Energy and Human Resource Development in Developing Countries
Energy and Human Resource Development in Developing Countries
Resource Development
in Developing Countries
Towards Effective
Localization
William Hickey
Energy and Human Resource Development in
Developing Countries
William Hickey
ix
x PREFACE
transverse, yet at the same time, it is also a very tiny planet, where getting
from point to point can be reached quickly with the energy we have on
hand and the right logistical framework.
---
In 1996, I began working as a trainer for Motorola in the Chinese
manufacturing megacity of Tianjin. At that time, Motorola was at its apex
as cell phone king in China, with a very large market share. It was a hyper-
competitive business, with Nokia and Ericsson also gaining on Motorola.
The nature of this business required Motorola’s engineers to be at the top
of their game. I administered such trainings with titles such as ‘Cycle Time
Reduction’, ‘Benchmarking’, and ‘Six Sigma’, all operations management
based to keep Motorola’s people ahead of the competition. This was the
realm of hi-tech retail manufacturing. In my view, it was what nations
had to do to remain competitive in the world we lived. More skills were
required to keep ever-thin profit margins intact. It was the way it was.
Most Chinese and managers in this competitive environment became used
to it. Today, few know about Motorola cell phones, it is a market of Apple
and Android with touch screens that didn’t exist in 1996. Fierce competi-
tion forces quick change and disruptive technology. Those that cannot
change or adapt to the fast pace are quickly left behind and go bankrupt,
or are financially crippled.
In 2003, I was the recipient of a Fulbright professorship to go to
Kazakhstan, with my proposal being written on introducing the human
resources (HR) mindset required to create competitive economic condi-
tions there. I knew nothing about Kazakhstan or the CIS (Commonwealth
of Independent States) legacy countries of the former Soviet Union, as
they were referred to by the US State Department. I had heard rumors
before about oil and gas economies being non-competitive, but didn’t
clearly understand what this meant, and thought it may be some type of mis-
givings generated by people who didn’t understand those businesses. In my
world view at the time, competitive factors were the rule. There was no free
lunch, if the skills were not learned and applied toward building competitive
industry, countries could not succeed. It was as simple as that. End of story.
Kazakhstan was the first country I had ever lived in whose economy was
largely oil and gas (Nefte v Gaz in Russian) exports. Practically, 90 % of its
foreign investment was directed to such projects. Competitive manufac-
turing to these oil and gas economies was an unknown; things that were
needed were imported, mostly from next door China. Labor costs were
high as was housing. There were jobs, but many seemed underemployed.
In many ways, while Kazakhstan was the best economically perform-
PREFACE xi
oil companies don’t make much of the oil itself, but out of the services
provided. As a professor of HR, I was astounded at both admissions.
These contracts also allowed the free flow of expatriate labor without
any enforced mandate to develop locals. This meant that locals were effec-
tively paying the company already to use foreign workers, not to develop
them, under the reimbursable contracts terms. This was the same for local
content and capacity building. All these areas were ‘billed back’ to the host
country out of the first production oil under the reimbursable scheme.
HR deliverables were always kept murky and non-transparent in order not
to transfer any proprietary and competitive skills to locals for them to be
able to run the operations on their own. As one irate production manager
told me at length when I questioned this, ‘we are here to make money, not
feed the poor’. The energy business due to the large profits derived, seemed
to mimic ‘quasi-business’ that was not anchored to the same competitive
factors (or business textbooks) as customer-oriented businesses were, but
was instead well protected by monopolistic and government practices.
A few years later, in 2009, I won another Fulbright to India and
South Asia. It is an area sorely in need of electrification, but most are
poor and unskilled. Governments there have opened up to investment
in power projects, mostly Chinese coal-fired electricity-generating plants,
with some hydropower (dams) via Japanese investment. On a visit to one
such Chinese-invested coal-fired power plant in Puttalam, Sri Lanka, the
contrast of poor Sri Lankans digging potatos set against a backdrop of
an emerging coal-fired plant was noteworthy. Practically, all the work-
ers (including loaders and diggers), engineers, and equipment content,
used were Chinese. The standards used were Chinese. In essence, the Sri
Lankans were by and large uninvolved parties in the creation of this new
turnkey coal-fired electric plant that would provide them stable electric
and eventually be costed back to them.
