Topic 5: The Capital Asset Pricing Model
Topic 5: The Capital Asset Pricing Model
NGUYEN THI HOANG ANH, PHD
Introduction
• Asset Pricing – how assets are priced?
• Market Equilibrium concept
• Portfolio Theory – ANY individual investor’s
optimal selection of portfolio (partial
equilibrium)
• CAPM – equilibrium of ALL individual
investors (and asset suppliers)
(general equilibrium)
1
Intuition
• Risky asset i:
• Its price is such that:
An example to motivate
Expected Return Standard Deviation
Asset I 10.9% 4.45%
Asset j 5.4% 7.25%
2
An example to motivate
Expected Return Standard Deviation
Asset I 10.9% 4.45%
Asset j 5.4% 7.25%
Possible Answers:
(1) The equation, as intuitive as it is, is wrong.
(2) The equation is right, but the market prices of risk are
different for different assets.
(3) The equation is right, but the quantity of risk of any risky
asset is not equal to the standard deviation of its return.
3
CAPM’s Answers
• Specifically:
Total risk = systematic risk + unsystematic risk
CAPM says:
(1) Unsystematic risk can be costlessly diversified
away. “No free lunch” implies the market will NOT
reward you for bearing unsystematic risk if there is
NO cost of eliminating it through well
diversification.
(2) Systematic risk cannot be diversified away without
cost. In other words, investors need to be
compensated by a certain risk premium for bearing
systematic risk.
4
MPT and the CAPM
• William Sharpe, “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of
Market Equilibrium Under Conditions of Risk,” Journal
of Finance Vol.19 (September 1964): pp.425-442.
• John Lintner, “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the
Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and
Capital Budgets,” Review of Economics and Statistics
Vol.47 (February 1965): pp.13-37.
• Jan Mossin, “Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market,”
Econometrica Vol.34 (October 1966): pp.768-783.
5
MPT and the CAPM
• Like MPT, the CAPM assumes that investors have mean-
variance utility and hence that either investors have quadratic
utility functions or that the random returns on risky assets are
normallydistributed.
• Thus, some of the same caveats that apply to MPT also apply
to the CAPM.
• The traditional CAPM also assumes that there is a risk free
asset as well as a potentially large collection of risky assets.
• Under these circumstances, as we’ve seen, all investors will
hold some combination of the riskless asset and the tangency
portfolio: the efficient portfolio of risky assets with the highest
Sharpe ratio.
6
MPT and the CAPM
• In equilibrium, that is, “everyone” must “own the
market.”
• But why? What happens if not enough people
want to “own the market.”
• Asset prices must adjust so that “everyone owns the
market.”
• This logic turns the MPT – a theory of asset
demand – into the CAPM – an asset pricing
model.
CAPM
• 2 Sets of Assumptions:
[1] Perfect market:
• Frictionless, and Perfect information
• No imperfections like tax, regulations, restrictions on
short selling
• All assets are publicly traded and perfectly divisible
• Perfect competition – everyone is a price-taker
[2] Investors:
• Same one-period horizon
• Rational, and maximize expected utility over a mean-
variance space
• Homogenous beliefs
7
CAPM in Details:
What is an equilibrium?
CONDITION 1: Consistent with Individual investor’s Eqm.: Max U
• Assume:
[1] Market is frictionless
=> borrowing rate = lending rate
=> linear efficient set in the return-risk space
[2] Anyone can borrow or lend unlimited amount at risk-free rate
• [3] All investors have homogenous beliefs
=> they perceive identical distribution of expected returns on
ALL assets
=> thus, they all perceive the SAME linear efficient set (we
called the line: CAPITAL MARKET LINE
=> the tangency point is the MARKET PORTFOLIO
NOTE: 2-Fund Separation must hold under the above assumptions.
CAPM in Details:
What is an equilibrium?
CONDITION 1: Individual investor’s equilibrium: Max U
B
Q
E(RM)
Market Portfolio
Rf
σM
σp
8
CAPM in Details:
What is an equilibrium?
CONDITION 2: Demand = Supply for ALL risky assets
• Remember expected return is a function of price.
