SEEA-Water: System of Environmental-Economic Accounting For Water
SEEA-Water: System of Environmental-Economic Accounting For Water
SEEA-Water: System of Environmental-Economic Accounting For Water
System of Environmental-Economic
Accounting for Water
...............................................................1,740.00
...............................................................1,737.50
...............................................................1 735 00
-0 46 ...............................................................1 732 00
-0 46
...............................................................1 730 00
-0 44 -0 44
...............................................................1 728 50
-0 43 ...............................................................1 725 00
-0 43
-0 38 ...............................................................1 722 50 -0 38
-0 28 -0 28
-0 25 -0 25
ST/ESA/STAT/SER.F/100
System of Environmental-
Economic Accounting for Water
asdf
United Nations
New York, 2012
DESA
The Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the United Nations Secretariat is a vital
interface between global policies in the economic, social and environmental spheres and
national action. The Department works in three main interlinked areas: (i) it compiles,
generates and analyses a wide range of economic, social and environmental data and
information on which States Members of the United Nations draw to review common
problems and to take stock of policy options; (ii) it facilitates the negotiations of Member
States in many intergovernmental bodies on joint courses of action to address ongoing or
emerging global challenges; and (iii) it advises interested Governments on the ways and
means of translating policy frameworks developed in United Nations conferences and
summits into programmes at the country level and, through technical assistance, helps build
national capacities.
Note
The designations used and the presentation of material in this publication do not imply the
expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Secretariat of the United Nations
concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area, or of its authorities, or
concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries.
The term “country” as used in this publication also refers, as appropriate, to territories
or areas.
The designations “developed regions” and “developing regions” are intended for
statistical convenience and do not necessarily express a judgement about the stage reached by a
particular country or area in the development process.
Symbols of United Nations documents are composed of capital letters combined with
figures. Mention of such a symbol indicates a reference to a United Nations document.
ST/ESA/STAT/SER.F/100
United Nations publication
Sales No. E.11.XVII.12
ISBN: 978-92-1-161554-8
Copyright © United Nations, 2012
All rights reserved
iii
Preface
The System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water (SEEA-Water) has been prepared
by the United Nations Statistics Division (UNSD) in collaboration with the London Group
on Environmental Accounting, in particular its Subgroup on Water Accounting.
The preparation of the Handbook of National Accounting: Integrated Environmental and
Economic Accounting 2003, commonly referred to as SEEA-2003, provided a challenging
opportunity to develop methodologies for water accounts. Although country experiences in
water accounts were limited at the time that SEEA-2003 had been prepared, commonalities
in the various approaches to compiling water accounts emerged. Chapter 8 of SEEA-2003
constituted the first attempt to develop harmonized methodologies for water accounts.
In view of the prominence and recognition of water in national and international devel-
opment agendas, the increasing demands from countries for harmonization and guidance on
water accounting led UNSD to take on the task of advancing the methodology based on a
consensus of best practices. The present work builds on the results already achieved during
the preparation of SEEA-2003.
The Eurostat Task Force on Water Satellite Accounting has been a major contributor
in the development of harmonized concepts, definitions, classifications and sets of standard
tables. The Subgroup on Water Accounting of the previously mentioned London Group,
which had been established at the 8th meeting of the London Group, held in Rome in
November 2003, contributed text and country examples, reviewed the various versions of
the draft manuscript and assisted in its finalization. The Subgroup comprised approximately
20 experts from various countries, academia and international organizations.
Draft chapters were discussed at several meetings, including the 8th and 9th meetings
of the London Group, held in Rome in 2003 and in Copenhagen in 2004, respectively. The
final draft was discussed and reviewed during a meeting of the Subgroup in New York from
11 to 13 May 2005. During that meeting, the Subgroup agreed to include in the manuscript
a set of standard tables for the compilation of water accounts which countries would be
encouraged to compile. The final draft of SEEA-Water was presented at the preliminary meet-
ing of the United Nations Committee of Experts on Environmental-Economic Accounting
(UNCEEA), held in New York from 29 to 31 August 2005.
The revised draft was presented at the User-producer Conference: Water Account-
ing for Integrated Water Resources Management held in Voorburg, the Netherlands, from
22 to 24 May 2006, which had been organized by UNSD under the auspices of UNCEEA.
The Conference, which gathered together major users and producers of water information,
endorsed SEEA-Water, recognizing that it provides a much-needed conceptual framework for
organizing hydrological and economic information in support of integrated water resources
management. The Conference recommended the adoption of SEEA-Water as the interna-
tional standard for water statistics.
In the light of the recommendations of the Conference, the discussion during the first
meeting of UNCEEA on 22 and 23 June 2006 in New York and a subsequent e-consultation
among UNCEEA members, the final text of SEEA-Water was revised to conform to the con-
tent and style of an international statistical standard; a fictitious dataset was also developed
to populate the standard tables.
iv System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Acknowledgements
The present version of SEEA-Water was prepared under the responsibility of the United
Nations Statistical Division (UNSD). Coordination was carried out by Ilaria DiMatteo,
moderator of the Subgroup on Water Accounting of the London Group on Environmental
Accounting, with supervision provided by Alessandra Alfieri (UNSD) and under the overall
responsibility of Ivo Havinga (UNSD). Draft chapters were prepared by Ms. Alfieri, Ms.
DiMatteo (UNSD), Bram Edens (formerly with UNSD) and Glenn-Marie Lange (World
Bank, formerly with Columbia University, United States of America). Philippe Crouzet (Euro-
pean Environment Agency), Anton Steurer (Eurostat), Gérard Gié and Christine Spanneut
(consultants to Eurostat) and Jean-Michel Chéné (formerly with the United Nations Division
for Sustainable Development (UNDSD)) contributed to an earlier draft. The development of
the framework greatly benefited from discussions with Jean-Louis Weber (formerly with the
French Institute for the Environment and currently with the European Environment Agency)
and Gulab Singh (UNSD).
An electronic discussion group on terms and definitions used in water accounting
was established and moderated by UNSD in cooperation with UNDSD. In this regard, the
contributions of Aslam Chaudhry and Mr. Chéné were invaluable and are acknowledged
with gratitude.
The many contributions, comments and reviews by the members of the Subgroup on
Water Accounting of the London Group on Environmental Accounting and by the par-
ticipants in the meeting of the Subgroup in New York in May 2005 are also acknowledged
with gratitude. They include the following experts: Michael Vardon (formerly with UNSD);
Martin Lemire and François Soulard (Canada); Wang Yixuan (China); Thomas Olsen (Den-
mark); Mr. Crouzet and Mr. Weber; Christian Ravets (Eurostat); Jean Margat (France);
Christine Flachmann (Germany); Mr. Gié; Osama Al-Zoubi (Jordan); Marianne Eriksson
(Sweden); Riaan Grobler and Aneme Malan (South Africa); Leila Oulkacha (Morocco); Sjo-
erd Schenau and Martine ten Ham (Netherlands); Jana Tafi (Moldova); Mr. Lange; Mr.
Chéné; and Saeed Ordoubadi (formerly with the World Bank).
SEEA-Water also benefited greatly from the comments of the following experts: Rob-
erto Lenton (Global Water Partnership), Nancy Steinbach (formerly with Eurostat), Michael
Nagy (consultant to UNSD), Ralf Becker and Jeremy Webb (UNSD) and in particular Réné
Lalement (France), who substantially reviewed and contributed to the chapter on water qual-
ity accounts.
Mr. Vardon and Lisa Lowe (formerly with UNSD) proofread the manuscript. Ricardo
Martinez-Lagunes (UNSD) contributed to the final adjustments of the document prior to
its publication.
vii
Contents
Page
Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii
Acknowledgements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v
Abbreviations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiii
PART ONE
II. The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water . . . . 17
A. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
B. Water resource system and the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
1. The inland water resource system . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
2. The economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
C. The frameworks of the two systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
D. The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 24
1. Flow accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
2. Asset accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
3. Valuation of non-market flows . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
4. Classification of economic activities and products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
5. Main identities of the System of National Accounts accounting framework . . . 34
6. The water accounting framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
E. Spatial and temporal issues in water accounting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
1. Spatial dimension . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
2. Temporal dimension . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
Page
2. Water consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
3. Supplementary items in the physical supply and use tables for water . . . . . . . . . 50
4. Losses in distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
Page
ANNEXES
I. Standard tables for the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water . . 161
II. Supplementary tables for the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for
Water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
III. Water accounting and water indicators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
A. Indicators derived from the water accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
1. Water resource availability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
2. Water use for human activities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182
3. Opportunities to increase effective water supply: return flows, reuse and
system losses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183
4. Water cost, pricing and incentives for conservation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184
B. Links between indicators in the World Water Development Report and the
System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184
Glossary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193
x System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Page
Boxes
II.1. Main activities related to water in an economy under the International Standard
Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
II.2. Main products related to water according to the Central Product Classification
Version 2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
IV.1. Indicative list of the main pollutants in the European Union . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
V.1. From final consumption expenditure to actual final consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72
V.2. Individual and collective goods and services of government and non-profit
institutions serving households . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73
VII.1. European Union Water Framework Directive . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
V III.1. Shadow prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
V III.2. Categories of economic values for water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123
V III.3. Calculating residual value: an example from Namibia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127
V III.4. Adjusting the residual value of water for market distortions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129
V III.5. Marginal value of water in Canada, by industry, 1991 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130
V III.6. Linear programming approach to valuing irrigation water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
V III.7. Hedonic valuation of the quantity and quality of irrigation water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
V III.8. Two approaches for measuring the value of domestic water in Central America . . . . . . . 133
V III.9. Marginal cost of water degradation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136
IX.1. Water accounts and input-output analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149
IX.2. Projecting water use in Australia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151
IX.3. Evaluating agricultural water use on a catchment basis in South Africa . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152
IX.4. Impact of water price increases on GDP in Australia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
IX.5. Benefits of wastewater treatment in Wuxi, China . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
IX.6. Trade and the environment: the water content of trade in Southern Africa . . . . . . . . . . 155
IX.7. Forecasting water use at the district level in Sweden . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
FIGURES
II.1. Flows between the economy and the environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
II.2. Main flows within the inland water resource system and the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
II.3. The System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water framework . . . . . . . . . . 37
III.1. Flows in the physical supply and use tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
III.2. Detailed description of physical water flows within the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
IV.1. Wastewater and associated pollutant pathway . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60
VI.1. Natural water cycle . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
VI.2. Schematic representation of an asset account . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
VII.1. Comparison of assessment rules for two different sets of data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
VII.2. Global river quality in England and Wales, United Kingdom of Great Britain
and Northern Ireland, 1997-1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114
VII.3. Pattern index for the Republic of Ireland and Northern Ireland, 1990 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
V III.1. Demand curve for water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122
IX.1. Index of water use, population and GDP in Botswana, 1993-1998 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
IX.2. Index of growth of GDP, wastewater and emissions of nutrients and metals
in the Netherlands, 1996-2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
IX.3. Environmental-economic profiles for selected Swedish industries, 1995 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144
IX.4. Percentage of metal emissions originating abroad in 2000 polluting rivers
in the Netherlands . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146
IX.5. Costs and revenues for wastewater treatment services in the Netherlands, 1996-2001 . . 147
IX.6. Location, level and origin of nitrogen discharges into the river basin
of Loire‑Bretagne, France . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
Contents xi
Page
TABLES
III.1. Standard physical supply and use tables for water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
A. Physical use table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
B. Physical supply table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
III.2. Matrix of flows of water within the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
III.3. Detailed physical water supply and use tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
A. Physical use table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
B. Physical supply table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
III.4. Matrix of water flows within the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
III.5. Supplementary table of losses in distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
IV.1. Scope of emission accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
IV.2. Emission accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
A. Gross and net emissions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
B. Emissions by ISIC division 37 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
V.1. Hybrid supply table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
V.2. Hybrid use table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
V.3. Hybrid account for supply and use of water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
V.4. Hybrid account for water supply and sewerage for own use . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
V.5. Government accounts for water-related collective consumption services . . . . . . . . . . . 79
V.6. National expenditure accounts for wastewater management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85
V.7. Financing accounts for wastewater management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87
VI.1. Asset accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
VI.2. Matrix of flows between water resources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
VI.4. Asset accounts for a river basin shared by two countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
VI.3. Asset account at the national level (cubic metres) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
VII.1. Indicators and their determinands included in the System for the Evaluation
of the Quality of Water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
VII.2. Physicochemical quality elements used for the ecological status classification of
rivers in the European Union Water Framework Directive . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
VII.3. Quality accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108
VII.4. Quality accounts of French watercourses by size class . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
VII.5. Accounts of groundwater quality in Victorian provinces, Australia, 1985 and 1998 . . 110
VII.6. Number of determinands per chemical group in different assessment systems . . . . . . 111
V III.1. Valuation techniques for water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
IX.1. Water use in Denmark, by purpose, 1994 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
IX.2. Water use in Australia, by source, 2000-2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
IX.3. Water profile and water productivity in Australia, 2000-2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
IX.4. Water profile for Namibia, 1997-2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
IX.5. Water intensity and total domestic water requirements in Namibia, by industry,
2001-2002 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
IX.6. Water use in 2001 compared with estimated availability of water resources
in Namibia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148
A1.1. Standard physical supply and use tables for water . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
A. Physical use table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
B. Physical supply table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
A1.2. Emission accounts tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163
A. Gross and net emissions table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163
B. Emissions by ISIC division 37 table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163
xii System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Page
Abbreviations
CEPA Classification of Environmental Protection Activities and Expenditure
CNI change in net income (approach)
COFOG Classification of the Functions of Government
CPC Central Product Classification
EDG electronic discussion group (on terms and definitions for SEEA-Water)
GCF gross capital formation
GDP gross domestic product
ISIC International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities
IWRM integrated water resources management
NAMEA National Accounting Matrix including Environmental Accounts
NAMWA National Accounting Matrix including Water Accounts
NPISHs non-profit institutions serving households
OECD Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
SEEA-Water System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
SERIEE European System for the Collection of Information on the Environment
SNA System of National Accounts
SRU standard river unit
UNCEEA United Nations Committee of Experts on Environmental-Economic
Accounting
UNDSD United Nations Division for Sustainable Development
UNDP United Nations Development Programme
UNEP United Nations Environment Programme
UNESCO United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization
UNSC United Nations Statistical Commission
UNSD United Nations Statistics Division
USGS U.S. Geological Survey
WMO World Meteorological Organization
1
Chapter I
Overview of the System of
Environmental-Economic Accounting
for Water
A. Introduction
1.1. Water is essential for life. It is a key component in growing food, generating energy,
producing many industrial products and other goods and services, as well as in ensuring the
integrity of ecosystems. Increasing competition for freshwater use in the agricultural, urban
and industrial sectors, including through population growth, has resulted in unprecedented
pressures on water resources, with many countries experiencing conditions of water scarcity,
or facing limits to their economic development. Moreover, water quality continues to worsen,
further limiting the availability of freshwater resources.
1.2. The integral role of water in the development process is widely recognized. It is not
surprising that water is very high on the national and international development agendas,
with several international agreements specifying targets for water supply and sanitation.
The most notable of these is the inclusion of two indicators, namely, “proportion of popu-
lation using an improved water source” and “proportion of population using an improved
sanitation facility”, for target 7.C of the Millennium Development Goals, which aims to
“halve, by 2015, the proportion of people without sustainable access to safe drinking water
and basic sanitation”.1
1.3. Because water is critical to life and intimately linked with socio-economic devel-
opment, it is necessary for countries to move away from sectoral development and the
management of water resources to the adoption of an integrated overall approach to water
management.2
1.4. The System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water (SEEA-Water) pro-
vides a conceptual framework for organizing hydrological and economic information in
a coherent and consistent manner. The SEEA-Water framework is an elaboration of the
Handbook of National Accounting: Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting, 3
commonly referred to as SEEA-2003, which describes the interaction between the economy
and the environment and covers the whole spectrum of natural resources and the environ-
ment. Both SEEA-2003 and SEEA-Water use as a basic framework the System of National
1 See http://mdgs.un.org/unsd/mdg/Host.aspx?Content=Indicators/OfficialList.htm.
2 United Nations and the World Water Assessment Programme, United Nations World Water Develop-
ment Report 2: Water a Shared Responsibility (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.06.II.A.4).
3 United Nations, Handbook of National Accounting: Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting:
An Operational Manual, Series F, No. 78, Rev.1 (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.00. XVII.17)
(hereinafter referred to as the Handbook of National Accounting).
2 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Accounts, 2008,4 which is widely known as the 2008 SNA. It is the standard system for
the compilation of economic statistics and the derivation of economic indicators, the most
notable being gross domestic product (GDP).
1.5. Complementing the SEEA-Water conceptual framework is a set of standard tables
focusing on hydrological and economic information. SEEA-Water also includes a set of sup-
plementary tables covering information on social aspects; these tables enable the analysis of
interactions between water and the economy. The standard tables constitute the minimum
data set that all countries are encouraged to compile. Supplementary tables consist of items
that should be considered by countries in which information would, in their particular cases,
be of interest to analysts and policymakers, or for which compilation is still experimental or
not directly linked with the 2008 SNA. The set of tables, standard and supplementary, was
designed with the objective of facilitating the compilation of the accounts in countries and
collecting information which is comparable across countries and over time.
1.6. Only by integrating information on the economy, hydrology, other natural resources
and social aspects can integrated policies be designed in an informed and integrated man-
ner. Policymakers effecting decisions on water need to be aware of the likely consequences of
their decisions for the economy. Those determining the development of industries making
extensive use of water resources, either as inputs in the production process or as sinks for the
discharge of wastewater, need to be aware of the long-term consequences of their policies on
water resources and the environment in general.
1.7. Section B of the present chapter presents the main features of SEEA-Water and dis-
cusses the relationship of SEEA-Water to the 2008 SNA and SEEA-2003, as well as the
advantages of using the accounting framework of SEEA-Water to organize information on
water resources.
1.8. Section C introduces the concept of “integrated water resources management”
(IWRM), the internationally agreed and recommended strategy for the management of water
resources, and discusses how SEEA-Water can be used as an information system in support
of IWRM.
1.9. Section D offers an overview of the accounting structure and a brief summary of each
chapter. Section E looks at a number of issues related to implementing the system, while not-
ing areas for future work.
4 Commission of the European Communities, International Monetary Fund, Organization for Eco-
nomic Cooperation and Development, United Nations and World Bank, System of National Accounts,
2008 (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.08.XVII.29) (hereinafter referred to as the System of
National Accounts, 2008 in footnotes and “the 2008 SNA” in the text).
Overview of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 3
economic performance, both at the sectoral and macroeconomic levels, as well as a detailed
set of statistics to guide resource managers towards policy decision-making.
1.12. There are two features that distinguish SEEA-2003 and SEEA-Water from other infor-
mation systems related to the environment. First, SEEA-2003 and SEEA-Water directly link
environmental data and, in the case of SEEA-Water, water data, to the economic accounts
through a shared structure and set of definitions and classifications. The advantage of these
linkages is that they provide a tool to integrate environmental-economic analysis and to
overcome the tendency to divide issues along disciplinary lines, when analyses of economic
issues and of environmental issues are carried out independently of one another.
1.13. Second, SEEA-2003 and SEEA-Water cover all the important environmental-economic
interactions, a feature that makes them ideal for addressing cross-sectoral issues, such as
IWRM. It is not possible to promote IWRM from the narrow perspective of managing
water resources; rather, a broader approach that encompasses economic, social and ecosystem
aspects is needed. As satellite accounts of SNA, both SEEA-2003 and SEEA-Water are linked
to a full range of economic activities with a comprehensive classification of environmental
resources. SEEA-2003 includes information about all critical environmental stocks and flows
that may affect water resources and be affected by water policies.
1.14. While SEEA-2003 reports best practices and, wherever possible, presents harmo-
nized approaches, concepts and definitions, SEEA-Water goes a step further by providing a
set of standard tables that countries are encouraged to compile using harmonized concepts,
definitions and classifications. This is in line with the call by the Statistical Commission
of the United Nations Economic and Social Council to elevate SEEA-2003 to the level of
an “international statistical standard” by 2010,5 as had been recommended by the United
Nations Committee of Experts on Environmental-Economic Accounting.6
1.15. SEEA-Water includes, as part of its standard presentation, information on the following:
(a) Stocks and flows of water resources within the environment;
(b) Pressures imposed on the environment by the economy in terms of water abstrac-
tion and emissions added to wastewater and released into the environment or
removed from wastewater;
(c) The supply of water and its use as an input in the production process and by
households;
(d) The reuse of water within the economy;
(e) The costs of collection, purification, distribution and treatment of water, as well
as the service charges paid by its users;
(f ) The financing of these costs, that is, who is to pay for the water supply and sanita-
tion services;
(g) The payment of permits for access to abstract water or to use it as a sink for the
discharge of wastewater;
5 See Official Records of the Economic and Social Council, 2006, Supplement No. 4 (E/2006/24) and
document E/CN.3/2006/9.
6 The United Nations Committee of Experts on Environmental-Economic Accounting (UNCEEA)
was created by the United Nations Statistical Commission at its thirty-sixth session in March 2005.
More information about UNCEEA is available from the United Nations Statistics Division website
at http://unstats.un.org/unsd/envaccounting/ceea/default.asp.
4 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
7 Report of the United Nations Conference on Environment and Development, Rio de Janeiro, 3‑14 June
1992, vol. I, Resolutions Adopted by the Conference (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.93.I.8
and corrigendum), resolution 1, annex II (hereinafter referred to as Report of the Conference).
8 The official title is Directive 2000/60/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council establish-
ing a framework for the Community action in the field of water policy. It entered into force on 22
December 2000.
9 The group’s work was based in particular on a review of the following glossaries: 2001 UNSD ques-
tionnaire on water resources; 2002 OECD/Eurostat joint questionnaire on water resources; 2001
FAO/Aquastat questionnaire; UNESCO/WMO International Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed., 1992;
FAO/Aquastat Glossary online; Working copy of the terminology of water management: Flood pro-
tection TERMDAT; and United Nations Glossary of Environment Statistics, Studies in Methods, Series
F, No. 67, 1997.
Overview of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 5
1.31. Category 3: Asset accounts. This category of accounts (chap. VI) comprises accounts
for water resource assets measured mostly in physical terms. Asset accounts measure stocks
at the beginning and the end of the accounting period and record the changes in the stocks
that occur during the period. They describe all increases and decreases of the stock due to
natural causes, such as precipitation, evapotranspiration, inflows and outflows, and human
activities, such as abstraction and returns. These accounts are particularly useful because
they link water abstraction and return to the availability of water in the environment, thus
enabling the measurement of the pressure on physical water induced by the economy.
1.32. Category 4: Quality accounts. This category of accounts describes the stock of
water in terms of its quality (chap. VII). It should be noted that the quality accounts are
still experimental. Quality accounts describe the stocks of water resources in terms of qual-
ity: they show the stocks of certain qualities at the beginning and the end of an accounting
period. Because it is generally difficult to link changes in quality to the causes that affect
it, quality accounts describe only the total change in an accounting period, without further
specifying the causes.
1.33. Category 5: Valuation of water resources. The final category of the SEEA-Water
accounts comprises the valuation of water and water resources (chap. VIII). With regard to
the quality accounts, this category of accounts is still experimental; there is still no agree-
ment on a standard method for compiling them.
1.34. When natural resources are used in the production process, they are embodied in
the final good or service produced. The price charged for the product contains an element
of rent, which implicitly reflects the value of the natural resource. Establishing this implicit
element is at the heart of valuing the stock of the resource. In the case of water, however,
which is often an open access resource, this implicit element is often zero. Increasingly, water
is being treated as an economic good. Therefore, it is expected that in the future the resource
rent for water would be positive and thus the value of the water stocks would be included in
the balance sheets of a country.
1.35. The valuation of water resources is included in SEEA-Water because of its policy rel-
evance. However, since no agreement has yet been reached on how to value water (consistent
with 2008 SNA valuation concepts), SEEA-Water presents only the valuation techniques
commonly used in economic analyses, which may go beyond the value of the market trans-
actions recorded in the 2008 SNA, and their relationship to the concepts of the 2008 SNA,
while discussing the advantages and disadvantages of different techniques.
1.38. The following section affords a brief overview of each chapter of SEEA-Water. At
the beginning of each chapter a more extensive “road map” describes the objectives of the
chapter and presents a brief description of its contents.
1. Part one
1.39. Chapter II: The water accounts framework. SEEA-Water links the water resource
system with the economy. The water resource system and the hydrological cycles, as well as
the relations of the system with the economy, are described in detail.
1.40. Because SEEA-Water is rooted in the 2008 SNA, chapter II provides an overview
of the whole accounting system and describes how SEEA-Water expands the 2008 SNA
accounting framework. The chapter also describes in great detail the classifications used in
SEEA-Water, which form the backbone of the accounting framework and the interconnec-
tions between the different accounts.
1.41. Since water resources possess spatial and temporal characteristics, which are usually
not addressed in standard accounts, chapter II describes how SEEA-Water can be adapted
to compile information which is spatially and temporally disaggregated, without disrupting
the accounting structure.
1.42. Chapter II may be read at the outset as a preliminary overview of what is to follow
or as a synoptic review of the interconnections between the accounts and tables presented
in the subsequent chapters.
1.43. Chapter III: Physical water supply and use tables. Chapter III is the main chapter
concerned with compiling water flow accounts in physical terms. It is designed to show
how the use of water resources can be monitored in physical terms, using classifications and
definitions consistent with the economic accounting structure of the 2008 SNA.
1.44. This chapter distinguishes different types of flows, namely, flows from the environ-
ment to the economy, flows within the economy and flows from the economy back into the
environment.
1.45. Flows from the environment to the economy consist of water abstraction from the
environment for production or consumption purposes. Flows within the economy are within
the purview of the 2008 SNA. The SNA measures flows of water and wastewater within
the economy. It shows water that is used to produce other goods and services (intermediate
consumption) and to satisfy current human wants (final consumption), as well as water
that is exported (a small part since water is a bulky good). Flows from the economy into the
environment consist of discharges of wastewater back into the environment.
1.46. Chapter III describes the supply and use tables for physical flows of water. It furnishes
standard tables as well as more detailed supplementary tables for compilation. The detailed
tables are presented as numerical examples, and they are part of the previously mentioned
SEEA-Water-land database.
1.47. Chapter IV: Emission accounts. Chapter IV describes the pressure that the economy
puts on the environment in terms of emissions into water. Emission accounts describe the
quantity of pollutants that is added to wastewater as a result of production and consumption
activities and that is released into the environment. These accounts also describe the quantity
of pollutants which is removed as part of treatment by the sewerage industry.
1.48. The chapter presents a set of standard tables to be compiled by countries and SEEA-
Water-land data sets for use in the emission accounts tables.
10 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
1.49. Chapter V: Hybrid and economic accounts for activities and products related to
water. Chapter V describes the economy of water. It describes in monetary terms the use
and supply of water-related products, identifies the costs associated with the production of
these products, the income generated by them, the investments in hydraulic infrastructure
and the cost of maintaining it. These flows are captured within the 2008 SNA and need to
be separately identified.
1.50. Chapter V shows how a standard SNA supply and use table can be juxtaposed with
the corresponding part of the physical table described in chapter III. The result is conventional
national accounts presented together with physical information on water abstraction, supply
and use within the economy and discharges of water and pollutants into the environment.
These accounts, which are referred to as “hybrid accounts”, do not modify the basic structure
of the conventional SNA. The linkage between physical and monetary information afforded
by hybrid accounts is particularly useful for relating to particular industries the abstraction
of water resources, the generation of wastewater and the emission of pollutants.
1.51. In addition to the water supply and sewerage industries, other industries and house-
holds may abstract water for their own use or distribute it to other users; they may also treat
the wastewater they generate. In this chapter, the costs of production of these industries are
separately identified from the costs of the main activity in order to provide information on
the full extent of the national expenditure on water.
1.52. Users of water and water-related products do not always bear the entire costs associated
with water use: the users often benefit from transfers from other economic units, generally
the Government, as such units bear part of the costs. Similarly, investments in infrastructure
can be partly financed by different units. The financing of water and water-related products
is described in chapter V.
1.53. Economic instruments are increasingly being used to manage the use of water
resources. They include the imposition of taxes and the issuing of licences and permits to
grant property rights over water resources to designated users. The recording of these mon-
etary transactions in the accounting framework is also presented in the chapter.
1.54. The chapter provides standard tables for compilation of hybrid accounts for water,
financing and taxes, licences and permits. These tables are part of the SEEA-Water-land data
sets and are linked with the physical flows presented in the previous chapters.
1.55. Chapter VI: The asset accounts. Chapter VI looks at water assets and discusses how
to account in physical terms for changes in these accounts as a result of natural processes or
human activities.
1.56. Since the asset accounts describe water in the environment, the chapter describes the
hydrological cycle and how it is represented in the asset accounts. It describes the principles
behind physical asset accounts, that is, getting from opening stock levels to closing stock levels
by itemizing the flows within the accounting period. The chapter describes the classification
of water resources and furnishes standard tables for compilation. It also presents the compila-
tion of asset accounts for transboundary waters.
2. Part two
1.57. Chapter VII: Quality accounts. Quality accounts do not have a direct link to the
economic accounts, as changes in quality cannot be attributed to economic quantities using
a linear relationship, as in the case of the water asset accounts. Nevertheless, because quality
is an important characteristic of water ecosystems and limits water’s use, SEEA-Water covers
quality accounts.
Overview of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 11
1.58. Chapter VII furnishes basic concepts concerning the measurement of quality and
describes different approaches to defining quality classes and constructing quality accounts.
1.59. Chapter VIII: Valuation of water resources. The need to treat water as an economic
good has been widely recognized. The 2008 SNA records the value of transactions involv-
ing water within the economy. The prices charged for water in the market often do not
reflect its full economic value owing to certain characteristics unique to water. Water is a
collective good, heavily regulated and subject to multiple uses. The price charged often does
not reflect even its cost of production, and property rights are often absent. Economists
have developed techniques for estimating the value of water which are not consistent with
the 2008 SNA.
1.60. Chapter VIII describes background concepts in the economic valuation of water and
the valuation principles of SNA. It furnishes an overview of different valuation techniques,
their strengths and weaknesses as well as their relevance to particular policy questions.
1.61. Chapter IX: Examples of applications of water accounts. Water accounts are a rela-
tively new tool for organizing water-related information. Therefore, these accounts need to
be promoted among both the users and the producers of water information. Chapter IX
links the accounts to applications for water policy by showing how the accounts have been
used in countries for the derivation of indicators for monitoring and evaluating policies and
for scenario-modelling so as to estimate, for example, the impact of water pricing reforms or
project future demands.
1.62. Although the applications presented are derived from the techniques and tables con-
tained in the previous chapters, chapter IX is a stand-alone chapter. It can be read at the
outset because it furnishes an overview of the possible applications of the accounts and can
assist in setting implementation priorities: deciding on a set of priority indicators will lead
to a set of tables that should be compiled first. It can also be read at the end as it shows how
the information from different accounts is brought together and used for the derivation of
indicators and for economic modelling.
1.63. The first part of the chapter describes the most common indicators used to evaluate
patterns of water supply and use, and pollution. It presents indicators at the national level
and then more detailed indicators and statistics that shed light on the sources of pressure on
water resources, the opportunities for reducing the pressure, the contribution of economic
incentives to the problem and possible solutions. This information sets the stage for more
complex water policy issues that require economic models based on the water accounts.
1.64. The second part of the chapter describes the use of the accounts at the subnational
and river basin levels and discusses the possibility of introducing a more flexible temporal
dimension. It then discusses the links between water accounts and other resource accounts
in SEEA in support of IWRM.
1.65. Annexes. SEEA-Water contains three annexes. Annex I includes the standard tables
which are presented and discussed in chapters III to VI. The standard tables constitute the
minimum data set that all countries are encouraged to compile. Annex II contains supple-
mentary tables which cover items that should be considered by countries in which informa-
tion would, in their particular cases, be of interest to analysts and policymakers, or for which
compilation is still experimental and not directly linked to the 2008 SNA. In particular, the
supplementary tables afford a more detailed level of disaggregation of the standard tables,
tables on still experimental quality accounts and tables linking SEEA-Water to social aspects.
1.66. Annex III links the water accounts to indicators. In particular, section 1 of that annex
draws together the wide range of indicators that can be derived from the accounts presented
in SEEA-Water to show how, together, they supply a comprehensive set of water-related
12 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
indicators. Section 2 links the water accounts to the indicators proposed in the previously
mentioned World Water Development Report 2.13 It also describes the indicators that can be
derived from SEEA-Water, including the particular module of the water accounts.
1.67. Glossary. The glossary provides agreed terminology for water accounting. It combines
(a) hydrological terms, which were agreed upon by the previously mentioned electronic dis-
cussion group; (b) environmental-economic accounting terms, which were drawn from the
glossary of SEEA-2003; and (c) economic terms drawn from the glossary of the 2008 SNA.
The hydrological terms were drawn from international questionnaires, international glossaries
and selected country reports on water accounts and adapted to the needs of SEEA-Water.
1.68. The glossary standardizes terms and definitions from the hydrological and the eco-
nomic spheres in an agreed set of definitions. Its purpose is to facilitate the collection of
consistent data on water, based on existing international statistical standards, such as the
2008 SNA.
16 The directive requires Member States to ensure good ecological status for surface waters, good ecologi-
cal potential for heavily modified surface water bodies, good chemical status for surface waters and
good chemical and quantitative status for groundwaters by 2015, as well as to adhere to the general
principle of non-deterioration of water bodies.
PART ONE
17
Chapter II
The framework of the System
of Environmental-Economic Accounting
for Water
A. Introduction
2.1. SEEA-Water offers a systematic framework for the organization of water information
to enable the study of the interactions between the economy and the environment. It is a
further elaboration of the SEEA-2003 framework, focusing exclusively on water resources.
As with SEEA, SEEA-Water expands the 2008 SNA by identifying separately information
related to water in the 2008 SNA and linking physical information on water with economic
accounts. The purpose of this chapter is to describe the accounting framework for water.
2.2. Section B furnishes a description in diagrammatic form of the interactions between
the hydrological system and the economy. It describes in a non-technical way the hydro-
logical system, the economic system (as measured by the 2008 SNA) and the interactions
between these systems.
2.3. Section C introduces the SEEA-Water framework as a satellite system of the 2008
SNA and describes how SEEA-Water expands the 2008 SNA in order to address water-
related concerns. Section D presents the accounting framework in more detail: it describes
the various accounts in the SEEA-Water framework and presents the concepts, definitions
and classifications that are used in SEEA-Water. Section E introduces two cross-cutting
issues in the compilation of water accounts, namely, the identification of the temporal and
spatial references.
which is particularly important for the management of water resources, is not systematically
included in the SEEA-Water framework. However, information on some crucial social aspects
of water, such as access to safe drinking water and sanitation, are included in supplementary
tables in order to facilitate the analysis of the social impacts of water policies. Other social
aspects of water can be made explicit in SEEA-Water: for example, by disaggregating the
household sector according to specific characteristics, such as income, or rural versus urban
residence. Further methodological research and practical experience are needed to extend the
framework to the social dimension.
2.6. The framework of SEEA-Water is presented in simplified diagrammatic form in figure
II.1, which shows the economy, the system of water resources and their interactions. The econ-
omy and the inland water resource system of a territory, referred to as “territory of reference”,
are represented inside the figure as two separate boxes. The inland water resource system of
a territory is composed of all water resources in the territory (surface water, groundwater and
soil water) and the natural flows between and among them. The economy of a territory con-
sists of resident17 water users that abstract water for production and consumption purposes
and put in place the infrastructure to store, treat, distribute and discharge water. The inland
water system and the economy are further elaborated in figure II.2 in order to describe the
main flows within each system and the interactions between the two systems.
2.7. The inland water resource system and the economy of a given territory, which can be
a country, an administrative region or a river basin, can exchange water with those of other
territories through imports and exports of water (exchanges of water between economies) and
through inflows from upstream territories and outflows to downstream territories (exchanges
of water between inland water systems).
2.8. Figure II.1 also shows exchanges with the sea and the atmosphere, which are consid-
ered outside the inland water resource system. These flows are also captured in the SEEA-
Water accounting framework.
2.9. The economy uses water in different ways. It can physically remove water from the
environment for activities involving production and consumption or use water without
physically removing it from the environment. In the first case, the economy abstracts water
from the inland water bodies or the sea, uses the precipitation (in situ use of precipitation
in figure II.1) through rain-fed agriculture or water harvesting, and uses water for generat-
ing hydroelectric power. In the second case, the economy uses water for recreational and
navigational purposes, fishing and other uses that rely on the physical presence of water (in
situ uses) and often on the quality of the water also. Even though these uses may have a
negative impact on the quality of the water bodies, they are not directly considered in the
water accounts because they do not involve displacement of water. It should be mentioned,
however, that in the quality accounts, their impacts on the quality of water resources could,
in principle, be identified.
2.10. In addition to abstracting water, the economy returns water into the environment. As
shown in figure II.1, returns can be either into the inland water system or directly into the
sea. Usually, return flows have a negative impact on the environment in terms of quality, as
the quality of such water is often lower than that of abstracted water. Although returns to
the water resource system alter the quality of the receiving body, they represent an input into
the water system, as returned water then becomes available for other uses.
17 The concept of residence follows that of the 2008 SNA, according to which “the residence of each
institutional unit is the economic territory with which it has the strongest connection, in other words,
its centre of predominant economic interest” (System of National Accounts, 2008, op. cit., para. 4.10).
This concept can be applied also to geographical boundaries other than national ones.
The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 19
Figure II.1
Flows between the economy and the environment
Atmosphere
Precipication
Evapotranspiration
Territory of reference
In situ use
Returns
of precipitation
Economy
Returns
2.11. Figure II.2 shows in greater detail the flows of the inland water resource system and
the economy to illustrate the water flows captured by the accounts. It should be noted that, in
order to keep the figure as simple as possible, only the main flows are depicted. For example,
direct abstraction of sea water by industries is not explicitly shown even though it is recorded
in the accounts.
20 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Figure II.2
Main flows within the inland water resource system and the economy
Atmosphere
Vapour
Precipication
Evapotranspiration
Wastewater
Territory of reference
Liquid water
Collection
Returns
Returns
of precipitation
Abstraction Evapotranspiration
Sea Sea
Returns
Sewerage
Households Returns
Other industries
(incl. agriculture)
composed of the following: (a) all inland water resources from which water is, or can be,
abstracted; (b) water exchanges between water resources within the territory of reference, such
as infiltration, run-off and percolation; and (c) water exchanges with water resources of other
territories, that is, inflows and outflows. Exchanges of water between the water resources are
also referred to as natural transfers.