The Sri Lankan leaders, in their search for foreign investment had
allowed a Chinese state-owned company to come into their country, and
set up a turnkey electrification plant, without any obligation or mandate
to use local workers or transfer any critical skills to the host country. The
investment was on all Chinese terms with Chinese leaders and their coun-
terpart elites in Sri Lanka setting all the contractual terms. The largely
unskilled and underemployed Sri Lankans got little from the project except
a few truck driver jobs and the chance to pay a higher tariff for a more
stable electricity supply in the future. I soon realized that this project was
not so much about earning money for China but rather employing Chinese
workers from Chinese state-owned companies while expanding the Chinese
xiv PREFACE
6 Energy Ownership139
7 Localization163
8 China219
xv
xvi Contents
Bibliography283
Index299
List of Figures
Fig. 1.1 Macro, meso, and micro viewpoints of HRD from various
scholar and practitioners (Hickey) 12
Fig. 1.2 Interlinkages of competency for extractive resource development 23
Fig. 1.3 Hickey diamond of HRD and localization for natural resources 26
Fig. 2.1 The fossil fuel use spectra 37
Fig. 2.2 Graph of electricity generation by fuel type in the AEO 2015 37
Fig. 2.3 Worldwide energy use sources 38
Fig. 2.4 Worldwide energy profile and emissions, HSBC
global research report, ‘Stranded Assets, What’s Next?
(Used with permission) 43
Fig. 2.5 Selected country coal use in their overall electricity generation 46
Fig. 2.6 Energy production in China, 2015 52
Fig. 2.7 Types of renewable energy used in developing countries 53
Fig. 2.8 Sudan power plan forecast with nuclear option 59
Fig. 2.9 A knowledge map of methods for explicit, implicit, and tactical
knowledge building 62
Fig. 2.10 Growing global energy demand with breakout for
China and India 64
Fig. 3.1 Derivatives and risk management in the petroleum, natural
gas, and electricity industries 90
Fig. 4.1 Life cycle of greenhouse gas emissions based on
electricity generation source 103
Fig. 4.2 Climate change policies since 2005 110
Fig. 5.1 The apex of human capital development is ideas, not
finance or technological black boxes 116
Fig. 5.2 A simplified HRD training cycle 119
Fig. 5.3 Gap assessment derived from Rothwell, 2005 (Hickey) 120
xvii
xviii LIST OF FIGURES
xix
xx List of Tables
With 7.1 billion people, over 40 % of whom live in Asia alone, we live
on a tiny and crowded planet; to put one main thing in perspective, the
planet is finite and too small to tolerate today’s business as usual attitude
toward preservation of the planet for future generations. Much of the
world’s economic growth is projected for Asia in the twenty-first cen-
tury and much of the equatorial developing world, sub-Saharan Africa
and South America. Simply, there are many hungry mouths to feed and
demands on the Earth’s finite resources continue to grow exponentially
every year. Yet, the internet, social media, and global financial liquidity
have changed the paradigms of what is the developed, middle-income,
emerging, and developing world. What constitutes poverty and even
development may need new definitions. Is the World Bank’s (WB) $2 a
day a good poverty threshold measure? It may depend on, for example, if
the US dollar is strong or weak at any given time, or if the culture, such
as in Thailand or Bali, values community more than money, or if no other
employment opportunities exist, such as with nomadic peoples in Saharan
Africa or Central Asia or in extremely impoverished societies such as in
Eastern India. Many old indicators are in flux today, and being challenged
by information intensity in the twenty-first century.
What Is ‘Energy’?
Energy has been simply described as ‘the ability to do work’, or in this
case, kinetically, as a ‘heat source’1 either to sustain combustion such as
boiling water at extreme temperatures in a coal-fired thermal power plant
to turn an electricity-generating turbine or to create combustion, as in
a kerosene-fueled jet engine to create propulsion. There are many types
of energy. But mostly today, our world of mobility, transport, and com-
merce runs on fossil and carbon-based fuels: oil, gas, coal, biomass (wood
and palm oils), and most of our modern economic development has been
predicated on availability of such cheap energy supplies. Despite the pres-
sures arising from global warming on governments to ‘do something’ via
a Kyoto protocol, Copenhagen, Lima, or Paris climate change conference,
national governments, their economies and their elites are far too inter-
connected and complicit to automatically change this anytime soon.
What Is HRD?
Human resource development (HRD), by academic design, is a perfor-
mance system which consists of skills transfer, instructional design, training
needs assessment, organization development (OD), succession planning
(SP), and career development projects. It encompasses all the human soft-
ware of an organization. The HRD system can be utilized by any large or
small organization (business, public, or non-governmental) to enhance
strategy, structure, and efficiency in that system to improve individual,
group, and organizational effectiveness. In short, HRD has field specific
interventions (both instructional and non-instructional, such as compen-
sation and rewards systems) that can be brought together to solve human
performance problems, while also identifying improvement opportunities.
