Legitimacy and Parliamentary Oversight in Australia: The Rise and Fall of Two Public Accounts Committees

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 22

The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at

www.emeraldinsight.com/0951-3574.htm

Legitimacy and
Legitimacy and parliamentary oversight in
oversight in Australia Australia
The rise and fall of two public accounts
committees 13
Kerry Jacobs and Kate Jones
Australian National University, Canberra, Australia

Abstract
Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to address the question of whether two early Australian
public accounts committees were established for the purpose of legitimating governments of the time.
Design/methodology/approach – The paper addressed these issues through a study of the
establishment, early work and abolition in the 1930s of the Victorian Committee of Public Accounts
(VCPA) and the Joint Committee of Public Accounts (JCPA).
Findings – Clear evidence is found that the Joint Committee of Public Accounts (JCPA) had been
copied from the VCPA and that the VCPA had been copied from the UK House of Commons Committee
of Public Accounts, which was established in 1861. This would indicate that the primary objective in
the establishment of both these committees was legitimation rather than control. It was found that the
subsequent work of both the VCPA and the JCPA showed a drift away from an accounting focus
towards a policy focus. This is similar to the JCPA experience described by Degeling et al. in relation to
the JCPA, which also supports the legitimation argument. It was also found that both committees
could be disestablished with relative ease because their legitimating purpose was no longer strong
enough to demand their continuation and that, in fact, their abolition became the factor that served a
legitimating purpose for governments.
Originality/value – The paper suggests that the ideas of legitimation and mimetic isomorphism
provide a more convincing explanation for the nature and work of these two public accounts
committees than the idea of accounting colonisation.
Keywords Public sector accounting, Australia, Regulation, Modern history
Paper type Research paper

