Money and in Ation - The Cagan Model: Econ 208
Money and in Ation - The Cagan Model: Econ 208
Econ 208
Lecture 11
March 6, 2007
p (t ) = m (t ) + βµ and π (t ) = µ
But is this steady state stable? That is, if we start with π 0 6= µ, does π (t )
converge to µ?
The answer depends on the values of α and β.
The implicit tax revenue accruing to the issuer of money, equal to Ṁ/P
Suppose we take as exogenous not the rate of monetary expansion but the
required seigniorage δ
This is more realistic in the hyperin‡ation cases, where …scal pressures were
clearly driving monetary expansion
m p = βṗ, or
ṗ = (1/β) (p m)
Given a time path for m (t ) this di¤erential equation has a unique solution
for any given initial value p0 .
This means the time path of the price level is indeterminate.
Almost all equilibria are unstable
So perfect foresight seems to compound the possible instability problem.
ṗ = (1/β) (p m)
Example: constant money supply: m (t ) = m0 constant
In this case the equilibrium is
p (t ) = (p0 m0 ) e (1 /β)t + m0
which yields the stable path p (t ) = m0 if the initial price level is p0 = m0
but yields an unstable path for all other initial price levels.
More generally, for any path of m (t ) and any p0 there is one stable
equilibrium, known as the “forward equilibrium”:
Z ∞
p f (t ) = (1/β) e (1 /β)(t s)
m (s ) ds
t
and a continuum of “backward” equilibria:
Z t
p b (t ) = p0 e (1 /β)t (1/β) e (1 /β)(t s)
m (s ) ds,
0
one for each p0
This raises the question of what to do when the equilibrium is indeterminate?
Econ 208 (Lecture 11) Cagan Model March 6, 2007 9/9