HRD also encompasses a longer-term effort to prepare individuals to suc-
ceed each other for work in a global context. HRD is inter-discipline and
draws from the fields of business, education, economics, and communi-
cations (social sciences). It is not unique to any of these fields however,
and is best utilized in environments where there is considerable organiza-
tional, economic, or social change at a fast pace. Sometimes, HRD can be
inside an HRM, or human resource management, plan for either business
or public administration. Firstly, though, HRD needs to be clearly com-
municated and understood in order to be utilized and implemented for
maximum and thorough effectiveness.
INTRODUCTION TO ENERGY AND HRD: TOWARD EFFECTIVE LOCALIZATION 3
In short, HRD is about aligning human inputs for the best organizational
outputs.
One needs to only witness new toll roads in Nigeria and Pakistan, huge
maritime port expansions in Eastern Indonesia and Oman, or massive air-
port expansions in China, Malaysia, and Brazil to understand the enormity
and complexity of this business. That is just for transport. We have not
even mentioned new coal-fired power plants being commissioned in India
and Vietnam, fossil fuel use for heating homes and water, creating poly-
vinyl extrusions that make plastic bottles, accessories, clothing, and bags,
and the other fossil fuel products used in steelmaking, specialty chemicals,
and pharmaceuticals. The world’s burgeoning and accelerating demand
for resources and energy is staggering in the past 100 years alone.
Despite the press and attention given to global warming, in most of the
developing world, if it burns, it can, and it will, become a fuel source either
for direct combustion, such as cars, trucks, busses, or for heating water to
drive giant electricity-generating turbines. The addiction to fossil fuels in
the developing world is crystal clear. Yet, all fossil fuels are finite upstream
resources, and even biomass, such as coconut husks or palm oil residue,
requires a regrowth and regeneration timeline. Carbon-based fuels will
not be around forever, however, at current use rates and now pose even
more significant problems for the planet if it continued to be burned at
a breakneck pace in the residual of climate change.10 If all the carbon still
locked in the ground (coal, oil, and gas combined) and estimated at 2800
gigatons of reserves are burned, it would significantly physically alter the
planet we call Earth. This is not merely a figurative argument by any means,
global warming is happening, and quickly, according to 99.9 % of scientists
from the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), National
Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA), and National Oceanic and
Atmospheric Administration (NOAA). It is even acknowledged to be hap-
pening and well underway by most big oil companies (Shell and BP), the
US military, and the US CIA. We are past climate change being a negoti-
ated belief system. This will lead to profound changes into how energy is
used and carbon emissions responsibility in the near future.11
Correspondingly, a world addicted to fossil fuels buried deep under-
ground, with investors paying trillions of dollars per year for their extrac-
tion, refining, processing, and utilization, in practically all cases, generates
large profits and salaries for their workforces.12 Over 85 million barrels of
oil a day are consumed alone while falling slightly short with this year’s
drop in oil prices, 2016, while total world thermal coal consumption is fast
approaching 8 billion short tons a year, 80 % which is burned for elec-
tric power generation. Additionally, 110 trillion cubic feet of natural gas is
6 W. HICKEY
c onsumed yearly.13 Big oil and gas production projects that are holding
69 % of the world’s reserves will be found in developing countries in the
coming decade.14 Australia’s largest export is thermal coal, most of it going
to fuel the demand for electricity in the two Asian giants of China and India.
Canada is developing its bitumen rich ‘tar sands’ mostly for the benefits of
Chinese investors. Chinese are also driving and advancing credit for large
infrastructure projects across Africa, South, Central, and Southeast Asia,15
and most recently with an ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’ or AIIB,
to open up the arteries, if you will, for resource extraction and thus even
more fossil fuel burning.
According to Thomas Friedman, it is a hot, flat, and crowded planet
we must all share.16 The ‘Arab-Spring’ protests that started in part by
the masses of unemployed and redundantly employed in Tunisia, Syria,
Libya, and Egypt, may in part be a precursor of a burden-sharing need
the rest of the world faces.17 Developing countries simply cannot con-
tinue to entertain high unemployment for the benefits of the few entitled
and privileged in a traditional economic arrangement of the ‘natural state’
whereby it is business as usual for poor countries selling their only tangible
and exhaustible fossil fuel assets (oil/gas/minerals). Assets that would be
better served promulgating their competitive advantage if they had the
know-how to use it more effectively.
Therefore, a new socio-economic contract, rooted in stronger insti-
tutions18 is called for. As of this writing, the world sits in a deflationary
economic environment. At its root, there are simply too many unskilled
people and not enough unskilled jobs.19 Automation and overcapac-
ity have rendered many low- and medium-skilled jobs obsolete, if not
completely unnecessary (such as internet retailing, payroll processing,
high-tech assembly lines, and mining coal or ores).20 Growing unemploy-
ment problems continue to ferment political instability worldwide.