Introduction
Power (1997) claimed that institutions of oversight and audit have come to play an
increasingly important role in the creation of legitimacy and social stability in modern
society. He highlighted changes within the public sector and drew a link between
processes of audit, trust and risk within structures of governance and regulation. Hood
et al. (2001) also highlighted these issues of governance and regulation within a process
of the evolution of a risk society described by Ulrich Beck. However, these institutions
have long histories and interesting origins.
The research question addressed in this paper is whether the ideas of isomorphism
and policy transfer provide an explanation for the establishment and early work of the
Victorian and the federal Australian Public Accounts Committees (PAC). The PAC is a Accounting, Auditing &
key example of an institution of audit, governance and regulation within the Accountability Journal
Vol. 22 No. 1, 2009
pp. 13-34
q Emerald Group Publishing Limited
The authors wish to acknowledge the contribution of seminar participants at University of 0951-3574
Technology Sydney and the contribution of the two anonymous reviewers. DOI 10.1108/09513570910922999
AAAJ Westminster parliamentary system. Although it might not be considered a classical
22,1 example of accounting practice, it has been required to exercise an accounting role
through the control and oversight of parliamentary spending. Therefore, the PAC has
become a central element of the process of parliamentary and democratic
accountability. Our focus on this committee can be understood as part of the
institutional turn to public administration, politics and accounting. Hopwood (1984)
14 argued that accounting language and practices have become intertwined in issues of
public policy, both reflecting and influencing the public debate through the creation of
selective patterns of economic visibility and disciplining performance so that
accountability can be demanded, policed and enforced. It is these patterns and
practices, which make up the structures or institutions of accountability and oversight.
The paradox of any institutional analysis is that the institutions being studied are
the product of events and influences from the past and yet function and interact with
contemporary settings. Therefore, in order to adequately grasp the nature and
operation of these processes of oversight, governance and accountability that Power
(1997) claims characterise modern society, we must consider the origins and early
operations of these social institutions and practices.
Within the accounting literature, Degeling et al. (1996) provide one of the few studies
of the work of a parliamentary audit and oversight committee – the Australian federal
Joint Committee of Public Accounts (JCPA). Degeling et al. (1996) proposed that
accounting and economics tend to colonise broader concerns regarding equality, access
and quality within the work of the committee. However, they found that was not the case
and that the initial “accounting” focus of the reports produced by the JCPA was replaced
by a policy and political focus over time. The limitation of this work is that while
Degeling et al. (1996) provided a valuable description of the changing accountability
focus of the work of the JCPA, they failed to fully explore the origin and establishment of
this committee. They also did not consider that the JCPA was suspended in 1932 and not
re-established until 1952. These gaps provide the motivation and focus for our paper. We
note the direct links between the establishment of the JCPA and the earlier work of the
Victorian Committee of Public Accounts (VCPA). It can be established from
parliamentary debates and the legislation that the JCPA was copied from the VCPA,
which predated the JCPA by nearly 20 years. The JCPA and the VCPA were also
abolished at a similar time. Therefore, these institutions need to be understood as a pair
in both their establishment and their disestablishment. We pay particular attention to the
establishment of the Victorian committee (VCPA) because it predated the JCPA.
We found evidence that the JCPA had been copied from the VCPA and that the
VCPA had been copied from the Westminster Committee of Public Accounts, which
was established in 1861, in the UK House of Commons. This indicates that the primary
objective for the establishment of both these committees was legitimation rather than
control, which would be assumed if accounting served a functional role. Within the
institutional framework, this process of copying can be described as mimetic
isomorphism (Powell and DiMaggio, 1991; Scott, 2001). The concepts of mimetic,
coercive and normative isomorphism assume that institutional practices serve to create
legitimacy rather than fulfil a functional role. We explore this possibility further by
contrasting the work of the VCPA with the analysis presented by Degeling et al. (1996).
If the role of the VCPA were a functional one, it would be reasonable to expect that the
VCPA would achieve the objectives and purpose established at its foundation.
We addressed these issues through a study of the establishment and work of the Legitimacy and
VCPA between 1895 and 1931. We found evidence for the case of legitimation because oversight in
the subsequent work of the VCPA drifted from an accounting to a policy focus in a
manner similar to that of the JCPA, as described by Degeling et al. (1996). However, we Australia
suggest that the ideas of isomorphism and policy transfer provide a more convincing
explanation for the nature and work of these two committees.
15
Public accounts committees and legitimacy
McGee (2002, p. 9), in a review of the work of PACs and Auditors-General across the
Commonwealth, argued that democracy entails accountability for the exercise of power
and that the PAC is one organisational form in which Parliament ensures the
accountability of government, particularly the process of public financial
accountability. Normanton (1971, p. 312) suggested that public accountability was
the chief hallmark of western democracy, which called for “openly declared facts and
open debate of them by laymen and their elected representatives”. This perspective
adopts a strongly functionalist approach towards these social institutions, presenting a
regulative and possibly a normative argument for the nature and function of these
institutions. In that sense, the PAC can be seen as a vital pillar to the legitimacy of
political institutions, as argued by Jurgen Habermas (1976). Offe (1996) followed the
same argument with the idea that the elements of legislative representative bodies such
as parliamentary committees play an important role in securing public legitimacy for
the political systems.
Within the Westminster model of parliamentary systems, elements of accounting
oversight were introduced as early as 1861. The first PAC was established in the UK
Westminster parliament in 1861 by the then Chancellor of the Exchequer, William
Gladstone (McGee, 2002; Jacobs et al., 2007). The responsibility and role of the
Westminster PAC was to examine the accounts showing the appropriation of sums
granted by Parliament to meet the public expenditure. While the members nominated
were selected to give satisfaction to “both sides of the house”, they were primarily
intended to bring as much talent, knowledge and experience as possible to the
examination of accounts (Hansard, Vol. 162, 19 April 1861, col. 773). Gladstone claimed
that it was the members who were best qualified (in the examination of public
accounts) that were selected for a duty which was seen as being “of a dry and repulsive
kind” (Hansard, Vol. 162, 19 April 1861, col. 774; Stent, 2004). PACs were established as
guardians of the public finances, with a responsibility for holding the Government to
account for its use of public money and resources (McGee, 2002). Within this system,
accounting was presented, if not understood, as being an objective, neutral and
apolitical technology. Gladstone himself took the view that “Economy is the first and
great article (economy as I understand it) in my financial creed” (Morley, 1903, p. 62).
However his passion for thrift was combined with a desire to establish a regulated and
orderly system of financial control dominated not by politics but by the legal and
constitutional provisions. He was not alone in this. Chubb (1952) described the attitude
of members of parliament towards public spending in the following terms:
. . . they approached it rather as financial and constitutional experts than as politicians, and
the system they designed was intended primarily to deal with the facts and the law. The facts,
recorded in the accounts, were clear; the law, embodied in the Appropriation Acts and
Treasury regulations, was also clear. It remained for the Accounts Committee to give a
AAAJ decision. Thus the experts combined the predilections of the age with the knowledge that
came of investigation and study, and their conclusions were not only welcome, but
22,1 incontestable (Chubb, 1952, p. 35).
However, the link between legitimacy, democracy and accountability as embodied by
the PAC is complex. In general, the argument is that contemporary implementations of
NPM/NPFM reform have altered accountability; there is an increasing emphasis on
16 managerial and managerialist forms of accountability and correspondingly less on
political, parliamentary and public accountability (Hughes, 1998; Jacobs, 1998; Jacobs
et al., 2007). This point was clearly made by Gray and Jenkins (1993) in their review of
the place of accountability within the UK public sector. Pusey (1991) and Guthrie and
Parker (1998) have made a similar argument in the context of Australia.
Degeling et al. (1996) analysed the work of the Australian federal Joint Committee of
Public Accounts (JCPA) and compared the foundational statements about the
committee’s claimed accountability function with the performance of accountability as
contained in its reports. Degeling et al.’s (1996) thesis was that the JCPA would adhere
to its foundational focus on matters of financial accountability and possibly narrow its
sphere of interests, abstaining from any matters with a non-financial element. From a
functionalist perspective, it would be reasonable to assume that the JCPA would follow
its foundational mandate in the work conducted. However, from a legitimacy
perspective this is not a valid assumption as the committee itself would have either
been copied or imposed to improve the perceived legitimacy of the Commonwealth
Government. Degeling et al. (1996) found that the JCPA did not function as a colonising
influence and that while the early work of the JCPA reflected its financial
accountability mandate, this was not true in the later years, when it was concerned
with effectiveness and policy advice instead.
Degeling et al.’s (1996) conclusion that the financial accountability mandate was
colonised by the political is understandable as they focused on the early work of the
JCPA which predates NPM. What is not clear from Degeling et al. (1996) is the place
accounting played in the formation of these institutions. We will look in more detail at
the establishment of these committees, to consider both the JCPA and the Victorian
Committee of Public Accounts (VCPA) and provide an alternative explanation,
drawing from an institutional theoretical understanding. Because the VCPA predated
the JCPA by nearly 20 years (Davey, 1960, p. 3) and the structures mandate and
practices of the JCPA were copied from the VCPA it would be reasonable to describe
the initial structure of the JCPA as an example of isomorphism or policy transfer and
argue that the primary function and role of the JCPA was legitimacy. If this was true
then the JCPA’s abandonment of its financial accountability focus would be
unsurprising. Therefore it is necessary to study the earlier VCPA and determine the
nature and origin of its mandate within that jurisdiction and to understand what
influenced its establishment. This also raises the possibility that aspects of
accountability attributed to NPM reform may have a longer history as they may be
reflected in the institutional structures developed in the 1860s and 1870s.
New institutional theory (see, Powell and DiMaggio, 1991; Meyer and Rowan, 1977)
has been extensively used within the accounting literature to describe change over time
(e.g. Fogarty, 1996; Carpenter and Feroz, 2001; Fogarty and Rogers, 2005). The
argument is that institutions need legitimacy in order to function and to be perceived
as rational. Scott (2001, p. 58) provides a brief definition of legitimacy with the
statement that “. . . in addition to material resources and technical information Legitimacy and
organisations require social acceptability and credibility in order to survive and thrive oversight in
in their social environments”. Scott turns to the work of Suchman (1995, p. 574) to
provide a fuller definition of legitimacy as “. . . a generalised perception or assumption Australia
that the actions of an entity are desirable, proper, or appropriate within a socially
constructed system of norms, values, beliefs and definitions”. The argument is that
institutions comply with these social norms and value and tend to adopt similar 17
structures or practices in order to secure that legitimacy.
The way that organisations adopt similar structures or practices is described by
Meyer and Rowan (1977, p. 352) as institutional isomorphism. Powell and DiMaggio
(1991, p. 67) provided a three-part typology of the social rules and pressures, which
lead to institutional isomorphism: coercive isomorphism, mimetic isomorphism and
normative isomorphism. Powell and DiMaggio (1991, p. 67) identified the common
legal environment and state regulation as examples of coercive isomorphism. They
also stated that expectations and persuasion experienced as force constitute this kind
of isomorphism and that these pressures can take the form of budget standardisation,
performance measures, reporting systems or even the effects of monopolistic service
infrastructures such as transport and telecommunications. However, where
organisational technologies are poorly understood and goals are ambiguous,
uncertainty provides a powerful force that encourages imitation. Powell and
DiMaggio (1991, p. 69) described this as mimetic isomorphism. This process is also
described in the politics literature as policy transfer or policy learning (Dolowitz and
Marsh, 1996; Jacobs and Barnett, 2000). Powell and DiMaggio (1991, p. 71) suggested
that normative isomorphism stems primarily from professionalisation and the
expression of a set of values and expectations associated with university education and
cross-organisational professional networks. It is the commonality of values associated
with professional orientation and the selective recruitment of staff from certain
educational institutions (Powell and DiMaggio, 1991, p. 72) or certain social and
economic settings, which leads to similarity in organisational structures and practices
(Jacobs, 2003). Scott (2001, p. 56) further developed the idea of normative isomorphism
by arguing that common values also include rules, routines and procedures. Scott
(2001, p. 57) went so far as to include cultural and cognitive values as examples of
normative isomorphism – in effect, the shared conceptions associated with how actors
attribute meaning to social experience and construct social reality.
Isomorphism would explain the objective for the establishment of the early VCPA in
Victoria as strengthening the legitimacy of the colonial parliament. It could reflect a
coercive pressure from the UK to adopt structures and practices similar to those of the
Westminster parliament. It could also reflect institutional or policy transfer and
copying; the Westminster parliament was seen as an example of good government and
democracy, so it became desirable that the Victorian model copy it in every way. The
next part of this paper explores the establishment of the VCPA. We also briefly revisit
the establishment of the federal JCPA described by Degeling et al. (1996) to explore the
legitimacy aspects.

