the Fed. Peterson Institute for International
Economics.
Goodfriend, M. (2002). Interest on Reserves and Monetary Policy. Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review , 8 (1), 77–84.
Goodfriend, M. (2016). The Case for Unencumbering Interest Rate Policy at the
Zero Bound (Vol. 26).
Goodfriend, M., & McCallum, B. T. (2007). Banking and Interest Rates in
Monetary Policy Analysis: a quantitative exploration. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 54 (5), 1480–1507.
Gouveia, O., Dos Santos, E., de Lis, S. F., Neut, A., Sebastián, J., et al. (2017).
Central Bank Digital Currencies: assessing implementation possibilities
and impacts. BBVA.
He, D., Leckow, R., Haksar, V., Mancini-Griffoli, T., Jenkinson, N., Kashima,
M., . . . Tourpe, H. (2017). Fintech and Financial Services: Initial Consid-
erations. International Monetary Fund Staff Discussion Note, 17 (05).
Jakab, Z., & Kumhof, M. (2015). Staff Working Paper No. 529 Banks are not
intermediaries of loanable funds - and why this matters. Bank of England.
Joyce, M. A., Liu, Z., & Tonks, I. (2014). Institutional Investor Portfolio Allo-
cation, Quantitative Easing and the Global Financial Crisis.
Ketterer, J. A., & Andrade, G. (2016). Digital Central Bank Money and the
Unbundling of the Banking Function. Inter-American Development Bank.
Kimball, M., & Agarwal, R. (2015). Breaking Through the Zero Lower Bound.
IMF Working Paper (15/224).
Koning, J. (2014). Fedcoin. https://jpkoning.blogspot.com/2014/10/
fedcoin.html.
Kumhof, M., & Noone, C. (2018). Central Bank Digital Currencies design
principles and balance sheet implications. Bank of England.
31
McLeay, M., Radia, A., & Thomas, R. (2014). Money Creation in the Modern
Economy. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin Q1 .
Meaning, J., & Zhu, F. (2011). The Impact of Recent Central Bank Asset
Purchase Programmes.
Meaning, J., & Zhu, F. (2012). The Impact of Federal Reserve Asset Purchase
Programmes: another twist.
Mersch, Y. (2017). Digital Base Money: an assessment from the ECBs per-
spective. Speech at the Farewell ceremony for Pentti Hakkarainen, Deputy
Governor of Suomen Pankki–Finlands Bank. Helsinki , 16 .
Mishkin, F. S. (1995). Symposium on the Monetary Transmission Mechanism.
The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9 (4), 3–10.
Monetary Authority of Singapore. (2017). Project Ubin Phase 2. Monetary
Authority of Singapore.
Motamedi, S. (2014). Will Bitcoin Ever Become Money? A path to de-
centralized central banking. http://tannutuva.org/blog/2014/7/
21/will-bitcoins-ever-become-money-a-path-to-decentralized
-central-banking.
Qian, Y. (2017). Digital Currency and Central Bank Bank Accounts [translated].
Tsinghua Financial Review .
Rogoff, K. (2016). The Curse of Cash. Princeton.
Scorer, S. (2017). Central Bank Digital Currency: DLT, or not DLT? That is
the question. Bank Underground blog https://bankunderground.co.uk/
2017/06/05/central-bank-digital-currency-dlt-or-not-dlt-that
-is-the-question/.
Svierges Riksbank. (2017). Does Sweden need the e-krona? Re-
trieved from www.riksbank.se/en/Financial-stability/Payments/
Does-Sweden-need-the-e-krona/
Tobin, J. (1969). A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory. Journal
of money, credit and banking, 1 (1), 15–29.
Turner, A. (2015). The case for monetary finance: an essentially political issue.
IMF 16th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference.
32
alongside its store of value function it also provides an additional service as a means of
exchange, for instance, lowering transaction costs, φC . The total expected return from
a unit of CBDC is therefore30
R C + φC (3)
and no-arbitrage would imply
R = R C + φC (4)
meaning that
R C = R − φC (5)
This means that CBDC would clear at a rate below the theoretical risk-free rate by
a spread determined by the transactional utility supplied by CBDC. In the exposition
here we assume this transactional utility is fixed per unit of CBDC, independent of the
quantity of CBDC. This is purely for clarity of presentation and a credible alternative
assumption is that the degree of transactional utility is a function of the quantity of
CBDC held. Were transactional utility to be a negative function of quantity, but to
a decreasing extent (the implied function has a negative first derivative and positive
second derivative) then Friedman (1960) argues that, as the creation of central bank
money is costless, the supply should be expanded to the point where φC is zero and
RC = R. This would imply that the rate paid on CBDC could be considered a reflection
of the true risk-free rate.
Building from CBDC to a wider array of assets we look at each sector of the economy
in turn and work through the no-arbitrage conditions that their balance sheets would
imply.