For example, practically all countries in resource-rich Saharan Africa
have a greater than 10 % unemployment rate.21 Youth unemployment in
many developing countries, and with huge stocks of fossil fuels them-
selves, approaches 50 % or more. Mass migrations from developing coun-
tries (many rich with natural resources) to developed ones are straining
welfare and social systems in the said developed countries, and are redefin-
ing a type of ‘desperation economics’ of migrants risking everything to get
to a place they perceive as better, no matter what the costs, while ignoring
resources or opportunities in their own developing lands, due to political
upheavals and repression.
INTRODUCTION TO ENERGY AND HRD: TOWARD EFFECTIVE LOCALIZATION 7
business proposition, and foreign investors will seek to leave these diminish-
ing returns behind. However, if the right skills are applied and transferred to
lower wage host populations, more employment can be generated toward
successfully managing well life. This is similar for coal mining. Higher calorie,
low-ash-content coal, for example, is the most sought after, however, by add-
ing better management skills to the workers, lower calorie coal can be more
intensely mined on a lower capital return investment timeline, and then mixed
to enhance its downstream (sales) value.
Enhancement This concerns creating value added after the initial pro-
duction stage of the resource. Many countries, such as Malaysia and Saudi
Arabia, are now taking a second look at adding value beyond the crude
oil or raw ores stage of production. In Malaysia, crude palm oil (CPO) is
being refined to create better resins and substrates in order to add value to
their local workforce skills inventory. Instead of merely shipping CPO to
China or India for further processing there, they are seeking to add value
to their own people with attendant activity based on the in situ resource.
In Saudi Arabia, they are investing heavily in the creation of polyethylene
via the by-products of the huge amounts of natural gas that come with oil
production, instead of wasting it as was traditionally done through flaring.
Both the Malaysians and Saudis are thus ‘moving up the value chain’ to
middle-level semi-finished products level that will give their workforces
higher wage growth and competitive advantage.
initial onslaught of rising sea levels and submerging shorelines. Even the
USA is feeling this, Key West and South Florida in general have witnessed
so-called sunny day flooding,36 where rising tides impact communities.
Climate change is real, it is not an abstract belief system and will have real
impact on economics, society, and migration.
Fig. 1.1 Macro, meso, and micro viewpoints of HRD from various scholar and
practitioners (Hickey)
INTRODUCTION TO ENERGY AND HRD: TOWARD EFFECTIVE LOCALIZATION 13
Currency Wars and Quantitative Easing Countries are now trying to ‘out-
devalue’ each other and print more money (quantitative easing) to make their
goods and services cheaper than their neighbors’. If we take a step back, it
would seem absurd, by racing to the bottom of human development and
offering cut-rate labor prices, countries make themselves more desirable. The
idea being that cheaper goods and people will lead to more demand, more
exports, more business transactions. It’s the other way around: countries with
highly performing human resources, like Swiss or Germany, are the trend line
for quality investment. The entire world’s economic advancement is based
on a so-called ‘consumption economics’ model.45 In other words, this has
failed to materialize. In fact, it’s gone the other way, where in a deflationary
environment, as the world is now arguably facing,46 people simply put their
money aside (savings gluts) while awaiting cheaper prices and hold off on
big purchases of cars, real estate, and washing machines. Big ticket items that
make the economy go round that reinforce the circular model of services and
thus and ethereal ‘economic growth’ ensues.
Emerging China and India In total, both these countries combined are
home to nearly 40 % of the world’s population, encompassing a staggering
amount of humanity. These countries have rising GDPs (Gross Domestic
Products) and large populations that need gainful employment. Their
citizens demand and expect more, but their systems, infrastructures, and
policies are products rooted in another era. This contradiction is causing
growth pains and spawning social questions and political problems domes-
tically and foreign. While China has certainly outpaced India in terms of
total development, both these countries also have deeper issues with learn-
ing and educational development for the long term.
All these instability themes are linked to one constant and over-riding
theme: Energy and rights to natural resources. Global warming is about the
‘right’ to use heavily polluting or climate alternating types of energy at the
expense of the planet. Currency values in many countries are underwritten
INTRODUCTION TO ENERGY AND HRD: TOWARD EFFECTIVE LOCALIZATION 17
‘Localization’
Localization is at the meso level of a country’s economic and social devel-
opment. It should be viewed through a lens of globalization, not colo-
nialism or its current format, neo (new)-colonialism. It is underpinned by
relevant educational initiatives that empower people in a local community.