Establishing the Victorian Committee of Public Accounts


The VCPA was established in 1895, but the creation of a PAC in the Victorian
parliament was first proposed in 1870 by the Select Committee on Financial
AAAJ Arrangements. Prior to its successful creation, there had been two failed attempts in
22,1 1886 and 1891. There was no evidence of any effort on the part of the UK based colonial
authority to encourage or require the establishment of a PAC and therefore there is no
direct evidence of coercive isomorphism. There is evidence for mimetic isomorphism as
the first attempt proposed a committee that was based exactly on the British House of
Commons committee. The second attempt was more radical, arguing for a committee
18 that would be a cross between the British and the French systems of parliamentary
scrutiny, with power to examine the estimates as well as the appropriations (VPD,
Legislative Assembly 2 December 1891, p. 2805). The French system involved
committees in both houses. The 33-member Commission des Comptes had similar
responsibilities to the House of Commons committee, but the other committees dealt
with appropriations. Overall, the parliamentary committees in the French system
oversaw government finance at all stages. The initiative for the second attempt, in the
form of a Public Accounts Committee Bill, came from William Shiels, Attorney-General
and Minister of Railways, seconded by the premier, James Munro. Shiels described the
objective of this bill in his second reading speech:
The house had special duties to perform, and among them was that of putting down
extravagance. What was wanted in the public interest was a means of arriving at the truth
with respect to financial matters (VPD, Legislative Assembly 2 December 1891, p. 2807).
Shiel’s speech indicated that, from the early proposals, the role of the VCPA was to
provide an objective and politically independent analysis of financial activity and that
it was understood accounting could provide that. Jones (2006, pp. 198-199) argued that
the opposition to this bill was because it was proposed as legislation rather than as a
standing order (the then basis for the committee at Westminster) and that it diverged
from the practice of the Westminster House of Commons with the proposed additional
estimates review powers. In the debate there was clear resistance and opposition to the
Victorian Parliament going beyond the British model in any way (Jones, 2006, p. 199)
and while copying off the UK model was a powerful source of legitimacy, copying off
the French model was not.
In 1894, the conservative premier, James Patterson, established a royal commission
into constitutional reform with 12 members representing all political positions. The
royal commission not only recommended that Victoria establish a PAC but also
presented a draft standing order for the committee. The government changed several
months after the royal commission had reported and Patterson was replaced by a
Liberal, George Turner, but the move to establish a PAC still went ahead. The motion
that a standing order to establish the committee be prepared was moved by Robert
Best, who had chaired the royal commission. The background to, and bipartisan
support for, the establishment of the VCPA suggest that it was not the result of party
politics. Best was by this time a minister in the Liberal government and his motion was
seconded by the conservative Godfrey Carter, who had moved the 1886 motion. The
motion of Best and Carter clearly specified the financial accountability role of the
committee and the notion of its neutral and apolitical nature:
Financial matters should, in my opinion, be completely apart from party politics; they should
be dealt with on their sole merits. The very object of a neutral committee of this kind should
be to recommend as to the most economical management, financial and administrative, of
public affairs . . . (VPD, Legislative Assembly, 1894, p. 1212).
Like the 1891 proposal, the royal commission’s proposed standing order also included Legitimacy and
the power to examine the estimates. However, when Best put the motion to parliament, oversight in
he omitted the proposal to deal with estimates “to eliminate from the motion all
controversial matter . . . so that we may be exactly on all-fours with the English Australia
precedent” (VPD, Legislative Assembly 19 December 1894, p. 1210). This move was
correct because in the subsequent debate, any deviation from the English system and
any evidence of a move towards the French system were staunchly resisted (Jones, 19
2006, p. 200). The resulting standing order provided the following introduction and
specified the following duties for the committee:
At the commencement of every session of Parliament the Legislative Assembly, according to
the practice of Parliament with reference to the appointment of select committees, shall
appoint a select committee of seven members, to be called the Committee of Public Accounts,
with powers to send for persons, papers, and records. The duties of the Committee of Public
Accounts shall be as follows:
a. To examine the accounts of the receipts and expenditure of the colony, and to bring under
the notice of the Legislative Assembly any items in those accounts, or any circumstances
connected to them, to which it may consider the attention of the Legislative Assembly
should be directed.
b. To report to the House any alteration which may appear to the committee desirable to be
introduced in the form of or method of keeping the public accounts, or in the mode of
receipt, control, issue or payment of the public money.
c. To inquire into and report upon any question which may have arisen in connexion with
the public accounts.
d. To inquire into and report to the Legislative Assembly upon the investment of and
dealings with the funds of the Commissioners of Savings Banks.
e. To deal with any special references that may be made to them by the Legislative
Assembly (VPD, Legislative Assembly, 1895, pp. 2093-2094).

The introduction clause (a) of these standing orders covered the entire UK House of
Commons standing order while adding the additional duties of examining the receipts
(in addition to the expenditures) and reporting back to the Legislative Assembly
(parliament). Although the obligation to report any desirable change to the accounts
and accounting system (b) was beyond the formal UK mandate, this role was
performed in practice. The wide-ranging power reflected in clause (c) to inquire into
and report on any question connected with the public accounts was not reflected in UK
mandate, although Jones (2006, p. 205) claimed that the UK PAC may have taken this
power on itself. The focus (d) on the funds of the commissioner of savings banks was
peculiar to the Victorian committee and reflected a concern at the time with the
activities of the Victorian savings banks (Jones, 2006, p. 205). Therefore, this specific
focus can be seen as a reflection of the fact that the Government had been investigating
the structure and lending policies of Victorian savings banks (Jones, 2006, p. 205). This
banking focus was not retained in the mandate transferred to the federal JCPA in 1914.
Finally, clause (e) indicated that the VCPA was authorised to deal with any specific
reference from the Legislative Assembly. This role also reflected the actual work and
role of the UK PAC. The Victorian VCPA had taken 25 years to establish, and the
stated objective was to provide a neutral, objective and apolitical form of accounting
AAAJ control and measurement. While early initiatives had failed, they succeeded with an
22,1 “exact copy” of the UK committee.
There is an obvious question of why it took so long to establish the VCPA. We
would argue that there are a number of reasons for that. Jones (2006, p. 205) claimed
that the mandate of the VCPA indicates that it was not simply a copy of the mandate of
the UK PAC at its inception. However, the extended mandate of the VCPA reflected the
20 powers that had been granted to, or claimed by, the UK PAC by 1895. The concern with
the oversight of the commissioners of savings banks was the only acceptable deviation
from the UK model and, therefore, the only response to local Australian conditions. On
the whole, the process of the establishment of the VCPA would provide a strong
argument for mimetic isomorphism. It was important for legitimacy reasons that the
VCPA was seen as being an exact copy of the current practices of the UK PAC. Any
attempt to introduce ideas from the French was quickly rejected.