• Market price of any asset is such that its expected return is just
enough to compensate its investors to rationally hold its
outstanding shares.
CAPM in Details:
What is an equilibrium?
CONDITION 4: Aggregate borrowing = Aggregate
lending
• Risk-free rate is not exogenously given, but is
determined by equating aggregate borrowing and
aggregate lending.
9
CAPM in Details:
What is an equilibrium?
Two-Fund Separation:
Given the assumptions of frictionless market, unlimited
lending and borrowing, homogenous beliefs, and if the above
4 equilibrium conditions are satisfied, we then have the 2-fund
separation.
TWO-FUND SEPARATION:
Each investor will have a utility-maximizing portfolio that is a
combination of the risk-free asset and a portfolio (or fund) of
risky assets that is determined by the Capital market line
tangent to the investor’s efficient set of risky assets
Analogy of Two-fund separation
Fisher Separation Theorem in a world of certainty. Related the
two separation theorems to help your understanding.
U’’ U’
E(rp)
Efficient set
P
Endowment Point
σp
10
The Role of Capital Market
Efficient set
P
M
Endowment Point
Rf
σp
11
Deriving the CAPM
12
Deriving the CAPM
13
Deriving the CAPM
And since all individually optimal portfolios are located
along the CML, the equation
E rM rf
E rP rf P
M
implies that the market portfolio’s Sharpe ratio
E rM rf
M
measures the equilibrium price of risk: the expected return
that each investor gives up when he or she adjusts his or her
total portfolio to reduce risk.
14
Deriving the CAPM
• To answer this question, consider an investor who takes the
portion of his or her initial wealth that he or she allocates to
risky assets and divides it further: using the fraction w to
purchase asset j and the remaining fraction 1 𝑤 to buy
the market portfolio.
expected return
𝐸 𝑟˜𝑃 𝑤𝐸 𝑟˜𝑗 1 𝑤 𝐸 𝑟˜𝑀 ,
and variance
𝜎 𝑤 𝜎 1 𝑤 𝜎 2𝑤 1 𝑤𝜎
15
Deriving the CAPM
𝐸 𝑟˜𝑃 𝑤𝐸 𝑟˜𝑗 1 𝑤 𝐸 𝑟˜𝑀 ,
𝜎 𝑤 𝜎 1 𝑤 𝜎 2𝑤 1 𝑤𝜎
The red curve these traces out how σP and E (r˜P) vary as w
changes, that is, as asset j gets underweighted or
overweighted relative to the market portfolio.
16
Deriving the CAPM
For all other values of w , however, the red curve must lie
below the CML.
17
Deriving the CAPM
18
Deriving the CAPM
• But as all investors buy this undervalued asset,
its price will rise.
• Given future cash flows (future price from selling
the asset plus any dividends earned), a rise the asset’s
price will lower its expected return.
• Buying pressure will continue until the red curve
bends back below the CML.
19
Deriving the CAPM
• But as all investors sell this overvalued asset, its
price will fall.
20
Deriving the CAPM
E rM rf
M
21
Deriving the CAPM
Next, define the functions g (w ) and h(w )by
𝑔 𝑤 𝑤𝐸 𝑟˜𝑗 1 𝑤 𝐸 𝑟˜𝑀 ,
/
h(w)=) 𝑤 𝜎 1 𝑤 𝜎 2𝑤 1 𝑤𝜎
so that
𝐸 𝑟˜𝑃 𝑔𝑤
and
𝜎𝑃 ℎ𝑤 .
Substitute
𝐸 𝑟˜𝑃 𝑔𝑤
and
𝜎𝑃 ℎ𝑤 .
into
𝐸 𝑟˜𝑃 𝑓 𝜎𝑃
to obtain
𝑔𝑤 𝑓 ℎ𝑤
and use the chain rule to compute
𝑔′ 𝑤 𝑓′ ℎ 𝑤 ℎ′ 𝑤 𝑓 ′ 𝜎𝑃 ℎ′ 𝑤
22
Deriving the CAPM
𝑔′ 𝑤 𝑓 ′ 𝜎𝑃 ℎ′ 𝑤
𝑔′ 𝑤
to obtain 𝑓′ 𝜎
ℎ′ 𝑤
and compute 𝑔 ′ 𝑤 and ℎ′ 𝑤 from the formulas we
know.