2.13. The water resources considered in the inland water resource system are rivers, lakes,
artificial reservoirs, snow, ice, glaciers, groundwater and soil water within the territory of ref-
erence. These resources form the water asset classification presented in chapter VI. The main
natural inputs of water for these resources are precipitation and inflows from other territories
and from other resources within the territory. The main natural flows that decrease the stocks
of water are evapotranspiration, outflows to other water resources within the territory and
outside the territory. Human activities decrease and increase water stocks through abstraction
and returns.
2.14. The asset accounts module of SEEA-Water describes the inland water resource system
in terms of stocks and flows: it provides information on the stocks of water resources at the
beginning and the end of the accounting period and the changes therein. These changes are
described in terms of flows brought about by the economy and by natural processes. Asset
accounts can be thought of as a description in accounting terms of the hydrological water
balance.
2. The economy
2.15. As mentioned in previous paragraphs, water resources support several functions not
only for humankind, which uses water for survival and activities involving production and
consumption, but also for other forms of life which are sustained by water. As such, the
economy is one of many water users. The focus of water accounting is on the interactions
between and among water resources and the economy, where the economy is thought of as
the system which abstracts water for activities involving consumption and production, and
which puts into place the infrastructure to mobilize, store, treat, distribute and return water
into the environment.
2.16. In figure II.2, the box representing the economy has been expanded to show the main
economic agents related to water. In particular, the following are identified:
(a) The industry primarily involved in the collection, treatment and supply of water
to households, industries and the rest of the world;
(b) The industry involved primarily in the collection, treatment and discharge of
sewage (sewerage);
(c) Other industries which use water as an input in their production processes;
(d) Households, which use water to satisfy their needs or wants.
2.17. It should be noted that households are identified separately only as final consumers of
water. If water is used by households as an input in the production of agricultural products,
for example, water should be considered as an input in the production process and the activity
should be classified according to the relevant category of the classification of economic activity.
2.18. The box representing the economy in figure II.2 describes, in simplified format,
physical exchanges of water (represented by arrows) between economic units (represented
by boxes). For the sake of simplicity, not all exchanges within the economy are represented
in the figure. Additional information, which is an integral part of SEEA-Water, includes the
following:
22 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
(a) Monetary transactions related to water exchanges: (i) the costs of collection,
treatment and supply of water and that of sanitation services; (ii) fees and taxes
paid for water and sanitation services; (iii) payments for access to the resource
(e.g., water rights) as well as for discharging wastewater; and (iv) the financing
of these services, that is, the sectors bearing the costs of the services;
(b) Costs for environmental protection and resource management. These costs
describe the economy’s efforts to prevent environmental degradation or elimi-
nate part, or all, of the effects after degradation has taken place. They include
the actual expenses incurred (current and capital) by industries, households
and the Government, as well as the financing of such expenditures;
(d) The emission of pollutants into the environment. This information enables the
identification of pressures on the environment caused by various economic
agents, namely, industries, households and the Government.
2.19. Sources of water for the whole economy of a given territory include the following:
inland water resources in the environment of the territory of reference; precipitation,
which is either collected or used directly, such as rain-fed agriculture; sea water, which
can be used directly, such as for cooling purposes, or after desalinization; and imports of
water from other economies (the rest of the world). Once water enters an economy, it is
used, returned to the environment (to inland water resources and to the sea) or supplied
to other economies (exports). In addition, during use or transportation, water can be lost
through leakages or processes of evaporation and evapotranspiration.
2.20. Each economic unit either abstracts water directly from the environment or receives
it from other industries. Once water has been used, it can be discharged directly into the
environment, supplied to other industries for further use (reused water), or supplied to a
treatment facility, which in figure II.2 is denoted by the box entitled “sewerage”.
2.21. During use, some water may be retained in the products generated by the industry,
or some of it may have evapotranspired during use. It should be noted that in most indus-
trial activities water is lost mainly as a result of evaporation as opposed to the situation
in agriculture, where water is consumed as a result of evaporation and transpiration by
plants and crops. In this example, water is considered to have been “consumed” by the
industry. The term consumption often has different meanings depending on the context.
Here, the term “consumption” refers to the quantity mentioned above, that is, water which
after use is not returned to the environment (inland and sea water). It is different from
“water use”, which denotes the water that is received by an industry or households from
another industry or is directly abstracted. The term “water consumption” is used in the
hydrological sense; this term may create confusion among national accountants who tend
to consider the terms “consumption” and “use” as synonymous.
2.22. It should be noted that figures II.1 and II.2 are aimed at showing in a simple way
situations that are more complex in reality; therefore, they do not contain all the flows that
occur in reality and that are recorded in the accounts. For example, in figure II.2 flows of
water lost during distribution are not shown explicitly, but such losses often occur and at
times in significant quantities. Although not shown explicitly in the figures, these losses
are recorded in SEEA-Water.
The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 23
(a) Expanding the 2008 SNA asset boundary to include all water assets and their
quality and explicitly identifying produced assets that are used for mobiliz-
ing water resources. The 2008 SNA includes only “surface and groundwater
resources used for extraction to the extent that their scarcity leads to the
enforcement of ownership and/or use rights, market valuation and some meas-
ure of economic control”.18 SEEA-Water expands the 2008 SNA asset bound-
ary by including all water resources found in the territory, namely, surface
water, groundwater and soil water. It may be noted, however, that the exten-
sion of the 2008 SNA asset boundary in respect of water resources relates
only to recording such an asset in physical terms. In physical terms the water
asset accounts are an elaboration of the hydrological water balance, and they
describe the changes in stocks due to natural causes and human activities.
Water resources are also described in SEEA-Water in terms of their quality,
as the degradation of the quality of water resources is often a limiting factor
in the use of water. Quality accounts describe the quality of the stocks of
water at the beginning and the end of the accounting period. Quality can be
defined in terms of a single pollutant, a combination of pollutants, or in terms
of physical characteristics, such as the salinity level of water. Asset accounts
for infrastructure, such as pumps and dams, related to water and sanitation
are already included in the 2008 SNA; however, they are often not identified
separately from other produced assets. SEEA-Water enables the explicit identi-
fication of those assets related to water and sanitation. This type of information
has great analytical value as it provides an indication of the ability of a country
to mobilize water;
(b) Expanding the 2008 SNA by juxtaposing physical information with the mon-
etary accounts. In the 2008 SNA, the stocks or assets used in production
processes and the flow of products are measured only in monetary terms, even
if underlying physical information may be used in the compilation of the mon-
etary accounts. SEEA-Water enables the compilation of the accounts in physi-
cal terms. In the case of water, physical flows include the quantity of water
used for activities involving production and consumption and the quantity of
water reused within the economy and returned to the environment (treated
or untreated). Monetary flows include the current and capital expenditures
for abstraction, transportation, treatment and distribution of water resources
as well as the water-related and wastewater-related taxes paid and subsidies
received by industries and households;
(c) Introducing information on the relationship between the economy and the envi-
ronment in terms of abstractions, returns and emissions, thus enabling analysis of
the impact on natural assets caused by the activities of industries, households and
government as they involve production and consumption. Such activities affect
both the quality and quantity of water resources. By introducing information on
the abstraction and discharge of water by industry, households and the Govern-
ment, as well as information on the emission of pollutants into water resources,
SEEA-Water enables the study of the impacts of these activities both in terms of
the quantity and the quality of the water resources;
(d) Separately identifying expenditures for the protection and management of water
resources. The 2008 SNA already includes implicitly expenditures for the protec-
tion of the environment and the management of resources. SEEA-Water reorgan-
izes this information in order to make it more explicit, thus enabling the separate
identification of the expenditures for the protection and management of water, as
well as the identification of taxes, subsidies and financing mechanisms.
2.24. The strengths of using the national accounting framework to describe the interac-
tions between the environment and the economy are manifold. First, the 2008 SNA is an
international standard for compiling economic statistics. It provides a set of internationally
agreed concepts, definitions and classifications, which ensures the quality of the statistics
produced. The 2008 SNA is the main source of information for internationally comparable
economic indicators and for economic analysis and modelling. The integration of environ-
mental information into this framework requires the use of concepts, definitions and clas-
sifications consistent with those of SNA, thus ensuring the consistency of environmental and
economic statistics, and facilitating and improving the analysis of the interrelations between
the environment and the economy.
2.25. Second, the accounting framework contains a series of identities, for example, those
involving supply and use, which can be used to check the consistency of the data. Organizing
environmental and economic information into an accounting framework offers the advantage
of improving basic statistics.
2.26. Third, the accounting structure also enables the calculation of a number of indica-
tors which are precisely defined, consistent and interlinked with each other because they are
derived from a fully consistent data system. Compared with the use of loose sets of indicators,
using indicators that are derived from the accounts offers the advantage of enabling further
analyses of interlinkages and the causes of change, completed by scenarios and prognoses on
the basis of scientific macroeconomic models.
2.27. In short, the existence of an underlying integrated data system is essential for conduct-
ing integrated economic and environmental analyses: it allows for cost‑effectiveness, scenario
modelling, economic and environmental forecasting and the evaluation of trade-offs by ena-
bling the user to no longer have to view sectoral policies in isolation but in a comprehensive
economic and environmental context.
further disaggregation of the standard tables; they consist of items that should be considered
by countries in which information would, in their particular cases, be of interest to analysts
and policymakers. Part one of SEEA-Water expands what is presented in SEEA-2003 by
(a) presenting agreed concepts, definitions and classifications related to water; and (b) provid-
ing standard compilation tables. Part two describes modules that are more experimental and
for which not enough country experience exists; it also furnishes examples of applications of
the water accounts. Part two includes quality accounts, valuation of water and examples of
applications of the accounts; these are discussed in chapters VII, VIII and IX, respectively.
Chapters VII and VIII discuss issues relating to the compilation of those accounts, illustrat-
ing them by presenting country experiences and presenting supplementary tables for which
compilation is still experimental or not directly linked with the 2008 SNA. Part two does
not contain recommendations on how to compile those modules of the accounts. The SEEA-
Water framework consists of the accounts described below.
1. Flow accounts
2.29. The central framework of the 2008 SNA contains detailed supply and use tables in
the form of matrices that record how supplies of goods and services originate from domestic
industries and imports, and how those supplies are allocated among intermediate and final
uses and exports. The SEEA-Water flow accounts furnish information on the contribution of
water to the economy and the pressure exerted by the economy on the environment in terms
of abstraction and emissions.
also interesting to assess the contribution of water-related activities to the economy, linked
to the physical flows of water, in particular to understand the financing of these activities
and products. Monetary accounts for governmental expenditure on water-related activities
and hybrid accounts for the “collection, treatment and supply of water” as well as “sewer-
age” carried out as a principal and secondary activity or for own use furnish this kind of
information, which is useful for compiling expenditures on resource management and
environmental protection.
2.35. One outcome of the compilation of economic accounts for water is the construction of
a financing table, which enables the identification of units that bear the costs of production of
water supply and sanitation services and of those that receive transfers from other economic
units, the Government or other countries.
2.36. These accounts are presented in chapter V together with other economic transactions
related to water, namely, taxes, subsidies and water rights.
2. Asset accounts
2.37. Asset accounts measure stocks at the beginning and the end of the accounting period
and record the changes in stocks that occur during the period. Two types of assets are related
to water: produced assets, which are used for the abstraction, mobilization and treatment of
water; and water resources.
19 Based on the System of National Accounts, 2008, op. cit., para. 13.8.
20 Interested readers should refer to chaps. 10, 12 and 13 of the System of National Accounts, 2008, op. cit.
The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 27
2.40. The SEEA-Water asset boundary of water resources is very broad and includes, in
principle, all inland bodies of water, namely, surface water (rivers, lakes, artificial reservoirs,
glaciers, snow and ice), groundwater and soil water. In practice, it is very difficult to compile
asset accounts for all water resources in the SEEA-Water asset boundary. Nevertheless, they
are included in the asset classification for the sake of completeness and are important when
measuring exchanges between water resources (flows within the environment).
2.41. A small part of water resources is already included in the 2008 SNA asset boundary:
its category AN.214, water resources, includes surface and groundwater resources used for
extraction to the extent that their scarcity leads to the enforcement of ownership or use rights,
market valuation and some measure of economic control.
2.42. Asset accounts for water resources could also be compiled in monetary terms, but in
practice, it is more common to compile them only in physical units: only very rarely does
water have a positive resource rent, because it is often provided free of charge or at prices that
do not reflect the costs of providing the related services. Physical asset accounts are presented
in chapter VI.
lishments and are institutional units disaggregated into smaller and more homogeneous units.
Industries are groups of establishments. The production accounts and generation of income
accounts are compiled for industries as well as sectors.
2.47. The classification of industrial economic activities used in SEEA-Water is the same as
that used in SNA, namely, the International Standard Industrial Classification of All Eco-
nomic Activities (ISIC).
2.48. ISIC is a United Nations system for classifying economic data according to type
of economic activity in a number of fields; it is not a classification of industries, goods and
services. The activity carried out by a unit is the type of production in which it engages. This
is the characteristic of the unit according to which it is grouped with other units to form
industries. An industry is defined as a set of all production units engaged primarily in the
same or similar kinds of productive economic activity.22
2.49. In the ISIC system, no distinction is drawn according to the kind of ownership, the
type of legal organization or the mode of operation because such criteria do not relate to
the characteristics of the activity itself. Units engaged in the same kind of economic activ-
ity are classified in the same category of ISIC irrespective of whether they are incorporated
enterprises or part of such enterprises, individual proprietors or government, or whether the
parent enterprise consists of more than one establishment. Further, ISIC does not distinguish
between formal and informal or legal and illegal production, or between market and non-
market activity.
2.50. Because an establishment, as the statistical unit for industrial or production statistics,
may often engage in a number of activities, it is useful to distinguish between principal and
secondary activities. The output of principal and secondary activities, that is, principal and
secondary products, respectively, is produced for sale on the market, for provision to users
free of charge, or for other uses that are not prescribed in advance. For example, they may be
stocked for future sale or further processing. The principal activity of an economic entity is
that activity which contributes the most to the value of the entity, or the activity for which
the value added exceeds that of any other activity of the entity. A secondary activity is each
separate activity that produces products eventually for third parties and that is not a principal
activity of the entity in question.
2.51. In the 2008 SNA, the activity classification of each unit (establishment) is deter-
mined by the ISIC class in which the principal activity or range of activities of the unit is
included. However, there are cases in which the production of secondary activities within
an establishment is as important, or nearly as important, as the production of the principal
activity. In such cases, the establishment should be subdivided so that the secondary activ-
ity would be treated as taking place within an establishment separately from that in which
the principal activity would take place and be classified accordingly. SEEA-Water follows
the same principle.
2.52. Box II.1 provides a summary of the economic activities, classified according to ISIC
Rev. 4,23 which are primarily related to water in the sense that they furnish either water or
water-related services. Even though the simplified standard tables of SEEA-Water present only
two of the activities in box II.1, that is, class 3600 (collection, treatment and supply of water)
and ISIC class 3700 (sewerage), for analytical purposes it is useful to identify explicitly in the
accounting tables all water-related activities.
2.53. It should be noted that structural changes were introduced in ISIC Rev. 4 that modify
its previous version, ISIC Rev. 3.1.24 In particular, for activities related to water, two major
changes were introduced in ISIC Rev. 4:
(a) In order to reflect the fact that activities involving abstraction, purification and
distribution of water are often carried out in the same enterprise as activities of
wastewater treatment and disposal, ISIC Rev. 4 combines under the same sec-
tion (section E) activities of “collection, purification and distribution of water”
and “sewerage”, which were previously classified under different sections in ISIC
Rev. 3.1;
(b) Given the importance of activities aimed at the decontamination of water
resources and wastewater management, a division was introduced in ISIC Rev. 4
(division 39) to identify these activities explicitly.
2.54. The correspondence of codes between ISIC Rev. 4 and Rev. 3.1 is presented in this
chapter together with a detailed description of the categories relevant to water accounting. In
the remaining chapters, reference to a particular category is made according to ISIC Rev. 4.
The main activities related to water are described below.
2.55. Activities related to the operation of agricultural irrigation systems in support of crop
production include, among various support activities for crop production, all water mobili-
zation activities corresponding to agricultural uses, including groundwater abstraction, the
construction of dams and catchments for surface flows, etc., and the operation of irrigation
equipment. The operation of irrigation systems is recorded under class 0161 of ISIC Rev. 4
and corresponds to class 0140 of ISIC Rev. 3.1. Class 0161 of ISIC Rev. 4 does not include the
provision of water in class 3600 of ISIC Rev. 4 or any construction involved in the provision
of this service. However, it should be noted that special surveys often must be undertaken to
disaggregate information on class 0161 of ISIC Rev. 4 in order to identify explicitly activities
for the operation of irrigation systems.
2.56. Activities for the collection, treatment and supply of water (class 3600 of ISIC Rev.
4), include the following: collection of water from various sources (abstraction from rivers,
lakes, wells, etc., and collection of rainwater); purification of water for supply purposes; and
distribution of water through water mains, by truck or by other means for meeting domestic
and industrial needs. This class also includes the activity of desalinizing seawater or ground-
water in order to produce freshwater. The operation of irrigation canals is also included;
however, the provision of irrigation services through sprinklers, as well as similar agricultural
support services, is classified under the class 0161 of ISIC Rev. 4. Class 3600 of ISIC Rev. 4
corresponds to class 4100 of ISIC Rev. 3.1.
2.57. Sewerage activities (class 3700 of ISIC Rev. 4) include the following: the operation
of sewer systems or sewer treatment facilities; the collection and transportation of (human
and industrial) wastewater from one or several users, as well as urban run-off by means of
sewerage networks, collectors, tanks and other means of transport (sewage vehicles, etc.); the
treatment of wastewater by means of physical, chemical and biological processes, such as dilu-
tion, screening, filtering and sedimentation; the emptying and cleaning of cesspools and septic
tanks, sinks and pits of sewage; and the servicing of chemical toilets. This class also includes
activities involving the maintenance and cleaning of sewers and drains. It should be noted that
an economic unit engaged in the collection and treatment of wastewater (class 3700 of ISIC
Rev. 4), can also redistribute water and wastewater to specific users for further use.
24 United Nations, International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities. Revision 3.1,
Statistical Papers, Series M, No. 4/Rev. 3.1 (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.03.XVII.4).
30 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
2.58. Class 3700 of ISIC Rev. 4 corresponds to part of the activities classified in
class 9000 of ISIC Rev. 3. The remaining activities classified under class 9000 of ISIC
Rev. 3 relate to remediation activities and are explicitly identified in classes 3800 and
3900 of ISIC Rev. 4. Class 3800 of ISIC Rev. 4 is entitled “waste collection, treatment
and disposal activities and materials recovery”. Since these activities refer to solid waste,
they are not discussed further in SEEA-Water.
2.59. Remediation activities and other waste management services. These activities
are coded under class 3900 of ISIC Rev. 4; they include the provision of remediation
services, such as the clean-up of contaminated buildings and sites, soil, and surface water
or groundwater. Only part of these activities is related to water: (a) decontamination of
soil and groundwater at the place of pollution, either in situ or ex situ, using mechanical,
chemical or biological methods, for example; (b) decontamination and clean-up of surface
water following accidental pollution, such as through the collection of pollutants or the
application of chemicals; and (c) clean-up of oil spills and other pollutants on land, in
surface water and in oceans and seas, including coastal areas.
2.60. These activities are particularly useful in assessing environmental protection expen-
ditures. Class 3900 of ISIC Rev. 4 corresponds to part of class 9000 of ISIC Rev. 3.1.
2.61. Activities involving the transport of water are identified in ISIC classes 4923 and
4930, depending on whether the transport is by road, such as by tanker truck, or via
pipeline. These activities are related to the long-distance transport of water as opposed to
the distribution of water, which is classified under ISIC class 3600.
2.63. It should be noted that division 84 of ISIC Rev. 4 includes activities normally
carried out by public administration. However, the legal or institutional status is not, in
itself, the determining factor, as ISIC does not make any distinction regarding the insti-
tutional sector to which a statistical unit belongs. Activities carried out by governmental
units that are specifically attributable to other divisions of ISIC should be classified under
the appropriate division of ISIC but not under division 84 of ISIC Rev. 4. Often there is a
tendency to allocate to class 8412 of ISIC Rev. 4 activities for the collection, purification
and distribution of water (class 3600 of ISIC Rev. 4) and for activities related to sewage,
refuse disposal and sanitation (class 3700 of ISIC Rev. 4) when they are owned by the
Government. This can occur, for example, when the accounts of the local government are
not sufficiently detailed to separate water supply or sewage collection from other activities.
Division 84 of ISIC Rev. 4 includes the administration of programmes related to a variety
of services that enable the community to function properly, but it does not include the
actual operation of facilities, such as waterworks. Some activities in this division may be
carried out by non-governmental units.
2.64. Monetary supply and use tables are constructed for the products associated with
the industries listed in box II.1; they provide information on the value of the outputs pro-
duced (supplied) and their use for intermediate or final consumption and export purposes.
The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 31
Box II.1
Main activities related to water in an economy under the International Standard
Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities
ISIC class 0161: Support activities for crop production (corresponds to class 0140 of ISIC Rev. 3.1)
Among the various support activities for crop production, this class includes the following:
• Operation of agricultural irrigation equipment
ISIC class 3600: Water collection, treatment and supply (corresponds to class 4100 of ISIC Rev. 3.1)
This class includes water collection, treatment and distribution activities for domestic and industrial needs.
It includes the collection of water from various sources, as well as its distribution by various means. The op-
eration of irrigation canals is also included; however, the provision of irrigation services through sprinklers,
as well as similar agricultural support services, is not included. This class includes the following:
• Collection of water from rivers, lakes, wells, etc.
• Collection of rainwater
• Purification of water for the purposes of water supply
• Desalinization of sea water or groundwater to produce freshwater as the principal product of interest
• Distribution of water through mains, by truck or other means
• Operation of irrigation canals
This class excludes the operation of irrigation equipment for agricultural purposes (see class 0161); treat-
ment of wastewater in order to prevent pollution (see class 3700); and (long-distance) transport of water
via pipelines (see 4930).
ISIC class 3700: Sewerage (part of class 9000 of ISIC Rev. 3.1)
This class includes the following:
• The operation of sewer systems or sewer treatment facilities
• The collection and transport of human and industrial wastewater from one or several users, as well
as rainwater by means of sewerage networks, collectors, tanks and other means of transport (sewage
vehicles, etc.)
• The emptying and cleaning of cesspools and septic tanks, sinks and pits of sewage; and the servicing
of chemical toilets
• The treatment of wastewater by means of physical, chemical and biological processes, such as
dilution, screening, filtering and sedimentation
• The treatment of wastewater in order to prevent pollution, for example, from swimming pools and
industry
• The maintenance and cleaning of sewers and drains
• The cleaning and rodding of sewers
ISIC class 3900: Remediation activities and other waste management services
(part of class 9000 of ISIC Rev. 3.1)
This class includes the following:
• Decontamination of soil and groundwater at the place of pollution, either in situ or ex situ, using, for
example, mechanical, chemical or biological methods
• Decontamination of industrial plants or sites, including nuclear plants and sites
• Decontamination and clean-up of surface water following accidental pollution, for example, through
the collection of pollutants or through the application of chemicals
• Clean-up of oil spills and other forms of pollution on land, in surface water, and in oceans, and seas,
including coastal areas
• Abatement of asbestos, lead-based paint and other toxic materials
• Other specialized pollution-control activities
32 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Box II.1
Main activities related to water in an economy under the International Standard
Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities (continued)
This class excludes the treatment and disposal of non-hazardous waste (see class 3821); treatment and
disposal of hazardous waste (see class 3822); and outdoor sweeping and watering of streets, etc. (see
class 8129).
ISIC class 4923: Freight transport by road (corresponds to class 6023 of ISIC Rev. 3.1)
This class includes:
• All freight transport operations by road (e.g., haulage of logs and other bulk items, including haulage
in tanker trucks)
This class excludes, among other things, distribution of water by truck (see class 3600).
ISIC class 4930: Transport via pipeline (corresponds to class 6023 of ISIC Rev.3.1)
This class includes:
• Transport of gases, liquids, water, slurry and other specialized commodities via pipeline
• Operation of pumping stations
This class excludes the distribution of natural or manufactured gas, water or steam (see classes 3520, 3530,
3600) transport of water, liquids, etc. by truck (see class 4923).
ISIC 8412: Regulation of the activities of providing health care, education, cultural services
and other social services, excluding social security (corresponds to class 7512 of ISIC Rev. 3.1)
Source: United Nations, Internation- This class also includes the administration of:
al Standard Industrial Classification
of All Economic Activities (ISIC), Rev. 4, • Potable water supply programmes
Statistical Papers, Series M, No. 4, Rev. • Waste collection and disposal operations
4 (United Nations publication, Sales
No. E.08.XVII.25). • Environmental protection programmes
In national accounts, products are classified according to the Central Product Classification
(CPC) Version 2.25 CPC constitutes a comprehensive classification of all goods and services;
it classifies products based on their physical properties and intrinsic nature, as well as accord-
ing to the principle of industrial origin. CPC and ISIC are both general-purpose and inter-
related classification systems, with ISIC representing the activity side and CPC the product
side. It should be noted, however, that a one-to-one correspondence between CPC and ISIC
is not always possible as the output of an industry, no matter how narrowly defined, tends to
include more than a single product. Similarly, a product can be produced by industries clas-
sified under different categories. In general, however, each CPC subclass consists of goods or
services that are predominantly produced in a specific class or classes of ISIC Rev. 4.
2.65. The main products related to water, which are identified in CPC Version 2, are
described in box II.2 together with the reference to the ISIC Rev. 4 class in which most of the
goods or services in question are generally produced. It should be noted that bottled water is
not explicitly included in the list of water-related products; it is treated in the same way as other
beverages, such as soft drinks, beer and wine. While the SEEA-Water standard tables do not
explicitly record the physical and monetary exchanges of these products within an economy,
they can be easily expanded to add such information. However, they do record information
on the volumes of water used and discharged during the production of such beverages.
25 United Nations, Central Product Classification (CPC) Version 2 (United Nations and United Nations
Environment Programme, December 2008). Available from http://unstats.un.org/unsd/cr/registry/
cpc-2.asp.
The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 33
Box II.2
Main products related to water according to the Central Product Classification Version 2
2.66. The simplified standard tables explicitly identify only two of the products related to
water, which constitute the most important water-related products: CPC 18, natural water,
and CPC 941, sewerage, sewage treatment and septic tank cleaning services. However, it is
highly recommended that they also explicitly include the other water-related products.
2.67. Although the term natural water would seem to describe water in the natural environ-
ment, the CPC class “natural water” is very broad and covers all types of water: water in the
environment, water supplied and used within the economy and water discharged back into
the environment. The exact boundaries of this class are usually determined by the statistical
framework that uses CPC. To reflect these different types of water flows, water accounts
disaggregate the CPC class of natural water first in terms of the type of flow (from the envi-
ronment to the economy, within the economy and from the economy to the environment),
and second in terms of the type of water: water supplied to other economic units is further
disaggregated to identify, for example, whether it consists of wastewater supplied for further
use. This is particularly important for water conservation policies which encourage the reuse
of water. Examples of relevant categories of water in the physical supply and use tables are
presented in chapter III.
2.68. Physical supply and use tables record the amount of water that is exchanged between
an economic unit and the environment (abstraction and return flow) and between economic
units. However, monetary supply and use tables may report the value of the service associ-
ated with the water exchange, as well as the value of the water exchanged. This is because
the output of the supplying industry is generally a service, and the monetary supply and use
table records the value of the service. For example, the water supply industry, which collects,
treats and supplies water, generally charges only for the service of collection, treatment and
supply but not for water as a good.
2.71. On the other side (use), the goods and services produced can be used in various
ways. They can be used by (a) industries to produce other goods and services (intermediate
consumption); (b) households and government to satisfy their needs or wants (final con-
sumption); (c) industries acquiring them for future use in the production of other goods and
services (capital formation); and (d) the economy of another territory (exports). Therefore,
the following formula applies:
Total use = intermediate consumption + final consumption + gross capital formation + exports
Total supply and total use as defined above have to be equal. In SNA this identity is expressed
only in monetary terms, but in SEEA it holds true also when the accounts are compiled in
physical terms.
The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 35
2.72. Another identity of SNA involves the generation of value added. Gross value added
is the value of output less the value of the goods and services, excluding fixed assets, con-
sumed as inputs by a process of production (intermediate consumption). It is a measure of
the contribution to GDP made by an individual producer, industry or sector. When the
reduction in the value of the fixed assets used in production during the accounting period
resulting from physical deterioration, normal obsolescence or normal accidental damage
(consumption of fixed capital) is taken into account, then the net value added is obtained,
using the following formulas:
Gross value added = output – intermediate consumption
Net value added = output – intermediate consumption – consumption of fixed capital
2.73. Once the value added has been generated, it is decomposed in the primary generation
of income accounts for compensation of employees, taxes and subsidies on production and
operating surplus, according to the following formula:
(Gross) value added = (gross) operating surplus + compensation of employees + taxes – subsidies
2.74. Another identity of SNA particularly useful in SEEA involves assets, and it links
them with flows. This identity describes the stocks of assets at the beginning and the end
of an accounting period and their changes. Changes are the result of transactions on the
asset (gross fixed capital formation), consumption of fixed capital, changes in the volume
of the asset that are not due to transactions, such as changes in classification, discoveries
and natural disasters, and changes in their price (holding gains/losses on assets), using the
following formula:
losing stocks = opening stocks + gross fixed capital formation – consumption of fixed capital +
C
other changes in volume of asset + holding gains/losses on assets
2.79. The asset accounts are obtained in figure II.3 by combining the opening and closing
stocks of assets with that part of the supply and use tables which affects those stocks. In par-
ticular, figure II.3 distinguishes assets related to water, which are within the asset boundary
(unshaded box); such assets include the infrastructure for the storage, mobilization and use of
water, as well as the assets of water, which include mainly water in the environment. It should
be noted that part of the assets of water is already included in SNA, such as groundwater,
but are not shown separately for two reasons. First, these assets represent a minimal part of
all water assets; second, the valuation of those assets remains, in practice, a difficult exercise
(even though it is theoretically possible to value them). The valuation is often embedded in
the value of land.
2.80. The framework in figure II.3 can also be presented in matrix form. The matrix presen-
tation is commonly referred to as the National Accounting Matrix including Water Accounts
(NAMWA). NAMWA and more generally, the National Accounting Matrix including Envi-
ronmental Accounts (NAMEA) have been developed by Statistics Netherlands and adopted
by Eurostat. It should be noted that NAMWA is not a different framework; rather it is an
alternative presentation of the information contained in the supply and use tables presented
in figure II.3.
1. Spatial dimension
2.84. The choice of the spatial reference for the compilation of the accounts ultimately
depends on the objectives of the analysis. As previously mentioned, the compilation of
national water accounts is important for designing and evaluating macroeconomic water
policy. However, it is often more appropriate to use a finer spatial reference in order to reflect
The framework of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 37
Figure II.3
The System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water framework
Assets
by ISIC
Economic assets,
in particular assets
related to water
(e.g., infrastructures
Opening stocks Water resources assets
for the storage,
exploitation,
distribution and
treatment of water)
Households Rest of
Industries + +
and Government the world
Output of products
System of National
(including those
Accounts (SNA)
related to distribution, Imports
supply table
treatment and
(monetary units)
disposal of water)
Supply of distributed
water to other industries Imports
and households
Supply table
(physical units)
Supply of return Supply of return
flows to the flows to the Return flows
environment environment
Emission accounts
Supply of pollutants Supply of pollutants
(monetary,
to the environment to the environment
physical units)
Use of distributed
Use of
water (within Exports
distributed water
the economy)
Use table
(physical units)
Abstraction of water Own final consumption
Water abstraction,
resources (from of water (from
depletion/degradation
the environment) the environment)
Emission accounts
Treatment Treatment
(monetary,
of pollutants of pollutants
physical units)
+ +
Other changes in volume
Other changes in volume
(e.g., precipitation,
Other changes in assets and holding gains (losses)
evapotranspiration,
on economic assets
inflows, outflows)
SNA accounts
= =
Economic assets, Water resources, Physical/monetary
Closing stocks
closing stocks closing stocks acccounts
38 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
better spatial differences in water use, supply, and pressure on water resources and to make
decisions on the allocation of water between different users.
2.85. The water accounting framework can, in principle, be compiled at any level of geo-
graphical disaggregation of a territory. At the subnational level, the options are usually to
compile the accounts at the level of administrative regions, river basins or accounting catch-
ments.
2.86. An administrative region is a geographical area designated by the provincial govern-
ment for administrative purposes. Administrative regions are usually responsible for certain
economic policies within their jurisdiction, and regional economic accounts are usually com-
piled for administrative regions.
2.87. A river basin is a naturally defined region which is drained by a river or stream. It is
internationally recognized that the river basin is the most appropriate unit of reference for
IWRM (see, for example, Agenda 2126 and the previously mentioned European Union Water
Framework Directive). In particular, the Directive requires member States to formulate a river
basin management plan for each river basin district27 within their territory, and in the case
of an international river basin district, member States must ensure coordination with other
member States or third countries with the aim of producing a single international river basin
plan. Water management can in fact be pursued more effectively at the river basin level since
all water resources within a river basin are inextricably linked to each other in terms of both
quantity and quality. In this way, managers are able to gain a more complete understanding
of overall conditions in an area and the factors which affect those conditions. For example,
whereas emissions from a sewage treatment plant might be reduced significantly, the local
river and groundwater may still suffer adverse effects if other factors in the river basin, such
as polluted run-off from upstream emissions, go unaddressed.
2.88. As there are often large spatial differences in terms of the availability and use of water
resources between the different river basins of a country, especially in “water stressed” coun-
tries, the use of national averages is not always sufficient for making sound policy decisions at
the local level. Policy analyses for each main national “basin area” (a homogeneous basin area
formed by the association of contiguous river basins) are generally required. In addition, the
compilation of the accounts by local basin data providers for their water management needs
is generally essential for sustaining their involvement in the water accounting process.
2.89. Increasingly, river basin agencies have been established in countries; they are usually
governmental bodies endowed with their own resources and entrusted with looking after all
issues (economic, hydrological and social) related to water. They are often responsible, within
a clear legal and participatory framework, for collecting taxes and fees on water abstraction
and discharge and for making decisions on water allocation. To support their decisions, they
often collect physical and monetary data related to water resources. For instance, the Water
Framework Directive requires the establishment of competent authorities in river basin dis-
tricts and these are responsible for the implementation of the directive.
2.90. While the compilation of physical water accounts at the river basin level can be eas-
ily undertaken, as river basin agencies generally collect physical data at the river basin level,
the compilation of monetary water accounts at the river basin level requires extra work to
reconcile the spatial reference with economic information, such as output and value added,
which is available only at the administrative region level. Techniques to allocate economic
data to river basins often involve the allocation of economic accounts at the administrative
region level to the river basin on the basis of other socio-economic data.
2.91. Depending on the characteristics of the administrative regions and river basins in a
country, it may be useful to define regions for the compilation of water accounts for which
both economic and physical data are more easily available. Such regions are referred to here as
accounting catchments; they would be composed of river basins or sub-basins and would be
sufficiently large for economic information to be available. An accounting catchment could
consist, for example, of an administrative region and be composed of several river basins, or
it could be composed of several administrative regions to cover an entire river basin.
2. Temporal dimension
2.92. The temporal reference of economic data generally differs from that of hydrological
data: hydrological data generally refer to the hydrological year, a 12‑month period during
which the overall changes in storage are minimal and carry-over is reduced to a minimum;28
economic data, in particular accounting data, refer to the accounting year. It is imperative
that the hydrological and economic data used in the accounts refer to the same temporal
reference. Moreover, it is recommended that the reference period for the compilation of the
accounts be the same 12-month accounting period as that of the national accounts.
2.93. Yearly accounts often hide potential seasonal variability of water use and supply as
well as of availability of water resources in the environment. Ideally, quarterly water accounts
would be useful in the analysis of intra-annual variations. However, they are very data-
demanding and thus are often not considered a feasible option.
2.94. The choice of the frequency of the compilation of the accounts depends on the avail-
ability of data and the type of analysis. Annual accounts provide detailed information on
water resources and their use, and enable a detailed time series analysis. However, there may
be cases where compiling annual accounts on water use may not provide significant informa-
tion: the inter-annual variability may not be greater than the variability of the estimation
procedure. Moreover, an increase in those water uses which depend heavily on climatic vari-
ations, such as agriculture, may be interpreted as a structural change in water use, while in
reality the increase may be just a short-term one that occurs in response to a climatic change.
An alternative could be the compilation of accounts on water use every three or five years,
which would enable a sufficiently complete analysis of the water use trend.29
2.95. To reflect the long-term hydrological cycle (longer than a year), “budgetary” accounts
could be compiled. These accounts combine average data on water resources (budgetary asset
accounts) with actual annual information on water use. Budgetary asset accounts refer to an
average year in a series of years of long enough duration to be stable (20 or 30 years) and pro-
vide information on the average annual water availability in the environment. These accounts
could also be supplemented with accounts for a particular year, such as a dry year, which
would describe the worst condition of the natural water system. Annual water use accounts
describe the water use of the economy in a particular year. Combining hydrological informa-
tion on annual averages with economic information on water use for a specific year can be
justified because, while the variability of water resources is pseudocyclical and their average
28 For details of this definition, see International Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed., UNESCO/WMO, 1992.
A more recent version is available from http://www.cig.ensmp.fr/~hubert/glu/aglo.htm.
29 Jean Margat, ed., Les Ressources en Eau, Manuels et Méthodes, No. 28 (Rome, Food and Agriculture
Organization of the United Nations, and Orléans, France, Bureau de Recherches Géologiques et
Minières, 1996).
40 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
is relatively stable in the long term and in a given climatic situation (and it often forms the
reference for the assessment of water resources), water use tends to change over the years due,
for example, to an expanding population size and changes in the structure of the economy.