Scott (2001) indicates that the three institutional types of isomorphism are rarely
separate but often function together in the generation of legitimacy. Therefore, in
addition to the mimetic driver were there also elements of normative or coercive
isomorphism? While a strong normative element to these changes is unlikely, Jones
(2006, p. 208) does note that many of the key protagonists in the attempts to implement
a Victorian PAC had visited England and would have been influenced by the
parliamentary practices and systems they observed there. While there was strong
evidence of the desire to copy the UK model and therefore mimetic isomorphism, there
may still have been some of the ongoing cultural norms described by Scott (2001) and
therefore also be elements of normative isomorphism.
Writers on Australian politics have generally rejected a coercive argument in the
formation of the Government institutions. Jones (2006, p. 194) quotes the work of AF
Madden (1979), who suggested that at the time responsible government was being
established in Australia and New Zealand, there was little interest in exporting the
British model of Westminster to these colonies. Although most states had a period of
direct government from the UK, they were granted the power of self-government in the
1850s (Weller and Flemming, 2003 p. 14). New South Wales developed its own
constitution from 1850 (Smith, 2003, p. 44) and was quite independent before that time
given that the governor was generally appointed from within the colony rather than
from London. Therefore while the institutions and practices may have been modelled
on Westminster they were seen as not being imposed by Westminster. This also seems
to have been the case with the other states and clearly the case with the establishment
of the Commonwealth in 1901. Carroll (2006) indicated that until the 1850s there was a
measure of voluntary policy and institutional transfer from Britain to its colonies.
Between the 1850s and 1901 there was increasing local innovation and a growing
transfer within Australia after 1901. If there was clear coercive pressure from the UK it
is likely to have been more evident in the establishment of the institutions in the state
of Victoria in the mid 1800s than in the Commonwealth institutions in the 1900s. There
was no evidence of direct coercion in this case.
It is possible that the arguments against UK influence may have oversimplified the
situation. One explanation for the successful establishment of the VCPA in 1895 was the
crises of public confidence in the then Victorian government. The 1880s had been
prosperous years for the Victorian economy, with high prices being paid for wheat and
wool, high levels of British investment and a land boom fuelled by speculation. By 1894,
however, the economy had collapsed, unemployment had risen, government revenue had Legitimacy and
fallen and a number of banks had collapsed. Some colonial politicians, including Munro, oversight in
had been involved in scandals associated with land speculation and railways. Chua and
Poullaos note that of the 48 members of the Victorian parliament in the late 1880s and Australia
early 1890s, 30 were land speculators (Chua and Poullaos, 1998, p. 172).
In 1890-1891, for the first time, government expenditure exceeded revenue and
economy in government became a major concern. It was necessary to quickly and 21
clearly restore public confidence and legitimacy. The establishment of a public
accounts committee modelled on the Westminster model was an obvious and timely
solution. While not exactly coercive it should be noted that during the 1890s that
Victoria was heavily dependent on British capital (Chua and Poullaos, 1993, p. 699;
Chua and Poullaos, 1998, p. 162). Therefore economic collapse, political scandals and
the debts of the Victorian government meant that considerable pressure was applied to
restore the legitimacy of both the market and the parliament (Chua and Poullaos, 1998,
p. 173). The establishment of the VCPA in 1895 can be seen as a direct response to that
desperate need to restore legitimacy.
In their discussion of the federal JCPA, Degeling et al. (1996, p. 34) highlight a similar
need to strengthen public legitimacy and confidence. The Fisher Labor government had
lost the 1913 election amidst criticism of its financial and economic policies and following
the loss of a referendum to increase the powers of the Commonwealth. The Liberal Cook
government that succeeded it established the JCPA with a stated responsibility to
scrutinise and control public expenditure. Degeling at al.’s (1996) finding that the work of
the JCPA drifted from its initial mandate seems consistent with our understanding that
the establishment of the JCPA was an attempt to garner legitimacy of part of the
Government. When the Treasurer (Sir John Forrest) introduced the bill for the JCPA, he
made it clear that while the establishment of the committee was desirable, the duties and
roles of the committee would be left for the parliament to define (APD (Australian
Parliamentary Debates), 1913, p. 3277). It is clear from Forrest’s introduction that the
existence of the committee was deemed to be important rather than its having a
particular mandate or function. This would challenge Degeling et al.’s (1996) focus on the
mandate and the functionalist assumption that the committee was established to provide
financial oversight while lending some support to a legitimacy argument.
In discussing the JCPA bill, Forrest also cited the standing order that had
established the Victorian committee and set out its powers and duties together with
similar orders from Westminster as a guide to be followed by the Commonwealth (APD
(Australian Parliamentary Debates), 1913, p. 3278). The fact that the JCPA was a joint
upper and lower house committee was a substantial structural change from both the
Victorian and the British precedents. Nonetheless, in 1915, the committee requested
from the Victorian committee “copies of State records to assist and [sic]
Commonwealth Committee’s operations” (NAA: A12840, 2004/1). This is not
surprising. The Committee of Public Accounts Act that was finally passed specified
responsibilities for the JCPA almost identical to those of Victoria’s VCPA. From
Forrest’s statement, the evidence for the use of the Victorian standing order as a model
and the similarity between the Victorian standing order and the Commonwealth
legislation, it seems unquestionable that the JCPA proposal was copied from the VCPA
practice. Within the institutional theory framework, this is consistent with mimetic
isomorphism.
AAAJ The establishment of the JCPA as a joint committee of both the upper house (Senate)
22,1 and the lower house (House of Representatives) in an anomaly for an argument of
isomorphism. In this case the structure and practices were not a copy from the
Victorian model or from Westminster practice. However, it is clear that genuine
innovations are both practical and desirable. In that sense the establishment of the
JCPA as a joint committee can be argued as a functional response to the concern of both
22 houses to exercise financial oversight. In essence the joint approach prevented the
wasteful duplication of resources and the confusing duplication of role. However, it is
also possible to present a legitimacy argument. While the seats in the House of
Representatives are allocated to reflect the population and are therefore dominated by
the largest states (Victoria and New South Wales), the positions in the Senate are
structured to reflect the concern that the interests of the smaller states would be
protected and therefore the Senate is sometimes described as the “states house”. It was
this very concern that almost resulted in some of the smaller states not joining the
federation. Therefore the inclusion of representatives from both the Senate and the
House in the process of financial oversight can be seen as a savvy political move, which
provided further legitimacy to the actions of the JCPA.
We argue that the establishment of both the VCPA and the subsequent JCPA was
driven by the need for legitimacy. However, although an institution may be established
as a tool of legitimation under the influence of mimetic isomorphism, it has the
potential to change and evolve to better meet local needs and conditions as reflected in
the joint JCPA (Carroll, 2006). This provides a powerful institutional explanation for
the drift away from the initial JCPA mandate observed by Degeling et al. (1996). In the
next part of this paper, we explore whether a similar drift or evolution is also evident in
the work of the VCPA.