Companies seek to invest in host countries profitably and to increase their
market share. Yet, it’s becoming less about balance sheets and aggregate cus-
tomers as it is more about employing, developing and engaging local people
to do the work, most pressingly in many developing countries suffering from
high unemployment, redundancy or underemployment issues all leading to
instability.
While dictatorships may allow them, democratically elected host gov-
ernments in developing countries will no longer tolerate vast armies of
high-skilled, foreign workers coming in to extract their natural resources
or operate their power plants while their own constituencies push brooms
and load trucks, or worse, they stand around unemployed, completely
bereft of all operations and maintenance.49 This is the natural state of
things. Of course, many governments are also well aware of this construct.
They have failed to consider educational development and upbraiding
on the same level as economic, financial, and technical development, and
while imposing taxes, fines, and tariffs for disregarding human develop-
ment and skills at the same level as a mere financial infringement. In that
sense, government policy must be focused on localization outcomes, with
education, not only financial wherewithal. This last issue is difficult to
conceptualize, as the gods of high finance, we will see in Chapter 3, are
sacrosanct to the globalized world order of international business and
economies, not human resources, though it is a nice concept for political
platitudes and armchair discussion among world leaders.
Nonetheless, there is still no concentric or agreed-upon definition
of what constitutes an effective localization or how it can be templated
INTRODUCTION TO ENERGY AND HRD: TOWARD EFFECTIVE LOCALIZATION 19
Finally, even if specific hiring and development criteria are met, it can
never be put past the companies or host governments to game the system
for marketing or political grandstanding.51 This is a problem today, for
example, with the US H1b visa issue. The idea is to attract skilled foreign
workers when locals do not have the skills to do the jobs necessary. The
reality is that the H1b visa issue seems to mimic a compensation visa,52
20 W. HICKEY
Table 1.1 Sample of HRD competencies needed (outside of raw extraction) for
energy localization
Core Sustainability Enhancement Responsibility
competency
Specific ad hoc and downstream competencies required for certain energy businesses. By Dr. William
Hickey
wealth ensues. People don’t advance themselves, and poverty is the overall
result. Conversely, countries with a paucity of natural resources, such as
Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan, go in the other direction, human
development exceeds expectations, simply as people have only themselves
to advance and must develop their human capital.
Namely, only the energy business in terms of upstream, midstream, and
downstream can provide the resources needed on an economic scale to
lift large populations out of poverty and promote societal improvement
and local-content initiatives. Making T-shirts, candy bars, plastic acces-
sories, or handbags destined for export to the USA or European Union
(EU) in an era of cutthroat competition and manufacturing overcapacity
simply cannot do that. There are too many low-wage countries competing
for a slice of the export pie. A Blue Ocean or the ‘Cluster Economics’66
concept alone cannot solve this overcapacity/large unemployment reality
factor. Energy, even in a down economy, still delivers trillions of dollars in
revenues and profits to select holders of the resources each year.67 It needs
to be developed better for maximum value for localized populations.
We simply live in an overcrowded world with too many problems, such
as political instability, mass migrations, endemic poverty, and now climate
change to ignore this reality. The old business model must be changed. It
is no longer an option to accept this old way of doing business in light of so
many pressing needs. In this aspect, HRD is an in-part answer to these issues.
Fossil fuels and their transition carbon-based energies (CPO, liquefied
petroleum gas [LPG], liquefied natural gas [LNG], compressed natural
gas [CNG], ‘Biomass’, etc.) then that are economically and strategically
reconnoitered, with their populations on an empowered level, become a
new store of value that is urgently needed in developing countries under
the weight of unemployment and burgeoning, unskilled, youthful pop-
ulaces. This ‘new’ currency or social capital can in part be reflected by
the utilization of the resources of the country in situ or downstream if a
country does not have direct access to resources (i.e. Singapore and Asia’s
largest refineries).68 Utilization creates effective employment by way of
burden-sharing.69 Burden-sharing is not merely about upstream produc-
tion with a finite amount of knock-on jobs; however, it also creates oppor-
tunities in the competency sectors of resource enhancement, sustainability,
and responsibility (see Figure 1.3).
Elite ownership of the resources, legal and contractual policies rooted
in colonial systems, and corporate intransigence on proprietary rights will
dumb down and mitigate any true localization effort. Many researchers70
26 W. HICKEY
Fig. 1.3 Hickey diamond of HRD and localization for natural resources
the world. They know and demand what their rights are. The world simply
has too many people (expected to grow to 9 billion by 2020), too deep in
poverty, with too few opportunities, and with too finite resources (includ-
ing the atmosphere and oceans) available to waste time playing the old
extractive resources game, set in a different time and era, both physically
and politically, that is masquerading neo-colonialism today. Simply, we
have too many people on too small a planet.
