MP and The Crisis - Svenson
MP and The Crisis - Svenson
MP and The Crisis - Svenson
* * *
I thank Claes Berg, Marianne Nessén, Staffan Viotti and Barbro Wickman-Parak for comments on this speech.
The views expressed here are my own and not necessarily those of other members of the Riks-bank’s Executive
Board or of the Riksbank’s staff. Gabriela Guibourg of the Riksbank’s staff has contrib-uted to this speech.
As the world economy recovers from the recent financial crisis and the Great Recession that
followed, a debate is going on regarding the causes behind the crisis and how to reduce the
risk of future crises. The role of monetary policy and its relation to financial stability are also
under debate and some argue that there is a need to modify the framework of flexible
inflation targeting and give a greater role to financial-stability considerations. Some blame too
expansionary monetary policy by the Federal Reserve after 2001 for laying the foundation for
the crisis.
My view is that the crisis was largely caused by factors that had very little to do with
monetary policy. And my main conclusion for monetary policy is that flexible inflation
targeting – applied in the right way and in particular using all the information about financial
conditions that is relevant for the forecast of inflation and resource utilisation at any horizon –
remains the best-practice monetary policy before, during, and after the financial crisis.
A related conclusion is that neither price stability nor interest-rate policy is sufficient to
achieve financial stability. A separate financial-stability policy is needed. In particular,
monetary policy and financial-stability policy need to be conceptually distinguished, since
they have different objectives and different appropriate instruments, even when central banks
have responsibility for both 1.
So today, I will first briefly summaries my view of the causes of the crisis, and then discuss
what the possible lessons are for future monetary policy, and finally I shall emphasise the
distinction between monetary policy and financial-stability policy.
1
For a more detailed discussion of these issues, see Svensson (2010, section 5.2).
2
See Bean (2009) for more discussion.
3
See Svensson (2003) for a discussion of policy options before and in a liquidity trap.
4
See Assenmacher-Wesche and Gerlach (2009), Bean (2009), Bean et al. (2010), Bernanke (2010), Dokko et
al. (2009), IMF (2009).
5
Such considerations could include evidence of the “risk-taking channel” as in Borio and Zhu (2008). Adrian
and Shin (forthcoming) and Adrian and Shin (2010) argue, in a model with such a risk-taking channel, that
short interest-rate movements may have considerable effects on the leverage of securities broker-dealers in
the market-based financial sector outside the commercial-banking sector. If we assume that the risk of a
financial crisis increases as this leverage increases, and that policy rates affect leverage, then policy rates
would affect the risk of a financial crisis (Woodford 2010b). However, new regulation is likely to limit excess
leverage and limit the magnitude of these affects. The size of the market-based financial sector may end up
being smaller after the crisis. In Europe, Canada and the Nordic countries, commercial banks dominate the
financial sector.
Conclusions
My main conclusion from the crisis with regard to monetary policy so far is that flexible
inflation targeting – applied in the right way and using all the information about financial
conditions that is relevant for the forecast of inflation and resource utilisation at any horizon –
remains the best-practice monetary policy before, during, and after the financial crisis. But a
better theoretical, empirical and operational understanding of the role of financial conditions
and financial intermediation in the transmission mechanism is urgently required and needs
much work, work that is already underway in academia and in central banks. Furthermore,
monetary policy cannot guarantee financial stability. A separate financial-stability policy, with
the objective of financial stability and with suitable instruments other than the policy rate, is
required.
References
Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin (2010), “Financial Intermediaries and Monetary
Economics,” in Friedman, Benjamin M., and Michael Woodford (eds.), Handbook of
Monetary Economics, Volume 3, Elsevier, forthcoming.
Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin (forthcoming), “Liquidity and Leverage,” Journal of
Financial Intermediation, available as Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports 328,
2007.
Assenmacher-Wesche, Karin, and Stefan Gerlach (2009), “Financial Structure and the
Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices”, working paper, www.stefangerlach.com.
Bernanke, Ben S. (2007), “Global Imbalances: Recent Developments and Prospects,”
speech on 11 September 2007, www.federalreserve.gov.
Bernanke, Ben S. (2010), “Monetary Policy and the Housing Bubble”, speech on 3 January,
2010, www.federalreserve.gov.
Borio, Claudio, and Haibin Zhu (2008), “Capital Regulation, Risk-taking and Monetary Policy:
A Missing Link in the Transmission Mechanism?” BIS Working Paper 268, www.bis.org.
Carney, Mark (2009), “Some Considerations on Using Monetary Policy to Stabilise Economic
Activity”, in Financial Stability and Macroeconomic Policy, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City Jackson Hole Symposium.
Dokko, Jane, Brian Doyle, Michael Kiley, Jinill Kim, Shane Sherlund, Jae Sim and Skander
Van den Heuvel (2009), “Monetary Policy and the Housing Bubble”, Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2009–49, Federal Reserve Board, www.federalreserve.gov.
Gertler, Mark, and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki (2010), “Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in
Business Cycle Analysis,” in Friedman, Benjamin M., and Michael. Woodford, eds.,
Handbook of Monetary Economics, Volume 3, Elsevier, forthcoming.
International Monetary Fund (2009), World Economic Outlook, October 2009.