Therefore, the combination of these two types of information would enable analysis of the
natural water supply in relation to the evolution of human water demand.30
30 Ibid.
41
Chapter III
Physical water supply and use tables
A. Introduction
3.1. Physical water supply and use tables describe water flows in physical units within the
economy and between the environment and the economy. These accounts follow water from
its initial abstraction from the environment by the economy and its supply and use within the
economy to its final discharge back into the environment, with all entries being expressed in
quantitative terms. Physical supply and use tables have the same structure as their monetary
counterparts compiled as part of the standard national accounts. Chapter V presents mon-
etary tables as well as hybrid supply and use tables, in which physical and monetary informa-
tion is presented side by side. Organizing physical information, using the same framework as
the monetary accounts, is one of the characteristic features of SEEA-Water.
3.2. The compilation of the physical water supply and use tables enables (a) assessment
and monitoring of the pressure on water quantities that is exerted by the economy; (b) the
identification of the economic agents responsible for the abstraction and discharge of water
into the environment; and (c) the evaluation of alternative options for reducing the pressure
on water. Indicators of water use intensity and productivity can be calculated in combination
with monetary information on the value added.
3.3. The objective of this chapter is to provide a comprehensive overview of physical sup-
ply and use tables. Section B of this chapter introduces the distinctions among flows from
the environment to the economy (abstraction), flows within the economy (supply and use of
water between two economic units) and flows from the economy back into the environment
(returns). These distinctions are used to construct physical water supply and use tables and
to demonstrate the basic accounting rules described in section C. Section C also presents the
standard physical supply and use tables that countries are encouraged to compile and the
supplementary tables which further disaggregate items of the standard tables and may be of
interest for specific analyses and policies.
B. Types of flow
3.4. When constructing a supply and use table for water resources, SEEA-Water implicitly
takes the perspective of the economy as it describes the interactions between the environment
and the economy. SEEA-Water describes (a) flows from the environment to the economy;
(b) flows within the economy; and (c) flows from the economy to the environment, as depicted
in figure III.1. It should be noted that flows within the environment are described in the asset
accounts in chapter VI.
3.5. For each type of flow, the origin of the flow (supply) and its destination (use) are clearly
identified. The supply and use tables are constructed for each type of flow in such a way that
the basic accounting rule, that is, supply equals use, is satisfied.
42 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Figure III.1
Flows in the physical supply and use tables
Sea Sea
Figure III.2
Detailed description of physical water flows within the economy
Flows from
the economy
into the
environment
(dashed line) Inland water resource system and other sources
44 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
3.13. During the process of distributing water (between a point of abstraction and a point
of use or between points of use and reuse of water), there may be losses of water.31 Such losses
may be caused by a number of factors: evaporation when water is distributed through open
channels; leakages when water leaks from pipes into the ground; and illegal tapping when
water is illegally diverted from the distribution network. In addition, when losses during dis-
tribution are computed as the difference between the amount of water supplied and received,
there may also be errors in meter readings, malfunctioning meters, theft, etc. In the supply
and use tables, the supply of water within the economy is recorded net of losses during the
distribution process. Furthermore, the losses during distribution are recorded as return flows
when they are due to leakages and as water consumption in all other cases.32
3.14. The use table describing the flows within the economy shows the destination of these
flows: water can be used by industries to produce other goods and services (intermediate
consumption), by households for their own use (final consumption) and by the rest of the
world (export). Other economic uses of water, that is, change in inventories, are neglected,
since these are usually negligible in view of the fact that water is a bulky commodity.
3.15. The basic SNA supply and use identity is satisfied also for flows of water within the
economy, as the total water supplied by the national economy plus imports equals the sum
of water uses for intermediate consumption, final consumption and export.
31 It should be noted that the term “water loss” may have a different meaning in different contexts. Here,
the term refers to a loss of water from the economic system. Part of such losses can be seen as an actual
resource from the point of view of the inland water resource system, since water, by returning to water
resources, becomes available for use again.
32 See sect. C.1 for further details.
Physical water supply and use tables 45
tion on water use: the total water intake of an economic unit is the result of direct water
abstraction (flow from the environment to the economy) and water received from other
economic units (flow within the economy). Similarly, the supply table is obtained by merg-
ing information on the two types of water flow that leave an economic unit: one destined for
other economic units (flow within the economy) and the other destined for the environment
(flow from the economy into the environment).
3.21. Physical supply and use tables can be compiled at various levels of detail, depending
on the policy concern of a country and the availability of data. A simplified standard supply
and use table, which countries are encouraged to compile, contains basic information on the
supply and use of water and affords an overview of water flows. In addition, all the informa-
tion contained in the table is balanced, that is, supply equals use. As a second step, a more
detailed supply and use table can be compiled, with a more detailed breakdown of items in
the simplified supply and use table.
3.27. Water is abstracted either to be used by the same economic unit which abstracts it,
abstraction for own use, or to be supplied, possibly after some treatment, to other economic
units, abstraction for distribution. As mentioned previously, most of the water is abstracted
for distribution under ISIC division 36, water collection, treatment and supply; however,
there may be other industries which abstract and supply water as a secondary activity.
3.28. Abstraction from water sources includes abstraction from inland water resources as
well as abstraction of sea water and the direct collection of precipitation for production and
consumption activities. Water is abstracted from the sea generally for cooling purposes (the
corresponding wastewater flow is normally returned to the original source of water, that is, the
sea or ocean) or for desalination processes. Desalinated water could be returned to the inland
water resource and constitute a resource. A typical example of the collection of precipitation
is the harvesting of rainwater from roofs by households.
3.29. Abstraction from soil water includes water use in rain-fed agriculture, which is com-
puted as the amount of precipitation that falls onto agricultural fields. The excess of water,
that is, the part that is not used by the crop, is recorded as a return flow into the environment
from rain-fed agriculture. It is important to record this flow for several reasons: one reason is
that it shows the relative contribution of rain-fed and irrigated agriculture to food production.
In view of the importance of rain-fed agriculture worldwide (more than 60 per cent of all
food production in the world is produced under rain-fed conditions), such information can be
used to assess the efficiency of rain-fed agriculture, that is, to determine the crop production
per volume of water used, and to formulate water policies.
3.30. Within the economy, the use of water received from other economic units refers
to the amount of water that is delivered to an industry, household or the rest of the world
by another economic unit. Such water is usually delivered through mains, but other means
of transport are not excluded, such as artificial open channels. It also includes the flow of
wastewater to sewerage, which is identified separately along with reused water. The use of
water received from other economic units by the rest of the world corresponds to the export
of water. It is generally the industry under ISIC division 36 that exports water.
3.31. The total water use (row 3 in table III.1) of an industry is computed as the sum of the
amount of water directly abstracted (row 1 in the table) and the amount of water received
from other economic units (row 2 in the table). Although it might be perceived that water
abstracted for distribution is counted twice—first as a use when water is abstracted by the
distributing industry and second when it is delivered to the user—water abstracted for
distribution is a water use of the distributing industry even though that industry is not the
end-user of the water.
3.32. The supply of water to other economic units refers to the amount of water that is
supplied by one economic unit to another. The supply of water is recorded net of losses in
distribution. The supply to other economic units generally occurs through mains, but can
also occur through artificial open channels, trucks and other means. It should be noted that
the supply of water by the rest of the world corresponds to the import of water.
3.33. The supply and use of water to other economic units can be disaggregated into several
categories. However, in the standard tables only reused water and wastewater to “sewerage”
are explicitly identified in view of their importance in water conservation policies.
3.34. The concept of reused water is linked to that of wastewater. Wastewater is water that
is of no further immediate value with regard to the purpose for which it had been used or in
the pursuit of which it was produced, because of its quality, quantity or time of occurrence.
Wastewater can be discharged directly into the environment (in which case it is recorded as
a return flow), supplied to a treatment facility (under ISIC division 37) (recorded as waste
Physical water supply and use tables 47
Table III.1
Standard physical supply and use tables for water
7. Consumption (= 3 - 6)
water to “sewerage”) or supplied to another industry for further use (reused water). Table
III.1 calculates the total wastewater generated by an economic unit as the sum of the supply
of reused water, wastewater to sewerage and returns into the environment.
3.35. Reused water, defined as wastewater supplied to a user for further use with or without
prior treatment, excludes that water which is recycled within industrial sites. It is also com-
monly referred to as “reclaimed wastewater”. It is important to record this flow because the
reuse of water can alleviate the pressure on water resources by reducing direct abstraction
of water: for example, golf courses and landscaping alongside public roads can be watered
with (treated) wastewater instead of surface water or groundwater. Some industries, such as
power plants, can use reclaimed wastewater. A considerable volume of water is needed to
48 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
cool electricity-generating equipment; using wastewater for this purpose means that the
facility would not have to use higher-quality water that could be used more advantageously
somewhere else.
3.36. In order to avoid confusion, it should be noted that, once wastewater is discharged
into the environment, its abstraction downstream is not considered a reuse of water in the
accounting tables, but a new abstraction from the environment.
3.37. As previously mentioned, reused water excludes the recycling of water within the
same industry or establishment (on site). Although information on recycled water would
be very useful for the analysis of water use efficiency, generally it is not available; thus, the
simplified standard tables do not report it explicitly. However, a reduction in the total vol-
ume of water used while maintaining the same level of output can provide an indication of
an increase in the efficiency of water use, which, in turn, may be due to the use of recycled
water within an industry.
3.38. Within the economy, water can be exchanged between water producers and dis-
tributors (under ISIC division 36) before being effectively delivered to users. Such water
exchanges are referred to as intrasectoral sales. An example is when the distribution network
of one distributor/producer does not reach the water user and that network must then sell
water to another distributor in order for the water to be delivered to the intended user. Such
sales artificially increase the physical supply and use of water within the economy, but do
not influence the global (physical) balance of water within the environment, and thus they
are not recorded in the physical supply and use tables.
3.39. Total returns include water that is returned into the environment. Total returns can
be classified according to (a) the receiving media, that is, inland water resources (as specified
in the asset classification) and sea water, and (b) the type of water, such as treated water and
cooling water. The standard tables report only the breakdown according to the receiving
media in order to ensure that the links are maintained with the flows in the asset accounts.
More detailed tables can be compiled to show returns of different types of water.
3.40. The total water supply (row 6 in table III.1) is computed as the sum of the amount of
water supplied to other economic units (row 4 in the table) and the amount of water returned
to the environment (row 5 in the table).
3.41. Storage of water. It should be noted that water can be stored temporarily in the
economy, for example, in water towers and in closed cooling or heating circuits. Therefore,
when comparing the situation at the beginning and the end of the period, some changes in
inventories may occur. However, those changes are generally rather small (because water is
a bulky commodity and thus costly to store) in comparison with the other volumes of water;
therefore, the changes in inventory are not reported in the physical supply and use tables.
3.42. Table III.1 can be supplemented with information on the number of persons with
sustainable access to an improved water source and with access to improved sanitation
reported in supplementary tables, as presented in annex II. This information is particularly
important for the management of water resources and for the reduction of poverty: it is
used to monitor progress towards attainment of target 7.C of the Millennium Development
Goals, that is, to “halve, by 2015, the proportion of people without sustainable access to
safe drinking water and basic sanitation”. Presenting all water-related information, includ-
ing social information, in a common framework has the advantage of enabling consistent
analyses and scenario modelling. For example, analysis of the impact that investing in
water infrastructure would have on the number of people with access to improved water
sources can be undertaken easily if the information is organized according to the account-
ing framework.
Physical water supply and use tables 49
3.43. In order to gain a complete picture of the water flows within the economy, table III.1
can be supplemented with detailed information on the origin and destination of water flows
by identifying who is supplying water to whom. Table III.2 presents a matrix of transfers
within the economy. Each entry represents a water exchange from a supplier (by row) to a user
(by column). For example, the intersection of row ISIC division 37 with the column contain-
ing ISIC division 45, wholesale and retail trade and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles,
represents the amount of water that is supplied under ISIC division 37 to ISIC division 45,
which could use treated wastewater, for example, for washing cars.
Table III.2
Matrix of flows of water within the economy (physical units)
Industries 1-3
(by ISIC 5-33, 41-43
category)
35
36
37
38, 39, 45-99
Total
Households
2. Water consumption
3.44. The concept of water consumption gives an indication of the amount of water that is
lost by the economy during use, in the sense that the water has entered the economy but has
not returned to either water resources or the sea. This happens during use because part of the
water is incorporated into products, evaporated, transpired by plants or simply consumed by
households or livestock. The difference between the water use (row 3 in table III.1) and the
water supply (row 6 in the table) is referred to as water consumption. Water consumption
can be computed for each economic unit and for the whole economy. The concept of water
consumption that is used in SEEA-Water is consistent with the hydrological concept. It dif-
fers, however, from the concept of consumption that is used in the national accounts, which
instead refers to water use.
3.45. For the whole economy, the balance between water flows can be written as follows:
T otal abstraction + use of water received from other economic units = supply of water to other
economic units + total returns + water consumption
It should be noted that since the total water supply to other economic units equals the total
water use received from other economic units, the identity can be rewritten as follows:
Total abstraction = total returns + water consumption
3.46. Water consumption can include water that is stored, for example, in water towers, but
this quantity is usually very small because water is generally stored only for a short period
of time.
50 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
3.47. Water consumption computed for each industry gives an indication of the industry’s
water use efficiency. Since water supply does not equal water use by industry, water consump-
tion is computed as the difference between the use and supply by industry, using the following
formula:
ater consumption by industry i = total use of water by industry i – total supply of water by
W
industry i
3.48. From the perspective of the inland water resource system, discharges of water into the
sea should also be considered as lost water since this water, once in the sea, is not directly avail-
able for further use as it would be, by contrast, when discharged into a river, where discharged
water becomes a resource for downstream uses. The concept of “inland water consumption”
has been introduced in order to give an indication of the amount of water that is not returned
to the inland water system. Inland water consumption is thus calculated as follows:
Inland water consumption = water consumption + returns to other sources (e.g., sea water)
3.49. The concept of consumption can also be adapted to specific resources. For example,
the 2002 OECD/Eurostat joint questionnaire on inland waters used the concept of “fresh-
water consumption”, which takes into consideration water that is abstracted from freshwater
sources but discharged into non-freshwater sources.33
3.50. Since water consumption is calculated as the difference between water use and water
supply, the term may include flows that are very different in nature: for example, the part of
the losses in distribution which do not return to the water resources. For analytical purposes
it is useful to distinguish water consumption that results from evaporation and transpiration
or enters into products, as a result of the production process, from water “consumption” that
is the result of malfunctioning meters or illegal tapping.
3. Supplementary items in the physical supply and use tables for water
3.51. The standard physical supply and use table in table III.1 contains aggregate flows. In
practice, when compiling these accounts, a more detailed breakdown, both on the industry
side and on the type of water, is often necessary for making more detailed analyses. The level
of detail depends on the country’s priorities and the availability of data. Table III.3 presents
an example of the breakdown of water flows (shown in italics) which are useful for analytical
purposes, together with a numerical example.
3.52. In Table III.3, abstraction for own use is further disaggregated into the following uses:
• Hydroelectric power generation
• Irrigation water
• Mine water
• Urban run-off
• Cooling water
3.53. Water used for hydroelectric power generation consists of water used in generating
electricity at plants where the turbine generators are driven by falling water. Usually, such
water is directly abstracted by the power plant and returned immediately into the environ-
ment. It is important to record the amount of water used and discharged by a hydropower
facility, especially for allocation policies, as water used for the generation of hydroelectric
power may be in competition with other uses.
33 The desalination of sea water, where carried out, should, on the contrary, be counted as negative
consumption.
Physical water supply and use tables 51
3.54. Irrigation water consists of water which is artificially applied to land for agricul-
tural purposes.
3.55. Mine water is water used for the extraction of naturally occurring minerals, including
coal, mineral ore, petroleum and natural gas, and it includes water associated with quarrying,
dewatering, milling and other on-site activities carried out as part of mining operations. Mine
water use generally involves removal and displacement of water in the environment (during
dewatering processes) when the mine extends below the water table. It might be argued that
this should not be considered part of abstraction. However, it is important to record this
flow as it often results in the disposal of large volumes of water and the displacement of such
volumes could be damaging to the environment.
3.56. Urban run-off is defined as that portion of precipitation in urban areas that does not
naturally evaporate or percolate into the ground, but flows via overland flow, underflow, or
channels, or is piped into a defined surface water channel or a constructed infiltration facil-
ity. It is also referred to as “urban storm water”. It should be noted here that the term “urban
areas” may also include rural residential zones. When urban run-off is collected into the sew-
age system, it is recorded in the use table as an abstraction from other sources (in particular
from precipitation) under ISIC division 37; when it is discharged into the environment, it is
recorded in the supply table as a return flow.
3.57. It is important to record the collection and discharge of urban run-off for the fol-
lowing reasons: (a) for management purposes, in order to design policies aimed at reducing
the negative impacts of urban run-off on water resources, as urban run-off usually contains
relatively high concentrations of pollutants, including bacteria and viruses, solid waste and
toxic substances, such as heavy metals and petroleum-based compounds, which reach receiv-
ing waters; (b) for consistency with the monetary tables, because the value of corresponding
services (collection of urban run-off) is recorded in the economic table; and (c) for practical
reasons, in order to measure consistently the total supply and use of water under ISIC divi-
sion 37. Since urban run-off ultimately merges into the return flow from ISIC division 37 into
the environment, the total return of ISIC division 37 in the supply table would include urban
run-off in addition to the discharge of wastewater collected from industries and households.
3.58. Although separate estimates for urban run-off may be available in some countries,
these flows generally cannot be measured directly. What can be measured is the difference
between the volumes of wastewater discharged by economic units (industries and households)
into sewers and the volumes of wastewater leaving the sewers with or without treatment.
3.59. Cooling water is defined as water which is used to absorb and remove heat. Cooling
water has the potential not only to induce thermal pollution but also to emit pollutants that
are collected in the water during use, for example, when water is also used for rinsing in the
manufacture of basic metals.
3.60. It should be noted that in table III.3, abstraction for own use under ISIC division 36
(water collection, treatment and supply) represents part of the total abstraction for own inter-
nal use, such as the cleaning of pipes and backwashing filters. This water is then discharged
into the environment and is recorded as a return flow from ISIC division 36. In the numerical
example, ISIC division 36 abstracts a total of 428.7 million cubic metres of water, of which
23.0 million cubic metres are for own use and the rest is for distribution.
3.61. Returns to the environment (row 5 of table III.3) can also be further disaggregated
according to the type of water use. The following categories can be distinguished:
• Hydroelectric power generation
• Irrigation water
• Mine water
52 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
• Urban run-off
• Cooling water
• Losses in distribution owing to leakages
• Treated wastewater
3.62. It can be relatively straightforward to collect information on the returns of urban
run-off when a storm sewer system is in place and urban run-off is discharged separately from
wastewater. In other cases, when the discharge of ISIC division 37 combines urban run-off
with other wastewater discharges, estimates are necessary. In table III.3, the sewerage system
collects 100 million cubic metres of urban run-off, 99.7 per cent of which is discharged into
the environment.
3.63. In table III.3, 404.2 million cubic metres of water are abstracted from the environ-
ment by the industry ISIC division 35 (electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning supply), of
which 300 million cubic metres are used for hydroelectric power generation and 100 million
cubic metres for cooling purposes.
3.64. Losses in distribution, which are discussed in detail in the next section, are allocated to
the water supplier. In the numerical example of table III.3, the losses in distribution owing to
leakage occur in the water supply of ISIC division 36, water collection, treatment and supply.
Table III.3
Detailed physical water supply and use tablesa
The remaining part of the losses in distribution, which in the table corresponds to 0.5 million
cubic metres (row 7.a of table III.3), includes losses owing to evaporation and apparent losses
due to illegal use and malfunctioning meters.
3.65. In addition to the breakdowns shown in table III.1, it may be useful to identify
explicitly the supply of “desalinated water” (row 4.c of table III.3) for countries which rely
on water desalination as a source of fresh water. It is generally under ISIC division 36 that
water is desalinated and supplied within the economy. Other industries may also desalinate
sea water, but often it is for their own use.
3.66. Table III.4 shows the matrix of flows associated with table III.3. This numerical exam-
ple shows the origin and destination of the water flows within the economy. In particular,
it can be seen that ISIC division 37, sewerage, supplies reclaimed wastewater to ISIC divi-
sions 5-33 and 41-43, mining and quarrying, manufacturing, and construction (40.7 million
cubic metres) and to ISIC divisions 1-3, agriculture, forestry and fishing (2 million cubic
54 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Table III.4
Matrix of water flows within the economy (millions of cubic metres)
metres). In addition, agriculture, forestry and fishing also receive reused water from mining
and quarrying, manufacturing, and construction (10 million cubic metres).
4. Losses in distribution
3.67. Within the economy, water supply is recorded net of losses in distribution. Losses in
distribution are recorded in the tables as follows:
(a) The net supply plus the losses are shown in the amount abstracted from the envi-
ronment by the suppliers of water (typically ISIC division 36);
(b) The losses are allocated to the supplier of water but are not explicitly shown in
table III.1, although they are shown in the more detailed table III.3;
(c) Losses due to leakage are recorded in the return flows to the environment;
(d) Losses due to evaporation that occurs when, for example, water is distributed
through open channels are recorded as water consumption because the losses do
not return directly to water resources;
(e) Losses due to illegal tapping and meter malfunctioning are included under water
consumption of the supplier of water.
3.68. A supplementary table can be constructed to show explicitly the losses in distribution.
Table III.5 shows gross and net supplies of water within the economy as well as the losses in
distribution. The data are obtained by reorganizing entries in the physical supply and use
tables. Table III.5 enables the direct calculation of losses in distribution as a proportion of the
gross water supply, thus producing an indicator of the efficiency of the distribution network.
3.69. It should be noted that losses in distribution are generally calculated as the difference
between the quantity of water supplied and that received. In this case, losses in distribution
include not only real losses of water (due to evaporation and leakage) but also apparent losses,
which consist of unauthorized water use, such as theft or illegal use, and all the inaccuracies
associated with production and customer metering.
Physical water supply and use tables 55
Table III.5
Supplementary table of losses in distribution (millions of cubic metres)
1. (Net) supply of water to other economic units 17.9 127.6 5.6 379.6 42.7 49.1 622.5 235.5 858.0
2. Losses in distribution (= 2.a + 2.b) 0 0 0 25.0 0 0 25.0 0 25.0
2.a. Leakages 0 0 0 24.5 0 0 24.5 0 24.5
2.b. Other (e.g., evaporation, apparent losses) 0 0 0 0.5 0 0 0.5 0 0.5
3. Gross supply within the economy (= 1 + 2) 17.9 127.6 5.6 404.6 42.7 49.1 647.5 235.5 883.0
Source: SEEA-Water-land database.
3.70. There are cases where illegal tapping, that is, the illegal removal of water from the
distribution network, is sufficiently significant in magnitude not only to affect the efficiency
of the water distribution network but also, at times, to cause major problems within the
network, such as enabling contaminants to enter into the mains via back-siphonage. Specific
analyses may be required to determine the extent of this phenomenon.
3.71. For countries where illegal tapping is significant, it may be useful to identify the units
(households or industries) responsible for illegally connecting to the distribution network, as
well as the amount of water used by such units. This can easily be shown as a supplementary
item in the table. This information would be very useful for policy purposes as it provides
a more accurate indication of the actual level of water use by industries and households.
When linked to the monetary accounts, the information could be used in formulating pric-
ing policies.
3.72. Consistent with the 2008 SNA, where illegal tapping is not considered to be a transac-
tion (use) in the supply and use tables, SEEA-Water does not explicitly record such activities
in its standard tables.
57
Chapter IV
Water emission accounts
A. Introduction
4.1. Emissions into water can constitute a major environmental problem and cause the qual-
ity of bodies of water to deteriorate. Different types of pollutants generated during production
and consumption activities are discharged into bodies of water. Some of the pollutants emit-
ted into water resources are highly toxic and thus negatively affect the quality of the receiving
body of water and ultimately human health. Similarly, other substances, such as nitrogen and
phosphorus, can lead to eutrophication, or organic substances can have negative effects on the
oxygen balance, thus adversely affecting the ecological status of the receiving body of water.
4.2. Emission accounts describe the flows of pollutants added to wastewater as a result of
production and consumption, and flowing into water resources directly or indirectly through
the sewage network. They measure the pressure on the environment caused by human activi-
ties by presenting information on those activities responsible for the emissions, the types and
amount of pollutants added to wastewater as well as the destination of the emissions, such
as water resources and the sea. Emission accounts form a useful tool for designing economic
instruments, including new regulations aimed at reducing emissions into water. When ana-
lysed in conjunction with the technology in place to reduce emissions and treat wastewater,
such accounts can be used in impact studies of new technologies.
4.3. Section B presents some basic concepts used in the compilation of emission accounts
and defines their scope and coverage. Section C describes in detail the standard tables for the
compilation of the emission accounts.
34 European Commission, Guidance Document for EPER Implementation (Luxembourg, Office for Offi-
cial Publications of the European Communities, 2000). Available from http://eper.cec.eu.int/eper/
documents/guidance%5Fhtml, or http://www.eper.cec.eu.int/eper/documents/eper_en.pdf.
35 In the European context, emissions to air, land and water are covered, for example, in Council Direc-
tive 96/61/EC of 24 September 1996, concerning integrated pollution prevention and control, and in
Regulation (EC) No. 166/2006 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 January 2006,
concerning the establishment of the European Pollutant Release and Transfer Register.
58 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
4.5. Emission accounts record the amount of pollutants added to water by an economic
activity during a reference period (generally an accounting year); they are expressed in terms
of weight (kilograms or tons), depending on the pollutant under consideration. They describe,
in terms of pollutants, the part of the water flows in the physical supply and use tables of
chapter III that are destined for the environment either directly or through a treatment
plant. Emission accounts cover (a) pollutants added to wastewater and collected in the sewer-
age network; (b) pollutants added to wastewater discharged directly into water bodies; and
(c) selected non-point source emissions, namely, emissions from urban run-off and agricul-
ture. The emission accounts thus furnish descriptions, in terms of pollutants resulting from
production and consumption, of the wastewater flows discussed in chapter III. Table IV.1
affords an overview of the types of emission included in the emission accounts.
Table IV.1
Scope of emission accounts
Include Exclude
2. Water pollutants
4.10. Before starting the compilation of emission accounts, a list of pollutants has to be
defined. Most often, the list of pollutants is based on the country’s environmental concerns as
well as its national legislation on water and, where applicable, international agreements. For
example, in the case of countries in the European Union, the previously mentioned European
Union Water Framework Directive supplies, inter alia, an indicative list of pollutants, which
is reported in box IV.1, as well a list of priority substances.36
Box IV.1
Indicative list of the main pollutants in the European Union
1. Organohalogen compounds and substances which may form such compounds in an aquatic
environment.
2. Organophosphorous compounds.
3. Organotin compounds.
4. Substances and preparations, or their breakdown products, which have been proven to possess
carcinogenic or mutagenic properties or properties which may affect steroidogenic, thyroid,
reproductive or other endocrine-related functions in or via the aquatic environment.
5. Persistent hydrocarbons and persistent and bioaccumulable organic toxic substances.
6. Cyanides.
7. Metals and their compounds.
8. Arsenic and its compounds. Source: European Parliament and
9. Biocides and plant protection products. Council, Directive 2000/60/EC, Official
Journal of the European Commu-
10. Materials in suspension. nities 22/12/2000, annex VIII, 22 De-
11. Substances which contribute to eutrophication (in particular, nitrates and phosphates). cember 2000. Available from http://
europa.eu.int/comm/environment/
12. Substances which have an unfavourable influence on the oxygen balance and can be measured water/water-framework /index _
using parameters, such as biochemical oxygen demand and chemical oxygen demand. en.html.
36 The list of priority substances, which was established by Decision No. 2455/2001/EC of the European
Parliament and of the Council on 20 November 2001, lists 33 substances or groups of substances
which have been shown to be of major concern for European waters.
60 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Figure IV.1
Wastewater and associated pollutant pathway
Sewerage
Source: Dominique Preux and Benoît
Fribourg-Blanc, “Overview of emissions
to water: existing data collections”, paper
prepared for the Intersecretariat Working
Group on Environment Statistics, Work
Session on Water Statistics, Vienna, 20-22
June 2005. Available from http://unstats.
un.org/unsd/environment/envpdf/pap_ Water resources and sea
wasess4b1france.pdf.
industries and the rest of the world. The wastewater and associated pollutants are dis-
charged directly into the environment, with or without self-treatment, or supplied to a
wastewater treatment plant.
4.12. The fact that the discharge of pollutants into the environment can occur in one or
two steps (directly or through a treatment plant, ISIC division 37) leads to a distinction
between gross and net emissions. “Gross emissions” are the pollutants added to water by an
activity, assessed at the point where the wastewater leaves the activity’s site (or the dwelling,
in the case of households). “Net emissions” (or “final emissions”) correspond to the pollutants
discharged into water resources. When wastewater is discharged directly into a body of water,
gross and net emissions coincide. However, in practice, an economic activity may discharge
part of its wastewater directly into water resources, thus releasing the pollutants directly, and
thereafter supply the rest to a wastewater treatment plant which, after treating it, discharges
the “treated” wastewater into the environment. Since treated wastewater may still contain
traces of the pollutant generated by the economic activity, the net emissions of the economic
unit would correspond to the sum of the directly released pollutants into water resources and
that indirectly released through wastewater treatment plants.
4.13. For the whole economy, the difference between gross and net emission totals would
correspond to the pollution removed by purification processes, including wastewater treat-
ment plants. The distinction between gross and net emissions is not applicable for non-point
pollution, such as that which results from agriculture.
4.14. In the calculation of the net emissions, the release of pollutants by the sewerage indus-
try (ISIC division 37) has to be reallocated to the economic unit responsible for the discharge
in the first place. This is often difficult to calculate, because industry ISIC division 37 treats
aggregated flows of wastewater coming from diverse users of the sewage system. In general,
the allocation of emissions in the return flow of ISIC division 37 to the economic unit origi-
nally responsible for generating that pollution is obtained by applying global abatement rates
of the treatment plant to every emission collected by the treatment plant.
4.15. The exchange of pollutants with the rest of the world (import and export) covers only
exchanges of pollutants associated with the discharge of wastewater from one economy to a
wastewater treatment facility (ISIC division 37) of another economy. For example, the import
of a pollutant corresponds to the import of wastewater from the rest of the world with the aim
of discharging it, possibly after treatment, within the national territory. Emission accounts
Water emission accounts 61
do not include “imports” and “exports” of pollutants through natural flows, for example,
the pollutant content of rivers crossing country borders or flowing to the open sea. These are
covered in the quality accounts in chapter VII.
C. Emission accounts
4.16. As discussed in section B, the emission accounts record the pollution added to water
by an economic unit and not the total pollution discharged with wastewater. This implies
that, if an industry abstracts (or receives) 1 cubic metre of water which already contains
x kg of a pollutant and returns to a river 1 cubic metre of wastewater containing y kg of the
same pollutant, even though the total discharge of the pollutant into the river is y kg, only
(y - x) kg is recorded, as it represents the quantity of pollution generated by the industry.
This has several implications for the measurement of emissions: the level of emissions is
not that of the pollutants contained in the outgoing flows of water, but is measured by
calculating the difference between the pollutant content of the incoming and outgoing
flows. Although the pollutant content of drinking water should normally be negligible, the
pollutant content of the incoming water for some other uses, such as cooling, or process
water, can be significant.
4.17. Pollution is generally measured in terms of the quantity of a measured determinand
(see, for example, the list of pollutants shown in box IV.1) released during a certain period.
It can be expressed either directly in terms of the quantity of a determinand (for example,
in kilograms of dissolved oxygen) or in an arbitrary unit that represents one or more deter-
minands, such as the population equivalent,37 which includes biochemical oxygen demand
(BOD), nitrogen, phosphorus and suspended solids.
4.18. Information on emissions into water is organized in the accounts according to table
IV.2. In order to avoid double counting the emissions by ISIC division 37, sewerage, emission
accounts comprise two tables: the first, part A, starts with a description of the gross emis-
sions by industry. In this table, only the pollutant content of the urban run-off collected and
discharged by ISIC division 37 is recorded under the ISIC division 37 column, which is the
economic activity responsible for its collection and discharge.
4.19. The second part of the table of the emission accounts, part B, records the emissions
into water by ISIC division 37. It allows for the reallocation of emissions of ISIC division 37
to the industries generating them in the first place, thus enabling the calculation of net emis-
sions. Table IV.2, part A (gross and net emissions), reports the following items:
(a) The total amount of a pollutant generated by an economic unit (gross emissions)
measured at the point of discharge (row 1). This information is disaggregated into
the following categories:
(i) The quantity of pollutant that is released directly into water, that is, the
pollutant is contained in the direct discharge of wastewater into the environ-
ment (row 1.a);
(ii) The quantity of pollutant that is released into the sewer system (row 1.b). It
should be noted that the pollutant content of the urban run-off collected by
ISIC division 37 is recorded in this row;
37 According to the OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms, one population equivalent refers to the amount of
oxygen-demanding substances whose oxygen consumption during biodegradation equals the average
oxygen demand of the wastewater produced by one person. Here, it refers to an organic biodegradable
load (having a BOD5) of 60 grams of oxygen per day.
62 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
(b) The indirect emissions into the environment made by each industry through ISIC
division 37 (row 2). These emissions can be calculated once the emissions into
water by ISIC division 37 are identified in part B of table IV.2;
(c) The net emissions by industry (row 3) are obtained by summing the direct and
indirect emissions.
4.20. The direct emissions into water are further disaggregated according to whether waste-
water has undergone on-site treatment (rows 1.a.1 and 1.a.2 of table IV.2)38 and/or according
to the receiving media (rows 1.a.i and 1.a.ii), that is, water resources and the sea. Additional
information can be presented in supplementary tables to further disaggregate emissions
according to the type of receiving media, such as surface water or groundwater.
4.21. Part B (emissions by ISIC division 37) of table IV.2 presents detailed information on the
emissions into water by ISIC division 37, sewerage, and enables the calculation of net emissions by
various industries. In particular, the second part of table IV.2 presents the following information:
(a) The total amount of pollutant released by ISIC division 37, sewerage (row 4),
which is disaggregated as follows:
(i) The volume of pollutants that is released directly into water after having
undergone treatment (row 4.a);
(ii) The volume of pollutants that is released directly into water without treat-
ment (row 4.b), for example, in discharges of raw sewage through a sewage-
collecting system.
4.22. Emissions by ISIC division 37 are disaggregated according to the receiving media. Addi-
tional information can be presented in supplementary tables to further disaggregate emissions by
ISIC division 37, according to the type of receiving media, such as surface water or groundwater.
4.23. In order to calculate net emissions by industry, the emissions into water by ISIC
division 37 (row 4 of table IV.2) have to be reallocated to the industry responsible for the
discharge in the first place. Row 2 of table IV.2 shows explicitly the reallocation of emissions
from ISIC division 37 to the various industries. In this example, the emissions by ISIC divi-
sion 37 have been reallocated applying a global abatement rate of 67 per cent39 to the pol-
lutant release of each industry into the sewage network (row 1.b of table IV.2). It should be
noted that, in this numerical example, it is assumed that urban run-off is discharged without
treatment (see also table III.3); hence, for ISIC division 37, the figures in rows 2 and 4.b are
the same. Net emissions (row 3 of table IV.2) are calculated by adding the direct emissions
by industry (row 1.a) and the reallocation of emissions by ISIC division 37 (row 2).
4.24. When information is available, emissions from wastewater treatment plants could be
further disaggregated in table IV.2 according to the type of treatment process. Three types of
treatment processes are identified by the UNSD/UNEP questionnaire, namely, mechanical,
biological and advanced, and by the OECD/Eurostat joint questionnaires: namely, primary,
secondary and tertiary.
38 Note that it would be useful to have data on the amount of pollutant before the on-site treatment
and after treatment in order to compute the “depollution” efficiency of an industry. However, since it
is not mandatory to report emissions to an on-site facility in the emission registers for national poli-
cies, they are not included in the tables. (See European Commission, Guidance Document for EPER
Implementation (Luxembourg, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 2000),
annex 2, p. 77.)
39 In this example, the global abatement rate is obtained by dividing the pollutants removed by ISIC
division 37 (row 1.b-row 4) by the pollutant received by ISIC division 37 (row 1.b). This corresponds
to the equation: (16 878.0 – 5 594.8)/16 878.0 = 0.67.
Water emission accounts 63
Table IV.2
Emission accounts
1. Gross emissions (= 1.a + 1.b) 3 150.2 5 047.4 7 405.1 1 851.0 498.5a 1 973.8 19 925.9 11 663.6 31 589.5
1.a. Direct emissions to water
(= 1.a.1 + 1.a.2 = 1.a.i + 1.a.ii) 2 470.0 390.1 7 313.2 1 797.8 0.0 27.7 11 998.7 2 712.7 14 711.5
1.a.1. Without treatment 2 470.0 257.4 7 313.2 1 797.8 7.9 11 846.2 1 865.0 13 711.3
1.a.2. After on-site treatment 132.7 0.0 0.0 19.8 152.5 847.7 1 000.2
1.a.i. To inland water resources 2 470.0 311.8 5 484.9 1 797.8 27.7 10 092.2 2 599.7 12 691.9
1.a.ii. To the sea 0.0 78.3 1 828.3 0.0 0.0 1 906.6 113.0 2 019.6
1.b. To sewerage (ISIC 37) 680.2 4 657.3 92.0 53.2 498.5 1 946.0 7 927.2 8 950.9 16 878.0
2. Reallocation of emissions by ISIC 37 213.6 1 403.3 66.8 16.7 498.5 585.9 2 784.7 2 810.1 5 594.8
3. Net emissions (= 1.a + 2) 2 683.6 1 793.3 7 380.0 1 814.5 498.5 613.6 14 783.5 5 522.8 20 306.3
a Corresponds to the pollutant content of the urban run-off collected by sewerage. In this numerical example, urban run-off is collected and discharged without treat-
ment; thus, gross and net emissions coincide for ISIC division 37.
4.25. For policy purposes, it may be useful to record in supplementary tables additional
information, such as the pollutant content and volume of sludge generated by ISIC division 37
and the number of people with access to improved sanitation. Annex II furnishes an example
of a supplementary table to the emission accounts.
4.26. In some countries, legislation regulates the generation and disposal of sewage sludge.
Such legislation requires the collection of information on sludge production, usually its dry
weight, depending on the method of water treatment and sludge treatment, such as diges-
tion or filter-pressing, because the concentration of dry solids can vary considerably, as can
the pollutant content of the sludge. For European countries, for example, the “sewage sludge
directive”40 regulates the generation and use of sewage sludge in order to prevent harmful
effects on soil, vegetation, animals and people. The directive also encourages the use of sludge.