The work of the VCPA


Following the Degeling at al. (1996) template, we analysed the reports of the VCPA
from its establishment until its disestablishment in 1932. There were profound
differences in the political environments of the VCPA and the JCPA at their
establishment. In 1895, although groups inside parliament were described as parties
and described themselves as such, they did not have the organisational structure of
modern political parties; there was no extra-parliamentary infrastructure and no party
discipline. Although members of parliament could be broadly divided between liberals
and conservatives, they could, and did, form loose alliances and factions with each
other according to personal relationships, common interests and short-term advantage.
By the time the JCPA was established in 1914, political parties had become firmly
entrenched in Australian politics (Starr et al., 1978), the Australian labour movement
was in a position to contest the first federal election in 1901 as a party, the first Liberal
Party had been established in 1910 and the Country Party, the predecessor of the
National Party, had been created by state farmers’ organisations around the time of
World War I.
Between the establishment of the VCPA in 1895 and 1932, there were 15 committees.
The fifteenth committee, appointed in 1931, was the last until 1955 as no members were
appointed to it in 1932. Between 1895 and 1932, the VCPA published 57 reports, of
which 55 were reports of its inquiries. The remaining two, in 1897 and 1901, reported
only on the activities of the committee[1]. They were entitled Report on Activities and
have been excluded from the analysis. There were also some clear differences in the Legitimacy and
activity levels of some VCPAs, with the third (1900-1902) and the eleventh (1920-1921) oversight in
producing no reports at all while the eighth (1911-1914) produced eight reports and the
ninth (1914-1917) and the twelfth (1921-1924) both produced seven reports each. Australia
Initially the VCPA adhered to the financial focus laid down for it by the standing
order. The first seven committees, which covered the 17 years from 1895 to 1911,
produced reports mostly with a financial focus. The third (1900-1902) committee only 23
produced a report on its activities (1901), which noted that no questions had been
referred to it by parliament or government and that “the Annual Report of the Audit
Commissioners still continues to be presented to the House at such a late period as to
render it impossible for the Committee of Public Accounts to take it into consideration
during the Session in which it is received” (Committee of Public Accounts, 1901). In
other words, if neither government nor parliament referred questions to it and the audit
commissioners’ report was not available, the committee was left without work.
The eighth committee (1911-1914) began the move away from a financial oversight
focus and produced eight inquiry reports. The ninth committee spanned most of the
period of World War I and addressed a number of financial issues, such as the financial
position of the state coal mine at Wonthaggi (Committee of Public Accounts, 1916b),
the access of parliament to information included in the budget statement and the
Auditor-General’s annual report (Committee of Public Accounts, 1916a; Committee of
Public Accounts, 1917a). However, it also showed a clear willingness to address more
political issues, such as the management of the Government cool stores, the disposal of
funds on government research scholarships (Committee of Public Works, 1915;
Committee of Public Works, 1916) and the need for improvements in the management
of public sector organisations (Committee of Public Accounts, 1915a; Committee of
Public Accounts, 1917). Subsequent committees followed this movement into more
political themes, although financial issues were occasionally addressed. Reports
ranged over issues of substance related to land settlement, the Country Roads Board
and government-owned businesses. In effect, the work of the VCPA generally followed
the transition observed by Degeling et al. (1996) from a financial focus towards a more
political one. However, it needs to be noted that there were also substantial periods
when the work of the VCPA was intentionally or unintentionally blocked.
Both the VCPA and the JCPA had been established to bolster the legitimacy of the
Governments in their respective jurisdictions at a time when those governments
needed and wanted to assert their own economic and financial wisdom. They had
continued to exist regardless of how far their reports strayed from the mandates laid
down for them. They also played a legitimating role for the respective parliaments in
that their existence was evidence of how parliaments could oversee government
spending. This was significant, as the power of parties increased throughout the early
years of the twentieth century. Therefore, the power of legitimacy seemed to be derived
from the existence of the VCPA committee rather than the activity and did not seem to
be challenged by the periods of relative or enforced inactivity.
What remains unanswered is why the VCPA and the JCPA were abolished in 1932.
This seems to provide a major challenge to the legitimacy thesis. The explanation
given retrospectively and anecdotally in the case of the VCPA and at the time of
abolition in the case of the JCPA was “economy”. This was the height of the 1930s
Depression, and money would be saved if the committees ceased to operate. If the
AAAJ VCPA and the JCPA were created to bolster the public legitimacy of the parliamentary
22,1 systems, why did they suddenly become unnecessary? The next section of this paper
explores the issues and events associated with their suspension. It explores the final
reports produced by the VCPA and JCPA on the grounds that the committee
suspension might have been a political response to these reports rather than an
economy measure as reported.
24
The demise of the VCPA
By the late 1920s, the VCPA’s reports were principally concerned with politics and
policy rather than finance. Of the six reports produced by the fifteenth committee
(1929-1932), only one (on infringements of the Public Account Advances Act) focused
on financial control.
The operation of the Maffra Beet Sugar Factory was an important and political
issue, which generated considerable interest. The fourteenth VCPA had already
reported on it comprehensively in 1929 (Committee of Public Accounts, 1929). Sugar
beets had been grown in a small way in Victoria since 1866. The Victorian Government
had become involved in the 1890s when it advanced £63,000 to a company building a
beet sugar factory at Maffra. The company defaulted on the interest payments and the
Government took possession of the factory. It was idle for ten years, reopened in 1910
and was still operating when the VCPA began its inquiries. Some years after the
factory reopened in 1910, the Government decided to remodel it to increase its capacity.
Between 1917 and 1924, the Director of Agriculture and the manager of the factory had
visited the USA in pursuit of best practice. Subsequently, two American beet sugar
engineers had been brought to Victoria to report on the remodelling proposals. One of
them remained to supervise the work. The VCPA suggested that there was no apparent
benefit from this. It also reported that public servants who had been called before the
committee did not provide the material evidence requested (Committee of Public
Accounts, 1929, p. 5). The report of the fifteenth committee (Committee of Public
Accounts, 1930a) had a similar agenda, suggesting ways of improving the
management and organisation of the Maffra factory and increasing productivity. In
effect, the committee made itself responsible for reviewing the economic and financial
results of a government business through highlighting issues of efficiency and
effectiveness in the management of the organisation. This would have been seen to
challenge the legitimacy of the then government by questioning its management of the
sugar beet factory.
In 1930 and 1932, the committee also issued two reports on the Closer Settlement
Board (Committee of Public Accounts, 1930; Committee of Public Accounts, 1931a).
The term “closer settlement” referred to a longstanding government policy of
increasing the population in rural areas by granting land to prospective small farmers
(McDonald, 1978; Dingle, 1984). The effectiveness and success of the policy were
important political issues, and both reports went beyond financial matters to address
questions of its successes and failures. The first report was, for the most part, a severe
criticism of the accounting procedures of the Closer Settlement Board. However, it also
supported the view of a Commonwealth Royal Commission into Soldier Land
Settlement that the soldier settlers had failed in their settlements because the areas
granted were too small, they were undercapitalised, they were poorly trained to be
farmers and there had been a drop in the value of primary products. The second report
in 1931 reviewed the administration of the Lands Department and the Closer Legitimacy and
Settlement Board. The VCPA argued that the land settlement policy had become “a oversight in
heavy drain on the revenues of the State” and would have to be revised (Committee of
Public Accounts, 1931a, p. 4). These reports would also have been seen to challenge Australia
government policy and to publicly question the ability of the Government to effectively
manage state resources. It seems likely that this would have undermined the public
legitimacy of the Government. 25
The fifteenth committee issued five other reports on government businesses or
utilities. In 1930, it examined the Victoria Dock Cool Stores and in the Country Roads
Board. The report into the Victoria Dock Cool Stores (Committee of Public Accounts,
1930b) followed a letter to the Melbourne newspaper the Argus from the proprietor of
another cool store arguing that the Government was not equipped to conduct such a
commercial operation. The VCPA examined the operations of the Victoria Dock Cool
Store, supported its management and made some recommendations about its
improvement. In its report on the Country Roads Board (Committee of Public Accounts,
1930), the committee made recommendations that related to not only roads and the
management of the board but also registration fees and compulsory third party
insurance for motor vehicles. Such an active and public policy formation role would
have done little to build public confidence in the policies of the Government. While it is
clear that the fifteenth VCPA committee had moved substantially away from an initial
financial focus and was now engaged with the criticism and formation of policy, this
was not a particularly new activity. The move to disestablish the committee could have
been a response on the part of the Government to the criticisms and the associated loss
of public legitimacy. However, the then Labor government (Hogan 1929-1932) took no
direct action against the committee, possibly because of the weakness of his
government and the level of political instability at that time. The decision not to
establish a new VCPA was taken by the subsequent conservative (Argyle 1932-1935)
government.
While there were political motivations for the Argyle Government not to
re-establish the VCPA they may have also been broader social and political factors.
Like the rest of Australia, Victoria was hit hard by the Depression. Like the
Commonwealth and other state governments, the Victorian Government struggled to
find economic and social policies to combat it. At a conference of Commonwealth and
state ministers held in Melbourne between 18 and 21 August 1930, Sir Otto Niemeyer,
the Bank of England’s emissary, presented his prescription for Australia’s economic
and financial policy (Schedvin, 1970, pp. 179-184). In 1931, the Commonwealth Labor
government, led by James Scullin, introduced the Premiers’ Plan. This was a series of
financial measures to combat the Depression broadly built on Niemeyer’s prescription
of spending cuts and financial stringency. This plan led to a major split within the
Labor Party. Hogan, as the Victorian premier, supported it, but it was opposed by the
union movement and much of the ALP. In early 1932, the Victorian central executive
instructed Labor parliamentarians not to support the plan. In April, the Hogan
government fell when three independent members who supported the Premiers’ Plan
joined the opposition in a vote of no confidence (Louis, 1968, p. 193). In the May 1932
election, the ALP was defeated, its numbers in the Legislative Assembly being reduced
from 30 to 16, and replaced by a coalition government led by Sir Stanley Argyle. Hogan
and several others were expelled from the ALP in July. The Argyle government did not
AAAJ appoint members to the Committee of Public Accounts. There was no announcement or
22,1 foreshadowing, although later it was reported that the committee had not been
reappointed for reasons of economy (ABS (Australian Bureau of Statistics), 1980, p. 93).
It was clear that during the final part of the Hogan government the factional
fighting within the Labor Party meant that the premier retained little control over the
work of the VCPA. This could partially explain the open criticism expressed in some of
26 the late reports. At this time, party discipline and cohesion were weak, coalitions were
common, governments with a parliamentary majority were uncommon and the
lifespan of governments was often short (Strangio and Costar, 2006, p. 6). This does not
explain why a VCPA committee was not appointed under the Argyle government.
Clearly, one fear was that the open criticism of government policy seen under the
Hogan VCPA might be continued. The fact that the new government would avoid a
powerful source of public criticism of its policies and actions in failing to establish the
VCPA would have been attractive. However, the failure to reappoint a VCPA also
provided a socially acceptable response to the radical cost-cutting agenda promoted by
the Premiers’ Plan and the Niemeyer agenda. Cutting parliamentary spending rather
than public services would have led to public support and legitimacy, not least because
it was a visible way for the parliament to be seen to be subject to the same austerity
measures experienced by the public.