Beginning with the non-bank private sector, consistent with our stylised balance
sheets (see Figure 1), they can hold their wealth as a combination of three assets:
CBDC (denoted by C), bank deposits (D) and government bonds (B).31 For simplicity
of exposition we assume that each of these assets is one period in term, but can be
differentiated by other characteristics. As discussed above, each unit of CBDC held
provides a non-pecuniary benefit to the holder, φC , for instance as a result of lowering
transactional costs. Similarly, the interest rate paid on bank deposits is RD and bank
deposits offer a similar but not necessarily equivalent non-pecuniary return emanating
from its role as a means of exchange, φD . However, unlike CBDC, there is a probability,
γ, that banks will default on their deposits, in which case the depositor gets neither
the pecuniary return nor the non-pecuniary benefit. Lastly, government bonds offer
an interest rate RB . They are assumed to offer no transactional services, but are
defaultable with probability δ. Taken all together this means that the non-bank’s end
of period objective function can be written as
dU
= R C + φC = (7)
dC
30
With no default yet in the model, the expected returns are equal to the agreed returns.
31
We abstract from equity without any loss of insight for the themes with which we are concerned.
33
dU
= (1 − γ)[RD + φD ] = (8)
dD
dU
= (1 − δ)RB = (9)
dB
For the non-bank sector then, assuming that the rate on CBDC is set by the central
bank
RC + φC − (1 − γ)φD
RD = (10)
(1 − γ)
and
R C + φC
RB = (11)
(1 − δ)
This gives rise to two spreads. The spread of the deposit rate over the CBDC rate
is a positive function of the relative transactional services of CBDC compared with
deposits, and a positive function of the default rate. The spread of bond rates over the
CBDC rate is a positive function of the transactional service of CBDC money, and a
negative function of the default risk in the government bond. This all occurs in a one
period setting. In practice there is likely to be another significant premium driving a
wedge between the two rates, which is the term premium. This could be derived in a
multi-period model by the additional risk of locking funds away when you are subject to
unknown payments or liquidity shocks, and would appear as a positive function of the
term of the bond.32 As discussed previously, were we to assume that the transactional
utility of CBDC were a decreasing and concave function of the quantity of CBDC,
then the supply can, and arguably should, be expanded to the point at which φC = 0.
This would mean that the only differences between government bonds and CBDC were
default inherent in government bonds and term. For short-term government bonds in
stable economies both of these elements could be expected to be negligible, and so we
would expect the short-term government bond rate to be extremely close to the interest
rate on CBDC. As noted by Bordo and Levin (2017b), were the central bank to engage
in open market operations between treasury bills and CBDC, they could ensure that
this would be the case in practice.
We follow the same process for the banking sector. Banks can hold assets in the
form of CBDC (C), loans (L) or government bonds (B). Again, this is consistent with
our balance sheet diagram. As with non-banks, the banking sector receives both a
pecuniary return on its CBDC holdings, RC , and a non-pecuniary benefit from CBDC’s
transactional services, φB . Unlike non-banks, they receive an additional non-pecuniary
benefit, η, from CBDC through its role as a High Quality Liquid Asset (HQLA).
This could be due to a regulatory need to hold HQLA, or a portfolio preference of
the bank itself. In a system of mandated reserve requirements, this benefit could be
very significant. Government bonds also provide a benefit as HQLAs, but provide no
transactional services, and default with probability δ.
32
As another point of reference, bond rates will differ from the theoretical risk-free rate discussed above
to the extent of inherent default risk only. In practice there would also be other premia, such as term, which
would mean that the bond rate clears at a spread above the risk-free rate.
34
The last asset that banks can hold on their balance sheet is loans. The pecuniary
return is RL with a default probability of µ. We assume a cost of producing and
monitoring each loan, M . For a more developed model which includes monitoring
costs of this type, see Goodfriend and McCallum (2007). We further assume loans
offer no transactional services, nor liquidity services. Lastly, banks must finance the
asset side of their balance sheet with liabilities, meaning that they must pay RD on all
deposits owed to the non-bank sector.
Taken together we can write the bank’s optimisation problem as
dU
= RC + φB + η − (1 − γ)RD = 0 (13)
dC
dU
= (1 − δ)RB + (1 − δ) − (1 − γ)RD = 0 (14)
dB
dU
= (1 − µ)RL − M − (1 − γ)RD = 0 (15)
dL
and which optimises to give
RC + φB + η − (1 − δ)
RB = (16)
(1 − δ)
R C + φB + η + M
RL = (17)
(1 − µ)
This shows that from the viewpoint of the banking sector, the spread of bond rates
over the CBDC rate is a positive function of the transactional benefit of CBDC, of the
default risk in bonds, and the relative benefits of CBDC as a HQLA when compared
with bonds. When combined with the non-bank condition for bonds, this implies that
the relative transactional services received by banks compared with non-banks must
equal the additional benefit that banks receive from holding bonds as HQLA. The loan
rate spread is a positive function of the cost of producing a loan and the probability of
default.
35