The remaining chapters of this book return to and consider significant
points that will either promote or hinder a localization initiative via energy
policy in the Information Age. Chapter 2 considers types of energy uti-
lized for most of the planet, namely fossil fuels, though alternatives are on
the horizon and growing, they are not yet economically feasible. Chapter
3, energy as currency, concerns the stranglehold high finance and the US
dollar have on the world’s energy business and its users, in particular via
investment portfolios, abstract derivatives, and SWFs. Chapter 4 considers
the looming problem of climate change, and how addiction to the fossil
fuel model is creating a zero-sum game toward emissions controls under
the nation-state umbrella of sovereignty. Chapter 5 examines mainstream
methods of effective HRD, a very linear and objective process of educa-
tion and training for specific goals and competence. Chapter 6 is about
energy ownership, particularly ‘constitutionally empowered ownership’ of a
nation’s resources by all the citizens and what this really means in a modern
world underpinned with colonial concepts of resource extraction from a
bygone era that have traditionally benefited only elites (both local and for-
eign). Chapter 7 is about localization, transferring skills, jobs, and wealth to
a host country’s people, not only citizens but also all stakeholders. Chapter 8
discusses the new behemoth in world affairs, China, and how their state-
driven model of capitalism for a sacrosanct political stability cuts against the
grain of any Western-style capitalism for profits. Chapter 9 briefly discusses
corruption via HRD, nepotism and the ‘client driven model’ of business as
usual in energy and resource extraction namely set in place during colonial
and times of resource exploitation. Finally, Chapter 10 explores the total
integration of all the prefaced considerations in order to make it work. And
workable it is if the political will is there!
Systemic change is in order, change that will address significant issues
outside of ‘business-as-usual’ scenarios. This book is an HRD manifesto to
that end: Human resources are everything in an information-intensive age.
The world cannot afford to delay any longer or cling to old nineteenth-
century colonial practices or twentieth-century energy policies. Too many
INTRODUCTION TO ENERGY AND HRD: TOWARD EFFECTIVE LOCALIZATION 29
Notes
1. http://www.energyquest.ca.gov/story/chapter01.html
2. Rothwell, W. (2000) ASTD models for human performance improvement,
2nd Ed.: The American Society for Training and Development. Alexandria,
VA.
3. Trompenaars, F. (1998). Riding the waves of culture. Homewood, IL:
Irwin.
4. See Hampden-Turner, C., and Trompenaars, F. (2000). Building cross-
cultural competence. New Haven: Yale University Press; for more detail on
new social trends and for shifting tectonic plates in economics, education,
and migration, see Thurow, L.C. (1996). The future of capitalism.
New York: William Morrow & Co.
5. For an excellent case study on how to develop company workers in a
developing country, see: Yan, R. (1998). Short term results. Harvard
Business Review, 5 (11), 61–75.
6. Rothwell, W. (2000) ibid., see also Mager, R. and Pipe, P. (1997).
Analyzing Performance Problems, 2nd Ed. CEP Publishing: Atlanta.
30 W. HICKEY
19. Thurow, L. (1999) The Future of Capitalism. New York: Wm. Morrow &
Co.
20. Rifkin, J. (2000) The End of Work, see also Jacques Fitz-enz, Paul Ehrlich,
and others in regard to work and population.
21. Despite the largest commodity resources in the worlds, African unemploy-
ment notorious, and is a stability problem: http://www.tradingeconom-
ics.com/nigeria/unemployment-rate
22. North, D. (1990) ibid.
23. Douglas North was the 1993 Nobel Prize laureate for economics for his
theory on the ‘natural state’, where 10 % of any human system is composed
of elites who are served by the other 90 %. In a limited access order, only
elites possess the right to form contractual organizations whose internal
arrangements are enforced by the state. The heart of an open-access order is
fluidity and change in social arrangements, namely, the empowerment of all
citizens with their attendant rights. See also Sachs and Warner, 2001, and
Joergen Moeller’s significant and game changing writings on ‘Burden
Sharing’.
24. For elite ownership of resources, see: Mikesell, R. (1997) Explaining the
Resource Curse, with Special Reference to Mineral-Exporting Countries,
Resources Policy 23(4) and Ross, M. (2001) ‘Does Oil Hinder Democracy?’,
World Politics 53(3): 325–61.
25. Senge, P. (2002). Human capital in 21st century organizations. In:
Management: Inventing and delivering its future. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press. P. 118.
26. Sachs, J. (2008) Common Wealth: Economics for a Crowded Planet.
New York: Penguin Press.