The demise of the JCPA


Like the VCPA, the JCPA had also moved away from a focus on financial performance
to an engagement with politics and policy. In the last session of its existence, it
completed six reports. The first, tabled in December 1929, was about agricultural and
pastoral leases in what was then the Federal Capital Territory (Joint Committee of
Public Accounts, 1929). The inquiry had come about because of a deputation from the
Rural Lessees’ Association in the Federal Capital Territory to the Minister for Home
Affairs which expressed concerns about the shortness of tenure, cost of improvements
and size of holdings in the territory. The JCPA made specific policy recommendations,
such as the establishment of a land advisory board and financial assistance for
extending leases and purchasing fertilisers.
The second report, in April 1930, related to a claim against the War Service Homes
Commissioner (Joint Committee of Public Accounts, 1930) by Henry Dean and Son.
While Henry Dean and Son initially won their court case, they lost on appeal. They
then contacted the Prime Minister, James Scullin, who referred this to the chair of the
JCPA, requesting that the committee consider the company’s “moral claim for
compensation” (Joint Committee of Public Accounts, 1930, p. 5). The committee did not
support the compensation claim. Nonetheless, this report seemed unrelated to the
normal work of the JCPA, and there was no provision in the legislation for the Prime
Minister to refer matters to the committee.
Between 1930 and 1931, there were a number of inquiries and reports produced
dealing with financial problems associated within and between the states. The first
was an inquiry into Tasmania’s financial disabilities requested by the Prime Minister
in 1929 after consideration by Cabinet. The committee visited Tasmania, conducted an
inquiry and reported in August 1930. In September, the Acting Prime Minister, James
Fenton, wrote to the committee requesting it to inquire into the financial position of
South Australia (Joint Committee of Public Accounts, 1931, p. 5). The committee made
several visits to South Australia. On 14 March 1931, the Prime Minister informed the Legitimacy and
committee that the Government had decided to change the terms of reference. He asked oversight in
the committee to simultaneously review requests for “financial assistance to mitigate
the effects of Federation” from South Australia, Tasmania and Western Australia. The Australia
JCPA was being used as a buffer to distance the Government from the need to address
these deeply controversial resource allocation issues. While the JCPA agreed to carry
out the wishes of the Prime Minister, it did note that the task was virtually impossible 27
(Joint Committee of Public Accounts, 1931, p. 5). However, they did not object to the
fact that the request had originated from the Prime Minister.
The sixth report, tabled on 8 August 1930, was not a report of the committee but
was the report of a royal commission into allegations that members of the committee
had been bribed (Royal Commission, 1930). The Royal Commissioner, George
Dethbridge, rejected the allegations that the JCPA chairman, Percy Coleman, or any
other committee member had been paid a bribe. However, it is difficult to
underestimate the damage that these allegations would have made to the perceived
credibility of the JCPA as “honest brokers”. They would have substantially
undermined the usefulness of the JCPA as a tool for public legitimacy. In addition, it
was clear that the committee, while not openly challenging government policy, as in
the case of the VCPA, had substantially departed from a focus on financial probity to a
direct engagement with policy and politics. The tasks given to the JCPA by the Prime
Minister led to public criticisms. The committee had come under public attack for
wastefulness when it visited Hobart in 1930 (NAA: A12840, 2004/2002), and there were
some within parliament who argued that committees such as the JCPA were
extravagances that could and should be curbed.
After the agreement on the Premiers’ Plan in July 1931, the Federal Parliament
debated the budget estimates and looked at ways in which parliamentary expenditure
might be reduced (APD (Australian Parliamentary Debates), 1913, pp. 4573-4593).
Members proposed reductions in expenditure on the parliamentary refreshment rooms,
the heating of Parliament House and the suspension of the Public Works Committee
and the Committee of Public Accounts. Parliamentary salaries and allowances were
already being reduced as part of the general reduction in government salaries (Jones,
2007). Discernible in the debate was the feeling that parliament should be seen to be
contributing to the general sacrifice; if old age pensions are to be reduced, so must
parliament’s trappings of office (APD (Australian Parliamentary Debates), 1913,
pp. 4573-4593). Nonetheless, the central focus of the debate was on the Public Works
Committee and the JCPA. The foremost opponents of these committees were Robert
Archdale Parkhill, the Nationalist member for the Sydney electorate of Warringah, and
Joel Gabb, a former ALP member. Both these men were strongly committed to cutting
budget spending and both argued that the JCPA should be suspended. Other members
and senators did not support the committee’s suspension but agreed that its
expenditure should be reduced by reducing the number of members or cutting staff
In October 1931, following the estimates debate, Scullin introduced two bills to
reduce the number of members of the Committee of Public Accounts and the Public
Works Committee from nine to seven (Holmes, 1966, pp. 35-36). Parkhill supported the
abolition of both committees, which he described as “relics of the antiquated system of
‘perks’ for parliamentarians” (APD, 1931a, p. 658). Even a former member of the JCPA,
Senator Foll, complained that it had “roamed practically all over the Commonwealth,
AAAJ investigating matters which ought not to have been referred to such a body” (APD,
22,1 1931b, p. 837). The Scullin Government fell at the end of 1931 (November 1931) and the
bill lapsed.
At the December 1931 election, the Scullin Labor government was replaced by the
United Australia Party led by Joseph Lyons, which included former Nationalist,
independent and Labor members. The new parliament, which first met in February
28 1932, did not appoint any members to the Committee of Public Accounts. The
Governor-General, in his speech at the opening of parliament on 17 February 1932,
announced that the Government would suspend the operations of both the Committee
of Public Accounts and the Public Works Committees (APD, 1932, p. 9). It introduced
legislation to do so in October 1932. Parkhill became a minister and was a powerful
parliamentary and political figure within the United Australia Party. Gabb sat as an
independent, although he supported the Government and maintained a reputation for
his opposition to perceived extravagance.
At this time, what little legitimacy the JCPA provided was weakened by accusations
of bribery and waste. Even those involved acknowledged that the work the JCPA was
being asked to do had little resemblance to classical functions of a public accounts
committee and that the ongoing use of the committee by the Prime Minister for political
ends had undermined it. In this context, the increasing perception of the JCPA as a
political perk and Parkhill’s arguments for its abolition made the suspension virtually
inevitable. Given the financial austerity of the Depression, it is possible that the
disestablishment of the JCPA and the public works committee resulted in generating
legitimacy for the incoming Lyons government.