4.27. During wastewater treatment, solids are separated from water and they are accumu-
lated as sewage sludge. Owing to the physical-chemical processes involved in the treatment, the
40 European Parliament and Council Directive 86/278/EEC of 18 June 1986 on the protection of the
environment, and in particular of the soil, when sewage sludge is used in agriculture, Official Jour-
nal L 181, 04/07/1986 P. 0006-0012. Available from http://europa.eu.int/eur-lex/lex/LexUriServ/
LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:31986L0278:EN:HTML.
64 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
sludge tends to concentrate heavy metals and poorly biodegradable trace organic compounds as
well as potentially pathogenic organisms (viruses and bacteria), if they are present, in the waste-
water. Yet sludge can be rich in nutrients, such as nitrogen and phosphorous, and it may contain
valuable organic matter that is useful for replenishing depleted soils or those subject to erosion.
4.28. The previously mentioned target of the Millennium Development Goals reporting the
number of people with access to improved sanitation (target 7.C) is an indicator of a country’s
ability to prevent damage to human and environmental health originating from wastewater
discharge by avoiding, for example, the spread of excreta-related diseases and by reducing the
pollution of water resources. The indicator is based on the distinction between improved and
unimproved sanitation. Improved sanitation technologies consist of connection to a public
sewer, connection to a septic system, pour-flush latrines and ventilated improved pit latrines.
Unimproved sanitation technologies consist of service or bucket latrines, where excrement is
removed manually, public latrines and latrines with an open pit.41 Presentation of information on
this indicator together with the accounts facilitates integrated analyses of emissions into water.
1. Urban run-off
4.29. The collection and discharge of urban run-off is recorded in terms of both volume
(in the physical supply and use tables) and pollutant load (in the emission accounts). This is
because urban run-off is highly polluted and there is increasing awareness of the potential
danger of discharging it into the environment without treatment. Urban run-off usually
contains a great deal of litter and organic and bacterial wastes as well as chemicals, such as
oil, antifreeze, detergent, pesticide and other pollutants, that wash down from driveways,
backyards, parking lots and streets, and are usually collected through storm sewers (drains
usually at street corners or at low points on the sides of roads).
4.30. Even though the pollution content of urban run-off is the result of “diffuse” pollution
and the run-off can often have natural origins (for example, leaves washed into gutters can
create an organic form of pollution), its emissions into water are allocated to ISIC division 37,
sewerage, since this is the economic unit responsible for its collection and discharge.
4.31. It should be noted that, when urban run-off is collected in the same sewer system that
collects domestic and commercial wastewater (sanitary sewers), it may be difficult to measure
the amount of pollutant which pertains specifically to urban run-off.
41 World Health Organization and United Nations Children’s Fund Water Supply and Sanitation Col-
laborative Council, Global Water Supply and Sanitation Assessment, 2000 Report (Geneva, WHO, and
New York, UNICEF), pp. 77-78.
65
Chapter V
Hybrid and economic accounts
for activities and products related
to water
A. Introduction
5.1. The formulation and evaluation of a wide range of policies related to water, such as
those aimed at achieving efficient allocation of water and the recovery of the costs of water
services, are at the heart of water management. The objective of this chapter is to study the
economy of water, that is, to describe in monetary terms the supply and use of water-related
products and to identify (a) the costs associated with the production of these products; (b) the
income generated by their production; (c) the investment in water-related infrastructure and
the costs to maintain that infrastructure; and (d) the fees paid by the users for water-related ser-
vices, as well as the subsidies received. The economic instruments for managing water, namely,
taxes on the use of the resource and permits to access it, are also discussed in this chapter.
5.2. The starting point for studying the economy of water involves presenting the conven-
tional national accounts together with physical information on water abstraction, namely, its
supply and use within the economy, and the discharge of wastewater and pollutants into the
environment. These accounts are referred to as “hybrid accounts”, where the term “hybrid”
refers to the combination of different types of units of measurement in the same accounts.
The presentation of physical and monetary information in the same accounts enables the
derivation of consistent indicators for evaluating the impact on water resources of changes in
the economy, such as changes in economic structure and in interest rates. Using the hybrid
accounts in economic models makes possible the analysis of potential trade-offs between
alternative water policies and economic strategies. The structure of the hybrid accounts is
presented in section B.
5.3. Economic accounts expand the hybrid accounts for (a) water-related activities car-
ried out for own use, that is, when industries and households abstract water for their own
use, or treat the wastewater they generate; and (b) government expenditures for water-related
services, such as the formulation and administration of government policy and the setting
and enforcing of public standards. Even though the value of these activities is likely to be
small compared with other activities, the full extent of national expenditures on water can
be understood only when all these expenditures are accounted for. Economic accounts for
water-related activities carried out for own use and for government expenditures on water-
related services are discussed in section C.
5.4. Even though they are not explicitly discussed in SEEA-Water, complete stock accounts,
in physical and monetary units, for water-related infrastructure can be compiled by disaggre-
gating the relevant information from the standard 2008 SNA accounts for produced assets.
The standard tables furnish information only on the stocks of water-related infrastructure,
66 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
such as pumps and dams, as an example of the form of such accounts. Stock accounts for
water-related infrastructure, which are already part of the 2008 SNA, often require additional
data sources and the undertaking of data-collection activities to identify separately those
assets in monetary terms in the standard national accounts, as well as to obtain information
on the physical characteristics of these structures, such as their number, capacity, lifetime and
depreciation. Stock accounts for water-related infrastructure can assist in formulating and
evaluating policies that are aimed at improving access to water and sanitation. The ability to
improve access to these services is highly dependent on investments in infrastructure or on
infrastructure which is already in place.
5.5. Section D discusses how other monetary flows related to water, such as taxes and
subsidies, are recorded in the accounts.
5.6. Section E presents national expenditure and financing accounts for water-related activi-
ties classified by purpose. The national expenditure accounts give an indication of the expendi-
ture by resident units on specific activities related to water, such as wastewater and water
management. The financing accounts are particularly important because users of water and
water-related products do not always pay for the entire costs associated with their use. They
benefit from transfers from other economic units (generally governmental) which bear part of
the costs. Similarly, investments in infrastructure are also often partly financed by units other
than the one that benefits from its use. Analysis of the financing of the use of water and water-
related products, as well as investments in water-related infrastructure, produces information
on how the expenditures are financed: by which agent and by means of what instrument, such
as the sale of services or environmental taxes. Such information is relevant, for example, for
assessing the implementation of the polluter/user-pays principle, as the accounts for financing
show the portion of the total cost paid by the polluter or user.
5.10. The simplified standard hybrid supply and use tables explicitly identify the following
two water-related products in the monetary part of the tables:
(a) Natural water (CPC 1800), which is associated primarily with the output of ISIC
division 36, water collection, treatment and supply. In the monetary supply and
use tables, natural water corresponds to the exchanges of water between economic
units (mainly between ISIC division 36 and other economic units, such as other
industries, households and the rest of the world). It should be noted that this
division is very broad, covering very different types of water exchanged in the
economy, including reused water;
(b) Sewerage, sewage treatment and septic tank cleaning services (CPC 941). This
group includes sewerage and sewage treatment services (CPC 9411) and septic
tank emptying and cleaning services (CPC 9412). These services are primarily
associated with the output of ISIC division 37, sewerage.
5.11. Depending on data availability, other products related to water could also be explicitly
identified in the tables. These include the following: operation of irrigation systems for agricul-
tural purposes, which is part of CPC 86110 and is primarily (and uniquely) associated with the
output of ISIC class 0161, support activities for crop production; water-related administrative
services, which are part of CPC 91123 and primarily associated with the output of ISIC class
8412; and site remediation and clean-up services (for surface water and groundwater) (CPC
94412 and part of CPC 94413), associated primarily with the output of ISIC class 3900.
5.12. Economic activities, classified according to ISIC Rev. 4, are identified by column in
the supply and use tables. The level of disaggregation of industries depends on the country’s
situation and the availability of data. The simplified standard tables identify a limited number
of groups of industries for ease of compilation. These include the following:
(a) ISIC divisions 1-3: agriculture, forestry and fishing;
(b) ISIC divisions 5-33 and 41-43, which include mining and quarrying, manufac-
turing, and construction;
(c) ISIC division 35: electricity, gas, steam and air-conditioning supply, in particular;
and hydroelectric power generation, transmission and distribution (part of ISIC
division 3510);
(d) ISIC division 36: water collection, treatment and supply;
(e) ISIC division 37: sewerage;
(f ) ISIC divisions 38, 39 and 45-99, which correspond to the service industries.
5.13. It is highly recommended for analytical purposes when compiling water accounts to
further disaggregate the activities related to water other than ISIC classes 3600 and 3700,
namely, the operation of agricultural equipment (part of ISIC class 0161), remediation activi-
ties and other waste management services related to water (part of ISIC class 3900) and
administration of water-related programmes (part of ISIC class 8412).
5.14. It should be noted that in some countries the activities of water supply (ISIC divi-
sion 36) and sewerage (ISIC division 37) are carried out by the same establishment and no
separate accounts are kept by that establishment. This makes it difficult to separate informa-
tion on the costs related to the two separate ISIC divisions. To the extent possible, therefore,
information should be disaggregated in order to show explicitly the costs and the output of
each of these activities. Additional information and estimation may be needed to separate
these activities. As recommended in the 2008 SNA, in cases where water and wastewater are
produced in an integrated production process, the cost structure of the firm which is treating
the wastewater may be used only to estimate the portion of the cost for treating the wastewater.
68 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Table V.1
Hybrid supply table
35 Social transfers
in kind from
Government Total
(of Final and non-profit uses at
5-33, which): 38, 39, Total consumption institutions serving Govern- Capital purchaser’s
1-3 41-43 Total Hydro 36 37 45-99 industry expenditures households Total ment Total formation Exports price
1. Total intermediate
consumption and use
(billions of currency
units) 72.9 419.4 9.9 1.1 1.10 1.7 157.8 664.0 321.4 131.4 452.8 53.6 506.4 146.0 403.0 1 719.4
of which:
of which:
3.a.1. Abstraction
for own use 108.4 114.6 404.2 300.0 23.00 100.1 2.3 752.6 10.8 10.8 763.4
Box V.1
From final consumption expenditure to actual final consumption
Total final consumption in the economy may be viewed from two perspectives. It may be defined from the
expenditure side as the total value of all expenditures on individual and collective consumption goods and
services incurred by resident households, resident non-profit institutions serving households (NPISHs) and
general governmental units; or, it may be defined in terms of actual final consumption as the value of all
the individual goods and services acquired by resident households plus the value of the collective services
provided by general government to the community or large sections of the community.
The relevant paragraphs of the 1993 System of National Accounts (SNA) describing the concepts of final
consumption expenditure and actual final consumption are presented below.
Final consumption expenditure includes paras. 9.113, 9.114 and 9.115 of the 2008 SNA:
(a) Household final consumption expenditure consists of the expenditure, including expenditure whose
value must be estimated indirectly, incurred by resident households on individual consumption goods
and services, including those sold at prices that are not economically significant and including con-
sumption of goods and services acquired abroad;
(b) General government final consumption expenditure consists of expenditure, including expenditure
whose value must be estimated indirectly, incurred by general government on both individual con-
sumption goods and services and collective consumption services;
(c) Final consumption expenditure of NPISHs consists of the expenditure, including expenditure whose
value must be estimated indirectly, incurred by resident NPISHs on individual consumption goods and
services and possibly on collective consumption services.
Actual final consumption includes paras. 9.116, 9.117 and 9.118 of the 2008 SNA:
(a) Actual final consumption of households is measured by the value of all the individual consumption
goods and services acquired by resident households. There are three sets of goods and services enter-
ing into household actual final consumption:
• Those acquired through expenditure by households themselves (which corresponds to (a), house-
hold final consumption expenditure, above)
• Those acquired as social transfers in kind from general government and NPISHs that are the output
of these institutions as non-market producers
• Those acquired as social transfers in kind from general government and NPISHs that have been
purchased by these institutions from market producers for onward transmission to households
free or at prices that are not economically significant
(b) Actual final consumption of general government is measured by the value of the collective consump-
tion services provided to the community, or large sections of the community, by general government;
(c) Actual final consumption of NPISHs is measured by the value of the collective consumption services
provided to the community, or large sections of the community, by NPISHs.
The table below shows how to obtain information on actual final consumption from the 2008 SNA use table.
Total final consumption may be presented by reorganizing the columns as follows: the table on the left
shows the 2008 SNA presentation of the use table, that is, table 14.7 of the 2008 SNA, using the expenditure
side. The table on the right shows the SEEA-Water presentation of the use table using the acquisition side.
Total final consumption recorded in the 2008 SNA use table Total final consumption recorded in the SEEA-Water use table
Box V.2
Individual and collective goods and services of government and non-profit institutions
serving households
The consumption expenditures incurred by government units and non-profit institutions serving house-
holds (NPISHs) have to be divided into those incurred for the benefit of individual households and those
incurred for the benefit of the community as a whole, or large sections of the community.
Individual goods and services are essentially “private” goods, as distinct from “public” goods. They have
the following characteristics:
(a) It must be possible to observe and record the acquisition of the good or service by an individual
household or member thereof and also the time at which it took place;
(b) The household must have agreed to the provision of the good or service and take whatever action
is necessary to make it possible, for example, by attending a school or clinic;
(c) The good or service must be such that its acquisition by one household or person, or possibly by a
small, restricted group of persons, precludes its acquisition by other households or persons.
Most goods can be privately owned and are individual in the sense used here. On the other hand, certain
kinds of services can be supplied collectively to the community as a whole. The characteristics of these
collective services may be summarized as follows:
(a) Collective services can be delivered simultaneously to every member of the community or of
particular sections of the community, such as those in a particular region of a locality;
(b) The use of such services is usually passive and does not require the explicit agreement or active
participation of all the individuals concerned;
(c) The provision of a collective service to one individual does not reduce the amount available to
others in the same community or section of the community. There is no rivalry in acquisition.
The collective services provided by government consist mostly of the provision of security and defence, the
maintenance of law and order, legislation and regulation, the maintenance of public health, the protection
of the environment, research and development, etc. All members of the community can benefit from such
services. As the individual usage of collective services cannot be recorded, individuals cannot be charged
according to their usage or the benefits they derive. There is market failure and collective services that must Source: United Nations, SNA Hand-
be financed out of taxation or other government revenues. book on Integrated Environmental
and Economic Accounting (United
The services provided by NPISHs are often confined to the members of the associations that control them,
Nations publication, Sales No. F.93.
although they may also provide individual goods or services to third parties. Many NPISHs are concerned XVII.12); and Commission of the Eu-
only with protecting the interests or welfare of their members or providing recreational, sporting or cultural ropean Communities, Internation-
facilities which households or persons cannot otherwise easily obtain for themselves if acting individually. al Monetary Fund, Organization for
Although NPISHs may provide services to their members in groups, the services are essentially individual Economic Cooperation and Devel-
opment, United Nations and World
rather than collective. In general, persons other than their members are excluded and derive no benefit Bank, System of National Accounts,
from the services provided. Therefore, as already noted, all the services provided by NPISHs are by conven- 2008 (United Nations publication,
tion treated as individual. Sales No. E.08.XVII.29).
are carried out by the Government (as may be the case in some countries), they should be
classified to the extent possible in the specific divisions (ISIC 36 and 37) and not in ISIC
division 84, public administration.
5.29. Where information is available, the producing units could be further disaggregated
according to the type of institutional sector that owns them (Government, corporation or
household). Such information can be useful for assessing, for example, the degree of involve-
ment of the Government in water supply or wastewater sanitation.
5.30. Table V.3 also presents information on gross fixed capital formation for water-related
infrastructure by industry, which represents investments in fixed capital related to water
(infrastructure). It also shows the closing stocks of fixed assets for water supply and sanitation.
The stocks of fixed assets represent the total value of infrastructure in place, disaggregated
according to whether it relates to water supply or wastewater services.
74 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
5.31. In order to enhance their analytical capacity, the accounts can be augmented with
supplementary information on specific aspects related to water. Such information includes
labour input in the supply of water and sanitation services and information on social aspects
that are important for water management. Indicators on access to water and sanitation, which
are also indicators in target 7.C of the Millennium Development Goals, are notable examples
of social indicators that could be linked to the SEEA-Water accounting tables. Information
on labour input may be important for analysing the impact of water allocation policies on
employment. Similarly, information on access to water and sanitation may be used to evalu-
ate policy reforms and structural changes aimed at improving access to water and sanitation.
Actual final
Industries (by ISIC category) consumption
Taxes less
35 subsidies on
products,
(of Rest trade and Capital
5-33, which) 38, 39, Total of the transport House- Govern- forma-
1-3 41-43 Total Hydro 36 37 45-99 industry world margins holds ment tion Total
1. Total output and supply (billions of currency units) 137.6 749.0 22.1 3.3 1.7 9.0 367.0 1 286.4 363.0 70.0 1 719.4
of which:
1.a. Natural water (CPC 1800) 0.0 0.04 0.0 0.0 1.7 0.2 0.0 1.9 0.0 -0.1 1.8
1.b. Sewerage services (CPC 941) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 8.8 0.0 8.8 0.0 0.0 8.8
2. Total intermediate consumption and use
(billions of currency units) 72.9 419.4 9.9 1.1 1.1 1.7 157.8 664.0 403.0 452.8 53.57 146.0 1 719.4
of which:
2.a. Natural water (CPC 1800) 0.2 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.8 0.0 1.0 - 1.8
2.b. Sewerage services (CPC 941) 0.4 2.4 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.0 3.9 0.0 4.9 - 8.8
3. Total value added (gross) (= 1 - 2) (billions of currency units) 64.7 329.5 12.2 1.8 0.6 7.3 209.2 622.4 0.0 622.4
4. Gross fixed capital formation (billions of currency units) 6.6 65.7 13.1 11.8 10.5 23.7 131.4 131.4
of which:
4.a. For water supply 0.311 11.8 1.3 13.4 13.4
4.b. For water sanitation 0.2 9.2 0.01 9.4 9.4
5. Closing stocks of fixed assets for water supply
(billions of currency units) 5.2 197.1 22.2 224.4 224.4
6. Closing stocks of fixed assets for sanitation
(billions of currency units) 2.4 115.7 0.1 118.2 118.2
7. Total use of water (millions of cubic metres) 159.1 200.2 408.1 300.0 428.7 527.2 53.4 1 776.7 0.0 250.3 2 027.0
7.a. Total abstraction 108.4 114.5 404.2 300.0 428.7 100.1 2.3 1 158.2 10.8 1 169.0
Hybrid and economic accounts for activities and products related to water
of which:
7. a.1. Abstraction for own use 108.4 114.6 404.2 300.0 23.0 100.1 2.3 752.6 10.8 763.4
7.b. Use of water received from other economic units 50.7 85.7 3.9 - 0.0 427.1 51.1 618.5 0.0 239.5 858.0
8. Total supply of water (millions of cubic metres) 82.9 157.0 405.6 300.0 426.9 526.5 49.8 1 648.7 0.0 240.3 1 889.0
8.a. Supply of water to other economic units 17.9 127.6 5.6 0.0 379.6 42.7 49.1 622.5 0.0 235.5 858.0
of which:
8.a.1. Wastewater to sewerage 17.9 117.6 5.6 0.0 1.4 0.0 49.1 191.6 0.0 235.5 427.1
8.b. Total returns 65.0 29.4 400.0 300.0 47.3 483.8 0.7 1 026.2 4.8 1 031.0
9. Total (gross) emissions of chemical oxygen demand
(thousands of tons) 3 150.2 5 047.4 7 405.1 1 851.0 498.5 1 973.8 19 925.9 11 663.6 31 589.5
may operate their own wastewater treatment facilities, such as industrial wastewater treatment
plants and septic tanks. The costs associated with these activities do not appear explicitly in
the accounts described in the previous section because they are incorporated within those of
the principal activity.
5.38. In the 2008 SNA, goods and services produced for own use should be valued at the
basic prices of the same goods or services sold on the market, provided they are sold in suf-
ficient quantities to enable reliable estimates to be made of those average prices.47 However,
since reliable market prices do not generally exist for water-related activities, in SEEA-Water,
the value of the output of these activities is deemed, by convention, to be equal to the sum
of the costs of production, that is, as the sum of intermediate consumption, compensation of
employees, consumption of fixed capital and other taxes (less subsidies) on production.
5.39. Table V.4 presents the hybrid account for activities of “water abstraction” and “sewer-
age” carried out for own use. In SEEA-Water, these activities are recorded under the ISIC
division of the principal activity. For example, if a manufacturing industry (ISIC division 17)
treats wastewater on site before discharging it into the environment, the activity of treating
the wastewater is recorded under ISIC division 17. This presentation is consistent with the
way in which information is organized in physical terms (as presented in chaps. III and IV)
where wastewater discharged into the environment (with or without treatment) by an industry
is recorded under the ISIC division of the industry discharging the water. The costs of water
abstraction are therefore directly linked for each industry to the volumes of water abstracted,
and the costs of treating wastewater are linked with the volume of wastewater discharged after
on-site treatment.
5.40. For other purposes, it may be relevant to reorganize and allocate activities for own use
to the relevant ISIC categories, such as ISIC divisions 36 or 37. The separate identification of
water-related activities for own use, as reflected in SEEA-Water, enables this reorganization
to be done easily if so desired.
5.41. It should be noted that table V.4 also includes households as they may abstract water
directly from the environment and often carry out activities of wastewater treatment through
the use of septic tanks, for example.
5.42. The information required for table V.4 is not likely to be readily available in many
countries. Specific surveys need to be put in place in order to estimate the costs associated
with the activities of water collection, treatment and supply, and wastewater treatment when
they are carried out for own use. Information on the physical quantities of water abstracted
and the average costs could be used to populate the table as a first step in its compilation.
Table V.4
Hybrid account for water supply and sewerage for own use
35
(of
5-33, which) 38, 39, House- Total
1-3 41-43 Total Hydro 36 37 45-99 Total holds industry
Water 1. Costs of production (= 1.a + 1.b)
supply (millions of currency units) 336.0 355.3 1 253.0 930.0 71.3 310.3 7.1 2 333.1 33.5 2 366.5
for own
1.a. Total intermediate
use
consumption 162.6 171.9 606.3 450.0 34.5 150.2 3.5 1 128.9 16.2 1 145.1
1.b. Total value added (gross) 173.4 183.4 646.7 480.0 36.8 160.2 3.7 1 204.2 17.3 1 221.4
1.b.1. Compensation of
employees 104.1 73.3 258.7 192.0 14.7 64.1 1.5 516.4 0.0 516.4
1.b.2. Other taxes less subsidies
on production -1.7 -1.8 -6.5 -4.8 0.4 1.6 0.0 -8.0 0.5 -7.5
1.b.3. Consumption of fixed
capital 71.1 111.8 394.5 292.8 21.7 94.5 2.2 695.8 16.8 712.6
2. Gross fixed capital formation
(millions of currency units) 672.1 781.6 1 503.6 1 116.0 2.9 2 960.1 70.3 3 030.4
3. Stocks of fixed assets
(billions of currency units) 11.2 13.1 25.1 18.6 0.0 49.4 1.2 50.6
4. Abstraction for own use (millions
of cubic metres) (from table III.3) 108.4 114.6 404.2 300.0 23.0 100.1 2.3 752.6 10.8 763.4
Sewerage 1. Costs of production (= 1.a + 1.b)
for own (millions of currency units) 121.0 6.1 127.1 18.2 145.2
use
1.a. Total intermediate
consumption (millions of
currency units) 30.0 1.5 31.5 4.5 36.0
1.b. Total value added (gross) 91.0 4.6 95.6 13.7 109.2
1.b.1. Compensation
of employees 27.3 1.4 28.7 4.1 32.8
1.b.2. Other taxes less subsidies
on production -0.9 0.0 -1.0 -0.1 -1.1
1.b.3. Consumption of fixed
capital 64.6 3.2 67.8 9.7 77.5
2. Gross fixed capital formation
(millions of currency units) 266.2 2.4 268.6 38.1 306.7
3. Stocks of fixed assets
(millions of currency units) 3 354.1 30.5 3 384.6 480.2 3 864.9
4. Return of treated water (millions
of cubic metres) (from table III.3) 10.0 0.5 10.5 1.5 12.0
Source: SEEA-Water-land database.
5.47. Table V.5 presents economic accounts for government expenditures on water-related
collective consumption services. The collective consumption services are assumed to be pro-
duced and used by the Government. The value of these activities is equal to the costs of their
production, namely, the sum of intermediate consumption, compensation of employees, con-
sumption of fixed capital and other taxes less subsidies on production. These accounts could
be further disaggregated for central, state and local governments. This table serves as input
in the compilation of the table on financing covered in section D.
2. Water rights
5.51. One way in which governments control the use of water resources is by issuing water
rights. With the issuance of water rights for exploiting water resources in a particular water
Table V.5
Government accounts for water-related collective consumption services
Government
(by Classification of the Functions of the Government category)
05.6
05.3 (part) Environmental
05.2 Soil and protection not 06.3
Wastewater groundwater elsewhere Water
management protection classified supply
1.b.1. Compensation
of employees 0.42 0.13 0.69 0.11
1.b.2. Consumption of
fixed capital 0.55 0.00 0.01 0.07
Source: SEEA-Water-land database.
80 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
body, the government recognizes those water resources or part of them as economic assets.
These rights are granted through water licences—for a fee or free of charge—which entitle the
licence holder to use the water resources as an input into the economy or as a sink to absorb
pollutants. The terms of the agreements regarding the water licences may vary considerably,
within and between countries, with respect to their duration, payment schedule, transfer-
ability and other arrangements.
5.52. The payments for water rights are treated differently depending on the terms of agree-
ments of the rights to use the water resources. Permits to use water resources can be basi-
cally characterized according to three different sets of conditions. The owner may permit
the resource to be used in perpetuity. The owner may allow the resource to be used for an
extended period of time in such a way that, in effect, the user controls the use of the resource
during this time with little, if any, intervention from the legal owner. The third option is that
the owner can extend or withhold permission for continued use of the water resources from
one year to the next.
5.53. The first option, where the owner of the water rights is permitted to use the resources
in perpetuity, results in the sale of the resource, and the transaction is recorded in the capital
account. In the second option, in which the holder of the water rights (the user) controls
the use of the water resource over the contract period, an asset (non-produced assets called
contracts, leases and licences) for the user is created. This asset is distinct from the water
resource itself, but its value and that of the water resources are linked. The payment for the
water rights in this case is either recorded as payment of rent or purchase of water resources,
depending upon the terms of the water rights. In the third option, payments for the water
rights are recorded as rent for the use of the water resources.
5.54. As mentioned earlier, in situ use of water resources for transportation or recreation
purposes involves the use of space of land, the payment for which should be recorded as rent
on land, if it is recognized as an economic asset. Otherwise, the payments are considered
other taxes on production.
5.55. There is no single, universal or clear-cut criterion to distinguish between rent and sale
of an asset. The 2008 SNA (2008 SNA, para. 17.318) lists the following range of criteria:
(a) Costs and benefits assumed by licensee: The more the risks and benefits associ-
ated with the right to use an asset are incurred by the licensee, the more likely it
is that the transaction will be classified as the sale of an asset (as opposed to rent);
(b) Upfront payment or instalment: Generally, the means of paying for a licence is
a financial issue and, as such, not a relevant factor in determining whether or not
it is an asset. However, business practice shows that upfront payments of rent for
long periods are highly unusual and this favours interpretation as sale of an asset;
(c) Length of the licence: Licences granted for long periods suggest treatment as the
sale of an asset; shorter periods suggest treatment as payments for rent;
(d) Actual or de facto transferability: The possibility of selling the licence is a strong
indication of ownership and if transferability exists, this is considered a strong
condition for characterizing the licensing act as the sale of third-party property
rights.
(e) Possibility of cancellation: The stronger the restrictions on the issuer’s capacity
to cancel the licence at its discretion, the stronger the case for treatment as a sale
of an asset.
5.56. Not all of these considerations have to be satisfied in order to characterize the licence
as a sale of an asset, nor do even a simple majority of them. However, in order to qualify as
Hybrid and economic accounts for activities and products related to water 81
a payment of rent on water resources, at least some conditions of the following kind should
hold (2008 SNA, para. 17.319):
(a) The contract should be of short-term duration, or renegotiable at short-term
intervals;
(b) The contract should be non-transferable;
(c) The contract should contain detailed stipulations on how the holder of the water
right should make use of the water resource;
(d) The contract should include conditions that give the lessor the unilateral right to
terminate the lease without compensation;
(e) The contract would require payments over the duration of the contract, rather
than a large upfront payment.
50 Ibid.; Eurostat, The European System for the Collection of Information on the Environment: SERIEE
1994 Version (Luxembourg, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 2002);
Eurostat, SERIEE Environmental Protection Expenditure Accounts: Compilation Guide (Luxembourg,
Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 2002); and Eurostat, SERIEE Environ-
mental Protection Expenditure Accounts: Results of Pilot Compilations (Luxembourg, Office for Official
Publications of the European Communities, 2002).
82 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
51 See, for example, System of National Accounts, 2008, op. cit., para. 6.24.
52 Eurostat, SERIEE Environmental Protection Expenditure Accounts: Compilation Guide, op. cit.
Hybrid and economic accounts for activities and products related to water 83
5.68. In the case of water, “wastewater management” and “protection and remediation
of soil, groundwater and surface water” are considered to be activities for the protection of
the environment and are part of CEPA 2000.
5.69. Wastewater management (CEPA 2) comprises activities and measures aimed at
preventing the pollution of surface water through reductions in the release of wastewater
into inland surface water and seawater. This category includes the collection and treat-
ment of wastewater, including monitoring and regulation activities. Septic tanks are also
included (see explanatory notes of CEPA 2000 and SEEA-2003). In particular, wastewater
management includes (a) activities for the collection, treatment and disposal of wastewater,
activities aimed at controlling the quality of surface and marine water, and administra-
tion activities in the wastewater domain (these activities correspond to sewerage under
ISIC division 37 and part of the public administration activities under ISIC division 84);
(b) the use of specific products relevant to wastewater management, such as septic tanks;
and (c) specific transfers.
5.70. Protection and remediation of soil, groundwater and surface water (CEPA 4) refers
to measures and activities aimed at the prevention of pollutant infiltration, the cleaning
up of soils and bodies of water and the protection of soil from erosion and other forms
of physical degradation, as well as from salinization; monitoring and control of soil and
groundwater pollution are included (see explanatory notes of CEPA 2000 and SEEA-
2003). Protection and remediation of soil, groundwater and surface water mainly include
(a) activities for the protection of soil and groundwater (which correspond to part of ISIC
division 39, remediation activities and other waste management services, and to part of the
public administration activities of ISIC division 84); and (b) specific transfers.
tion and remediation of soil, groundwater and surface water; and water management and
exploitation. The standard tables for the national expenditure and financing accounts are
compiled only for “wastewater management” and “water management and exploitation”.
For their compilation, the tables on protection and remediation of soil, groundwater and
surface water require additional disaggregation of the data included in the standard tables
and are thus included as part of the supplementary tables.
5.75. This subsection describes the component of the national expenditures for environmen-
tal protection and illustrates the national expenditure accounts for wastewater management
(table V.6). These accounts can also be compiled for water management and exploitation and
for protection and remediation of soil, groundwater and surface water.
5.76. The main components of the national expenditure for environmental protection,
described by row in the accounts presented in table V.6, consist of the following:
(a) Use of environmental protection services by resident units (except “specialized
producers” to avoid double counting (see para. 5.78 for a detailed explanation)).
This is the sum of intermediate and final consumption and capital formation.
Intermediate consumption includes the use of environmental protection services
for own use and for services purchased by “other producers”. Only in the case
of soil remediation can the use of such services for capital formation (row 1.c of
table V.6) be non-zero for “other producers”. This entry consists of improvement
of land as a result of decontamination of soil. It is not included in row 2 of table
V.6 because it is a use of the output of ISIC division 39 by other producers and
not an investment for the production of environmental protection services or land
acquisition, which are recorded in row 2 of table V.6. In the case of wastewater
management, the use of environmental protection services corresponds to the
use of wastewater services (CPC 941 and CPC 91123) for intermediate and final
consumption by resident units (except by “specialized producers”—in this case,
ISIC division 37). Capital formation is not relevant for water and wastewater
services; thus, it is not recorded under this category;
(b) Use of “adapted” and “connected products” for intermediate and final consump-
tion. In the case of wastewater management, adapted products include, for exam-
ple, phosphate-free washing products and highly biodegradable products. Con-
nected products include, for example, septic tanks, biological activators of septic
tanks and services for collecting septic tank sludge;
(c) Gross capital formation for producing environmental protection services. This
item corresponds to the investments made by environmental protection producers
for producing environmental protection services. It includes gross fixed capital
formation and net acquisition of land. In the case of wastewater management,
it corresponds to the gross capital formation related to wastewater management
activities: the installation of sewage networks and treatment plants, for example.
This corresponds to the investments made by the producers of wastewater services
for collecting, treating and discharging wastewater;
(d) Specific transfers received for environmental protection. Specific transfers are
unrequited payments received by residents or non-resident units which contrib-
ute to the financing of characteristic activities and uses of specific products or
constitute a compensation for income or losses related to environmental protec-
tion (SERIEE, section 203954). This item includes current and capital transfers
for environmental protection. The transfers are not counterparts of the previous
Table V.6
National expenditure accounts for wastewater management (billions of currency units)
Users/beneficiaries
Specialized Rest
producers Other House- Govern- of the
(ISIC 37) producers holds ment world Total
items in the table created, in order to avoid double counting. In the case of waste-
water management, specific transfers consist, for example, of subsidies to special-
ized producers of sewerage and treatment services, and of transfers to the rest of
the world in order to finance programmes of collective sewerage and treatment
in other countries (international public or private aid for development) (SERIEE,
section 4071).
5.77. The sum of the above-mentioned categories corresponds to the total domestic use
of environmental protection services. Since the national expenditure is aimed at recording
the expenditure of resident units and is financed by resident units in order to get a total that
corresponds to the effort that a country is making using its own resources, the financing of
the “rest of the world” (row 6 of table V.6) for environmental protection has to be subtracted
from total domestic use. In the case of wastewater management, such financing consists of
international aid for wastewater management.
5.78. National expenditure for environmental protection is allocated by column to the
following categories of beneficiary: “producers”, “final consumers” and “rest of the world”.
Producers are further disaggregated into “specialized producers” and “other producers”. Spe-
cialized producers are defined as those that carry out an environmental protection activity
as their principal activity. In the case of wastewater management, the specialized producers
correspond mainly to those classified in ISIC division 37. “Other producers” are those that
use environmental protection services (including the use of such services for own use) and
connected and adapted products for their intermediate consumption, invest in the pro-
duction of environmental protection services for own use and receive specific transfers for
environmental protection.
5.79. Final consumers identified in national expenditure accounts are “households” as
actual consumers of environmental protection services and connected and adapted prod-
ucts, or as beneficiaries of specific transfers, and “Government” in its capacity as consumer
of collective services.
86 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
5.80. The classification rest of the world is included by column as part of the users/ben-
eficiaries because it may receive specific transfers for environmental protection. In the case
of wastewater management, transfers to the rest of the world include transfers to finance
programmes of collective sewerage and treatment in other countries (SERIEE, section 4071).
5.81. Expenditure by specialized producers (ISIC division 37) consists of gross capital
formation for the production of wastewater services (row 2 of table V.6) and specific trans-
fers (row 4). The entries in the other cells of the column for specialized producers should
not be recorded in order to avoid double counting between the output and subsequent uses.
The use of wastewater services and “connected and adapted products” for intermediate
consumption by specialized producers is part of the output of the specialized producers
and recorded as intermediate consumption of other producers and final consumption of
households and Government. It is thus already included in the total national expenditure.
The use of environmental protection services for capital formation (row 1.c) likewise should
not be recorded for specialized producers, as it represents the use of capital goods for the
production of environmental protection services and thus should be included under gross
capital formation in row 2.
5.82. The expenditures of other producers include the use of wastewater services as inter-
mediate consumption (including also services produced for own use) (row 1.b); investments
for the production of wastewater services as a secondary activity or for own use (row 2); the
use of connected and adapted products (row 3); and specific transfers (row 4).
5.83. Information in rows 1 and 2 of table V.6 is derived from the hybrid account for
supply and use of water in table V.3, the hybrid account for water-related activities for own
use in table V.4 and government accounts for water-related collective services in table V.5.
For example, the use of wastewater services by other producers is the sum of the use of
sewerage services from table V.3 and the value of the output of sewerage service for own
use from table V.4.
5.84. The use of wastewater services by households corresponds to their actual final con-
sumption: 4.9 billion currency units are derived from row 2.b of table V.3. The use of waste-
water services by the Government is derived from the government accounts for water-related
collective services. It corresponds to row 1 of table V.5 (3.79 million currency units).
5.85. Information additional to that contained in the tables in sections B and C of this
chapter is required in order to compile the national expenditure accounts, namely, informa-
tion on the use of connected and adapted products, “specific transfers” and “financing from
the rest of the world”.
3. Financing accounts
5.86. Users of water-related products do not always bear the entire costs of production. In
the case of water, it is not uncommon for users to receive transfers from other units (generally
the Government). These transfers include subsidies for the production of water-related prod-
ucts, investment grants and other transfers that are financed either from government expendi-
ture or from specific taxes. This section describes the financing of national expenditures by
identifying the financing sector (the sector providing the financing) and the beneficiaries (the
units benefiting from the financing), as well as the amount being financed.
5.87. Table V.7 presents the financing accounts for wastewater management in order to
show how the national expenditure for wastewater management is financed. The columns
of table V.7 show the same categories of users/beneficiaries identified in table V.6. The rows
of table V.7 show the different financing units (those actually bearing the cost), which are
Hybrid and economic accounts for activities and products related to water 87
Table V.7
Financing accounts for wastewater management (millions of currency units)
Users/beneficiaries
Specialized Rest
producers Other of the
Financing sectors: (ISIC 37) producers Households Government world Total
classified according to the institutional sectors of the national accounts: general Government,
which can be further disaggregated under central and local government, non-profit institu-
tions serving households, corporations and households.
5.88. The expenditures recorded in the column of “specialized producers” correspond to
their gross capital formation and net acquisition of land. The table entries describe how
capital formation is financed: partly by the specialized producers themselves (row 3.a) and
partly by the Government through investment grants (row 1). However, if the investment
grants are funded from earmarked taxes, it is assumed that the taxpayers (in general house-
holds and other producers) are the financing units (rows 4 and 3.b, respectively).