27. Sachs, J. and Warner, A.M. (2001) The Curse of Natural Resources,
European Economic Review, 45, Issues 4–6, pp. 827–38.
28. Chang, H.J. (2008) Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret
History of Capitalism. Bloomsbury Press. And also Easterly, W. (2007). The
White Man’s Burden. Oxford University Press.
29. Pinto, P. and Zhu, B. (2009) Fortune or Evil? The Effects of Inward Foreign
Direct Investment on Corruption, Saltzman Institute of War and Peace
Studies (SIWPS) Working Paper No. 10.
30. Moeller, J. (2010) Savvy and Foresight Will Be the Winning Commodities
in This Era of Scarcity. Yale Center for the Study of Globalization in The
Jakarta Post, 8/12/2010.
31. Taleb, N. (2007) The Black Swan book is about random events happening
outside stable systems with catastrophic and exponential outcomes on tra-
ditional processes, for example the Asian economic crisis in 1997.
32. Senge, P. (2006) The Fifth Discipline: The Art and Practice of the Learning
Organization, NY: Doubleday.
32 W. HICKEY
is why they invested in the first place), but the energy business is opposite
this.
51. See the political science work of Michel Crozier regarding system changes
and manipulation in Strategies for Change (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
1982).
52. Hickey, W. and O’Lawrence, H. ‘H1-b Technology Visas and their impacts
on international training efforts’ (IVETA Conference Keynote, Kinston,
Jamaica, 2001).
53. CCP, in Saudi Arabia, employs over 130,000 in the oil business.
54. Most oil and mining companies in developing countries are contracted for
some social obligation, usually cash payments to a village but could be schol-
arships, vocational center, or hospital, but are largely unstructured.
55. See Peter Senge’s work, 2006. The idea of systems thinking is not new to
resource extraction and economics. Systems thinking was founded by Dr. Jay
Forrester at MIT in the 1950s who was later invited to the Club of Rome to
ask if this system could be used for modeling to predict availability of oil
resources with economic growth. Namely, systems thinking states that the
structure of any system is just as important in predicting behavioral outcomes
as the individual actors themselves.
56. Porter, 1990, ibid.
57. Rothwell, 2003, ibid.
58. This is the concept behind the ‘Coleman Boat’ for social awareness and
societal change. Coleman, J.S. (1990) Foundations of Social Theory.
Cambridge, MA: Belknap.
59. Porter, M. (1998) On Competition. Harvard Business School Press:
Cambridge, MA.
60. Porter, M. ibid.
61. GDP can be skewed to the upside, for example, such as by a natural disas-
ter that brings in considerable foreign aid, or FDI targeted at only the
fossil fuel industry.
62. Strahan, D. (2007) The Last Oil Shock: A Survival Guide to the Imminent
Extinction of Petroleum Man. John Murray Publishers: London.
63. Yergin, D. (2008) The Prize: The Epic Quest for Oil, Money & Power.
Simon and Schuster: New York.
64. See Exxon record profits for 2011. Retrieved from: http://thinkprogress.
org/climate/2012/01/31/415337/exxonmobil-41-billion-but-pays-
tax-rate-lower-than-most-taxpayers-but-not-romney/
65. Various citations here, consider a few: Karl, T. (1997). The Paradox of Plenty:
Oil Booms and Petro-States. Stanford: University of California Press; Gylfason,
T. (2001), ‘Natural resources, education, and economic development’,
European Economic Review, 45, pp. 847–59; Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M.
34 W. HICKEY
Introduction
Before HRD can be engaged in an industry, the content and drivers of that
industry must be thoroughly understood for it to be a valid framework
for development. This includes all the industries’ direct products and pro-
cesses, the energy itself, and indirect or extraneous influences, such as pol-
lution, finance, regulations, insurance, and politics. Any discussion about
energy must first begin with the economics of it all. All countries seek
economic growth, and the cost of energy is the make or break litmus that
will ultimately determine their competitiveness or not. Whether one looks
at Indonesia, China, India, Nigeria, or Brazil, one theme emerges among
all of them with only nuanced differences: that is, predication of economic
development and future growth on a baseload capacity of fossil fuels and
at a breakneck pace. The fossil fuel model powers most of the world either
via combustion for transport (oil) or for electricity generation (coal). Even
at present, it is still the most cheaply available fuel source on the planet on
the front end. As recap, we briefly consider what fossil fuels are.