Conclusion
In this paper we have adopted an institutional approach to the study of parliamentary
oversight and governance. While authors have highlighted the need to adopt an
institutional approach to the understanding of audit, regulation and governance, little
work has been done that takes seriously the concept that these institutions are
established for legitimacy rather than functionalist purposes. Both Hood (1991, 1995)
and Power (1997) have argued that these institutions of oversight and audit have come
to play an increasingly powerful role in contemporary society. We have argued that in
order to understand this role, we need to more fully understand the driver for their
establishment.
We adopted the work of Degeling et al. (1996) as a starting point for our own study.
Degeling et al. (1996) studied the work of the Australian federal parliamentary public
accounts committee (JCPA) from its establishment in 1913 until its suspension in 1932.
Degeling et al. (1996) argued that it was likely that the financial focus of this committee
would colonise other aspects but found that, although the initial mandate was focused
on financial accountability, the work of the committee shifted to a focus on issues of
policy and politics. Instead of Degeling et al.’s (1996) focus on accountability and
colonising, we adopted an institutional theoretical focus more consistent with the
activities and changing nature of these committees. In particular, we believe that this
enables us to more fully explain the establishment of the JCPA and the changing nature
of its work. By way of contrast, we discussed the Victorian Committee of Public
Accounts (VCPA), which pre-existed the JCPA by nearly 20 years and was openly
acknowledged in parliamentary documents as the template and example for the JCPA Legitimacy and
mandate and structure. oversight in
By more fully exploring the establishment of the earlier VCPA and the subsequent
JCPA, we found that the primary objective for the establishment of both these Australia
committees was legitimation. Therefore, the early functional mandate was not of
critical importance and the subsequent deviation from it to focus on broader issues of
policy and politics is more understandable. The central element of the legitimating 29
power was that both these institutions were seen as an accurate copy of existing
British practice as reflected in the Westminster parliament. However, from records and
documents it seems clear that the Victorian practice, as reflected in the VCPA,
presented a more proximate mimetic source for the establishment of the JCPA.
The work of both these committees diverged over time from the mandates given to
them in their founding documents as they drifted from a focus on accounting to a focus
on policy. Degeling et al. (1996) have argued that this represents a colonisation of
accounting by politics. Implicit in their analysis is the belief that the establishment of
the JCPA was driven by a concern for the function of the committee – that is, the
content of its reports and the recommendations within them. We have argued that the
purpose of both the JCPA and the VCPA was to provide legitimacy for the
Governments at the time of their establishment. The VCPA was established in 1895 at
a period of policy transfer from Britain to its colonies and the JCPA in 1913 when policy
transfer was beginning to occur within Australia (Carroll, 2006).
Following from Degeling et al.’s (1996) methodology, we analysed the work of the
VCPA between 1895 and 1931 and established that it had followed a similar path, with
a transition from a focus on financial matters to a focus on politics and policy. We also
established that the content of the reports appeared to have little impact on the
existence or status of the committees. In other words, the Governments that had
facilitated the establishment of the committees appeared not to care that they were
ignoring their designed purpose. To further follow up this phenomenon, we analysed
the events surrounding the demise of the two committees, including the last reports
they produced. We found that the VCPA was openly critical of government and was
actively involved in policy formation. The JCPA was also directly involved in policy
formation, although this was in cooperation with the Government rather than in
criticism of it. However, the JCPA also faced two other major challenges. Its members
were accused of taking bribes and it was publicly criticised for profligacy. In addition,
it was directed by the Prime Minister to undertake major economic inquiries which
were both beyond its expertise and inappropriate in terms of its mandate.
In the political crisis that emerged from the Depression, both the VCPA and the
JCPA became perceived as unnecessary extravagances. Political capital and
corresponding public legitimacy could be generated by abolishing them. In both
cases, they were abolished by conservative governments that replaced Labor
governments that had failed to control the financial crisis and that had been torn apart
by internal dissension. In the abolition of the VCPA and the JCPA the new
governments could be seen to exercise the same economies that they proposed for the
public. Therefore in 1932, the acquisition of legitimacy for the Governments (and to
some extent the parliaments) lay in the abolition of the VCPA and the JCPA, just as in
earlier years it had resided in their creation.
AAAJ Degeling et al. (1996) conclude that the work of the JCPA shows little evidence of
22,1 instrumental purpose or violation. But rather than such organisations and structures
are inevitably a product of social and political processes. While we agree with this
conclusion we would argue that the idea of social and political legitimacy provide a
powerful way to explain and understand these particular social and political processes.
the case of the VCPA and JCPA provides an important insight into processes of
30 institutional change and legitimacy. While the establishment of these committees
delivered a level of public legitimacy, particularly due to the fact that they were visibly
copied from the UK model, the disestablishment of the same committees also delivered
legitimacy. The absence of an established functional role did not seem to be
particularly problematic. It is important to recognise that while mimetic and other
forms of isomorphism can deliver a level of legitimacy when an institution is
established, this legitimacy is not necessarily sustained over time. In this case, the
broader social focus on austerity associated with the Depression and the urgency to
cut, and be seen to cut, expenditure meant that the disestablishment of these
committees generated legitimacy rather than their ongoing existence or work.
We suggest that these insights provide a radically different perspective on the
contemporary process of financial oversight, governance and the audit society. It is
important to separate the functional perspective on these institutions from an
institutional/legitimacy one. We cannot take for granted, as has been in much of the
NPM literature, that institutions such as public accountants committees play a
functional role. Clearly the advocates for a public accounts committee in Victoria
understood that the function of the VCPA was to provide conventional financial
oversight. Indeed, these ideals are still expressed by those who describe how these
committees should operate now (McGee, 2002). While these norms are clearly desirable,
it is also evident that over time the nature of the work of the VCPA (and the JCPA) more
clearly reflected political aims and influences. It showed that in practice it was not
possible to isolate the practice of financial oversight and accounting measurement from
the intensely political environment in which it functioned and the need to generate
legitimacy in that setting. In that sense, Hopwood’s (1984) point that accounting
language and practices have become intertwined in substantive issues of policy may
have been true for a much longer time than suggested by Hopwood’s (1984) analysis
and that drawing a neat distinction between politics and accounting within this setting
becomes meaningless. While it is not necessary for accounting to dominate politics, it is
interesting that the perception of an accounting focus provided such an important
source of legitimacy. It may prove that the growth of practices of governmentality and
oversight described by Power (1997) are not principally associated with functional
activities but are primarily driven by the need to create and sustain the legitimacy of
broader institutions and structures, such as parliament and democracy and that this
may have been happening for a far longer time than authors such as Power (1997) and
Hopwood (1984) have previously indicated.
From a contemporary perspective, this narrative provides an important insight into
the power of mimetic isomorphism and the legitimacy power of the British
Westminster models and practices. It also seems clear that once a PAC has been
institutionalised, it will rarely be challenged to justify its current actions and functions.
Recent reviews of the Australian PACs illustrate that considerable diversity is evident
in practice (KPMG, 2006; Jones and Jacobs, 2006). After all, these institutions
functioned for 26 and 18 years respectively. It is important to note that these Legitimacy and
committees were subsequently re-established in the 1950s after calls for their oversight in
re-establishment from both inside and outside parliament.
Australia
Note
1. An inquiry represented a major investigation or study conducted by the VCPA and therefore
is a good measure of substantial work done while the reports only summarised activities 31
such as the meetings or visits conducted and therefore represented the basic requirement to
report to parliament on committee activity.