5.89. The national expenditure recorded in the column of “other producers” corresponds
to the sum of the intermediate consumption of wastewater services (including those pro-
duced for own use), capital formation (investment in infrastructure and net acquisition of
land) for secondary and own-use activities for wastewater services and specific transfers
they may receive. The various column entries describe how this expenditure is financed.
Other producers may finance their intermediate consumption and capital formation them-
selves (row 3.b) or may receive subsidies from specialized producers (row 3.a) or the Gov-
ernment (row 1) through specific transfers and investment grants. If these subsidies and
investment grants are funded through revenues from earmarked taxes, it is assumed that
the unit that pays the taxes is the financing unit.
5.90. National expenditure of “households” corresponds to their actual final consump-
tion of wastewater services, connected and adapted products and any transfers they receive.
Entries in the column describe how this expenditure is financed. Households may finance
part of their final consumption themselves (row 4); however, they may receive (a) social
transfers in kind from the Government and non-profit institutions serving households
(rows 1 and 2); and (b) subsidies that lower the price of environmental protection services or
products, in which case it is assumed that the Government is the financing unit. However,
when subsidies originate in earmarked taxes, it is assumed that the units that pay the taxes
(in general households and other producers) are the financing units.
88 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Chapter VI
Water asset accounts
A. Introduction
6.1. This chapter links the information on the abstraction and discharge of water with
information on the stocks of water resources in the environment, thus enabling an assessment
of how current levels of abstraction and discharge affect the stocks of water.
6.2. The chapter begins with a description of the hydrological cycle, which governs water
movement from the atmosphere to the Earth, and its links with the water asset accounts
(section B). Unlike other natural resources, such as forests or mineral resources which are
subject to slow natural changes, water is in continuous movement through the processes of
evaporation and precipitation, etc. It is important to understand the natural cycle of water in
order to reflect it correctly in the accounting tables and to determine, for analytical purposes,
how to meet the demand for water in dry seasons, for example.
6.3. Section C describes how the 2008 SNA asset boundary has been expanded. It pre-
sents the SEEA-Water asset classification and describes the SEEA-Water standard tables for
asset accounts. In cases where water resources are shared among several countries, the asset
accounts can identify explicitly information on the part of the water resources belonging to
each country and the origin and destination of the water flows between countries. Water asset
accounts can be used for the management of shared water as they facilitate the formulation
and monitoring of policies for the allocation of water among countries with connected water
resources. Section D describes how information on transboundary waters is included in the
asset accounts.
6.4. This chapter focuses only on the quantitative assessment of the stocks and the changes
in stocks which occur during the accounting period. The qualitative characteristics of the
stocks are dealt with in the quality accounts presented in chapter VII. The monetary descrip-
tion of the assets of water resources is not considered in this chapter: as yet, no standard
techniques exist to assess the economic value of water; market prices do not fully reflect the
value of the resource itself; and the resource rent is often negative. A discussion on various
methods for valuing water is presented in chapter VIII.
Figure VI.1
Natural water cycle
and subsurface of land, the natural input of water is precipitation. Part of this precipitation
evaporates back into the atmosphere, some infiltrates into the ground to recharge groundwater,
and the remainder drains into rivers, lakes and reservoirs and eventually may reach the sea.
This cycle continues as water evaporates from land, oceans and seas into the atmosphere and
falls back onto land and into oceans and other bodies of water in the form of precipitation.
6.6. The natural water balance describes the hydrological cycle by relating the flows
described above in the following way:
Precipitation = evapotranspiration + run-off +/- changes in storage
some measure of economic control”. Thus, only a small portion of the total water resources in
a country is included in the 2008 SNA.
6.11. As indicated in para 2.23(a), the extension of the 2008 SNA asset boundary with
respect to water resources relates only to recording such assets in physical units (quantity). Val-
uation of water resources in monetary terms is not recommended except for those recognized
as assets in the 2008 SNA, namely those surface and groundwater resources used for exploi-
tation to the extent that their scarcity leads to the enforcement of ownership or use of water
rights, market valuation and some measures of economic control (2008 SNA, para. 10.184)
2. Asset classification
6.12. Water resource assets are defined as water found in freshwater, brackish surface water
and groundwater bodies within the national territory that provide direct use benefits, cur-
rently or in the future (option benefits), through the provision of raw material, and may be
subject to quantitative depletion through human use. The SEEA-Water asset classification of
water resources consists of the following categories:
EA.13: Water resources (measured in cubic metres)
EA.131: Surface water
EA.1311: Artificial reservoirs
EA.1312: Lakes
EA.1313: Rivers and streams
EA.1314: Glaciers, snow and ice
EA.132: Groundwater
EA.133: Soil water
6.13. The SEEA-Water asset classification expands the SEEA-2003 classification by includ-
ing the categories EA.1314, glaciers, snow and ice, and EA.133, soil water. While SEEA-2003
acknowledges the importance of these resources in terms of flows, it does not include them in
the asset classification because they represent only the temporary storage of water. The explicit
inclusion of glaciers, snow, ice and soil water in the SEEA-Water asset classification reflects
the increasing importance of these resources in terms of stocks, in particular soil water; it
also allows for a clearer representation of water exchanges among water resources. Water in
the soil, for example, is a very important resource (both in terms of stocks and flows) for food
production as it sustains rain-fed agriculture, pasture, forestry, etc. Water management tends
to focus on water in rivers, lakes, etc., and to neglect soil water management, even though
the management of soil water holds significant potential for saving water, increasing water
use efficiency and protecting vital ecosystems.
6.14. Glaciers are included in the asset classification even though their stock levels are not
significantly affected by human abstraction. The melt derived from glaciers often sustains
river flows in dry months and it contributes to water peaks. Moreover, monitoring glacier
stocks is also important for monitoring climate change.
6.15. Surface water comprises all water that flows over or is stored on the ground surface.56
Surface water includes artificial reservoirs, which are constructed reservoirs used for the
storage, regulation and control of water resources; lakes, which are generally large bodies of
standing water occupying depressions in the Earth’s surface; rivers and streams, which are
56 For details of this definition, see International Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed. (UNESCO/WMO, 1992).
92 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
bodies of water flowing continuously or periodically in channels; snow and ice, which include
seasonal layers of these forms of frozen water on the ground surface; and glaciers, which are
defined as an accumulation of ice of atmospheric origin, generally moving slowly on land over
a long period. Snow, ice and glaciers are measured in water equivalents.
6.16. Groundwater comprises water which collects in porous layers of underground forma-
tions known as aquifers. An aquifer is a geologic formation, group of formations, or part of a
formation that contains sufficient saturated permeable material to supply significant quantities
of water to wells and springs. An aquifer may be unconfined, that is, have a water table and an
unsaturated zone, or it may be confined between two layers of impervious or almost impervi-
ous formations. Depending on the recharge rate of the aquifer, groundwater can be fossil (or
non-renewable) in the sense that water is not replenished by nature during the human lifespan.
It should be noted that the concerns about non-renewable water apply not only to groundwater,
but also to other bodies of water: for example, lakes may be considered non-renewable when
their replenishment rate is very slow compared with their total volume of water.
6.17. Soil water consists of water suspended in the uppermost belt of soil, or in the zone
of aeration near the ground surface, that can be discharged into the atmosphere by evapo-
transpiration.
6.18. The asset classification can be adapted to specific situations depending on data avail-
ability and country priorities. For example, the classification could be further disaggregated
to classify artificial reservoirs according to the type of use, such as for human, agricultural,
hydroelectric power generation or mixed use. Rivers could be further classified on the basis of
the regularity of the run-off: as perennial rivers, where water flows continuously throughout
the year, or ephemeral rivers, where water flows only as a result of precipitation or the flow of
an intermittent spring.
6.19. It should be noted that boundaries between the different categories in the asset clas-
sification, such as between lakes and artificial reservoirs and rivers and lakes/reservoirs, may
not always be precise. However, this is mostly a hydrological problem; it does not affect the
accounts. In those cases in which the separation between two categories is not possible, a cat-
egory combining the two categories could be introduced in the table for ease of compilation.
These assets, in general, do not incur depletion. Water in oceans, seas and the atmosphere is
recorded in the accounts only in terms of abstracted water as described below:
(i) The physical supply and use tables (see chap. III) record (a) water abstracted from
and returned into the sea (for example, in the case of the abstraction of sea water for
cooling purposes or for desalination); (b) precipitation used directly by the economy
(for example, in the case of water harvest); and (c) evaporation and evapotranspiration,
which occur within the economic sphere (part of water consumption);
(ii) The asset accounts record (a) water flowing into oceans and seas (outflows from rivers);
(b) water vaporized and evapotranspired from water resources; and (c) precipitation
into water resources (dropping from the atmosphere into inland water resources).
3. Asset accounts
6.24. Water asset accounts describe the stocks of water resources and their changes during
an accounting period. Figure VI.2 presents an asset account, in schematic form, in particular:
(a) Opening and closing stocks, which are the stock levels at the beginning and the
end of the period;
(b) Increases in stocks, which include those due to human activity (returns) and
natural causes, such as inflows and precipitation;
(c) Decreases in stocks, which include those due to human activity (abstraction) and
natural causes, such as evaporation/evapotranspiration and outflows.
These accounts are particularly relevant because they link water use by the economy (repre-
sented by abstraction and returns) and natural flows of water to the stocks of water in a country.
Figure VI.2
Schematic representation of an asset account
Opening stocks
+
Increases in stocks:
Due to human activity
Due to natural processes
-
Decreases in stocks:
Due to human activity
Due to natural processes
=
Closing stocks
6.25. The standard table for asset accounts for water resources is presented in table VI.1.
The columns refer to the water resources as specified in the asset classification, and the rows
describe in detail the level of the stocks and the changes therein due to economic activities
and natural processes. The items presented in the table are discussed in detail below.
6.26. Returns represent the total volume of water that is returned from the economy into
surface and groundwater during the accounting period. Returns can be disaggregated by
type of water returned, for example, irrigation water, treated and untreated wastewater. In
this case, the breakdown should mirror that used to disaggregate the returns in the physical
supply and use tables in chapter III.
6.27. Precipitation consists of the volume of atmospheric wet precipitation (rain, snow,
hail, etc.) on the territory of reference during the accounting period before evapotranspira-
tion takes place. Most of the precipitation would fall on the soil and would thus be recorded
in the column under soil water in the asset accounts. Some precipitation would also fall into
other water resources, such as surface water. It is assumed that water would reach aquifers
after having passed through either the soil or surface water, such as rivers and lakes; thus,
no precipitation would be shown in the asset accounts for groundwater. The infiltration of
precipitation into groundwater is recorded in the accounts as an inflow from other water
resources into groundwater.
6.28. Inflows represent the amount of water that flows into water resources during the
accounting period. The inflows are disaggregated according to their origin, that is, (a) inflows
from other territories/countries; and (b) from other water resources within the territory.
Inflows from other territories occur in the case of shared water resources. For example, when
a river enters the territory of reference, the inflow is the total volume of water that flows into
the territory at its entry point during the accounting period. If a river borders two countries
without eventually entering either of them, each country could claim a percentage of the flow
as attributable to its territory. If no formal convention exists, a practical solution is to attribute
50 per cent of the flow to each country. Inflows from other resources include transfers, both
natural and artificial, among the resources within the territory. They include, for example,
flows of infiltration and seepage, as well as channels built for water diversion.
6.29. Abstraction represents the amount of water removed from any resource, either per-
manently or temporarily during the accounting period, for final consumption and produc-
tion activities. Water used for hydroelectric power generation is considered part of water
abstraction. Given the large volumes of water abstracted for generating hydroelectric power,
it is advisable to identify separately the abstraction by, and returns from, the power plant.
Abstraction also includes the use of precipitation for rain-fed agriculture as this is considered
removal of water from the soil as a result of a human activity, such as agriculture. Water used
in rain-fed agriculture is thus recorded as abstraction from soil water.
6.30. Evaporation/actual evapotranspiration is the amount of evaporation and actual
evapotranspiration that occurs in the territory of reference during the accounting period.
It should be noted that evaporation refers to the amount of water evaporated from bod-
ies of water, such as rivers, lakes and artificial reservoirs. Evapotranspiration refers to the
amount of water that is transferred from the soil to the atmosphere by evaporation and
plant transpiration. Evapotranspiration can be “potential” or “actual” depending on the
conditions of the soil and vegetation: potential evapotranspiration refers to the maximum
quantity of water capable of being evaporated in a given climate from a continuous stretch
of vegetation covering the entire area of ground that is well supplied with water. Actual
evapotranspiration, which is reported in the accounts, refers to the amount of water that
evaporates from the land surface and is transpired by the existing vegetation/plants when
the moisture content of the ground is at its natural level, which is determined by precipi-
Water asset accounts 95
Table VI.1
Asset accounts (millions of cubic metres)
EA.1311 EA.1314
Artificial EA.1312 EA.1313 Snow, ice EA.132 EA.133
reservoirs Lakes Rivers and glaciers Groundwater Soil water Total
1. Opening stocks 1 500 2 700 5 000 0 100 000 500 109 700
Increases in stocks
2. Returns 300 0 53 315 0 669
3. Precipitation 124 246 50 23 015 23 435
4. Inflows 1 054 339 20 137 437 0 21 967
4.a. From upstream territories 17 650 17 650
4.b. From other resources in the territory 1 054 339 2 487 0 437 0 4 317
Decreases in stocks
5. Abstraction 280 20 141 476 50 967
6. Evaporation/actual evapotranspiration 80 215 54 21 125 21 474
7. Outflows 1 000 100 20 773 0 87 1 787 23 747
7.a. To downstream territories 9 430 9 430
7.b. To the sea 10 000 10 000
7.c. To other resources in the territory 1 000 100 1 343 0 87 1 787 4 317
8. Other changes in volume 0
9. Closing stocks 1 618 2 950 4 272 100 189 553 109 583
Source: SEEA-Water-land database.
Note: Dark grey cells indicate zero entries by definition.
tation. It should be noted that actual evapotranspiration can be estimated only through
modelling, and it may be a rough approximation.
6.31. Outflows represent the amount of water that flows out of water resources during
the accounting period. Outflows are disaggregated according to the destination of the flow,
namely: (a) to other water resources within the territory, (b) to other territories/countries and
(c) to the sea/ocean. Outflows to other water resources within the territory represent water
exchanges between water resources within the territory. In particular, they include the water
flowing out of a body of water and reaching other water resources within the territory. Out-
flows to other territories represent the total volume of water that flows out of the territory of
reference during the accounting period. Shared rivers are a typical example of water flowing
from an upstream country to a downstream country. Outflows to the sea/ocean represent the
volume of water that flows into such bodies of water.
6.32. Other changes in volume include all the changes in the stocks of water that are not
classified elsewhere in the table. This item may include, for example, the amount of water in
aquifers discovered during the accounting period, and the disappearance or appearance of
water due to natural disasters, etc. Other changes in volume can be calculated directly or as
a residual.
6.33. Exchanges of water between water resources are also described in more detail in a sep-
arate table, table VI.2. This table, which expands the information contained in rows 4.b and
7.c of table VI.1, furnishes information on the origin and destination of the flows between the
water resources of the territory of reference, enabling better understanding of the exchanges
of water between resources. This table is also useful for the calculation of internal renewable
water resources and for reducing the risk of double counting when separately assessing this
96 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
indicator for surface and groundwater due to the water exchanges between these resources.58
Table VI.2 assists in identifying the contribution of groundwater to the surface flow, as well
as the recharge of aquifers by surface run-off.
6.34. In table VI.1, sustainable water abstraction, which broadly is the level of abstraction
that meets the needs of the current generations without compromising the ability of future
generations to meet their own needs, can be specified for each water resource. This variable
is exogenous to the accounts; it is often estimated by the agencies in charge of water man-
agement and planning in a country. Its estimation takes into account economic, social and
environmental considerations.
58 Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, “Statistics on Water Resources by Coun-
try in FAO’s Aquastat Programme”, Working Paper No. 25, Joint ECE/Eurostat Work Session on
Methodological Issues of Environment Statistics, Ottawa, 1-4 October 2001.
59 Igor A. Shiklomanov, “World Water Resources: Modern Assessment and Outlook for the 21st Cen-
tury” (Summary of World Water Resources at the Beginning of the 21st Century, prepared in the
framework of the International Hydrological Programme of UNESCO) (St. Petersburg, Russian
Federation, Federal Service of Russia for Hydrometeorology and Environment Monitoring, State
Hydrological Institute, 1999). Available from http://www.unep.org/vitalwater/05.htm.
Water asset accounts 97
Table VI.2
Matrix of flows between water resources (millions of cubic metres)
as well as the destination of water discharges by the economy. It enables evaluation of the
pressure exerted by the economy on the environment in terms of abstraction and returns.
Table VI.3
Asset account at the national level (cubic metres)
1. Opening stocks
Increases in stocks
2. Returnsa
3. Precipitation n/a
4. Inflows:
4.a. From upstream territoriesa
4.a.1. Country 1a
…
4.b. From other water resources in the territory n/a
Decreases in stocks
5. Abstractiona
6. Evaporation/actual evapotranspiration n/a
7. Outflows:
7.a. To other water resources in the territory n/a
7.b. To the sea n/a
7.c. To downstream territoriesa
7.c.1. Country 2a
6.43. Established quotas for abstractions and returns (merely in physical terms) as well as
for other flows can be included in the tables in a separate column in order to monitor com-
pliance with the treaties, as in table VI.3; however, for the sake of simplicity of presentation,
this information is not included in table VI.4.
Table VI.4
Asset accounts for a river basin shared by two countries
Water resources
(classified according to the asset classification)
1. Opening stocks
Increases in stocks
2. Returns:a
2.a. By country 1a
2.b. By country 2a
3. Precipitation
4. Inflows from other resources:a
4.a. From country 1a
4.b. From country 2a
Water asset accounts 99
Water resources
(classified according to the asset classification)
Decreases in stocks
5. Abstraction:a
5.a. By country 1a
5.b. By country 2a
6. Evaporation/actual evapotranspiration
7. Outflows to other resources in the
country:a
7.a. Country 1a
7.b. Country 2a
a Each of these flows may be subject to
8. Outflows to the sea quotas established in treaties and agree-
9. Other volume changes ments between riparian countries. Infor-
mation on such quotas, when available,
10. Closing stocks should be reported in a separate column.
PART TWO
103
Chapter VII
Water quality accounts
A. Introduction
7.1. Water quality determines the uses that can be made of water. Pollution creates health
hazards, detrimentally affects biodiversity, raises the cost of treating water and increases water
stress. The pollution of groundwater aquifers can be almost irreversible if not detected at an
early stage.
7.2. The importance of monitoring and accounting for water quality is internationally
recognized.60 International targets have been established with regard to the quality of water.
For example, the previously mentioned European Union Water Framework Directive requires
European Union countries to establish water policies aimed at ensuring that all water would
meet “good status” requirements by 2015 (see box VII.1).
7.3. Whereas the previous chapters focused on water in terms of input into the production
process and water availability regardless of its quality, this chapter focuses on the quality
of water and its link to various uses, which could be seen as being the first step towards
ecosystem accounting and its variants.
7.4. Quality accounts do not have a direct link to the economic accounts in the sense that
changes in quality cannot be attributed to economic quantities using linear relationships, as
in the case of the water asset accounts presented in chapter VI. However, SEEA-Water cov-
ers the quality accounts since quality is an important characteristic of water and can limit
its use. Further, SEEA-Water covers driving forces in terms of the structure of the economy
and the population, pressures in terms of the abstraction of water and emissions into it, and
responses in terms of environmental expenditures and the taxes and fees charged for water
and sanitation services. The state of water quality and related impacts are represented in the
quality accounts.
7.5. Quality accounts describe the quality of the stocks of water resources. The structure
of the quality accounts is similar to that of the asset accounts. The quality accounts, however,
appear to be much simpler than the asset accounts, as changes in quality are the result of
non-linear relationships. Therefore, it is not possible to distinguish changes in quality due to
human activities from changes in quality due to natural causes.
7.6. Although constructing quality accounts may be simple from a conceptual point of
view, there are two main issues with regard to implementation: the definition and the mea
surement of water quality classes. Water quality is generally defined for a specific concern;
there is little standardization of concepts and definitions or aggregation methods. Aggrega-
60 See, for example, World Meteorological Organization, Dublin Statement and Report of the Confer-
ence: International Conference on Water and the Environment: Development Issues for the 21st Century
(Geneva, WMO, 1992); and General Assembly resolution 55/2 of 8 September 2000.
104 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
tion can be over (a) different pollutants, in order to construct one index which measures
the combined impact of pollutants on water resources; (b) time, in order to address seasonal
variations; and (c) space, in order to reach a single quality measure for measurements at dif-
ferent locations.
7.7. Because of the issues outlined above and the insufficient number of country experi-
ences, this chapter is presented in terms of the issues and lessons learned from trial imple-
mentations rather than ready-made solutions. Section B describes the basic concepts of water
quality assessment, including the difficulty of defining quality in the presence of multiple
uses. Section C discusses the structure of quality accounts. Section D focuses on two issues:
the assessment and choice of “determinands”, that is, those characteristics that help in deter-
mining quality. Two indices that are used when aggregating over space are presented in sec-
tion E. Section F describes the exercise currently under way in the European Environment
Agency that is aimed at constructing quality accounts for rivers.
Box VII.1
European Union Water Framework Directive
The European Union Water Framework Directive, which came into force on 22 December 2000, has the
following key elements:
• It expands the scope of water protection to all waters. Distinctions are made between surface waters
(rivers, lakes, transitional and coastal waters), groundwater and protected areas, that is, areas that are
designated for water abstraction, protection of aquatic species or recreational purposes. “Water bodies”
are the units used for reporting and assessing compliance with the Directive’s environmental objectives.
For each surface water category, water bodies are differentiated according to their “type” (depending
on the ecoregion, geology, size, altitude, etc.). The main purpose of this typology is to enable type-
specific “reference conditions” to be defined, which are key to the quality assessment process.
• It sets a deadline of 2015 for achieving “good status” for all waters. For surface water, this comprises
both “good ecological status” and “good chemical status”. Good ecological status is defined in annex V
of the Directive in terms of the biological community, hydrological characteristics and physicochemical
characteristics. Member States are to report the ecological status for each surface water category in five
classes, ranging from “high” to “bad”. The boundary values are established through an intercalibration
exercise. Chemical status is reported as “good” or “failing to achieve good”. For groundwater, because
the presumption is that it should not be polluted at all, the approach is slightly different. There is a
prohibition on direct discharges and a requirement to reverse any anthropogenically induced upward
Source: European Parliament and
pollution trend. Besides reporting the chemical status, quantitative status is reported as either “good”
Council, Directive 2000/60/EC, Offi- or “poor”, depending on the sustainability of its use.
cial Journal of the European Com- • It endorses a “combined approach” of emission limit values and quality standards. In a precautionary
munities (22 December 2000).
Available from http://ec.europa.eu/
sense, it urges that all existing source-based controls be implemented. At the same time, a list of prior-
environment/water/water-frame- ity substances, annex X of the Directive, are defined and prioritized according to risk, the load of which
work/index_en.html. should be reduced based on an assessment of cost-effectiveness.
Water quality accounts 105
7.10. Quality describes the current state of a particular body of water in terms of certain
characteristics, called determinands. The term determinand is used rather than pollutant,
parameter or variable61 in order to underscore the fact that a determinand describes a feature
constitutive of the quality of a body of water; it is not exclusively associated with either human
activities or natural processes. Examples of determinands, as used in Le système d’évaluation
de la qualité des cours d’eau (the System for the Evaluation of the Quality of Water) or SEQ-
eau as it is widely known (see below), are depicted in the second column of table VII.1.
7.11. For policy purposes, such as for setting objectives and checking compliance, it is
necessary to define the quality of water by specifying the series of normative values for its
determinands, which represent the requirements for certain uses62 or the allowable deviations
from reference conditions, as in the previously mentioned European Union Water Framework
Directive, for example. For reasons of practicality and ease of reporting, as well as the inherent
uncertainty involved, water quality is eventually reported in the form of discrete classes. The
description of quality accounts in SEEA-2003 supposes that quality classes have been defined
(see section C).
7.12. The quality of a body of water may be approached in terms of its uses/functions,
although there is no standard classification of water uses/functions. Nonetheless, the uses/
functions most commonly used are drinking water, leisure, irrigation and industry; by con-
trast, France uses aquatic life, drinking water, leisure, irrigation, livestock and aquaculture.63
Table VII.1
Indicators and their determinands included in the System for the Evaluation of the Quality
of Water
Indicators Determinandsa
Organic and oxidizable matter Dissolved oxygen (O2), percentage of oxygen (%O2), chemical oxygen demand (COD),
biochemical oxygen demand (BOD), dissolved organic carbon (DOC), ammonium
minus nitrogen (NKj), ammonium (NH4)
Nitrogen (except nitrates) NH4+, NKj, nitrogen dioxide (NO2)
Nitrates Nitrate radical (NO3)
Phosphorus Phosphate (PO43-), total phosphorus
Suspended matter Suspended solids, turbidity, transparency
Colour Colour
Temperature Temperature
Salinity Conductivity, chlorine (Cl-), sulphate (SO42-), calcium (Ca2+), magnesium (Mg2+),
potassium (K+), toxic air contaminant (TAC), hardness (mineral content)
Acidity Acidity or alkalinity (pH), dissolved aluminium (Al)
Phytoplankton %O2, and pH, zero pigments (chlorophyll a + pheopigments), algae, ∆O2 (24 hours)
Source: Louis-Charles Oudin, “River qual-
Micro-organisms Total coliforms, faecal coliforms, faecal streptococci ity assessment system in France”, paper
Mineral micropollutants Arsenic, mercury, cadmium, lead, total chromium, zinc, copper, nickel, selenium, presented at the International Workshop
in water barium, cyanides Monitoring Tailor-Made III—Information
for Sustainable Water Management, Nun-
Metal on bryophytes (moss) Arsenic, mercury, cadmium, lead, total chromium, zinc, copper, nickel speet, Netherlands, 2001. Available from
Pesticides in water 37 substances are of concern http://www.mtm-conference.nl/mtm3/
docs/Oudin2001.pdf.
Organic pollutants 59 substances are of concern a The original list does not use the term
(except pesticides) in water determinand, but parameter.
61 Peter Kristensen and Jens Bøgestrand, Surface Water Quality Monitoring. Topic Report, Inland Waters
No. 2/96 (Copenhagen, European Environment Agency, 1996).
62 Russell E. Train, Quality Criteria for Water (London, Castle House Publications, 1979).
63 Louis-Charles Oudin and Danièle Maupas, Système d’ évaluation de la qualité des eaux des cours d’eau,
SEQ-eau, version 1, Les études des agences de l’eau n° 64 (Paris, Office International de l’eau, 1999).
106 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Australia and New Zealand mention aquatic ecosystems, primary industries, recreation and
aesthetics, drinking water and industrial use, as well as cultural and spiritual values, although
for the latter two categories no quality guidelines are provided.64 The Millennium Ecosys-
tem Assessment investigates functions such as services supplied by aquatic ecosystems: flood
mitigation, groundwater recharge, food provision and pollution control.65
7.13. Some researchers66 assess water quality in terms of hydrological power. That power
is defined based on topographic position, which gives indications of the potential for hydro-
electric power generation, and osmotic power due to salt concentrations, which limit water
availability for animal and plant nutrition.
7.14. Countries assign water uses/functions to bodies of water in different ways. France has
adopted an approach that uses the same water uses/function for all water bodies of a certain
type (rivers, lakes or groundwater) independent of the actual uses/functions of the specific
body of water.
7.15. Since 1999, France has used SEQ-eau67 as an assessment framework, which is based
on the concept of suitability for a use or function, with a specific instance for every category
of water (rivers, lakes, groundwater, etc.). For rivers, SEQ-eau considers five uses: drinking,
leisure, irrigation, livestock watering and aquaculture, and one function, aquatic life, which
together are called “uses”. The evaluation system is based on 15 suitability indicators (see
table VII.1), each expressing a possible alteration of suitability. For each use, a subset of these
indicators is selected: for example, for the use “irrigation” only 4 indicators apply, namely,
salinity, micro-organisms, micropollutants and pesticides, but for drinking water, 13 out of 15
apply. Each indicator has a set of determinands (a group of parameters having similar impacts)
selected from a list of 135 monitored parameters, as specified in table VII.1. For example, the
“nitrogen (except nitrates)” indicator is computed from the concentration values for NH4+,
NKj, NO2-. A class is assigned to each determinand of an indicator using threshold values
which are indicator-specific and use-specific. A final suitability class for each use can then be
defined by taking the worst score obtained for any relevant indicator, and for each indicator,
the worst score obtained for any determinand. When multiple samples are used during the
monitoring period, the “90th percentile” rule is applied.
7.16. In the French approach, it is possible to derive a global quality index and a global
quality class for a body of water. This is not done by taking the worst of the worst scores
obtained for the different uses of water, but by defining “quality” threshold values for each
indicator determinand and selecting the “suitability” threshold values associated with the
most restrictive use (considering only aquatic life, drinking water and leisure). For instance,
the high-quality threshold for nitrate is defined as 2 mg/l, the lower value of 2 mg/l being
for aquatic life and 50 mg/l for drinking water. The global quality index is the worst score
obtained for any indicator.
64 Australian and New Zealand Environment and Conservation Council (ANZECC) and Agriculture
and Resource Management Council of Australia and New Zealand (ARMCANZ), Australian and
New Zealand Guidelines for Fresh and Marine Water Quality, vol. 1, Guidelines (chaps. 1-7), Paper
No. 4, vol. 1, 2000. Available from http://www.mincos.gov.au/publications/australian_and_new_
zealand_guidelines_for_fresh_and_marine_water_quality.
65 Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Wetlands and Water Synthesis
(Washington, D.C., World Resources Institute, 2005).
66 G. Gascó and others, “Influence of salt concentration and topographical position on water resource
quality: the Spanish case study”, Water SA, vol. 31, No. 2, pp. 199-208 (2005). Available from http://
www.wrc.org.za.
67 Louis-Charles Oudin, “River quality assessment system in France”, paper presented at the International
Workshop Monitoring Tailor-Made III: Information for Sustainable Water Management, Nunspeet,
Netherlands, 2001. Available from http://www.mtm-conference.nl/mtm3/docs/Oudin2001.pdf.
Water quality accounts 107
7.17. Other countries, such as Australia and the United States of America, define water
uses/functions specific to the actual uses/functions of the body of water. For each such body,
a specific use or uses are identified and the quality criteria are set accordingly. The standards
are specific for the body of water. In the case of multiple uses, water quality could be defined
in terms of its most sensitive or stringent use. In Australia, for example, “where two or more
agreed uses are defined for a water body, the more conservative of the associated guidelines
should prevail and become the water quality objectives”.68
7.18. The quality assessment for ecological status used in the European Union Water
Framework Directive (see box VII.1) is not based on a specific classification for different
uses, but evaluates quality as the deviation from the reference conditions observed for each
“type” of body of water. The directive classifies surface water bodies into five ecological
status classes: high, good, moderate, poor and bad. This classification is the result of obser-
vations of quality elements: biological, physicochemical (as illustrated in table VII.2) and
hydromorphological.
7.19. The observation of a quality element depends on the monitoring of its determinands.
For example, three determinands are considered for the “oxygenation” quality element:
chemical oxygen demand, biochemical oxygen demand and dissolved oxygen. Each determi-
nand is valued using a “ratio” between 0 and 1, with values close to 1 representing reference
conditions for the type of body of water. The [0, 1] interval is divided into 5 subintervals for
each of the status classes. The boundaries between moderate and good status and between
good and high status are made comparable across countries through an intercalibration
exercise. In order to determine the quality class for a quality element, the values of a group
of determinands may be combined (by taking the average, median, etc.) when they show
Table VII.2
Physicochemical quality elements used for the ecological status classification of rivers in the European Union Water Framework
Directive
General The values of the physicochemical elements Temperature, oxygen balance, acidity or basicity, acid- Conditions consistent with
conditions correspond totally or nearly totally with neutralizing capacity and salinity do not reach levels the achievement of the
undisturbed conditions. outside the range established in order to ensure the values specified for the
Nutrient concentrations remain within the range functioning of the type-specific ecosystem and the biological quality elements.
normally associated with undisturbed conditions. achievement of the values specified for the biological
quality elements.
Levels of salinity, pH (acidity or basicity),
oxygen balance, acid neutralizing capacity and Nutrient concentrations do not exceed the levels
temperature do not show signs of anthropogenic established in order to ensure the functioning of the
disturbance and remain within the range ecosystem and the achievement of the values specified
normally associated with undisturbed conditions. for the biological quality elements.
Specific Concentrations close to zero and at least below Concentrations not in excess of the standards set in Conditions consistent with
synthetic the limits of detection of the most advanced accordance with the procedure detailed in section 1.2.6 the achievement of the
pollutants analytical techniques in general use. of the Directive without prejudice to Directive 91/414/EC values specified for the
and Directive 98/8/EC. biological quality elements.
Specific Concentrations remain within the range normally Concentrations not in excess of the standards set in Conditions consistent with
non-synthetic associated with undisturbed conditions. accordance with the procedure detailed in section 1.2.6 the achievement of the
pollutants of the Directive without prejudice to Directive 91/414/EC values specified for the
and Directive 98/8/EC. biological quality elements.
Source: European Parliament and Council, Directive 2000/60/EC—Official Journal of the European Communities (22 December 2000). Available from http://ec.europa.eu/
environment/water/water-framework/index_en.html.
Note: Waters achieving a status below moderate shall be classified as poor or bad. Waters showing evidence of major alterations in the values of the biological quali-
ty elements for the surface water body type and in which the relevant biological communities deviate substantially from those normally associated with the surface wa-
ter body type under undisturbed conditions shall be classified as poor. Waters showing evidence of severe alterations in the values of the biological quality elements for
the surface water body type and in which large portions of the relevant biological communities normally associated with the surface water body type under undisturbed
conditions are absent shall be classified as poor.
sensitivity to the same range of pressures; otherwise, the worst class is assigned to the quality
element. At the end, the worst class of all the relevant quality elements determines the status
class of the body of water.
Table VII.3
Quality accounts (physical units)
Quality classes
69 Johan Heldal and Torbjørn Østdahl, “Synoptic monitoring of water quality and water resources: A
suggestion on population and sampling approaches”, Statistical Journal of the United Nations, vol.
ECE2, pp. 393-406.
70 System of National Accounts, 2008, op. cit., para. 8.128.
Water quality accounts 109
7.25. The total quantity of SRUs should appear in the total column of table VII.3, even
though the quantity cannot be related to the total column in the asset accounts for rivers,
which is expressed in volume, not in SRUs. This quantity strongly depends on the mini-
mum size of rivers to be considered in a river basin. Because of the lack of adequate data,
the marginal contribution of the smallest rivers is generally unknown.
7.26. In the case of France, the national river system is composed of about 10.8 million
SRUs for its approximately 85 000 km of main courses; the river system is disaggregated
into 55 catchments. Estimates from the Institut Français de l’Environnement suggest that
considering all rivers mapped at a scale of 1:50000 would increase by a factor of 2.5 the total
SRUs mapped at a scale of 1:1400000.71 Therefore, it was concluded that the total quantity
of SRUs should not be aimed at covering the entire river system, but only that part of it
which is actually being monitored and is subject to quality assessment. The ratio between
the quantity of SRUs for the monitored rivers and an estimate of the quantity of SRUs
for the entire system produces an estimate of the monitoring coverage of the river system.
7.27. Table VII.4 shows the quality accounts for rivers in France as compiled for the years
1992 and 1994. Five quality classes are used, 1A (best), 1B, 2, 3 and NC (not classified)
(worst). The description of stocks according to quality was available for two years and the
figures are comparable because they were obtained from comparable assessment methods.
The quality accounts show that there has been an improvement between the two years:
there are more SRUs in good quality classes (1A and 1B) and fewer in poor quality classes
(3 and NC).
7.28. In the case of groundwater, since the flow is very low, quality accounts can be con-
structed directly in volumetric units, such as cubic metres. Table VII.5 provides an example
of quality accounts for groundwater in Australia, using salinity levels for defining quality
classes: fresh (salinity < 500 mg of sodium chloride per litre), marginal (500 < salinity <
1 500), brackish (1 500 < salinity < 5 000) and saline (salinity > 5 000). These categories
correspond to potential limitations for economic uses: fresh quality is recommended for
human consumption, marginal quality can be used for irrigation and, at the end of the
range, some industrial processes are able to use very saline water, including sea water (the
salinity of which is about 35 000 mg/l).
Table VII.4
Quality accounts of French watercourses by size class (organic matter indicator: in 1 000 standard river units)
1A 1B 2 3 NC 1A 1B 2 3 NC 1A 1B 2 3 NC
Main rivers 5 1 253 891 510 177 3 336 9 -183 -165 8 1 583 893 358 12
Main tributaries 309 1 228 1 194 336 50 16 464 -275 -182 -22 325 1 691 919 154 288
Small rivers 260 615 451 128 47 44 130 -129 -17 -28 306 749 322 110 188
Brooks 860 1 464 690 243 95 -44 176 228 15 -23 810 1 295 917 258 72
Source: Institut Français de l’Environnement, The Accounts of the Quality of the Watercourses: Implementation of a Simplified Method, On-going Development
(Paris, IFEN, 1999).
Note: The figures in the middle column (in italics) do not in all cases match precisely the calculated difference between 1992 and 1994. This is because of difficulties in
comparing certain groups of watercourses in some watershed basins between the two years. The “organic matter indicator” considers the following parameters: dissolved
oxygen, biochemical oxygen demand at five days, chemical oxygen demand and ammonium. It also considers eutrophication and the presence of nitrates.
Table VII.5
Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, Accounts of groundwater quality in Victorian provinces, Australia, 1985 and 1998 (gigalitres)
Water Account for Australia 1993-94 to
1996-97 (Canberra, ABS, 2000).
Fresh Marginal Brackish Saline Total
Abbreviation: n/a = not applicable.
a The 1998 assessments are based on 1985 477.5 339.2 123.3 32.3 972.3
permissible annual volume (PAV), which
1998 (incomplete)a (39.1) (566.6) (141.1) (n/a) (746.8)
is equivalent to sustainable yield.
7.29. Although complete accounts could not be established in 1998 (only groundwater
in so-called groundwater management areas was monitored), the study of the major dif-
ferences between the two assessments shows a shift from the fresh to the marginal water
quality category. The volume of brackish water also increased between the two years.