23
Deriving the CAPM
𝑔𝑤 𝑤𝐸 𝑟˜𝑗 1 𝑤 𝐸 𝑟˜𝑀 ,
implies
𝑔′ 𝑤 𝐸 𝑟˜𝑗 𝐸 𝑟˜𝑀
/
h(w)=) 𝑤 𝜎 1 𝑤 𝜎 2𝑤 1 𝑤𝜎
implies
1 2 w j 2 1 w M 2(1 2 w) jM
2 2
h ' w
2 w2 2 1 w 2 2 2 w(1 w) 1/2
j M jM
w 2j 1 w M2 (1 2 w) jM
h ' w 1/ 2
w2 2j 1 w 2 M2 2 w(1 w) jM
24
Deriving the CAPM
g ' w
f ' P
h ' w
𝑔′ 𝑤 𝐸 𝑟˜𝑗 𝐸 𝑟˜𝑀
w 2j 1 w M2 (1 2 w) jM
h ' w 1/ 2
w2 2j 1 w 2 M2 2 w(1 w) jM
1/2
w2 2j 1 w 2 M2 2 w(1 w) jM
f ' P E (rj ) E (rM )
w j 1 w M (1 2 w) jM
2 2
25
Deriving the CAPM
When w = 0,
1/2
w2 2j 1 w 2 M2 2 w(1 w) jM
f ' P E (rj ) E (rM )
w j 1 w M (1 2 w) jM
2 2
implies
M
f ' P E (rj ) E (rM )
jM M2
E (r
M ) rf jM M2
E (rj ) E (rM )
M2
2
E (rj ) E (rM ) jM E (rM ) rf E ( rM ) rf
M
jM
E (rj ) rf 2 E (rM ) rf
M
26
Deriving the CAPM
jM
E (rj ) rf 2 E (rM ) rf
M
Let jM
2
M
so that this key equation of the CAPM can be written as
E ( rj ) rf j E (rM ) rf
E (rj ) rf j E (rM ) rf
This equation summarizes a very strong restriction.
27
Deriving the CAPM
28
Interpreting the CAPM
• The first interpretation goes directly back to the MPT: a
stock with low and especially negative σjM will be most
useful for diversification.
• But then all investors will want to hold that stock. In
equilibrium, therefore, the stock’s price will be high and,
given future cash flows, its expected return will be low.
• Therefore, stocks with low or negative betas will have low
expected returns. Investors hold these stocks, despite their low
expected returns, because of they are useful for diversification.
29
Interpreting the CAPM
The second interpretation uses the CAPM equation
in its original form
jM
E ( rj ) rf 2 E ( rM ) rf
M
together with the definition of correlation, which implies
jM
jM
j M
E (rM ) rf
E (rj ) rf j
M jM
30
Interpreting the CAPM
E (rM ) rf
E (rj ) rf j
M jM
E (rM ) rf
E (rj ) rf j
M jM
31
Interpreting the CAPM
E (rM ) rf
E (rj ) rf j
M jM
E (rM ) rf
E (rj ) rf j
M jM
32
Interpreting the CAPM
E (rM ) rf
E (rj ) rf j
M jM
33
Interpreting the CAPM
rj rM j
Do you remember the formula for βj , the slope coefficient in a
linear regression? It is
σjM
βj = 2
σM
34
Interpreting the CAPM
Use”s” of CAPM
• For valuation of risky assets
35
How to test CAPM
• An enormous literature is devoted to empirically testing the
CAPM’s implications.
• Although results are mixed, studies have shown that when
individual portfolios are ranked according to their betas, expected
returns tend to line up as suggested by thetheory.
• A famous article that presents results along these lines is by
Eugene Fama (Nobel Prize 2013) and James MacBeth, “Risk,
Return, and Equilibrium,” Journal of Political Economy Vol.81
(May-June 1973), pp.607-636.