References
ABS (Australian Bureau of Statistics) (1980), Victorian Year Book, Government Printer,
Melbourne.
APD (Australian Parliamentary Debates) (1913), Senate and House of Representatives Debates,
Vols LXX-LXXII.
Carpenter, V.L. and Feroz, E.H. (2001), “Institutional theory and accounting rule choice: an
analysis of four US state governments’ decisions to adopt generally accepted accounting
principles”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 26 Nos 7-8, pp. 565-96.
Carroll, P. (2006), “Historical trends in policy transfer in Australia”, paper presented at
Australasian Political Studies Association Conference, University of Newcastle,
Newcastle, 25-27 September.
Chua, W.F. and Poullaos, C. (1993), “Rethinking the profession-state dynamic: the case of the
Victorian charter attempt 1885-1906”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 18 Nos
7-8, pp. 691-728.
Chua, W.F. and Poullaos, C. (1998), “The dynamics of ‘closure’ amidst the construction of market,
profession, empire and nationhood: an historical analysis of an Australian accounting
association, 1886-1903”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 23 No. 2, pp. 155-87.
Chubb, B. (1952), The Control of Public Expenditure: Financial Committees of the House of
Commons, Clarendon Press, Oxford.
Committee of Public Accounts (1901), Report, Government Printer, Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1915a), Report (State Expenditure), Government Printer,
Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1916a), Report (Railway Loan Application Act), Government
Printer, Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1916b), Report (Financial Position of State Coal Mine),
Government Printer, Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1917), Report (State Audit Office), Government Printer,
Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1917a), Report (Finance Statement – Auditor-General’s Annual
Report), Government Printer, Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1929), Report from the Committee of Public Accounts (Maffra
Beet Sugar Factory), Government Printer, Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1930), Report from the Committee of Public Accounts (Accounts of
the Closer Settlement Board at 30 June 1929), Government Printer, Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1930a), Report from the Committee of Public Accounts
(Supplementary) upon the Maffra Beet Sugar Factory, Government Printer, Melbourne.
AAAJ Committee of Public Accounts (1930b), Report from the Committee of Public Accounts (Victoria
Dock Cool Stores), Government Printer, Melbourne.
22,1
Committee of Public Accounts (1931), Report from the Committee of Public Accounts (Country
Roads Board), Government Printer, Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1931a), Report from the Committee of Public Accounts (Lands
Department and Closer Settlement Board), Government Printer, Melbourne.
32 Davey, R.C. (1960), The Public Accounts Committee of the Commonwealth Parliament, 3rd rev.,
Joint Committee of Public Accounts, Canberra, January.
Degeling, P., Anderson, J. and Guthrie, J. (1996), “Accounting for public accounts committees”,
Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, Vol. 9 No. 2, pp. 30-49.
Dingle, T. (1984), The Victorians: Settling, Fairfax, Syme & Weldon, Melbourne.
Dolowitz, D. and Marsh, D. (1996), “Who learns what from whom: a review of the policy transfer
literature”, Political Studies, Vol. 44, pp. 343-57.
Fogarty, T.J. (1996), “The imagery and reality of peer review in the US: insights from
institutional theory”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 21 Nos 2-3, pp. 243-67.
Fogarty, T.J. and Rogers, R.K. (2005), “Financial analysts’ reports: an extended institutional
theory evaluation”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 30 No. 4, pp. 331-56.
Gray, A. and Jenkins, W. (1993), “Codes of accountability in the new public sector”, Accounting,
Auditing and Accountability Journal, Vol. 6 No. 3, pp. 52-67.
Guthrie, J. and Parker, L.D. (1998), “Recent public sector financial management change in
Australia”, in Olson, O., Guthrie, J. and Humphrey, C. (Eds), Global Warning: Debating
International Developments in New Public Financial Management, Cappelen Akademisk
Folag, Oslo.
Habermas, J. (1976), Legitimation Crises, Heinemann, London, trans Suhrakamp, Frankfurt 1973.
Holmes, J. (1966), “The Standing Committee System in the Commonwealth Parliament from 1901
to 1950”, Australian Quarterly, Vol. 38 No. 4, pp. 29-49.
Hood, C. (1991), “A public management for all seasons?”, Public Administration, Vol. 69 No. 1,
pp. 3-19.
Hood, C. (1995), “The ‘New Public Management’ in the 1980s: variations on a theme”, Accounting,
Organizations and Society, Vol. 20 Nos 2-3, pp. 93-109.
Hood, C., Rothstein, H. and Baldwin, R. (2001), The Government of Risk: Understanding Risk
Regulation Regimes, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Hopwood, A.G. (1984), “Accounting and the pursuit of efficiency”, in Hopwood, A.G. and
Tomkins, C.R. (Eds), Issues in Public Sector Accounting, Philip Allan, Oxford, pp. 167-87.
Hughes, O. (1998), Public Management and Administration, 2nd ed., Macmillan, London.
Jacobs, K. (1998), “Value for money auditing in New Zealand: competing for control in the public
sector”, British Accounting Review, Vol. 30 No. 4, pp. 343-60.
Jacobs, K. (2003), “Class reproduction in professional recruitment: examining the accounting
profession”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 14 No. 5, pp. 569-96.
Jacobs, K. and Barnett, P. (2000), “Policy transfer and policy learning: a study of the 1991 New
Zealand Health Services Taskforce”, Governance: An International Journal of Policy and
Administration, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 185-213.
Jacobs, K., Jones, K. and Modell, S. (2007), “Parliamentary financial oversight and accountability
in the Antipodes”, paper presented at Asia Pacific Interdisciplinary Perspectives on
Accounting Conference, Auckland, July.
Joint Committee of Public Accounts (1929), Report on Agricultural and Pastoral Leases in the Legitimacy and
Federal Capital Territory, Government Printer, Canberra.
oversight in
Joint Committee of Public Accounts (1930), Report on Claim of Charles Dean and Others, Trading
under the Name of Henry Dean and Son, Against the War Services Homes Commissioner Australia
for Compensation to Cover Losses Alleged to Have Been Sustained as the Result of
Extensions and Alterations Made to their Works to Provide Bricks for the Erection of War
Service Homes, Government Printer, Canberra. 33
Joint Committee of Public Accounts (1931), Report on the Finances of Tasmania as Affected by
Federation, Government Printer, Canberra.
Jones, K. (2006), “‘Exactly on all-fours with the English precedent’ – establishing a public
accounts committee in the Antipodes”, Victorian Historical Journal, Vol. 77 No. 2,
pp. 194-211.
Jones, K. (2007), “Daring and discretion: paying Australian legislators”, Journal of Legislative
Studies, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 235-53.
Jones, K. and Jacobs, K. (2006), “Governing the Government: the paradoxical place of the public
accounts committee”, Australasian Parliamentary Review, Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 63-79.
KPMG (2006), The Parliamentary Public Accounts Committee: an Australian Perspective, KPMG,
Canberra.
Louis, L.J. (1968), Trade Unions and the Depression: A Case Study of Victoria, 1930-1932,
Australian National University Press, Canberra.
McDonald, S.R. (1978), “Victoria’s immigration scandal of the thirties”, Victorian Historical
Journal, Vol. 49 No. 4, November, pp. 228-37.
McGee, D.G. (2002), The Overseers: Public Accounts Committees and Public Spending,
Commonwealth Parliamentary Association in Association with Pluto Press, London.
Madden, A.F. (1979), “Not for export: the Westminster model of government and British colonial
practice”, Journal of Commonwealth and Imperial History, Vol. 8 No. 1, October, pp. 10-29.
Meyer, J.W. and Rowan, B. (1977), “Institutionalized organizations: formal structure as myth and
ceremony”, American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 83 No. 2, pp. 340-63.
Morley, J. (1903), The Life of William Ewart Gladstone, Vol. II, Macmillan and Co., London.
Normanton, E.L. (1971), “Public accountability and audit: a reconnaissance”, in Smith, B.R.L. and
Hague, D.C. (Eds), The Dilemma of Accountability in Modern Government: Independence
versus Control, St Martin’s Press, New York, NY.
Offe, C. (1996), Modernity and the State, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Powell, W.W. and DiMaggio, P.J. (1991), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis,
The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
Power, M. (1997), The Audit Society: Rituals of Verification, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Pusey, M. (1991), Economic Rationalism in Canberra: a Nation-Building State Changes its Mind,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Royal Commission (1930), Report of the Royal Commission Appointed to Inquire into Allegations
Affecting Members of the Parliamentary Joint Committee of Public Accounts in Connexion
with Claims Made by Broadcasting Companies against the Commonwealth Government,
Government Printer, Canberra.
Schedvin, C.B. (1970), Australia and the Great Depression: A Study of Economic Development and
Policy in the 1920s and 1930s, Sydney University Press, Sydney.
Scott, W.R. (2001), Institutions and Organizations, Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA.
AAAJ Smith, R. (2003), “New South Wales”, in Moon, J. and Sharman, C. (Eds), Australian Politics and
Government: The Commonwealth, the States and the Territories, Cambridge University
22,1 Press, Cambridge, pp. 41-73.
Starr, G., Richmond, K. and Maddox, G. (1978), Political Parties in Australia, Heinemann
Educational, Richmond.
Stent, W. (2004), Dry and Repulsive – The Parliamentary Component of Supreme Audit
34 Institutions, The Public Sector Governance and Accountability Research Centre, La Trobe
University, Melbourne.
Strangio, P. and Costar, B. (2006), “Introduction: Premiers and Politics, 1856-2006”, in Strangio, P.
and Costar, B. (Eds), The Victorian Premiers 1856-2006, Federation Press, Sydney,
pp. 1-11.
Suchman, M. (1995), “Managing legitimacy: strategic and institutional approaches”, Academy of
Management Review, Vol. 20, pp. 571-610.
Weller, P. and Flemming, J. (2003), “The Commonwealth”, in Moon, J. and Sharman, C. (Eds),
Australian Politics and Government: The Commonwealth, the States and the Territories,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 12-40.

Further reading
Committee of Public Accounts (1915), Report (Government Cool Stores), Government Printer,
Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1916), Report (Government Research Scholarships), Government
Printer, Melbourne.
Committee of Public Accounts (1930c), Report from the Committee of Public Accounts (Public
Account Advances Act), Government Printer, Melbourne.
Hansard (Parliamentary Debates UK) (1861), Debates, Vol 162, April.
Joint Committee of Public Accounts (1930), Report on the General Question of Tasmania’s
Disabilities, Government Printer, Canberra.
National Archives of Australia (NAA): Joint Committee of Public Accounts (n.d.), Miscellaneous
Papers, A12840.
VPD (Victorian Parliamentary Debates) (1894-1895), Debates, Vols 74-80.

Corresponding author
Kerry Jacobs can be contacted at: [email protected]

To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: [email protected]


Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints

You might also like