7.30. Quality accounting is useful for following the evolution of the water quality and it
furnishes an indication of the efficiency of the measures taken to protect or improve the state
of bodies of water. The comparison of changes in “stocks of quality” is expected to provide
an assessment of the effectiveness of protective and restorative measures.
7.31. There is a complication, however, as changes in water quality may have different
causes. The changes could result from the emission of pollutants, self-purification, changes
in dilution factors owing to the increased abstraction of water and increased run-off due to
uncontrolled events or new regulations restricting emissions, among other such events. Each
of these events has an effect, positive or negative, on changes in water quality. This is illus-
trated in the conceptual scheme below: water quality at time t1 is the result of an unknown
non-linear function f of water quality at t0 and possible causes (including interactions):
Water quality t1 = f(water quality t0, ∆(uncontrolled events), ∆(abstractions), ∆(emissions),
∆(expenditure))
where ∆(uncontrolled events) signifies the change that occurred between t 0 and t1 which
cannot be related to any event in the economic sphere; and ∆(abstractions), ∆(emissions)
and ∆(expenditure) represent causes related to the economic sphere. Thus, it is difficult to
attribute changes in stocks of quality to the direct causes. Quality accounts have therefore a
much simpler structure than the asset accounts.
7.32. It should be noted, however, that analyses of cost-effectiveness may be carried out with
the help of these accounts. An example is supplied in the following situation: the global qual-
ity of water at t0 was 6.6; there were no major natural events during the accounting period;
no less emissions; and no more abstractions on this particular stretch of river. If measuring
the quality at t1 shows that it has increased to 7.0, this change of 0.4 could be attributed to
the environmental expenditures that were made (for instance, to restore the self-purification
capacity of the ecosystem) and derive a cost-effectiveness estimate as the ratio 0.4/∆(expendi-
ture). However, this does not imply that the quality increase would have been 0.8 if the
expenditures had been doubled in value.
D. Issues
1. The choice of determinands
7.33. Different countries use different determinands, as illustrated by table VII.6. Large
differences exist in both the number and choice of the determinands used; also, the number
of common determinands is very low. This variety reflects primarily different concepts and
understandings of local problems. The large difference in pesticides, for instance, reflects the
existence of different agricultural practices.
Water quality accounts 111
7.34. The choice of determinands is the outcome of a scientific, practical, economical and
political compromise. Some important determinands cannot be reliably and affordably
monitored. This is especially so for pesticides, of which only a few dozen can be accurately
quantified among the several hundred active substances in use. The same problem occurs
when considering biological toxins, especially cyanotoxins, and endocrine disruptors. Large
numbers of chemicals, such as toxic hydrocarbon derivatives, are virtually insoluble in water;
they pose considerable problems when attempts are made to obtain reliable samples.
7.35. There has been little or no standardization of determinands or the methods to measure
them, or of threshold values to define quality classes. The main consequence of this lack of
standardization has been the inability to compare accounts across countries. In the context
of the previously mentioned Directive, attempts are under way to standardize both the choice
of determinands and the threshold values for assessing quality classes.
Table VII.6
Number of determinands per chemical group in different assessment systems
to several indicators or several uses, the rule means that all indicators or uses must be taken
into account equally. It is the first instance of this rule which is problematic, as is shown in
figure VII.1 for arbitrary values.
7.37. Figure VII.1 represents a hypothetical situation in which 12 measurements are obtained
from 2 locations (A and B) in years 1 and 2. Each point represents the quality index result-
ing for each sample; each of them is plotted in the figure, in which the 5 quality classes are
represented on the y axis. Location B shows a significant improvement in quality during year
2. However, since 2 measurements are in the worst class, year 2 is classified identically as
year 1. The case of location A is slightly different: it is classified as the worst in year 1 and as
bad in year 2, despite the fact that the results suggest a significant improvement in quality.
7.38. Several issues arise with regard to the rule of the worst. Extreme values, as illustrated
in figure VII.1, can have a significant impact on the eventual classification of a body of water.
A body of water is classified as bad regardless of whether it has only a single trespassing value,
or has a permanently bad quality status. Furthermore, the improvement in monitoring often
results in the apparent worsening of the quality index (a larger number of measurements of
a larger number of determinands increases the probability of monitoring extreme values).
Finally, the rule of the worst tends to hide seasonal variations.
7.39. One possible solution in dealing with extreme values is to smooth the effect. As an
example, according to the French SEQ-eau approach, the score for each indicator is deter-
mined by the most downgrading sample observed in at least 10 per cent of the samples ana-
lysed during the monitoring period.72
7.40. An alternative to the rule of the worst is exemplified by the Canadian federal sys-
tem.73 The principle is based on the weighting of three factors of trespassing values at each
site. It takes into account the number of determinands beyond their threshold: scope (S) =
number of failed determinands (variables, the objectives of which have not been met/total
number of determinands monitored); the frequency with which the objectives have not been
met during the assessment period (frequency (F) = number of failed tests/total number of
tests); and the distance (or amplitude) between the threshold and the observed value (excur-
sion (E) = [observed value/target value] – 1. All factors are normalized so that they fall within
the range of 0 to 100.
7.41. The final CCME Water Quality Index (CCME WQI) is equal to 100 minus the
length of the three-dimensional vector [S,F,E] normalized to 0-100.
S2 + F 2 + E2
CCMEWQI =100 −
3
This means that CCME WQI is 100 (best quality) when the length of the vector [S,F,E]
is zero. By construction, the index can be applied to different sets of determinands and
therefore different uses of water, as long as annual series exist in order to assess frequency.
The authors recommend that datasets should have at least four values per year. The over-
all quality is classified in one of 5 classes: excellent (100-95); good (94-80); fair (79-65);
marginal (64-45) and poor (44-0).
Figure VII.1
Comparison of assessment rules for two different sets of data
80
A Year 1
Good
60
Mediocre B Year 2
40
Bad
B Year 1
20
Worst
∑ Sj × Gj
10 j
RQGI = ×
n ∑ Sj
j
7.46. As an application, figure VII.2 shows the RQGI score for each river basin in England
and Wales in the period 1997-1999.74 The overall index for all reviewed catchments improved
from 6.50 in 1990 to 7.47 in that period.
7.47. As an application of the pattern index, figure VII.3 shows the aggregated map of river
basins in the Republic of Ireland and Northern Ireland having potentially mediocre-quality
waters. These basins, although not showing a high proportion of bad quality waters, record
a low proportion of good quality waters. Owing to their low variance in quality per stretch,
severe water quality problems could be an issue.
Figure VII.2
Global river quality in England and Wales, United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern
Ireland, 1997-1999
74 Environment Agency of England and Wales and published in European Environment Agency report
entitled, Test Application of Quality Water Accounts in England and Wales, prepared by Beture-Cerec
(Copenhagen, EEA, 2001).
Water quality accounts 115
Figure VII.3
Pattern index for the Republic of Ireland and Northern Ireland, 1990
Quality pattern
Good (19)
Acceptable/Local (10)
Mediocre/Local (4)
Bad/Black spots (0)
Very bad (0)
ND (7)
Chapter VIII
Valuation of water resources
A. Introduction
8.1. National accounts value water in the same way that they value all other products: at
the price of water transactions. Unlike many other products, however, the prices charged for
water often furnish only a poor and inadequate indicator of water’s economic value, a situa-
tion arising from the following unique characteristics of water:
(a) Water is a heavily regulated commodity for which the price charged (if any) often
bears little relation to its economic value or even to its cost of supply. This situa-
tion is sometimes severe in water-scarce developing countries where water may be
supplied to some users at no charge. Administered prices occur in part because
the natural characteristics of water inhibit the emergence of competitive markets
that establish economic value;75
(b) Water supply often has the characteristics of a natural monopoly because water
storage and distribution are subject to economies of scale;
(c) Property rights, essential for competitive markets, are often absent and not always
easy to define when the uses of water exhibit characteristics of a public good
(flood mitigation), a collective good (a sink for wastes), or when water is subject
to multiple and/or sequential use;
(d) Water is a “bulky” commodity, that is, its weight-to-value ratio is very low, inhib-
iting the development of markets beyond those in the local area;
(e) Large amounts of water are abstracted for own use by industries other than those
under ISIC division 36 (water collection, treatment and supply), such as agricul-
ture or mining. Abstraction for own use is not recorded explicitly as an interme-
diate input of water; hence, the use of water is underestimated and the value of
water’s contribution, for example, to agriculture, is not explicit but accrues to the
operating surplus of agriculture.
8.2. The need to treat water as an economic good has been recognized as an essential com-
ponent of sustainable water management. IWRM, the previously described concept for water
management, identifies maximizing the economic value obtained from the use of water and
from investments in the water sector as two of its key objectives, along with equity and envi-
ronmental sustainability.76 This principle has been reaffirmed at international meetings and
75 For a more detailed exploration of this topic, see William K. Easter, Nir Becker and Yacov Tsur, “Eco-
nomic mechanisms for managing water resources: Pricing, permits and markets”, in Water Resources:
Environmental Planning, Management and Development, Asit K. Biswas, ed. (New York, McGraw-
Hill, 1997); and Robert A. Young, Measuring Economic Benefits for Water Investments and Policies,
World Bank Technical Paper, No. 338 (Washington, D.C., World Bank, 1996).
76 Global Water Partnership, “Integrated water resources management”, TAC Background Paper 4
(Stockholm, GWP, 2000).
118 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
in major publications.77 Nevertheless, the prices charged for water recorded in the national
accounts often do not reflect its full economic value.
8.3. The economic valuation of water can be useful in many policy areas, for example, to
assess efficiency in the development and allocation of water resources. Efficient and equitable
allocation of water takes into account the value of water used by competing end-users in
the current generation, the allocation of resources between current and future generations
and the degree to which wastes discharged into water are treated among other activities that
affect water quality. Water valuation can also be useful in setting water pricing policy and in
the design of economic instruments to achieve better use of water resources. Instruments for
water comprise property rights, tradable water markets, taxes on water depletion and pollu-
tion, and subsidies for water demand management.
8.4. Economists have developed techniques for estimating the value of water. This chap-
ter reviews the techniques for valuation and discusses their consistency with the 2008 SNA
valuation. It does not make recommendations on which valuation technique should be used;
the chapter should be seen as an overview of existing practices. Further, because there is
no consensus on the valuation techniques to use or on the inclusion of these techniques in
SEEA-Water (because of their lack of consistency with the 2008 SNA valuation principle),
this chapter is presented as an add-on to the water accounts because of its policy relevance.
8.5. The valuation techniques reviewed include those commonly used for the water goods
and services currently included in the water accounts:
(a) Water as an intermediate input to production in agriculture and manufacturing;
(b) Water as a final consumer good;
(c) Environmental services of water for waste assimilation.
8.6. Other water values, notably, for recreation, navigation and biodiversity protection,
and water qualities, such as reliability and timing of water availability, are not addressed.
8.7. Section B discusses some issues that arise in valuing water, such as the aggregation
of water values from the local to the national levels. Section C describes some background
concepts in the economic valuation of water and the valuation principle of the 2008 SNA.
Section D provides an overview of the valuation techniques and section E discusses the
strengths and weakness of each water valuation technique through empirical examples.
77 The World Summit on Sustainable Development, which was held in Johannesburg, South Afri-
ca, from 26 August to 4 September 2002; the Third World Water Forum, held in Kyoto, Japan,
16-23 March 2003; and the Millennium Project Report to the United Nations Secretary-General:
Investing in Development: A Practical Plan to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals (New York,
UNDP, 2005).
Valuation of water resources 119
as a river basin. There has been little experience in aggregating these localized values at the
national level.
8.10. Because water is a bulky commodity and the costs of transporting and storing it are
often high, the value of water is determined by local and regional site-specific characteristics
and options for its use. For example, the value of water as an input to agriculture will often
vary a great deal by region because of differing factors that affect production costs and prod-
uct value, including soil, climate, market demand, cost of inputs, etc. In addition, the timing
of water availability, the quality of water and the reliability of its supply are also important
determinants of the value of water. Consequently, the value of water can vary enormously
within a country, even for the same sector.
8.11. The site-specific nature of water values means that those estimated for one area of a
country cannot be assumed to apply in other areas. This poses a problem for constructing
accounts for water value at the national level, because the method commonly employed for
national accounts—scaling up to the national level from sample data—cannot be applied
as readily. It is more accurate and useful for policymakers to construct water accounts at the
level of a river basin or an accounting catchment for which economic information can be
compiled, and aggregate them at the national level in order to obtain national water accounts.
River basin accounts may also be more useful for policymakers because many water manage-
ment decisions are taken at the level of the river basin, and even policy at the national level
must take into account regional variations in water supply, demand and value. Furthermore,
in some countries, there may be extensive transfers of water between river basins. Interbasin
transfers are often valued according to the use made of the water in the receiving river basin.
2. Double counting
8.12. In interpreting accounts for the value of water, care must be taken to avoid double
counting. The value of water as an intermediate input is already fully included in the 2008
SNA, although it is rarely identified explicitly; for example:
(a) For industries purchasing water from ISIC classes 0161 (support activities for crop
production-operation of agricultural irrigation equipment) and 36 (water collec-
tion, treatment and supply), the water value in the 2008 SNA is spread out among
three components of an industry’s production costs: the service charge paid, any
additional current and capital costs (purchases of equipment, energy, labour and
other inputs) incurred by a company for the treatment, storage or transport of
water, and industry value added where any residual water value accrues;
(b) For industries abstracting water for own use, the value of water is split between
the costs incurred for the abstraction, transport, treatment or storage of water,
and the industry’s value added;
(c) For households, water value in the 2008 SNA includes the portion paid to water
utilities or incurred by self-providers for abstraction.
8.13. The value of wastewater treatment may be reflected partly in the cost of services
provided under ISIC division 37, sewerage, and the costs of self-treatment by industry and
households. Damage to industrial productive capacity as a result of changes in water quality
and the cost to industry of averting behaviour are already included in the 2008 SNA as part
of the affected industries’ costs of production. Some averting behaviour by consumers and
health costs may be included in the 2008 SNA as part of consumer expenditures, but others
may not be, or they may not be easy to identify. The value of recreational or aesthetic water
services to consumers may also be reflected, at least partly, in the market prices of land, hous-
ing or tourism facilities.
120 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
8.14. In summary, most values for water are already included in the 2008 SNA, but they are
not explicitly attributed to water. The role of water valuation is to make those values explicit;
however, they should not be interpreted as additional values not included in the 2008 SNA.
The value of water when extracted directly from the water resources is part of the SNA pro-
duction boundary. As such its value should be imputed even if no transaction takes place.
78 Office of Management and Budget of the United States, “Draft 2003 report to Congress on the costs
and benefits of federal regulations”, Federal Register, vol. 68, No. 22 (3 February 2003), pp. 5492-5527.
Valuation of water resources 121
Box VIII.1
Shadow prices
In economic analysis, such as an evaluation of alternative allocations of water among competing users,
it is necessary to express the costs and benefits in monetary terms, using prices and quantities. Often,
observed prices are used; however, observed prices sometimes fail to reflect true economic values.
Examples include government regulation that sets prices for commodities, such as water and energy;
taxes or subsidies that distort market prices of agricultural commodities; minimum wages that are set
above market-clearing prices; or trade restrictions that increase the price of domestically produced
goods. In such cases, it is necessary to adjust the observed market price to accommodate these distor-
tions. In other cases, there may be no market price at all, and the price must be estimated. The resulting
adjusted or estimated price is called a “shadow price”.
8.22. The 2008 SNA records actual market (and near market) transactions; the 2008 SNA
value of a product is its market price. In competitive markets, prices represent the marginal
values of goods and services. However, there are many instances in which observed prices may
differ from marginal values, sometimes significantly, owing to factors such as market failure,
administered prices, taxes and subsidies, and trade protection. Sometimes these distortions
may be large; other times they may be small.
8.23. Non-market valuation techniques estimate marginal value, average value or total
economic value, which includes “consumer surplus” in addition to the market price paid.
122 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Consumer surplus is the difference between what an individual is willing to pay and the price
that the individual actually pays. The difference arises because all consumers are charged the
same price in a given market regardless of what the consumer is willing to pay. Prices in the
2008 SNA may be quite different from marginal values, but the 2008 SNA does not include
measures of consumer surplus. The relationships among these three concepts of economic
value are illustrated in figure VIII.1 and described below:
(a) The total economic value of water is measured as the sum of the total willingness
to pay of all consumers, and is typically displayed as the area under the demand
curve. For quantity Q*, total economic value is the area A + B. This measure is
appropriate in applications such as cost-benefit analysis when the purpose is to
measure the total change in economic welfare;
(b) The figure (A + B)/Q* represents the average value of a unit of water when Q*
units of water are used. The average value is larger than the marginal value (by
the amount A/Q*) because it includes a portion of consumer surplus, the dif-
ference between the consumers’ willingness to pay (the demand curve) and the
market price;
(c) P* represents the marginal value of a unit of water at Q*. For an individual, the
marginal value represents the benefit from the use of one more unit of water.
For a business, the marginal value represents the increase in net revenue made
possible by increasing water input by one unit. The marginal value is relevant for
assessing the economic efficiency of the allocation of water among alternative
uses. Competitive market prices equal the marginal value.
8.24. In some instances it is easier to measure total and average values than marginal
values, but the consequences for valuation can be large. For example, it is not uncommon
for practitioners to estimate the total damage resulting from water pollution, then divide
that estimate by the tons of pollutant emitted in order to obtain the average damage per ton
of pollutant. This average value is likely to differ significantly from the marginal values if
the dose/concentration-response function is non-linear. It can be quite misleading to apply
the average value obtained from one study in one location to another location, or even the
same location at a different point in time. As mentioned previously, water services are often
provided and acquired without trade or through trade in imperfect markets; hence, infor-
mation is not available for the specification of proper demand functions and the calculation
Figure VIII.1
Demand curve for water
Price
Demand curve
A
A
P*
of marginal or total economic values. In such cases, cost rather than benefit-based measures
are commonly used to value water.
Box VIII.2
Categories of economic values for water
Use values
• Direct use values: the direct use of water resources for consumptive uses, such as input to agricul-
ture, manufacturing and domestic use; and non-consumptive uses, such as generating hydroelectric
power, recreation, navigation and cultural activities
• Indirect use values: the indirect environmental services provided by water, such as waste assimila-
tion, habitat and biodiversity protection and hydrologic function
• Option value: the value of maintaining the option for use of water, direct or indirect, in the future
Non-use values
• Bequest value: the value of nature left for the benefit of future generations
• Existence value: the intrinsic value of water and water ecosystems, including biodiversity; for ex-
ample, the value people place simply on knowing that a wild river exists, even if they never visit it
124 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
may not be available, such as for protecting wetlands or endangered species. In the next sec-
tion, each technique is described in greater detail.79
Table VIII.1
Valuation techniques for water
79 A more detailed discussion of valuation methodologies for water, with references to many studies in
the literature, can be found in Diana C. Gibbons, The Economic Value of Water (Washington, D.C.,
Resources for the Future, 1986); Kerry Turner and others, “Economic valuation of water resources
in agriculture: from the sectoral to a functional perspective of natural resource management”, FAO
Water Reports 27 (Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 2004); and
Robert A. Young, Measuring Economic Benefits for Water Investments and Policies, op. cit. An exhaus-
tive review of water valuation studies in the United States can be found in the work by Kenneth D.
Frederick, Tim Vandenburg and Jean Hanson, “Economic values of freshwater in the United States”,
Resources for the Future, Discussion Paper 97-03 (Washington, D.C., RFF, 1997).
80 Frederick, Vandenburg and Hanson, “Economic values of freshwater”, ibid.; Gibbons, The Economic
Value of Water, op. cit.; and Young, Measuring Economic Benefits, op cit.
Valuation of water resources 125
(a) Residual value, change in net income and production function approaches
8.33. Residual value and its related techniques of change in net income and the production
function approach are techniques applied to water used as an intermediate input into produc-
tion. They are based on the idea that a profit-maximizing firm will use water up to the point
where the net revenue gained from one additional unit of water is just equal to the marginal
cost of obtaining the water. Residual valuation assumes that if all markets are competitive
except for water, then the total value of production exactly equals the opportunity costs of all
the inputs. When the opportunity costs of non-water inputs are given by their market prices
(or when their shadow prices can be estimated), then the shadow price of water is equal to
the difference (the residual) between the value of the output and the costs of all non-water
inputs to production, using the following formulas:
TVP = ∑ pi qi + VMPw qw
TVP − ∑ pi qi
VMPw = qw
where
81 Peter H. Gleick, ed., Water in Crisis: A Guide to the World’s Fresh Water Resources (New York, Oxford
University Press, 1993).
82 Gibbons, The Economic Value of Water, op. cit.
83 Young, Measuring Economic Benefits, op. cit.
84 Gunnar Brånvall and others, Water Accounts: Physical and Monetary Data Connected to Abstraction,
Use and Discharge of Water in the Swedish NAMEA (Stockholm, Statistics Sweden, 1999).
85 Hua Wang and Somik Lall, “Valuing water for Chinese industries: a marginal productivity
approach”, paper prepared for the World Bank Development Research Group, World Bank, Wash-
ington, D.C., 1999.
86 Frederick, Vandenburg and Hanson, “Economic values of freshwater”, op. cit.
126 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
87 Robert Johansson, “Pricing irrigation water: a literature survey”, World Bank Policy Research Work-
ing Paper, No. 2449 (Washington, D.C., World Bank, 2000).
88 Glenn-Marie Lange, “Water accounts in Namibia”, in Glenn-Marie Lange and Rashid M. Hassan,
The Economics of Water Management in Southern Africa: An Environmental Accounting Approach (Chel-
tenham, Edward Edgar Publishing, 2006); and Glenn-Marie Lange, “Estimating the value of water
in agriculture: Case studies from Namibia”, paper presented at the Biennial Conference of the Inter-
national Society for Ecological Economics, 6-9 March 2002, Souse, Tunisia.
Valuation of water resources 127
Box VIII.3
Calculating residual value: an example from Namibia
The residual value technique was applied to agricultural production in the Stampriet region of Namibia,
where farmers abstract groundwater to raise cattle and irrigate crops, including lucerne, for their livestock.
A survey was undertaken in 1999 and data for farm income and costs were obtained for 16 of the 66 farmers
in the region. The data on some items are considered reasonably accurate, notably, farm income, inputs of
most goods and services, and the compensation of employees. Fixed capital costs, one of the largest cost
components, were difficult to estimate because farmers often did not keep good records. Farmers also do
not always meter their water use; thus, the estimates of water use must be treated with caution. From the
survey, average farm income and costs were calculated. Average residual value was calculated using the
following formula:
Gross farm income - inputs of goods and services - compensation of employees - farmers’
imputed income - capital costs (depreciation, working capital, cost of fixed capital)
Despite the weakness of the data, the results are useful in illustrating the sensitivity of the residual method
to the assumptions made. The table below shows the costs of production and residual value of water
under different assumptions about the cost of capital. Assuming a 5 per cent cost for capital investments,
the residual value of water was 19 Namibian cents per cubic metre. However, if the real cost of capital rose
to 7 per cent, farmers would not earn enough to cover even the capital costs and the value of the water
would be negative.
Farm revenue and costs (in 1999 Namibian dollars) Data source
Gross farm income $601 543 Output multiplied by market prices obtained from
survey
Source: Adapted from Glenn-Marie
Inputs of goods and services $242 620 Inputs multiplied by prices obtained from survey Lange, “Water valuation case stud-
ies in Namibia”, in Glenn-Marie Lange
Value added, of which: $358 923 and Rashid M. Hassan, The Econom-
Compensation of employees $71 964 Wages paid + in kind payments obtained from survey ics of Water Management in South-
ern Africa: An Environmental Ac-
Gross operating surplus, of which: $286 959 counting Approach (Cheltenham,
Imputed value of farmers’ $48 000 Imputed value based on average salary of hired farm United Kingdom, Edward Elgar Pub-
labour manager lishing, 2006); Glenn-Marie Lange, J.
MacGregor and Simon Masirembu,
Depreciation $66 845 Standard depreciation rates multiplied by farmers’ “The economic value of groundwa-
estimated historical cost of capital in survey ter: case study of Stampriet, Namib-
Cost of working capital $17 059 Imputed as percentage of the value of fixed capital ia”, paper presented at the Workshop
of the Resource Accounting Network
Cost of fixed capital $75 739 to $176 724 Based on farmers’ estimated historical cost of capital of East and Southern Africa, Preto-
including land, 3-7 per cent reported in survey ria, South Africa, 4-8 June 2000; and
Glenn-Marie Lange, “Estimating the
Residual value of water $79 316 to -$21 669
value of water in agriculture: Case
Amount of water used 154 869 Farmers’ “best guess” (water is not metered) studies from Namibia”, paper pre-
(cubic metres) sented at the Biennial Conference
of the International Society for Eco-
Residual value (Namibian dollars/ $0.51 to -$0.14 logical Economics, 6-9 March 2002,
cubic metre) Souse, Tunisia.
8.39. It is not uncommon for Governments to subsidize the costs of critical inputs to
agriculture, notably, fertilizer and energy. Some developing countries also fix the price paid
for major agricultural crops, often below their marginal value. In other countries, the price
of agricultural commodities may not be directly subsidized, but trade protection is used to
maintain high crop prices. In applying the residual value technique, these distorted input
and output prices must first be corrected.
8.40. Box VIII.4 shows two examples of residual value adjusted for trade protection: the
United Kingdom and Jordan. In the example of the United Kingdom, information was not
available concerning the amount of water used for each crop, so the residual value is given as
the value per hectare, that is, for the total amount of water required to cultivate a given crop
128 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
on a hectare of land. After correcting for trade protection, only one crop, potatoes, would
generate a positive return to water.
8.41. For irrigated farming, capital can be a substantial component of costs, and the
correct costing of capital raises several challenges. In some studies, fixed capital may be
omitted entirely or in part.89 This may be appropriate when there is a short-term disruption
in the water supply, such as a drought, where the objective is to maximize profits by allocat-
ing water to higher-value crops under such unusual short-term conditions. However, these
short-term values of water do not reflect the long-term values; they are not appropriate for
long-term water management because they are overestimated.
8.42. Residual value, as described above, is suitable for a single-crop or single-product
operation. For multiple products, a slightly different version is used: the change in net
income (CNI) approach. CNI measures the change in net income from all crops as a result
of a change in the input of water, rather than the value of all water used in production.
The CNI approach is often used to compare the value of water under current allocation
to the value that would be obtained under an alternative allocation of water. For example,
this technique might be used to assess a farmer’s response to a policy initiative intended to
bring about a change in crop mix or production technology. In contrast to residual value,
CNI measures the marginal value of water by measuring the impact of a change, rather
than the average value obtained with the residual value approach.
8.43. It has been noted that the CNI approach is used more often than the single-crop
residual value approach.90 The use of CNI encounters the same problems in correctly
specifying the production function and correcting for missing or distorted prices. Since
CNI essentially compares existing production to a hypothetical change, it faces additional
data challenges in correctly specifying the resulting income and costs of production for the
alternative.
8.44. The “production function approach” uses regression analysis, usually for a cross-
section of farmers or manufacturers, to estimate a production function, or, equivalently,
a cost function which represents the relationship between inputs and outputs, specifically
water and crop yields. The functions are developed from experiments, mathematical simu-
lation models and statistical analyses of survey or secondary data. The marginal value of
water is obtained by differentiating the function with respect to water, that is, measuring
the marginal change in output, or reduction in cost, that results from a small change in
water input.
8.45. The production function approach and mathematical programming (see below) are
the most widely applied techniques for valuing water used in manufacturing. The residual
value method is not used for water valuation in industry because the cost share of water
is quite small in most industrial applications and the residual value method is very sensi-
tive to the quantity of water input. A production function approach has also been used to
measure the marginal value of water in manufacturing (see box VIII.5).91 A similar study
was undertaken in China in 1993, using data for about 2 000 firms, mostly medium-sized
and large State-owned enterprises.92
89 For example, Radwan A. Al-Weshah, “Optimal use of irrigation water in the Jordan Valley: a case
study”, Water Resources Management, vol. 14, No. 5, pp. 327-338.
90 Young, Measuring Economic Benefits, op. cit.
91 Steven Renzetti and Diane Dupont, “The value of water in manufacturing”, CSERGE Working Paper
ECM 03-03 (Norwich, United Kingdom, University of East Anglia’s Centre for Social and Economic
Research on the Global Environment, 2003).
92 Wang and Lall, “Valuing water”, op. cit.
Valuation of water resources 129
Box VIII.4
Adjusting the residual value of water for market distortions
The case studies for the United Kingdom and Jordan show the importance of adjusting for market distor-
tions occurring as a result of trade protection. In both cases, the residual value of water is calculated with
and without the effective subsidies from trade protection. Substantial differences occur as a result.
Case 1. United Kingdom. Bate and Dubourg estimated the residual value of water used for irrigating five
crops in East Anglia from 1987 to 1991, using data from farm budget surveys. However, because data about
actual water use were not available, the residual value was calculated for the amount of water needed
to cultivate a hectare of a given crop. When the effective subsidies from the European Union’s Common
Agricultural Programme are taken into account, the residual value is negative for all crops except potatoes.
Case 2. Jordan. Schiffler calculated residual value for fruit crops (apples, peaches, olives, grapes) and veg-
etable crops (tomatoes, watermelon, cucumbers, squash and wheat) in 1994 based on data from farm
surveys. Values were calculated with and without trade protection. The difference was small (7 per cent)
for fruit crops, but nearly 50 per cent for vegetables.
Box VIII.5
Marginal value of water in Canada, by industry, 1991
Using a production function approach, the marginal value of raw water was estimated for 58 manufac-
turing industries in Canada in 1981, 1986 and 1991. Assuming that firms would minimize their costs, the
researchers formulated a translog cost function based on the quantity of output; the quantity of water;
the price of capital, labour, energy, materials, water recirculation and in-plant water treatment; as well as
several dummy variables that took into consideration site-specific and industry-specific characteristics,
such as the aridity of provinces and the share of raw water that was used for industrial processes. In the
cost function approach, the shadow price of water was estimated as the marginal change in costs resulting
from an incremental change in the quantity of raw water intake. The mean shadow value across industries
was C$ 0.046 per cubic metre in 1991 prices. In very dry provinces, the shadow value was higher than in
water-abundant provinces: C$ 0.098 and C$ 0.032, respectively.
used to determine the impact of trade reform on the shadow value of water in agriculture.93
The long-term change in shadow prices (the shadow prices themselves are not reported)
ranged from -22 per cent for wheat to +25 per cent for fruits and vegetables.
93 Xinshen Diao and Terry Roe, “The win-win effect of joint water market and trade reform on interest
groups in irrigated agriculture in Morocco”, in The Political Economy of Water Pricing Reforms, Ariel
Dinar, ed. (New York, Oxford University Press, 2000).
Valuation of water resources 131
Box VIII.6
Linear programming approach to valuing irrigation water
Box VIII.7
Hedonic valuation of the quantity and quality of irrigation water
Hedonic pricing was used to estimate the value of water for irrigation use in Cyprus where saltwater intru-
sion is occurring in coastal areas. The researchers had to address an additional challenge to hedonic model-
ling: land could be used for either agriculture or tourism. Land that is closer to the sea is less productive for Source: Phoebe Koundouri and Pa-
agriculture owing to saltwater intrusion, but it has a higher value for tourism. Therefore, they regressed land nos Pashardes, “Hedonic price analy-
values (from a 1999 survey of 282 landowners) on a number of variables reflecting existing infrastructure, sis and selectivity bias”, in Economics
location, quality of land and the salinity of the underlying groundwater, which was represented by proxim- of Water Resources, Theory and Pol-
icy, Panos Pashardes, Timothy Swan-
ity to the coast. The sample selection included only agricultural land users, excluding land used for tour- son and Anastasios Xepapadeas, eds.
ism so that the value of the land would not be affected by the demand for land for tourism. The marginal (Dordrecht, Netherlands, Kluwer Ac-
amount farmers were willing to pay for avoiding saline groundwater was 10.7 pounds sterling per hectare. ademic Publishers, 2002), pp. 69-80.
94 For an overview of these markets and how they function, see Alberto Garrido, “The economics of
water allocation and the feasibility of water markets in agriculture”, in Sustainable Management of
Water in Agriculture (Paris, OECD, 2003).
95 Young, Measuring Economic Benefits, op. cit.
132 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
1 per cent of the total abstractions by the mid-1990s and prices ranged from US$ 250 to
$4 500 a share (4 250 cubic metres).96 The development of water markets was greatest in
areas with effective water-use associations, well-defined property rights and good irrigation
infrastructure (large reservoirs and adjustable gates with flow meters); in areas without these
characteristics, high transaction costs limited the development of the water market. In a few
countries, tradable water rights may furnish a basis for water valuation in the future, but this
technique has not yet been applied.
96 Monica Rios Brehm and Jorge Quiroz, The Market for Water Rights in Chile, World Bank Technical
Paper, No. 285 (Washington, D.C., World Bank, 1995); and Robert R. Hearne and K. William
Easter, Water Allocation and Water Markets: An Analysis of Gains from Trade in Chile, World Bank
Technical Paper, No. 315 (Washington, D.C., World Bank, 1995).
97 For a more detailed discussion, see Ian Walker and others, “Pricing, subsidies and the poor: demand
for improved water services in Central America”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper,
No.2468 (Washington, D.C., World Bank, 2000).
98 Ibid.
Valuation of water resources 133
services for which there are no market prices, such as recreation, water quality and aquatic
biodiversity. CVM was first used several decades ago; it gained in popularity after 1993
when standardized guidelines for CVM applications were set out by a prestigious panel of
economists following a disastrous oil spill off the Alaskan coast.99 The technique has some
application to consumer water demand, in which consumers are asked how much they
would be willing to pay for water. CVM typically measures total economic value, from
which an average value can be estimated.
8.54. Box VIII.8 discusses a case where consumer demand curves are derived using both
methods: CVM and estimated demand functions. Although the results are similar in some
cases, they are quite different in others. The demand function approach is considered more
reliable because it is based on actual market behaviour; in estimating consumer water
demand, CVM is not a good substitute for revealed preference.100 A comparison of values
derived from CVM and revealed preference studies for a wider range of environmental
services show a similar disparity.101
Box VIII.8
Two approaches for measuring the value of domestic water in Central America
A group of researchers used two different methods to estimate the value of water: revealed preference
and contingent valuation. The revealed preference approach derived a demand curve based on surveys of
household water consumption and expenditure from 1995 to 1998 in seven cities in Central America. The
survey distinguished households with piped and unpiped water. The price paid for a cubic metre of water
was different for households with piped and unpiped water; thus, a demand curve was derived from the
two points. For households that relied on unpiped water, water expenditure included both cash payments
for water plus the opportunity cost of the time required to haul the water, so there were further variations
in the cost per cubic metre of water depending on the distance to the water source.
The other method, the contingent valuation survey, asked households how much they would be willing to
pay for improved service with a monthly consumption of 30 cubic metres. Each household was given only
one price to which it could respond; each could answer yes or no. Different households were given different
prices; the distribution of yes and no answers for the different prices was used to derive a demand curve.
In four cities, the revealed preference and contingent valuation methodology (CVM) estimates were fairly
similar, but in the other three cities, the two approaches differed by 100 per cent. It was concluded that the
variation was too great to use the CVM where good revealed preference data were available.
Revealed
CVM preference
99 Kenneth Arrow and others, “Report of the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation”, Federal Register,
vol. 58, No. 10, pp. 4601-4614.
100 Walker and others, “Pricing, subsidies and the poor”, op. cit.
101 Nick Hanley and Clive L. Spash, Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Environment (Cheltenham, United
Kingdom, Edward Elgar Publishing, 1993).
134 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
102 Korea Environment Institute (KEI), Pilot Compilation of Environmental-Economic Accounts: Republic
of Korea (Seoul, UNDP, KEI and United Nations, 1998).
103 National Statistical Coordination Board, Philippine Asset Accounts: Environmental and Natural
Resources Accounting, vol. 1, Environmental Degradation Due to Economic Activities and Environmental
Protection Services, vol. 2 (Manila, NSCB, 1998).
136 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
8.65. The benefit obtained from the damage averted is a widely used approach in the cost-
benefit literature and the preferred technique for SEEA. Often, the results are reported as the
total benefit from costs averted or the average cost per statistical life saved or illness prevented.
Marginal costs, which relate the potential damage averted to marginal changes in water qual-
ity (measured as the concentration of substances), are not often reported. One study does use
marginal damage cost functions.104 Box VIII.9 shows part of the results of that study.
Box VIII.9
Marginal cost of water degradation
In a report to the Australian National Land and Water Resources Audit, two researchers estimated the
value of water under different uses, and the costs of water degradation countrywide, which included water
degradation due to salinity, erosion, sedimentation and turbidity. The authors estimated marginal damage
costs using cost functions derived from engineering studies. With regard to salinity, the major problem is
corrosion of equipment. The marginal damage from a unit increase in salinity is shown below. Households
use the most water (85 per cent) and suffer the highest costs from a marginal increase in salinity, mainly
from damage to plumbing systems, hot water heaters and rain tanks. For industry, the major form of dam-
age is to cooling towers and the water feeders of boilers.
104 Stefan A. Hajkowicz and Michael D. Young, eds., “Value of Returns to Land and Water and Costs of
Resource Degradation”, consultency report to the National Land and Water Resources Audit (Can-
berra, Land and Water Division of the Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisa-
tion, 2002).
137
Chapter IX
Examples of applications
of water accounts
A. Introduction
9.1. Global freshwater resources are under pressure from the ever-increasing demand cre-
ated by human activities, from the contamination caused by pollution, from the increasing
incidence of water-related disease, from the loss and degradation of freshwater ecosystems and
from global climatic change that affects water supply and demand. As the limits of domestic
water resources are reached, countries are becoming increasingly dependent on shared inter-
national water resources, a situation that raises the potential for conflict. These concerns affect
industrialized countries with highly developed water and sanitation infrastructure as well
as developing countries where many people still do not have access to basic services. Social
disruption, premature death and lost productivity from water-related illnesses impose a heavy
cost on developing countries. Under these growing pressures, water management has become
increasingly difficult.
9.2. Most water statistics focus on hydrology and water quality, but not much attention has
been paid to the economic and social aspects of water.105 Some critical policy questions require
the linking of data on water with economic data, such as the following:
(a) The consequences for water resources of economic growth and the patterns of
household consumption and international trade;
(b) The social and economic impacts of water policy instruments, such as regulation,
water pricing and property rights;
(c) The contribution of specific economic activities to the pressure on water resources
and the options for reducing that pressure.