• Early work on the MPT, the CAPM, and econometric tests of
the efficient markets hypothesis and the CAPM is discussed
extensively in Eugene Fama’s 1976 textbook, Foundations of
Finance.
36
[2] Testable ?
E (rj ) rf j E (rM ) rf
Ideally, we need the following inputs:
[a] Risk-free borrowing/lending rate {rf}
[b] Expected return on the market {E(RM)}
[c] The exposure to market risk
{βi = cov(Ri,RM)/var(RM)}
[2] Testable ?
E (rj ) rf j E (rM ) rf
In reality, we make compromises:
[a] short-term T-bill (not entirely risk-free)
[b] Proxy of market-portfolio (not the true market)
{E(RM)}
[c] Historical beta
{βi = cov(Ri,RM)/var(RM)}
37
[2] Testable ?
Problem 1:
What is the market portfolio? We never truly observe the
entire market.
We use stock market index to proxy market, but:
[i] Only 1/3 non-governmental tangible assets are owned by
corporate sector. Among them, only 1/3 is financed by
equity.
[ii] What about intangible assets, like human capital?
[iii] Which market index to use? Or how many to use?
[iv] What about international market?
[2] Testable ?
Problem 2:
Without a valid market proxy, do we really observe
the true beta?
[i] suggesting beta is destined to be estimated with
measurement errors.
[ii] how would such measurement errors bias our
estimation?
38
[2] Testable ?
Problem 3:
Borrowing restrictions. Short-selling restrictions.
Problem 4:
Expected return measurement.
[i] are historical returns good proxies for future
expected returns? Ex Ante VS Ex Post
[3] Regression
E (rj ) rf j E (rM ) rf
E (rj ) rf j E (rM ) rf
With our compromises, we test :
E (rj ) rf j E (rM ) rf
Using the following regression equation :
E (rj ) rf 0 1 j j
In words,
Excess return of asset i at time t over risk-free rate
is a linear function of beta plus an error (ε).
Cross-sectional Regressions to be performed!!!
39
[3] Regression
E (rj ) rf 0 1 j j
CAPM predicts:
[a] γ0 should NOT be significantly different from
zero.
[b] γ1 = (RMt - Rft)
[c] Over long-period of time γ1 > 0
[d] β should be the only factor that explains the
return
[e] Linearity
E (rj ) rf 0 1 j j
[a] γ0 > 0
[b] γ1 < (RMt - Rft)
[c] Over long-period of time, we have γ1 > 0
[d] β may not be the ONLY factor that explains the
return
(firm size, p/e ratio, dividend yield, seasonality)
[e] Linearity holds, β2 & unsystematic risk become
insignificant under the presence of β.
40
[4] Generally agreed results
[Rit – Rft]
CAPM Predicts
Actual
γ1 = (RMt - Rft)
γ0 = 0 βi
Roll’s Critique
Message: We aren’t really testing CAPM.
Joint Hypothesis testing:
1) “CAPM is valid” and 2) “Market portfolio is ex post efficient”
41
Against CAPM
• More recent evidence against the CAPM’s implications
is presented by Eugene Fama and Kenneth French,
“Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and
Bonds,” Journal of Financial Economics Vol.33 (February
1993): pp.3-56.
• This paper shows that equity shares in small firms and in
firms with high book (accounting) to market value have
expected returns that differ strongly from what is predicted
by the CAPM alone.
• Quite a bit of recent research has been directed
towards understanding the source of these “anomalies.”
Final words
• Despite some empirical shortcomings,
however, the CAPM quite usefully deepens
our understanding of the gains from
diversification.
• Related, the CAPM alerts us to the important
distinction between idiosyncratic risk, which
can be diversified away, and aggregate risk,
which cannot
42
Final words
• Like MPT, the CAPM must rely on one of the two
strongassumptions – either quadratic utility or
normally-distributedreturns – that justify mean-
variance utility.
• And while the CAPM is an equilibrium theory of
asset pricing, it stops short of linking asset returns to
underlying economic fundamentals.
• These last two points motivate our interest in other
asset pricing theories, which are less restrictive in
their assumptions and/or draw closer connections
between asset prices and the economy as a whole.
43