Water accounts comprise a unique tool for improving water management because they inte-
grate data on both the environmental and economic aspects of water supply and use.
9.3. The ability to address jointly the environmental, economic and social aspects of water
policy is central to IWRM, a widely accepted approach to water management adopted by
Agenda 21, the European Union Water Framework Directive and the Third World Water
Forum.106 IWRM has also been identified as one of the immediate approaches that countries
should take for achieving the Millennium Development Goals; the approach has been widely
adopted as the framework for development.107
105 Michael Vardon and Stuart Peevor, “Water accounting in Australia: Use and policy relevance”, paper
presented to the London Group on Environmental Accounting, Copenhagen, 2004.
106 See works cited in notes 7, 8 and 76; and Millennium Project Task Force on Water and Sanitation,
“Background paper on water and sanitation”, UNDP, 2003.
107 Millennium Project Task Force on Water and Sanitation, “Background paper”, ibid.
138 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
9.4. IWRM is based on the perception of water as an integral part of the ecosystem, a
natural resource and a social and economic good, the quantity and the quality of which
determine the nature of its utilization.
9.5. Water accounting has a unique contribution to make to IWRM because it is the
only approach that integrates economic accounts with accounts for water supply and use in a
framework that supports quantitative analysis. Water managers often have access to informa-
tion about water use by broad groups of end-users, but such data cannot be easily used for
economic analysis because the classification of end-users rarely corresponds to the classifica-
tion of economic activities used for the national accounts. The water accounts, in contrast to
other water databases, links water data (supply, use, resources, discharge of pollutants, assets,
etc.) directly to economic accounts. They achieve this by sharing structures, definitions and
classifications with the 2008 SNA; for example, water suppliers and end-users are classified
by the same system used for the economic accounts, that is, ISIC.108
9.6. The first part of this chapter focuses on the policy uses of water accounts, with exam-
ples drawn from countries that have compiled water accounts. As is the case with other
environmental accounts and economic accounts, water accounts furnish (a) indicators and
descriptive statistics for the purposes of monitoring and evaluation; and (b) detailed statistics
for policy analysis. Section B describes the most common indicators used to evaluate the
current patterns of water supply and use, and of pollution. It begins with macrolevel indica-
tors that serve as “warning” signs of trends that may be unsustainable or socially undesir-
able, often at the national level. It then progresses to more detailed indicators and statistics
from the water accounts that shed light on the sources of pressure on water resources, on the
opportunities for reducing the pressure and on the contribution of economic incentives, such
as pricing, to the problem and its possible solutions. These indicators can be compiled directly
from the water accounts without requiring much technical expertise.
9.7. Annex III to the present report addresses more thoroughly the link between indicators
that can be derived from the water accounts and the sets of indicators and index numbers
developed by international organizations, such as the United Nations (Millennium Devel-
opment Goals), the United Nations Commission on Sustainable Development (sustainable
development indicators), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(environmental indicators) and various other major publications of United Nations agencies
and programmes.109
9.8. This information sets the stage for the analysis of more complex water policy issues,
based mostly on economic models that incorporate the water accounts. Section C is aimed at
demonstrating the use of water accounts for several critical policy issues, such as projecting
future water demand or estimating the impact of water pricing reform, rather than attempting
a comprehensive review. Generally, these applications require cooperation among statisti-
cians, economists and other specialists with expertise in various analytical techniques.
9.9. Countries generally do not embark on the compilation of all the modules of the water
accounts at once; rather, they start with those modules that address the country’s policy con-
cerns more directly. Countries generally start with physical supply and use tables, emission
accounts and asset accounts. They add monetary accounts at a later stage of implementation
depending on the policy concerns and availability of data. Most examples of policy applica-
tions utilize accounts for the supply and use of water and the emission accounts described in
chapters III and IV.
9.10. Although the water accounts are usually compiled at the national level for an account-
ing period of one year, doing so is often not very useful for water managers because water
availability and use often vary among regions, and from one season to the next within a year.
Section D addresses this problem by describing the development of water accounting on a
regional basis: often for river basins or the type of “accounting catchment” defined in chapter
II. Several countries now compile water accounts on a regional basis, for example, Australia,
France, the Netherlands and Sweden. The possibility of introducing more flexible temporal
dimensions is also discussed.
9.11. IWRM is based on the concept that water resources (rivers, groundwater, lakes,
wetlands, etc.) are linked to each other, to human activities and to other resources, such as
forests and land use. Improved water management requires taking into account all related
resources. Section E describes some of the links between water accounts and other resource
accounts in SEEA-2003 that would be useful for IWRM and a more comprehensive
approach to sustainable development.
110 Rob Van der Veeren and others, “NAMWA: a new integrated river basin information system”, Nation-
al Institute for Integrated Water Management and Wastewater Treatment Report 2004.032 (Voorburg,
Netherlands, Central Bureau of Statistics, 2004), figure 25. Available from http://www.rws.nl/rws/
riza/home/publicaties/riza_rapporten/rr_2004_032.html.
140 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Figure IX.1
Index of water use, population and GDP in Botswana, 1993-1998
1.30
GDP per cubic metre of water
1.25
1.20
1.15
erlands had grown considerably, the country managed to reduce the volume of water pollutants
substantially (figure IX.2). Of course, to assess the pressure on water, either as a source or a
sink, these trends must be evaluated against water availability in specific places and seasons.
Most countries have not integrated this step within their water accounts, an issue taken up
later in this chapter.
9.16. Even at the macroeconomic level, further distinctions are typically made in the water
accounts based on the characteristics of water in order to provide a more thorough and useful
assessment of trends. Some of the most common characteristics include the following:
(a) Volume of water used disaggregated by purpose, such as cooling, industrial pro-
cess and cleaning. These data are useful for identifying the potential for water
conservation and improvements in water efficiency. In Denmark, for example,
79 per cent of water was used for cooling (table IX.1);111
(b) Volume of water supplied by water utilities compared with the water abstracted
for own use and the reuse of water. Nearly half of the water use in Australia
in 2000/01 was abstracted directly by end-users, with the remaining supplied
through water mains or the reuse of water (table IX.2). This distinction is impor-
tant because in some countries there are significant differences among these
sources in terms of water regulations; the capacity for monitoring may also differ
and investment strategies for the future are affected by the source of water;
(c) Volume of water abstracted by natural source. Overexploitation of groundwater,
for example, may be a critical issue in some countries. Therefore, water managers
need accounts that would identify trends in groundwater abstraction and the
users of groundwater. Similarly, it may be very helpful to identify the use of water
from shared international water resources when allocations from such resources
are restricted;
(d) Wastewater returned to inland water resources. For example, the proportion of
wastewater collected that is treated and the amount of pollution discharged;
Figure IX.2
Index of growth of GDP, wastewater and emissions of nutrients and metals in the
Netherlands, 1996-2001
120
GDP
115
110
105
100
Wastewater
Source: Rob Van der Veeren and oth-
ers, “NAMWA: a new integrated river ba-
sin information system”, National Insti-
95
tute for Integrated Water Management
and Wastewater Treatment Report
Metals 2004.032 (Voorburg, Netherlands, Cen-
90 tral Bureau of Statistics, 2004), figure 25.
Available from http://www.rws.nl/rws/
riza/home/publicaties/riza_rapporten/
rr_2004_032.html.
85 Nutrients Note: 1996=1.00. These indicators can
be derived from the physical supply and
use table and the emissions table de-
80 scribed in chapters III and IV.
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Table IX.1
Water use in Denmark, by purpose, 1994
Source: Adapted from Thomas Bie and
1 000 m3 Percentage Bo Simonsen, “NAMEA with water ex-
traction and use”, Environmental Ac-
Tap watera 434 400 6 counting Project Report to European
Community Project, DG XVI ERDF file
Cooling 5 356 157 79 No. 97/01/57/009 (Copenhagen, Statistics
Denmark, 2001).
Production processes 58 276 1 Note: This table can be derived from the
physical supply and use table described
Added to products 3 996 b
in chapter III.
a Refers to water distributed by the wa-
Other purposes 885 896 13 ter supply industry, ISIC division 36, water
collection, treatment and supply.
Total 6 738 725 100
b Less than 1 per cent.
Table IX.2
Water use in Australia, by source, 2000-2001
(e) The quality status of bodies of water, identified by catchment and size classes.
Identifying the various sources of pollution, such as municipal point sources,
industrial point sources and other non-point sources, as well as the contributions
of the different sources, enables the identification of sound investments for cor-
rective purposes.
Table IX.3
Water profile and water productivity in Australia, 2000-2001
9.19. Water productivity is the most widely used indicator from the water accounts for
cross-sector comparisons. It furnishes a first approximation of the potential gains and losses
from a reallocation of water (an issue taken up in more detail in section C). Water produc-
tivity is also interpreted as a rough approximation of the socio‑economic benefits generated
by allocating water to a particular industry; it is sometimes mistakenly confused with water
value (see chap. VIII for a discussion of this distinction). As shown in table IX.3, the water
accounts of Australia reveal that water productivity in agriculture (A$ 0.58 of value added
per cubic metre of water) is orders of magnitude less than that in services (other industries,
A$ 487.65 of value added).
9.20. It is quite useful to compile a time series of environmental-economic profiles over
time, such as the water productivity time series for Namibia in table IX.4. Water profiles can
also be much more extensive, as shown in the example of two industries in Sweden (figure
IX.3), using 14 measures of performance: 3 measures of economic contribution (production,
value added, hours worked), 1 non-water environmental factor (energy use) and 10 factors
related to water use and wastewater treatment.
9.21. For effective water management, the reasons for large differences in water use and
pollution emissions from different industries must be understood. A country’s use of water
or level of pollution depends on several factors: size and structure of the economy, technology
and population. Size is indicated by total GDP; structure, by each industry’s share of GDP;
and technology, by the water intensity of each sector.
9.22. Table IX.5 shows the distribution of water use in Namibia by industry and the water
intensity of each industry. In the period 2001-2002, commercial crop farming accounted for
43 per cent of total water use and a “water intensity” of 327 litres per dollar of output, that
is, commercial crops required 327 litres of water to generate 1 dollar of output. Within the
agricultural sector, water intensities vary a great deal. Commercial livestock farming has a
water intensity of only 18 litres per dollar of output; for other activities the water intensity
is much higher. In most countries, agriculture is the most water-intensive sector; all other
sectors are an order of magnitude or more lower in water intensity. Even a small increase in
agricultural production would make a substantial impact on water use because of its relatively
high water intensity, whereas the same increase in service sector production, or even mining
and manufacturing, would make a much smaller impact on water use.
9.23. Water productivity could be increased within an industry by introducing more water-
efficient technology or changing the product mix from lower-value products to higher-value
Table IX.4
Water profile for Namibia, 1997-2001 (Namibian dollars of value added per cubic metre of water
use, at constant 1995 prices)
Agriculture 5.5 5.6 5.5 5.2 4.5 Source: Based on Namibian Department
of Water Affairs, “Water accounts for Na-
Commercial crops 0.8 0.8 0.7 0.8 1.0 mibia: Technical report”, draft, Wind-
Commercial livestock 18.5 18.6 19.2 22.2 20.9 hoek, 2005; and Glenn-Marie Lange,
“Water accounts in Namibia”, in Glenn-
Traditional agriculture 7.5 8.4 8.1 6.2 4.6 Marie Lange and Rashid M. Hassan, The
Economics of Water Management in
Fishing 14 352.5 1 573.9 936.2 983.3 991.3
Southern Africa: An Environmental Ac-
Mining 130.3 132.9 172.1 174.4 167.0 counting Approach (Cheltenham, Unit-
ed Kingdom, Edward Elgar Publishing,
Manufacturing 227.7 205.9 228.5 223.9 226.6 2006).
Services 547.7 535.9 582.7 590.2 575.3 Note: This table can be derived from the
physical supply and use table described
Government 211.1 211.8 236.7 216.6 234.2
in chapter III.
144 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Figure IX.3
Environmental-economic profiles for selected Swedish industries, 1995
Production value
Value added
Hours worked
Use of energy
Use of self-supplied water
Use of distributed water
Source: Gunner Brånvall and others,
Water Accounts: Physical and Mone- Use of water for cooling
tary Data Connected to Abstraction, Use
and Discharge of Water in the Swedish Use of water in the industrial process
NAMEA (Stockholm, Statistics Sweden,
Environment Statistics, 1999). Other uses of water
Note: The values are percentages of Direct discharge of wastewater
the total for manufacturing enterprises
recorded against each variable. The in- Discharge to metropolitan wastewater treatment plant
dicators for this profile were obtained
from the physical supply and use ta- Enviromental protection expenditure (internal)
ble (chap. III), the emission accounts Enviromental protection expenditure payments to
(chap. IV) and the tables for environmen- metropolitan wastewater treatment plant
tal protection expenditures and invest- Enviromental protection investment for wastewater
ment (chap. V).
0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100
ones. Water productivity could also be increased by reallocating water from highly water-
intensive industries to less (low) water-intensive ones. For a water-scarce country, the funda-
mental messages from such analysis are that:
(a) Sustainable economic growth may be limited if based on water-intensive sectors;
(b) Measures must be introduced to reduce water intensity if economic growth is to
be based on water-intensive sectors, such as agriculture.
This does not mean that agriculture-led development is not feasible; rather, it indicates that
consideration of the higher-value, less water-intensive agricultural subsectors, accompanied by
incentives to increase water efficiency and conservation, should be taken into account when
designing development policies.
9.24. The assessment of water intensity enables water managers to know why water use or
pollution is so high, but it is also important for understanding the “driving forces”, that is,
the forces that determine the level and structure of industrial production. For example, Aus-
tralian households used 1 800 gigalitres of water directly in the period 1994-1995, but they
consumed many goods and services which also required water in their production. When
taking into account all the water (direct and indirect) required to meet household demand,
total water use rose almost ninefold, to 16 172 gigalitres.112
9.25. This principle of measuring the “upstream” water requirements can be applied to each
product or category of final demand using hybrid input-output tables, which are input-output
tables augmented by water accounts (described in chap. V). Hybrid input-output tables can
be used to calculate the total water requirement (direct and indirect) per unit of industrial
output and compare it with the direct water requirement per unit of industrial output (water
112 Manfred Lenzen and Barney Foran, “An input-output analysis of Australian water usage”, Water
Policy, vol. 3, No. 4, pp. 321-340.
Examples of applications of water accounts 145
Table IX.5
Water intensity and total domestic water requirements in Namibia, by industry, 2001-2002
intensity). In the previous example for Namibia, total domestic water requirements (shown
in the last column of table IX.5) are considerably higher than the direct water requirements
in most instances. This important indicator is on the borderline of water statistics and more
complex policy analysis; it will be taken up again in the next section in relation to trade.
Figure IX.4
Percentage of metal emissions originating abroad in 2000 polluting rivers in the Netherlands
100
90
80
Source: Adapted from Rob Van der
Veeren and others, “NAMWA” a new in- 70
tegrated river basin information sys-
tem”, National Institute for Integrated 60
Water Management and Wastewater 50
Treatment Report 2004.032 (Voorburg,
Netherlands, Central Bureau of Statis- 40
tics, 2004). Available from http://www.
rws.nl/rws/riza/home/publicaties/riza_ 30
rapporten/rr_2004_032.html. 20
Note: These indicators can be obtained
from the supply and use table for emis- 10
sions (chap. IV). 0
Arsenic Copper Zinc
113 Australian Bureau of Statistics, Water Account, Australia 2000-01 (Canberra, ABS, 2004).
114 Glenn-Marie Lange, “Water valuation case studies in Namibia”, op. cit.
115 Australian Bureau of Statistics, Water Account, Australia 2000-01 (Canberra, ABS, 2004). Summary
available from http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/[email protected]/mf/4610.0.
Examples of applications of water accounts 147
Figure IX.5
Costs and revenues for wastewater treatment services in the Netherlands, 1996-2001
(millions of euros)
1400 Costs
Revenues
1200
Source: Rob Van der Veeren and others,
“NAMWA” a new integrated river basin
1000 information system”, National Institute
for Integrated Water Management and
800 Wastewater Treatment Report 2004.032
(Voorburg, Netherlands, Central Bureau
of Statistics, 2004). Available from http://
600
www.rws.nl/rws/riza/home/publicaties/
riza_rapporten/rr_2004_032.html.
400 Note: Data are compiled only for house-
holds and companies connected to mu-
200 nicipal sewer systems. These figures can
be compiled from the hybrid supply and
0 use tables presented in chapter V.
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
116 See, for example, Statistics Sweden, Water Accounts 2000 with Disaggregation to Sea Basins (Stock-
holm, Statistics Sweden, 2003).
117 Glenn-Marie Lange, “Water valuation case studies in Namibia”, op. cit.
118 Van der Veeren and others, “NAMWA”, op. cit.
148 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Table IX.6
Water use in 2001 compared with estimated availability of water resources in Namibia
(h) What is the highest value allocation of water among countries sharing an inter-
national river or lake?
(i) How will external phenomena, such as climate change, affect water resources and
how can an economy best prepare for such impacts?
9.34. The water accounts provide detailed information that can be used to analyse the pres-
sure on water resources, formulate long-term water management strategies and design effec-
tive policies for implementing a given strategy, such as appropriate water pricing and effluent
taxes. These applications typically require linking the water accounts described in chapters
III to V to economic models; integrating the input-output table with the water accounts is
an essential step in building many of these models (see box IX.1). The consistency between
national accounts and water accounts enables the easy incorporation of water accounts into
many different kinds of economic models.
9.35. The number and range of potential policy applications of water accounts are vast.
Because it is not possible to present a comprehensive review in this chapter, a selection of
examples based on water accounts is given instead. These examples address issues such as
projecting future water demand, listing the socio-economic benefits that can be realized from
water policy reform, assessing the costs and benefits of water treatment and analysing the
links between trade and water use.
Box IX.1
Water accounts and input-output analysis
There are many tools for economic analysis and those taking a multisectoral approach are often built
around input-output tables. Multisectoral models include standard input-output analysis as well as other
modelling approaches, notably, computable general equilibrium modelling (which uses a social accounting
matrix, an input-output table expanded for institutions) and econometric models. Various partial equilib-
rium models, such as those developed for life-cycle analysis, also use input-output tables.
The water supply and use tables described in chapters III to IV are directly linked to the national accounts’
supply and use tables; just as the input-output table is constructed from the supply and use table, water ac-
counts can be derived from the water supply and use table. In modelling, water in physical units is included
in the input-output table as a primary input of production. Input-output analysis of the water accounts
provides very useful information regarding the structure of the economy, driving forces, and water use
and pollution, as described in section B of this chapter. Input-output-based, multisectoral models are also
Source: Statistics Denmark, The
widely used for projecting future water demand, or analysing different policy options and the economic Danish Environmental Accounts
instruments for achieving them. Statistics Denmark has noted that its water accounts are used most ex- 2002 (Copenhagen, Statistics Den-
tensively for input-output analysis. mark, 2004).
150 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
9.37. In Australia, water accounts have been used extensively for water planning at the
regional and national levels.119 For example, on behalf of the Australian Productivity Com-
mission, impacts on water demand have been projected under different scenarios for irrigated
agriculture in the Murray-Darling Basin.120 The Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial
Research Organization (CSIRO) used water accounts, along with other data, to project water
requirements for Australia in the year 2050 under a range of alternative scenarios of popula-
tion growth, irrigated agricultural expansion, technological improvements in water efficiency
and measures to improve or compensate for declining water quality (see box IX.2). Section D
presents an example of projecting water use at the regional level for Sweden.
Box IX.2
Projecting water use in Australia
The Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation (CSIRO), a major Australian research
centre, undertook a study of future water use to 2050, considering options for improved technology, as
well as population and income growth and the expansion of irrigated agriculture. Using a range of data,
including those from the Australian water accounts, in a simulation model, total managed water usage was
projected to expand from 24 000 gigalitres per year in 2000-2001 to more than 40 000 gigalitres per year by
2050. This would be due to a major expansion in irrigated agriculture in northern Australia as constraints on
the availability and quality of water are experienced in the southern part of the country. The model assumes
widespread introduction of best practice technology in non-agricultural sectors. The water requirements
for industry, mining and domestic use represent about 20 per cent of the total. Water use by animals re-
flects the growth of the dairy industry in particular, which is relatively water-intensive. The importance of
international trade in driving water use should be noted: Australia exports an estimated 4 000 gigalitres
more of embodied water than it imports. This is about the same amount used each year by urban Australia.
30 000
20 000
9.42. The partial equilibrium approach of input-output may indicate the relationship
between the current allocation of water and income and employment, but a different model-
ling approach is needed to determine what the optimum allocation of water would be in an
economy. Optimization models for water (see chap. VIII for a discussion of different model-
ling approaches) estimate the potential gains from reallocating water to the highest value
users. All optimization models require a database for water use that could be afforded by the
water supply and use tables described in chapters III and V. The results include projected water
demand by industry, the value of water and the resulting structure and level of economic
activity, such as GDP growth. If pollution and pollution abatement costs or damage costs are
included, the levels and costs of pollution would also be calculated.
152 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Box IX.3
Evaluating agricultural water use on a catchment basis in South Africa
Water resources are under increasing pressure in post-apartheid South Africa for several reasons, notably,
improved access to safe drinking water for millions of previously excluded households, and the emphasis
on economic growth and job creation, often in water-intensive industries. An evaluation of the socio-
economic benefits generated by each economic activity relative to its water use is essential to good water
management. The researcher who was the source of this information provided such an evaluation for differ-
ent agricultural activities within the Crocodile River catchment for the Water Research Council of South Af-
rica. He measured the “direct” value added and the employment generated per cubic metre of water used
in each activity. He also extended the analysis to consider the “indirect” benefits by measuring the value
added and the employment generated by upstream and downstream linkages to each agricultural activity.
Upstream linkages consist of inputs into agricultural activities, such as fertilizer and agricultural chemi-
cals and fuels. Downstream linkages consist mainly of food processing industries and wood processing
industries, including paper and pulp, wood products and furniture. These linkages are measured using a
well-established economic tool, input-output analysis. The analysis revealed that a simple comparison of
benefits across sectors did not provide an accurate picture of the full, economy-wide benefits.
In considering only the direct effects, both the income generated (value added) and employment were
highest for mangoes, but when indirect effects were added, pinewood appears to be the best. This is largely
because there is very little additional processing that adds value for mangoes, while pinewood is used in
many wood products. At the opposite end, sugar cane appears to be the least beneficial crop when only
the direct income and employment are considered, but taking into account the indirect effects, sugar cane
moves to third place.
Socio-economic benefits from water use for different agricultural activities in the
Crocodile River catchment, South Africa, 1998
Value-added (rands/cubic metre of water input) Employment (1 000 person days/cubic metre of water)
Source: Adapted from Rashid M. Avocados 1.7 Sugar cane 9.9 Grapefruit 13 Sugar cane 44
Hassan, “Economy-wide benefits Eucalyptus 1.5 Mangoes 8.9 Eucalyptus 12 Oranges 39
from water-intensive industries in
South Africa: quasi input-output anal- Grapefruit 1.5 Oranges 6.6 Bananas 7 Mangoes 37
ysis of the contribution of irrigation Bananas 1.3 Grapefruit 4.9 Pine 6 Grapefruit 28
agriculture and cultivated plantations
in the Crocodile River catchment”, De- Pine 1.2 Avocados 3.4 Avocados 5 Bananas 12
velopment Southern Africa, vol. 20,
Sugar cane 0.9 Bananas 3.2 Sugar cane 2 Avocados 7
No. 2, pp. 171-195.
9.44. Economic models, such as those used for assessing the optimum allocation of
water, can introduce water price accounts for estimating the economy-wide impact of
price reform. Similar analysis can be made for assessing the impact of pollution taxes and
increased charges for wastewater treatment. Box IX.4 summarizes a simulation study for
water charges in Australia.
9.45. The water accounts report emissions of pollution and, if fully monetized, include
estimates of the cost of pollution, or the value of maintaining clean water. The economic
valuation techniques that would be used for monetization were described in chapter VIII.
There are no water accounts currently that have fully monetized water pollution accounts.
In part, the challenge is that most water accounts are compiled at the national level, while
water pollution is a localized phenomenon. Based on a cost-benefit analysis rather than water
accounts, box IX.5 furnishes an example of valuing water quality and the use of this approach
to assess the costs and benefits of wastewater treatment.
Box IX.4
Impact of water price increases on GDP in Australia
Since the period 1996-1997, water charges across Australia have, on average, doubled. Water trading has
been introduced in part of the Murray-Darling river basin, resulting in a significant improvement in water
use efficiency. The Centre for International Economics has developed a model to simulate over a five-
year period the impact on GDP of water pricing changes through induced changes in water use efficiency
that result in more water-efficient technology and the reallocation of water among sectors. For irrigated
agriculture, the Centre found that water use efficiency would have to increase by 1.5 per cent annually to
counterbalance the impact of increased water charges.
The Centre then considered the impact of reducing current water diversions in order to increase environ-
mental flows through alternative economic instruments: administered reduction applied proportionately
to all users is considerably more costly than allocating the cuts through a market-based method of tradable
water rights.
Box IX.5
Benefits of wastewater treatment in Wuxi, China
The source of this information measured the costs and benefits of wastewater treatment in Wuxi, a rapidly
industrializing city in the Yangtze river delta of China. Wuxi has over 200 km of waterways and borders
a scenic lake that is popular for recreation. The study reported the discharge of 9 different water pollut-
ants from the 13 most important industries in the area. The cost of water treatment was measured as
the current value (over 20 years) of additional infrastructure and operating costs needed to meet water
quality standards. The benefits from treatment were measured as the value of the damage prevented.
The damage was valued in terms of the reduced capacity of the lake to provide water services: potable
drinking water, industry-standard water, water for fish farming, a clean environment for residents on the
lake shore and for recreation and tourism. The net benefit of wastewater treatment was estimated to be
almost US$ 3.5 million.
Source: Based on Fan Zhang, “Mar- Health benefits (reduced illness) 2.60
ginal opportunity cost pricing for Residents’ amenity benefits 3.60
wastewater disposal: a case study
of Wuxi, China”, Research Report Residents’ recreational benefits 1.73
No. 1999071, Economic and En- Tourism 3.73
vironmental Economics Program
for Southeast Asia (Ottawa, Inter- Subtotal, benefits 25.91
national Development Research
Net benefit 3.48
Centre, 2003).
122 Ashok K. Chapagain and Arjen Y. Hoekstra, “Water footprints of nations: water use by people as a
function of their consumption pattern”, Water Resources Management, vol. 21, No. 1, pp. 35-48.
123 United Nations and the World Water Assessment Programme, United Nations World Water Develop-
ment Report 2, op. cit.
Examples of applications of water accounts 155
9.48. The measurement of virtual water should include the water used both directly and
indirectly in production. “Direct water” is the amount used during the production process;
this figure is obtained from the water supply and use table. Indirect water is the amount
used to produce all the non-water inputs into the production of a given product. The differ-
ence between direct water use and total (direct + indirect) water use can be substantial: for
example, very little water may be needed to produce a loaf of bread, but a great deal of water
may be embodied in the grain used to make the bread. The methodology for measuring total
water use, based on input-output models extended for direct water inputs (as described in
box IX.1), is well established in the economics literature.124 Box IX.6 shows an analysis of
trade in virtual water among Botswana, Namibia and South Africa, and between these three
countries and the rest of the world.
Box IX.6
Trade and the environment: the water content of trade in Southern Africa
Botswana, Namibia and South Africa have designed strategies for economic development based in part on
economic growth, diversification and trade promotion. As in many developing countries, the structure of
exports in these countries is heavily weighted towards primary commodities and the processing of these
commodities, which is often water-intensive. These countries have identified the lack of water as a primary
constraint to development; South Africa has already been categorized as a water-stressed country.
An input-output analysis of the total (direct + indirect) water content of trade among the three countries
and with the rest of the world reveals that Botswana and Namibia are significant net water importers (45
and 33 per cent of their total national water use, respectively). South Africa, on the other hand, is a net water
exporter (11 per cent of its national water use in 1998).
Net water imports as a percentage of total national water use for Botswana,
Namibia and South Africa, 1998
124 Finn R. Førsund, “Input-output models, national economic models, and the environment”, in Hand-
book for Natural Resource and Energy Economics, vol. 1, Allen V. Kneese and James L. Sweeney, eds.
(New York, Elsevier Publishing Company, 1985), pp. 325-341; Ronald Miller and Peter D. Blair,
Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, United States,
Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1985); and P. J. G. Pearson, “Proactive energy-environment policy strategies: A
role for input-output analysis?”, in Environment and Planning A, vol. 21, No. 10, pp. 1329-1348.
156 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
irrigation, trade protection can inadvertently divert water to irrigation, thereby increasing
the pressure on water resources and reducing the water available for other, often higher-
value, uses. Economic models, either partial or general equilibrium, are used to assess the
impact of trade protection on water use and pollution, and the environmental and economic
consequences.
9.50. Chapter VIII discussed the impact of trade protection on agriculture and the demand
for irrigation water, using several examples. The example for Morocco125 used a linear pro-
gramming model (based on an input-output table with water use accounts) to assess the
optimum allocation of water under several alternative scenarios. One of the alternative sce-
narios included a reduction in trade barriers (import quotas, voluntary export restrictions)
on agricultural commodities. In the model, farmers could choose what crops to plant and
whether to sell them in domestic or international markets; water was allocated on the basis
of its profitability. The model demonstrated the potential that the country had for realizing
significant economic gains by reducing trade barriers and allowing water to be reallocated to
different crops.
125 Hynd Bouhia, Water in the Macro Economy (Aldershot, United Kingdom, Ashgate Publishing Com-
pany, 2001).
Examples of applications of water accounts 157
is the “river basin district”, that is, the upper management unit that can extend over several
provinces or States.
9.54. In most cases, the catchment area, or river basin, is the most appropriate geographical
level for analysis. In some instances, water management at the catchment level may require
international cooperation, for example, a catchment area may cover several countries, or sev-
eral catchment areas may empty into a regional sea. Such cases require common management
of the water resources.
9.55. The actual catchment area may differ from the topographic surface watersheds, which
are the portions of territory that can be delimited by the lines of crest, owing to the exist-
ence of underlying groundwater resources. Furthermore, catchment areas generally do not
match administrative areas, which constitute the basis for economic data. Because of the
need to make hydrological and administrative regions coincide, a compromise is often made;
the resulting region is called an “accounting catchment area”. In general, elaborating water
accounts at the river basin level necessitates geographically referenced data on water flows
and the discharge of pollutants, that is, spatial identification of establishments, wastewater
treatment plants, etc.
9.56. All of the indicators and policy analyses discussed previously in this chapter can be
applied at the catchment or regional level as well. Environmental economic profiles can be
constructed for each water-accounting catchment. Box IX.7 shows the profiles for two sea
basins in Sweden. The accounts can also be used for modelling at the regional level.
9.57. Regional accounts are necessary for the management of an individual river basin, but
decision-making at the national level also needs an overview that brings together the different
regions into a national accounting framework, as shown in figure IX.6. The overview helps
Box IX.7
Forecasting water use at the district level in Sweden
Under the European Union Water Framework Directive, Sweden prepared forecasts of water use in 2015 at
the district level. The estimates were made by using a regional economic model developed by the Swedish
Business Development Agency, which classified 289 municipalities into 5 water districts. Built from rela-
tions at the municipality level, it has 5 submodels: (a) population, (b) labour market, (c) regional economy,
(d) housing market and (e) supplementary model for municipalities. The regional model first forecast popu-
lation, employment and economic development until 2015 for each water district and, based on these
results, forecast water use based on water use parameters prevailing in the base year, 2000. For the three
most water-intensive industries, namely, pulp and paper, chemicals and basic metals, an alternative fore-
cast (scenario 2) was made, assuming increased water efficiency (water use/production value), based on
the same gains in water efficiency achieved between 1995 and 2000.
Figure IX.6
Location, level and origin of nitrogen discharges into the river basin of Loire-Bretagne, France
national decision makers in two ways: (a) in setting priorities for action among different
river basins by demonstrating the relative severity of water problems in each basin; and (b) in
providing national water managers with a tool for negotiating with decision makers in other
sectors in order to coordinate policy.
9.58. Figure IX.6 shows an example of the daily discharge of nitrogen, indicating both the
magnitude of nitrogen emissions in each part of the river basin and the source of the pollut-
ant. Agriculture is the major source of pollution in all the heavily polluted parts of the river.
Households are the second most important source of nitrogen, and the primary source in
areas with little agriculture.
2. Temporal dimension
9.59. Water use is often concentrated in certain seasons; notably, irrigation water is in
demand during the growing season. Because irrigation requires so much water—up to 80
per cent of total water use in developing countries126 —it is extremely important to match
seasonal supply with demand. Water pollution may also have a different impact on water
quality depending on the time of the year. In some periods, the quantity of water that is
flowing may be so reduced that dilution of the pollutants cannot occur. Abstractions and
emissions usually cover an entire year, but this period does not provide an accurate picture
of the stress on water resources because the seasonal variations may be hidden.
9.60. One possibility is to reduce the duration of the accounting period: in many countries,
quarterly national accounts are already being built. Quarterly water accounts may be useful in
some countries: for example, seasonal water accounts for Spain would reveal higher pressure
on water in summer compared with winter. Abstraction of water and the level of emissions are
higher in the summer as a result of tourism, while the volume of available water is smaller due
to the reasons described previously. While the quarters of the year used for national accounts
may not coincide with seasonal variations in water availability and demand for all countries,
the preparation of quarterly accounts for water would probably still be a useful step towards
representing seasonal variations.
9.61. Accidents resulting in unusually high discharges of polluting substances at a certain
point in time present another challenge for water accounts. An accidental discharge, when
added to annual discharges, may not appear to be serious; the averaging of annual discharges
over annual water resources may indicate an acceptable level of pollutant concentration.
However, the temporary concentration from an accident may be high enough to cause serious
damage. Even quarterly accounts may not adequately represent the impact of accidental spills.
It is not feasible to produce monthly or weekly accounts, so indicators should be designed
that would show the degree of damage caused by accidental spills. These indicators should
complement the accounts by taking cognizance of factors such as the concentration of a pol-
lutant, the threshold for water abstraction beyond which aquatic life would be impeded and
the possible synergies among two or several pollutants.
9.62. The construction of such indicators implies a detailed knowledge of the absorption
capacities of the different bodies of water vis-à-vis the pressures exerted against them. The
location and the timeliness of the pressure are not independent in their effects, since the
critical thresholds vary, notably, according to the volume and flow of the body of water. The
severity of the pressure is also related to the current state of the water environment, that is,
to the pressures accumulated over time. Thresholds should be estimated for each place, each
period and each type of pressure. Possible indicators include, for example, the number of days
(in the year, in a quarter) in which the thresholds have been exceeded. However, this type of
information currently cannot be handled within the framework of water accounts.
127 Herbert Acquay, “Integrated land and water management: the Global Environment Facility’s per-
spective”, in Freshwater Resources in Africa, John Gash and others, eds. (Potsdam, Germany, BAHC
International Project Office, 2001).
128 United Nations, Handbook of National Accounting: Integrated Environmental and Economic Account-
ing: An Operational Manual, op. cit.
160 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
In managing water, it is important to account for these additional services and for related
resources and ecosystems that may affect the quantity or quality of water. Only the major
issues are noted here. Future revisions of SEEA-Water for water accounting are likely to
address these broader issues.
Annex I
Standard tables for the System of
Environmental-Economic Accounting
for Water
This annex shows the set of standard tables that have been presented in more detail through-
out the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water (SEEA-Water).
162 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Table A1.1
Standard physical supply and use tables for water (chap. III)
7. Water consumption (= 3 - 6)
Table A1.2
Emission accounts tables (chap. IV)
of which:
of which:
35 Social transfers
in kind from Total
Government and uses
(of Final non-profit institu- at pur-
5-33, which): 38, 39, Total consumption tions serving Govern- Capital chaser’s
1-3 41-43 Total Hydro 36 37 45-99 industry expenditures households Total ment Total formation Exports price
1. Total intermediate
consumption and use
(monetary units)
of which:
of which:
Standard tables for the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
3.a.1. Abstraction
for own use
1. Total intermediate
consumption and use
(monetary units)
Actual final
Industries (by ISIC category) Taxes less consumption
subsidies on
35 products,
Rest trade and Capital
5-33, (of which) 38, 39, Total of the transport House- Govern- forma-
1-3 41-43 Total Hydro 36 37 45-99 industry world margins holds ment tion Total
Table A1.5
Hybrid account table for water supply and sewerage for own use (physical and monetary units) (chap. V)
35
(of
5-33, which) 38, 39, House- Total
1-3 41-43 Total Hydro 36 37 45-99 Total holds industry
1.b.1. Compensation of
employees
1.b.1. Compensation of
employees
Table A1.6
Government account table for water-related collective consumption services (chap. V)
05.6
05.3 (part) Environmental
05.2 Soil and protection not 06.3
Wastewater groundwater elsewhere Water
management protection classified supply
1.b.1. Compensation
of employees
1.b.2. Consumption of
fixed capital
Standard tables for the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water 169
Table A1.7
National expenditure account tables (chap. V)
Users/beneficiaries
Specialized Rest
producers (ISIC Other House- Govern- of the
division 37) producers holds ment world Total
4. Specific transfers
7. National expenditures (= 5 - 6)
Users/beneficiaries
Specialized Rest
producers (ISIC Other House- Govern- of the
division 36) producers holds ment world Total
4. Specific transfers
7. National expenditures (= 5 - 6)
Table A1.8
Financing account tables (chap. V)
Users/beneficiaries
Specialized Rest
producers Other of the
Financing sectors: (ISIC 37) producers Households Government world Total
1. General Government
3. Corporations
4. Households
5. National expenditure
7. Domestic uses
Users/beneficiaries
Specialized Rest
producers Other of the
Financing sectors: (ISIC 37) producers Households Government world Total
1. General Government
3. Corporations
4. Households
5. National expenditure
7. Domestic uses
Table A1.9
Asset account table (physical units) (chap. VI)
EA.1311 EA.1314
Artificial EA.1312 EA.1313 Snow, ice EA.132 EA.133
reservoirs Lakes Rivers and glaciers Groundwater Soil water Total
1. Opening stocks
Increases in stocks
2. Returns
3. Precipitation
4. Inflows
Decreases in stocks
5. Abstraction
6. Evaporation/actual evapotranspiration
7. Outflows
9. Closing stocks
Annex II
Supplementary tables for the
System of Environmental-Economic
Accounting for Water
Table A2.1
Supplementary informationa to the physical supply and use tables (chap. III)
of which:
Irrigation water
Mine water
Urban run-off
Cooling water
Treated wastewater
Other
5.a.
To inland water resources
(= 5.a.1 + 5.a.2 + 5.a.3)
5.a.2. Groundwater
7. Consumption (= 3 - 6)
of which:
7.a.
Losses in distribution not
because of leakage
Table A2.2
Matrix of flows of water within the economy (physical units) (chap. III)
Industries 1-3
(by ISIC
category) 5-33, 41-43
35
36
37
Total
Households
Table A2.3
Supplementary information to the emission accounts (chap. IV)
Surface water
Groundwater
To water resources
Surface water
Groundwater
To the sea
4.b. Without treatment
To water resources
Surface water
Groundwater
To the sea
ISIC division 37
Table A2.4
Supplementary information to hybrid and economic accounts (chap. V)
35
2-33, 38, 39,
1 41-43 Total (of which) Hydro 36 37 45-99 Total industry
Labour input
Number of workers
Total hours worked
B. National expenditure accounts for the protection and remediation of soil, groundwater and surface water (monetary units)
Users/beneficiaries
C. Financing accounts for the protection and remediation of soil, groundwater and surface water (monetary units)
Users/beneficiaries
1. General Government
2. NPISHs
3. Corporations
3.a. Specialized producers
3.b. Other producers
4. Households
5. National expenditure
6. Rest of the world
7. Domestic uses
Table A2.5
Supplementary information to the asset accounts (chap. VI)
EA.1312. Lakes
EA.1313. Rivers
EA.132. Groundwater
A2.6
Quality accounts (physical units) (chap. VII)
Quality classes
Opening stocks
Changes in stocks
Closing stocks
A2.7
Supplementary information to the water accounts: social indicators (chap. VII)
Proportion of population with sustainable access to an improved water source, urban and rural
Total population
179
Annex III
Water accounting and water indicators
A3.1. Water accounts constitute a very powerful tool for improving water management
as they provide basic information for the derivation of many water-related indicators and
a structured database for economic and hydrologic information. Therefore, the advantage
of deriving indicators from such a framework is the ensured consistency of the indicators
and the ability to study further the interlinkages and causes of changes, as well as model-
ling scenarios.
A3.2. This annex addresses more thoroughly the links between the water accounts and
water indicators. Section 1 draws together the wide range of indicators that can be derived
from the accounts to show how, together, they provide a comprehensive set of indicators
for water and sanitation policy appropriate for IWRM. Section 2 links the indicators
proposed in the World Water Development Report 1 to the water accounts, in particular, by
looking at which of the indicators in that report can be derived from SEEA-Water.
1 United Nations and the World Water Assessment Programme, United Nations World Water Develop-
ment Report 2: Water a Shared Responsibility (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.06.II.A.4).
180 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
as ecological obligations, that constrain the amount of naturally available water resources
that can be exploited.
A3.12. The remaining indicators in table A3.1 reflect pressure on water resources from
population, total water use and vulnerability to depletion.
A3.13. Dependency ratio indicates the reliance of a country on water resources generated
outside its territory. This indicator is computed as the ratio of external renewable resources
over total natural renewable resources. It can be derived from the asset accounts, because
both the numerator and the denominator of the ratio can be derived from the accounts (see
previous indicators).
A3.14. The dependency ratio varies between 0 and 1. It increases as the amount of water
received from neighbouring countries increases compared with the total natural renewable
resources. Jean Margat also presented a complementary indicator, the indicator of independ-
ence, which measures the degree of autonomy a country enjoys from resources generated
Table A3.1
Selected indicators of water resource availability and pressure on water derived from water accounts
Internal renewable water resources Average annual flow of rivers and recharge of groundwater generated from endogenous precipitation.a
External renewable water resources Part of the country’s renewable water resources shared with neighbouring countries. Total external resources
are the inflow from neighbouring countries (transboundary groundwater and surface water inflows), and the
relevant part of the shared lakes or border rivers. The assessment considered the natural resources generally; if
there are reservations in neighbouring countries, they are called actual resources.a
Total natural renewable water resources The sum of internal and external renewable water resources. It corresponds to the maximum theoretical amount
of water available for a country on an average year on a long reference period.a
Total actual renewable water resources (Fresh water resources total.) The sum of internal and external renewable water resources, taking into
consideration the quantity of flow reserved to upstream and downstream countries through formal or informal
agreements or treaties and reduction of flow due to upstream withdrawal. Cf., external surface water inflow,
actual or submitted to agreements. It corresponds to the maximum theoretical amount of water actually
available for a country at a given moment. The figure may vary with time. Their computation is referring to a
given period and not to an inter-annual average.a
Dependency ratio Ratio between the external renewable resources and total natural renewable resources.
Indicator expressing the part of the total renewable water resources originating outside the country.a,b,c
Exploitable water resources Part of the water resources which is considered to be available for development under specific technical,
(manageable resources) economic and environmental conditions.a
Per capita renewable resources Ratio between total renewable water resources and population size.b,c
Density of internal resources Ratio between the average internal flow and area of the territory.c
Annual withdrawals of groundwater and surface The total annual volume of ground and surface water abstracted for water uses as a percentage of the total
water as a percentage of total renewable water annually renewable volume of freshwater.d
Exploitation index
Consumption index Ratio between water consumption and total renewable resources.c
a Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Aquastat Glossary online, available from http://www.fao.org/nr/water/aquastat/data/glossary/search.
html?lang=en.
b UNESCO and its World Water Assessment Programme, United Nations World Water Development Report: Water for People, Water for Life (Paris, UNESCO, and New
York, Berghahn Books, 2003).
c Jean Margat, ed., Les ressources en eau: manuels et méthodes, No. 28 (Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, and Orléans, France, Bureau de
Recherches Géologiques et Minières, 1996).
d United Nations, Indicators of Sustainable Development: Guidelines and Methodologies, 3rd ed. (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.08.II.A.2).
182 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
outside its borders.2 The indicator of independence is obtained as the ratio of internal over
total natural renewable resources.
A3.15. It is often important to relate information on water resources to economic, demo-
graphic and social information, such as population size and total land area. For example,
total renewable water resources compared with the population size would furnish informa-
tion on the natural ability of a territory to generate water resources in line with its population
size. In other words, this indicator would show whether the natural water supply, measured
in terms of renewable water resources, is sufficient to meet the demand of the current popu-
lation. If overexploitation occurs and there is increased pressure on the resource due to an
increase in the population, alternative sources of water supply may have to be developed in
order to reduce the stress on water resources. Another example would be the comparison
of internal (or total) renewable water resources with the area of a territory, which provides
some information on the geography of the available water resources.
A3.16. Water availability is an indicator that is often mentioned but rarely defined. It is often
used as a synonym for renewable water resources, following from the notion that abstract-
ing water at the same rate as its recharge would not lead to depletion of the water resources.
This is a simplified view, however. First, depletion of water resources is a long-term concept;
depletion is not simply linked to renewable water and abstraction in one year. Moreover,
water availability is linked to existing technologies in place for the abstraction, treatment and
distribution of water. In some cases, even marine water may be considered to be available
water, if the technology for desalinating the water is in place.
A3.17. The concept of water availability is related to the ability of a country to mobilize water.
It therefore includes factors such as the economic feasibility and the level of technology for
storing part of flood water in artificial reservoirs, extracting groundwater and desalinating
water. For water-stressed countries, water of low quality (requiring extensive treatment before
use) may be considered available, while in countries where water scarcity is not an issue, the
same type of water may not be considered to be available for abstraction. Similarly, the level
of technology available has a significant impact on the water that is considered available in a
country. For these reasons, comparing countries on the basis of this indicator is very difficult
and “total actual renewable resources” is often used as a proxy for water availability.
A3.18. FAO/Aquastat suggests the use of an indicator of exploitable (or manageable) water
resources, which is defined as that part of the water resources considered to be available
for development under specific technical, economic and environmental conditions. This
indicator is the result of several considerations, such as the dependability of the flow, the
extractability of groundwater, the level of minimum flow required for environmental, social
and non-consumptive use, etc.3
2 Jean Margat, ed., Les Ressources en Eau: Manuels et Méthodes, No. 28 (Rome, Food and Agriculture
Organization of the United Nations, and Orléans, France, Bureau de Recherches Géologiques et
Minières, 1996).
3 Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Aquastat Glossary online, available from
http://www.fao.org/ag/agl/aglw/aquastat/glossary/index.jsp.
Water accounting and water indicators 183
well as the broader socio-economic benefits generated by use of water for different economic
activities. Table A3.2 presents examples of indicators that can be derived from the supply and
use tables in chapters III, IV and V, which are particularly useful for this aspect of IWRM.
Table A3.2
Selected indicators of water intensity and water productivity
Cubic metres of water use per unit of physical output Water use or tons of pollution emitted per unit of output, such as:
Tons of pollution generated per unit of physical output • Population
• Number of households
• Tons of wheat, steel, etc., produced
Cubic metres of water use per value added Water use or tons of pollution emitted per unit of value added, measured in currency units
Tons of pollution per value added
Table A3.3
Indicators of opportunities to increase effective water supply
1. Return flows
Quantity of return flows, by source May distinguish treated return flows (from municipal and industrial users) from untreated return flows, such as agriculture
2. Water reuse
Reuse of water as a share of total May distinguish the reuse of water within a plant from water supplied by ISIC 36, water collection, treatment and supply
industrial water use
3. Losses
Losses in distribution as a share of total Both the amount of and the reason for these losses are usually known by the water utility
water supply
Losses unaccounted for as a share of total These losses occur owing to various causes and it is usually not certain how much each cause contributes to the losses
water use
184 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Table A3.4
Indicators of costs and price of water and wastewater treatment services
Implicit wastewater treatment price Volume of water treated divided by supply cost
Average wastewater treatment cost per cubic Volume of wastewater divided by treatment cost for that industry
metre, by industry
Average wastewater treatment price per cubic Volume of wastewater divided by actual payments for treatment
metre, by industry by that industry
Subsidy per cubic metre, by industry Average wastewater price minus average wastewater supply cost
4 For the sake of simplicity, the acronym WWDR (2006) will be used hereinafter in this annex to refer
to the following publication: United Nations World Water Development Report 2: Water a Shared
Responsibility (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.06.II.A.4); and WWDR (2003) will be used
to refer to the following publication: UNESCO and its World Water Assessment Programme, United
Nations and the World Water Assessment Programme, United Nations World Water Development
Report: Water for People, Water for Life (Paris, UNESCO, and New York, Berghahn Books, 2003).
Water accounting and water indicators 185
ments (three indicators), ecosystems (five indicators), health (six indicators), risk (three
indicators) and knowledge (one indicator) are not reported in the table as they go beyond
the scope of water accounts. Although those indicators cannot be derived directly from the
core water accounts, they can be presented side by side with the accounts in supplementary
tables to enable integrated analyses.
A3.26. Table A3.5 presents, in the second to fourth columns, a brief description of the
indicator, its relevance for water policy, and details on the calculation methods. This infor-
mation is based on the “indicator profile sheet” of WWDR (2006) and its CD‑ROM. The
last column describes the link with the information provided by the water accounts.
A3.27. As can be seen from the table, 21 of the 385 indicators can be derived directly from
the accounts; 5 can be partially derived from the accounts; and 12 cannot be derived from
the accounts but can be included as supplementary information. Of these 12 indicators, 4
are social indicators, such as the urban and rural population, 3 are related to land area and
can be derived from land accounts, 3 are related to types of energy and can be derived from
energy accounts, and the remaining 2 (trends in ISO 14001 certification and capability of
hydroelectric power generation) are not part of the water accounts.
Table A3.5
Indicators of selected challenge areas from the United Nations World Water Development Report 2
Global Index of non-sustainable water use K The indicator is computed as Derived from the water
This indicator provides a measure of the human water use in follows: accounts.
excess of natural water supply (local run-off plus river flow). Q – DIA, or Q – A Water use by sector is
Areas with high water overuse tend to occur in regions that are where: derived from the physical
highly dependent on irrigated agriculture. Urban concentration supply and use tables
of water use adds a highly localized dimension to these D = domestic water use (km³/yr) (chap. III) and renewable
broader geographic trends. I = industrial water use (km³/yr) water resources from the
These areas are dependent on infrastructure that transports A = agricultural water use (km³/yr) asset accounts (chap. VI).
water over long distances (i.e., pipelines and canals) or on Q = renewable freshwater
the mining of groundwater reserves, a practice that is not resources (km³/yr)
sustainable over the long term.
Relative water stress index K The indicator is computed as Derived from the water
This indicator provides a measure of water demand pressures follows: accounts.
from the domestic, industrial and agricultural sectors relative DIA/Q Water use by sector is
to the local and upstream water supplies. Areas experiencing where: derived from the physical
water stress and water scarcity can be identified by relative supply and use tables
water demand ratios exceeding 0.2 and 0.4, respectively. D = domestic water demand (chap. III) and renewable
(km³/yr) water resources from the
A threshold of 0.4 (or 40 per cent use relative to supply)
signifies severely water-stressed conditions. The combination I = industrial water demand asset accounts (chap. VI).
of a water stress threshold and gridded population data (km³/yr)
enables identification of water stress “hot spots”, areas where A = agricultural water demand
large numbers of people may be suffering from the effects of (km³/yr)
water stress and its consequent impacts. Q = renewable freshwater
resources (km³/yr)
5 The indicators in the challenge area called “sharing” and the water pollution index are not included
in the analysis, as their definition is not provided in WWDR (2006).
186 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Table A3.5
Indicators of selected challenge areas from the United Nations World Water Development Report 2 (continued)
Surface water as a percentage of TARWR D The indicator is computed as Derived from the water
This indicator illustrates the degree to which a country is using follows: accounts.
its surface water resources. It is computed as the quantity of 100 (surface water abstraction)/ This indicator can be derived
surface water abstracted as a percentage of the surface run-off (surface water run-off). from the asset accounts
(SWAR). (chap. VI).
Sectoral breakdown of water
abstraction is available in
the physical supply and use
tables (chap. III).
Groundwater development (groundwater as a percentage K The indicator is computed as Derived from the water
of TARWR) follows: accounts.
This indicator illustrates the degree to which a country is 100 (groundwater abstraction)/ This indicator can be derived
exploiting its groundwater resources in terms of groundwater (groundwater recharge). from the asset account
abstraction as a percentage of the groundwater recharge. (chap. VI).
Groundwater abstraction is the quantity of groundwater Sectoral breakdown of water
resources used by major sectors (municipal, agricultural and abstraction is available in
industrial). Groundwater recharge is a component of TARWR. the physical supply and use
tables (chap. III).
Overlap as a percentage of TARWR D Derived from the asset
accounts (chap. VI).
Inflow as a percentage of TARWR D Derived from the asset
accounts (chap. VI).
Outflow as a percentage of TARWR D Derived from the asset
accounts (chap. VI).
Total use as a percentage of TARWR D Derived from the asset
accounts (chap. VI).
Agriculture Percentage of undernourished people K Percentage of people not Not derivable from the water
The proportion of undernourished people in a population having access to sufficient, safe accounts.
provides a measure of the extent to which hunger is a problem and nutritious food that meets This is a social indicator,
for a region/country and thus may be considered a measure of their dietary needs and food which could be included as
food insecurity. preferences for an active and supplementary information.
healthy life.
Percentage of poor people living in rural areas K Percentage of poor people living Not derivable from the water
Knowing the proportion of poor people living in rural areas, in rural areas. accounts.
where agriculture and related activities are the primary This is a social indicator,
source of livelihood, furnishes a measure of the importance of which could be included as
agriculture in the fight against poverty. supplementary information.
Relative importance of agriculture in the economy K This indicator is computed as Derived from the monetary
The importance of the agricultural sector in the country’s follows: accounts (chap. V).
economy is an indication of the “political muscle” that it can The share of the country’s GDP
bring to bear in the competition for water resources. derived from agriculture.
188 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Table A3.5
Indicators of selected challenge areas from the United Nations World Water Development Report 2 (continued)
Agriculture Irrigated land as a percentage of cultivated land K Area under irrigation as a Not derivable from the water
(continued) This indicator furnishes a measure of the importance of proportion of total cultivated land. accounts.
irrigation in agriculture. This indicator can be derived
from the land accounts.
Relative importance of agricultural withdrawals in water K This indicator is computed as Derived from the water
balance follows: accounts
This indicator measures the importance of agriculture, Water withdrawal for agriculture/ Agricultural water use from
especially irrigation, in a country’s water balance. renewable water resources. physical supply and use
tables (chap. III); renewable
water from asset accounts
(chap. VI).
Extent of land salinized by irrigation K This indicator is computed as Not derivable from the water
Salinization, the process by which water-soluble salts follows: accounts.
accumulate in the soil, is a concern, as excess salts impede crop Area of soil salinized by irrigation This indicator can be derived
growth and thus threaten agricultural production. The area as a percentage of total irrigated from the land accounts.
salinized by irrigation refers to the total irrigated area affected land.
by salinization. This does not include naturally saline areas.
Importance of groundwater irrigation K This indicator is computed as Not derivable from the water
The purpose of this indicator is to assess the dependency follows: accounts.
of a country’s irrigated agricultural sector on groundwater Percentage of land under irrigation This indicator can be derived
resources. that relies on groundwater. from the land accounts.
Industry Trends in industrial water use K This indicator is computed as Derived from the physical
In many developing countries, industrial production and follows: supply and use tables
hence the sectoral use of water have grown rapidly, putting Wi = Ci + Ei (chap. III).
increasing pressure on scarce water resources. The relationship where:
between industrial water withdrawal and industrial growth
is not linear, as technological advances lead to water savings Wi = water withdrawal by industry
as well as water reuse in industry. Hence, industrial water Ci = water consumption by
withdrawals in many developed countries have flattened off, industry
while industrial water consumption, which is only a fraction of Ei = industrial effluent discharge
the total water withdrawal, continues to grow.
Water use by sector K This indicator is computed as Derived from the physical
Comparing sectoral use patterns is useful for recognizing follows: supply and use tables
potential conflicts. This indicator highlights the water demand 100 (Wi/Wt ); 100 (Wa/Wt); (chap. III).
from industry compared with other sectoral uses of water. 100 (Ws/Wt); 100 (Wd/Wt)
where:
Wi = water withdrawal by industry
Wa = water withdrawal by
agriculture
Ws = water withdrawal by services
Wd = water withdrawal by the
domestic sector
Wt = total water withdrawal
Organic pollution emission by industrial sector K Proportion of organic water Derived from the emission
Most industrial sectors discharge effluents containing a load pollution discharged by the accounts (chap. IV).
of organic pollutants which can be measured by biochemical industrial sector.
oxygen demand (BOD), thus showing the extent to which the
water quality has been compromised. Some sectors pollute
more than others.
If data were available regarding total annual discharges from
industry, as well as the BOD concentrations of these discharges,
the values of the indicator could be calculated based upon
the actual values. However, as these data are not available for
most industries in most countries, it is necessary to calculate
the indicator indirectly, based upon an assumed sectoral
pollution-to-labour ratio, as well as employment data, which
are currently available for every industrial sector in every
country.
Water accounting and water indicators 189
Industry Industrial water productivity K This indicator is computed as Derived from the hybrid
(continued) The productivity of water used in industry, in terms of the follows: accounts (chap. V).
economic value added by industrial production based upon Pi = Vi/Wi
the water withdrawn. where:
Pi = productivity of water used
in industry i
Vi = total annual value added by
industry i (United States dollars/
year)
Wi = annual water withdrawal by
industry i (m³/year)
Trends in ISO 14001 certification, 1997-2002 K This indicator is computed as Not derivable from the water
Companies adhering to the ISO 14001 environmental follows: accounts.
standard conduct water audits and evaluate environmental 100 (Nc/N) This indicator could be
performance regularly. With this information, companies can where: included as supplementary
improve their water use efficiency and water productivity, information.
and reduce pollution, thus reducing pressure on the water Nc = number of companies
resources and the environment. registered per country
N = total number of companies
registered worldwide
Energy Capability of hydropower generation, 2002 K Gross theoretical capability Not derivable from the water
In many countries, hydropower is already well developed of hydropower generation; accounts.
and still growing, while in others it has the potential to technically exploitable This indicator could be
expand greatly. Hydropower generation is measured on capability; and economically included as supplementary
a large scale, that is, in the number of terawatts per hours exploitable capability, in TWh/ information.
generated annually (TWh per year). The gross theoretical year (terawatt hours per year).
capability expresses the total amount of electricity which
could potentially be generated if all available water resources
were turned to such use. The technically exploitable capability
expresses the hydropower capability which is attractive and
readily available with existing technology. The economically
exploitable capability is that amount of hydropower
generating capacity which could be built, after having carried
out a feasibility study on each site at current prices, which
produces a positive outcome.
Access to electricity and water for domestic use K Percentage of population in each Not derivable from the
Comparison of secure access to electricity versus access to country with secure access to water accounts.
an improved water source for domestic use. There are many electricity (where secure access This is a social indicator,
countries where secure access to electricity still lags far to electricity means access to a which could be included as
behind access to water. safe, legal and adequate supply). supplementary information.
Electricity generation by energy source, 1971-2001 K Electricity generation by energy Not derivable from the
This indicator enables measurement of the contribution of source, worldwide, in time series water accounts.
hydropower to electricity supplies over time compared with data in gigawatt-hours (GWh) This indicator can be
other energy sources. per year. derived from the energy
accounts.
Total primary energy supply by source, 2001 K The percentage share of any Not derivable from the
Primary energy refers to energy sources as found in their given fuel may be calculated as water accounts.
natural state. Total global use of the various sources of follows: This indicator can be
energy currently deployed, including coal, oil, gas, nuclear, 100 (Ef/E) derived from the energy
hydropower, geothermal, solar, wind and other combined where: accounts.
renewable sources and waste. This enables the computing of
hydropower as a proportion of total primary energy supply. Ef = primary energy supply by
fuel, worldwide, in metric tons of
oil equivalent (m.t.o.e.)
E = total global primary energy
supply
Carbon intensity of electrical production, 2002 K The indicator is calculated as Not derivable from the
This is a measure of the carbon dioxide emissions associated follows: water accounts.
with climate change which are produced in the process of Ce = C/Ee grams of carbon per This indicator can be
electricity generation in various countries. Hydropower is kilowatt-hour (gC/kWh) derived from the energy
one of the “clean” power options in the sense that it does not where: accounts.
generate greenhouse gases.
190 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Table A3.5
Indicators of selected challenge areas from the United Nations World Water Development Report 2 (continued)
Volume of desalinated water produced K The indicator is calculated as Derived from the physical
Where energy is available, but water supply is constrained, follows: supply and use tables
desalination is an increasingly attractive option for providing Volume of desalinated water (chap. III).
essential drinking-quality water. produced is measured in millions
of cubic metres of drinking-
quality water produced by these
means per annum
Valuing Water sector share in total public spending D The indicator can be computed Derived from the monetary
Determining what proportion of the public budget is devoted as follows: accounts (chap. V).
to the water sector would illustrate in concrete terms the 100 (PSws/TPSes)
investment priority and political commitment assigned by where:
Government to meeting the Millennium Development Goals
on water. PSws = public spending in the
water sector
The indicator is based on the following definitions:
TPSes = total public spending in
National public expenditure refers to total public expenditure all economic sectors.
in all formal and informal economic sectors of the economy.
Water sector expenditure covers investments in the water
sector infrastructure and its operation and maintenance,
including those for capacity-building, as well as for
implementing policy and institutional reforms.
Sectors are segments of the economy that are identified in
terms of their contributions to the economy and daily quality
of life. The water sector generally comprises water supply,
sewerage, sanitation, irrigation and drainage infrastructure,
and IWRM.
Ratio of actual to desired level of public investment in D The indicator would be Partially derived from the
water supply computed as follows: water accounts.
This ratio would indicate whether investments to meet The ratio of actual level of The actual level of
water-related targets are on track. A ratio of less than 1 would investment to the desired level investment can be derived
indicate the magnitude by which actual investment in the of investment in providing from the monetary
water sector would need to be increased, thus enabling safe drinking water supply, as accounts (chap. V).
Governments to adjust their financial responses to meet the warranted under the relevant The desired level of
water-related Millennium Development Goals. Millennium Development Goals. investment is exogenous
The indicator is based on the following definitions: and may be the result of
Actual level of investment is the actual investment in the modelling based on the
provision of water supply and services from all sources. water accounts.
Desired level of investment is a value that captures the cost of
providing water to different settlements (urban and rural) for
given technological choices and targets to be met in terms of
providing access to water services.
Rate of cost recovery D The indicator can be computed Partially derived from the
An assessment of the existing water fee collection system as follows: water accounts.
could guide institutional reforms for strengthening the 100 (AWFC/TWFC) Actual water fees collected
financial viability of water utilities, thus improving water where: can be derived from
governance. This indicator measures the water fees actually the monetary accounts
collected as a percentage of the total collectable charges AWFC = actual water fees (chap. V).
billed by the water utility. collected
TWFC = total water fees to be
collected.
Water accounting and water indicators 191
Valuing The indicator is based on the following definitions: The water accounts provide
(continued) Water fees comprise the rate/tariff structure established by the information on the actual
water utility (in the form of per unit of water used, a flat rate, or costs of providing water
block rate, etc.) as a monetary amount of costs to be recovered (and wastewater services).
from consumers for the purposes of sustaining the supply Thus, the rate of recovery
agency, providing incentives for conservation and assuring based on the ratio of actual
supplies for the less well-off. water fees collected and
total costs of water supply
Actual water fees collected are the amounts collected/ would measure that part
received by the water utility from different consumers in return of the total costs of water
for providing them with water supply and services. supply recovered through
water fees.
Water charges as a percentage of household income D The indicator can be computed Derived from the monetary
Water charges are seen as an important economic instrument as follows: accounts (chap. V).
for improving water use efficiency and securing the financial 100 (EW/HI)
sustainability of the water utility. At the same time, it is where:
important that water services be made accessible and
affordable to all. EW = the total amount spent on
water supply by the household
This indicator shows the proportion that water charges
constitute of household income. The indicator is based on the HI = total household income.
following definitions:
Expenditure on water charges is the actual monetary amount
paid by households to the water utility in return for receiving
water supply and services.
Household income, in simple terms, is defined as the total
amount of income received by all persons living in the same
household. This includes, but is not limited to, wages or salary
income; net self-employment income; interest, dividends,
or net rental or royalty income or income from estates and
trusts, etc.
Sharing Water interdependency indicator C The definitions for these indicators are not available but, in
principle, the indicators which are based on physical information
Cooperation indicator C on the flows between countries can be derived from the asset
accounts (chap. VI).
Vulnerability indicator C
Fragility indicator C
Development indicator C
Source: Adapted from United Nations and the World Water Assessment Programme, United Nations World Water Development Report 2: Water a Shared Responsibil-
ity (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.06.II.A.4).
a Description based on the indicator profile sheet of WWDR (2006).
b Level of development, ranging from the highest to lowest: B = basic indicator, K= key indicator, for which an indicator profile sheet and statistical data exist; D = deve
loping indicators, for which there is an indicator profile sheet but not yet a statistical presentation; and C = conceptual indicator, for which only discussion has taken place.
193
Glossary
Abstraction: The amount of water that is removed from any source, either permanently or
temporarily, in a given period of time for final consumption and production activities. Water
used for hydroelectric power generation is also considered to be abstraction. Total water
abstraction can be broken down according to the type of source, such as water resources and
other sources, and the type of use. (EDG)
Abstraction for distribution: Water abstracted for the purpose of its distribution. (EDG)
Abstraction for own use: Water abstracted for own use. However, once water is used, it can
be delivered to another user for reuse or for treatment. (EDG)
Actual evapotranspiration: The amount of water that evaporates from the land surface and is
transpired by the existing vegetation/plants when the ground is at its natural level of moisture
content, which is determined by precipitation. (EDG)
Actual final consumption of households: The value of the consumption of goods and services
acquired by individual households, including expenditures on non-market goods or services
sold at prices that are not economically significant and the value of expenditures provided by
government and NPISHs. (2008 SNA, para. 9.81)
Actual final consumption of general government: The value of the government’s total final
consumption expenditure less its expenditure on individual goods or services provided as
social transfers in kind to households. It is thus the value of the expenditures that the govern-
ment incurs on collective services. (Based on 2008 SNA, paras. 9.103)
Aquifer: A geologic formation, group of formations, or part of a formation that contains
sufficient saturated permeable material to yield significant quantities of water to wells and
springs. (USGS)
Artificial reservoirs: Man-made reservoirs used for storage, regulation and control of water
resources. (EDG)
Brackish water: Water with a salinity content between that of freshwater and marine water.
(EDG)
Catchment (synonym: river basin): An area having a common outlet for its surface run‑off.
(UNESCO/WMO International Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed., 1992)
Cooling water: Water which is used to absorb and remove heat.
Determinand: Parameter, water quality variable or characteristic of water quality.
Direct use benefits: Benefits derived from the use of environmental assets as sources of mate-
rials, energy or space for input into human activities. (SEEA-2003, para. 7.36)
Economic unit: A unit that engages in production and/or consumption activities.
Emission to water: Direct release of a pollutant into water, as well as its indirect release by
transfer to an off-site wastewater treatment plant. (Based on the European Commission,
2000, available from http://www.eper.cec.eu.int/eper/documents/guidance_html/index.htm)
194 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Evapotranspiration: The quantity of water transferred from the soil to the atmosphere by
evaporation and plant transpiration. (EDG)
Exports: Water that exits the territory of reference through mains or other forms of infra-
structure. (EDG)
Final consumption expenditure of households: The expenditure, including imputed expend-
iture, incurred by resident households on individual consumption goods and services, includ-
ing those sold at prices that are not economically significant. (2008 SNA, para. 9.94)
Fresh water resources: Naturally occurring water having a low concentration of salt. (EDG)
Glaciers: An accumulation of ice of atmospheric origin generally moving slowly on land over
a long period. (UNESCO/WMO International Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed., 1992)
Gross capital formation: The total value of the gross fixed capital formation, changes in
inventories and acquisitions less disposal of valuables for a unit or sector. (2008 SNA, para.
10.31)
Groundwater: Water which collects in porous layers of underground formations known as
aquifers. (SEEA-2003)
Groundwater recharge: The amount of water added from outside to the zone of saturation
of an aquifer during a given period of time. Recharge of an aquifer is the sum of natural and
artificial recharge. (EDG)
Hydrological cycle (synonym: water cycle): The succession of stages through which water
passes from the atmosphere to the Earth and returns to the atmosphere: evaporation from
the land, sea or inland water, condensation to form clouds, precipitation, accumulation in
the soil or in bodies of water, and re-evaporation. (UNESCO/WMO International Glossary
of Hydrology, 2nd ed., 1992)
Hydroelectric power generation, water use for: Water used in generating electricity at plants
where the turbine generators are driven by falling water. (USGS, available from http://pubs.
usgs.gov/chapter11/chapter11M.html)
Imports: Water that enters the territory of reference through mains or other forms of infra-
structure. (EDG)
Inflow: Water that flows into a stream, lake, reservoir, container, basin, aquifer system, etc.
It includes inflows from other territories/countries and inflows from other resources within
the territory. (EDG)
Intermediate consumption: The value of the goods and services consumed as inputs by a
process of production, excluding fixed assets, the consumption of which is recorded as con-
sumption of fixed capital; the goods or services may be either transformed or used up by the
production process. (Based on 2008 SNA, para 6.213)
Irrigation water: Water artificially applied to land for agricultural purposes. (UNESCO/
WMO International Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed., 1992)
Lake: A generally large body of standing water occupying a depression in the Earth’s surface.
(EDG)
Mine water (synonym: mining water use): Water used for the extraction of naturally occur-
ring minerals including coal, ores, petroleum and natural gas. It includes water associated
with quarrying, dewatering, milling and other on-site activities carried out as part of mining.
Excludes water used for processing, such as smelting and refining, or slurry pipeline (indus-
trial water use). (USGS, available from http://pubs.usgs.gov/chapter11/chapter11M.html)
Glossary 195
Non-point source of pollution: Pollution sources that are diffused and without a single point
of origin or not introduced into a receiving stream from a specific outlet. The pollutants are
generally carried off the land by storm-water run-off. The commonly used categories for non-
point sources are agriculture, forestry, urban areas, mining, construction, dams and channels,
land disposal and saltwater intrusion. (UNSD, online glossary of environment statistics)
Option benefits: Benefits derived from the continued existence of elements of the environ-
ment that may one day provide benefits for those currently living. (SEEA-2003, para. 7.37)
Outflow: Flow of water out of a stream, lake, reservoir, container, basin, aquifer system, etc.
It includes outflows to other territories/countries, to the sea and to other resources within
the territory. (EDG)
Perennial river: A river which flows continuously throughout the year. (Based on UNESCO/
WMO International Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed., 1992).
Point source of pollution: Emissions for which the geographical location of the discharge of
the wastewater is clearly identified, for example, emissions from wastewater treatment plants,
power plants and other industrial establishments.
Population equivalents: One population equivalent (p.e.) means the organic biodegradable
load having a five-day biochemical oxygen demand (BOD5) of 60 g of oxygen per day.
(OECD/Eurostat joint questionnaire on inland water)
Potential evapotranspiration: The maximum quantity of water capable of being evaporated
in a given climate from a continuous stretch of vegetation covering the whole ground well
supplied with water. It thus includes evaporation from the soil and transpiration from the
vegetation of a specified region in a given time interval, expressed as depth. (EDG)
Precipitation: The total volume of atmospheric wet precipitation, such as rain, snow and hail,
on a territory in a given period of time. (EDG)
Recycled water: The reuse of water within the same industry or establishment (on site).
(EDG)
Reused water: Wastewater delivered to a user for further use with or without prior treatment.
Recycling within industrial sites is excluded. (EDG)
Rivers and streams: Bodies of water flowing continuously or periodically in a channel. (EDG)
River basin (see also catchment): An area having a common outlet for its surface run-off.
(EDG)
Run-off: The part of precipitation in a given country/territory and period of time that appears
as stream flow. (EDG)
Sewage sludge: The accumulated settled solids separated from various types of water, either
moist or mixed with a liquid component, as a result of natural or artificial processes. (OECD/
Eurostat joint questionnaire on inland water)
Social transfers in kind: Individual goods and services provided as transfers in kind to
individual households by government units (including social security funds) and NPISHs,
whether purchased on the market or produced as non-market output by government units
or NPISHs; the items included are: (a) social security benefits and reimbursements; (b) other
social security benefits in kind; (c) social assistance benefits in kind; and (d) transfers of indi-
vidual non-market goods or services. (Based on 2008 SNA, para 8.141)
Soil water: Water suspended in the uppermost belt of soil, or in the zone of aeration near the
ground surface that can be discharged into the atmosphere by evapotranspiration. (EDG)
196 System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Water
Standard river unit (SRU): A river stretch of one kilometre with a water flow of one cubic
metre per second. (SEEA-2003, para. 8.128)
Supply of water to other economic units: The amount of water that is supplied by one eco-
nomic unit to another and recorded net of losses in distribution. (EDG)
Surface water: Water which flows over, or is stored on, the ground surface. It includes artifi-
cial reservoirs, lakes, rivers and streams, glaciers, snow and ice. (EDG)
Trade margin: The difference between the actual or imputed price realized on a good pur-
chased for resale (either wholesale or retail) and the price that would have to be paid by the
distributor to replace the good at the time it is sold or otherwise disposed of. (2008 SNA,
para 6.146)
Transboundary waters: Surface or ground waters which mark, cross or are located on bound-
aries between two or more States; wherever transboundary waters flow directly into the sea,
these transboundary waters end at a straight line across their respective mouths between
points on the low-water line of the banks. (UNECE, 1992, available from http://www.unece.
org/env/water/pdf/watercon.pdf)
Transport margin: Transport charges payable separately by the purchaser in taking delivery
of goods at the required time and place. (2008 SNA, para. 6.141)
Urban run-off: That portion of precipitation on urban areas that does not naturally percolate
into the ground or evaporate, but flows via overland flow, underflow or channels, or is piped
into a defined surface water channel or a constructed infiltration facility.
Use of water received from other economic units: The amount of water that is delivered to
an economic unit from another economic unit. (EDG)
Water body: A mass of water distinct from other masses of water. (UNESCO/WMO Inter-
national Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed., 1992)
Watercourse: A natural or man-made channel through or along which water may flow.
(UNESCO/WMO International Glossary of Hydrology, 2nd ed., 1992)
Wastewater: Water which is of no further immediate value to the purpose for which it was
used or in the pursuit of which it was produced because of its quality, quantity or time of
occurrence. However, wastewater from one user can be a potential supply of water to a user
elsewhere. It includes discharges of cooling water. (EDG)
Water consumption: That part of water use which is not distributed to other economic units
and does not return to the environment (to water resources, sea and ocean) because during
use it has been incorporated into products, or consumed by households or livestock. It is
calculated as the difference between total use and total supply; thus, it may include losses due
to evaporation occurring in distribution and apparent losses due to illegal tapping as well as
malfunctioning metering. (EDG)
Water losses in distribution: The volume of water lost during transport through leakages
and evaporation between a point of abstraction and a point of use, and between points of use
and reuse. Water lost due to leakages is recorded as a return flow as it percolates to an aquifer
and is available for further abstraction; water lost due to evaporation is recorded as water
consumption. When computed as the difference between the supply and use of an economic
unit, it may also include illegal tapping. (EDG)
Water returns: Water that is returned into the environment by an economic unit during a
given period of time after use. Returns can be classified according to the receiving media
(water resources and sea water) and to the type of water, such as treated water and cooling
water). (EDG)
Glossary 197
Water supply: Water leaving/flowing out from an economic unit. Water supply is the sum of
water supply to other economic units and water supply to the environment. (EDG)
Water supply to the environment: see water returns.
Water supply within the economy: Water which is supplied by one economic unit to another.
Water supply within the economy is net of losses in distribution. (EDG)
Water use: Water intake of an economic unit. Water use is the sum of water use within the
economy and water use from the environment. (EDG)
Water use within the economy: Water intake of one economic unit, which is distributed by
another economic unit. (EDG)
Water use from the environment: Water abstracted from water resources, seas and oceans,
and precipitation collected by an economic unit, including rainfed agriculture. (EDG)
Contact information:
2 UN Plaza
New York, NY 10017, USA
Tel.: +1-917-367-4130
Fax: +1-212-963-9851
e-mail: [email protected]
http://unstats.un.org