Fossil fuels are the remains of living organisms that died millions of
years ago from simple plants to dinosaurs then decomposed over that time
with varying factors of pressure, chemical content, such as sulfur or salt,
and rate of decay to determine whether gas, oil, or coals were formed.1
Natural gas, as it is called, is mostly methane or hydrogen atoms on a
carbon atom, CH4, and can be found in oil reservoirs, sandstones, and
shale rock.2 Crude oil is found in reservoirs deep underground or beneath
the sea. It has different forms and qualities. Oil gas is considered ‘light’ if it
has few hydrocarbons (usually less than 3 or 4 carbon atoms per molecule),
‘heavy’ if it has a long hydrocarbon chain (usually 12 or more carbon
atoms per molecule), ‘sweet’ if it has little or no sulfur content, and ‘sour’
if laden with sulfur via sulfuric acid (H2SO4). ‘Sweet, light, crude’ is the
most highly prized oil as is it easy to work with, with a low-carbon chain,
and can be refined quickly; Saudi Arabia and Nigeria have large stocks of
this oil. ‘Sour, heavy crude’ is the least desirable and requires significant
energy inputs to break it down to more useful fuels. This oil is representa-
tive of the large reserves in Kazakhstan and Venezuela. We can see then that
oil is not always about quantity, but rather quality in its value. Grading the
quality and weight of crude oil is an extremely complicated and detailed
business.3 Oil then produces all types of value-added downstream products
from kerosene to plastics (polyvinyl chlorides). See Figure 2.1.
Coal is from the formation of highly pressurized carbon in a solid form.
It has three grades: lignite, considered the lowest grade, used in many
developing countries for cooking; bituminous or black coal, used for ther-
mal (steam-generated power plants); and anthracite or ‘King Coal’, high
caloric and high carbon composition,4 used in steelmaking and metallurgy.
Anthracite is the least polluting of the three grades. Similar to crude oil,
coal stock can be used to produce a plethora of products.
However, this chapter by no means seeks to praise fossil fuel usage in
today’s world. On the contrary, fossil fuel usage is polluting the world and
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 37
Fig. 2.2 Graph of electricity generation by fuel type in the AEO 2015 (Source:
EIA)
With these things said, any transition energy sources (such as to natural
gas or shale oil) or alternative renewable energy sources (such as wind
power or solar energy) will all be based on what skills base is known,
available, and transferred from fossil fuels. This means that all extendable
energy use know-how for the production, finance, safety, and downstream
value-added enhancement is based, for better or worse, on the fossil fuel
model, and the trials and errors with it from its historic past. It also means
the world will continue to be beholden to the fossil fuel industry no mat-
ter what energy type is utilized into the foreseeable future. It is highly
doubtful, due mostly to costs, that an entirely new skills base will be cre-
ated overnight to service and maintain any new alternative energy source.
An exception to the fossil fuels-based HRD model of skills basing would
be NP (Nuclear Power), which is discussed later in detail, and brings its
own set of skills issues and safety problems to the energy table, in regard
to safety, storage, and public acceptance. Hydropower (dams), while a tre-
mendous electricity generator, and also with its own skill sets, is still a tiny
part of the world’s overall energy portfolio, with the exception of certain
developing countries, such as Tanzania and Sudan.5 Overall ~88 % of the
world’s total energy is derived from carbon-based fuels. See Figure 2.3.
These issues are especially exacerbated in a fossil fuel-addicted develop-
ing world, now with burgeoning wealth due to higher education levels
and economies soaring with increased exports to the USA/EU that are
reflexively stoking even more internal demand. Yet, if developing coun-
try. Today, in Colombo, the streets and homes that harkened back to days
of the British Empire are being torn down and replaced with bigger man-
sions, housing blocks, and wider roads. Cars, three-wheeled motorcycles,
and buses clog the roads, and property prices are soaring with new economic
vibrancy. An expansive airport, toll roads, and port, all China financed, are
taking on a new hurried dimension to the fossil-fueled dependency. With
no natural resources of its own, Sri Lanka must import oil and coal.7 The
Colombo stock market index was the world’s best performer in 2011 with
returns of almost 50 %, but has cooled off the past five years. Consumer
fuel subsidies and a pegged currency in Sri Lanka have helped to keep the
boom going, but are quickly depleting government coffers and contributed
to an ongoing currency devaluation and driving up inflation, nonetheless
the roots of a new fossil fuel-addicted country are apparent everywhere.
Individually, none of these cities is doing anything ‘wrong’. They are
all developing their economies based on their needs as they see fit, and on
a historic economic precedent of oil- and gas-fueled growth. However,
this situation, when taken in aggregate, is simply not sustainable for the
planet we live on if multiplied by the dozens of emerging and developing
economies. When all the cities of an emerging Asia (especially considering
China/India), Africa, and South America are summed, we have a problem
with enlargement of the world’s fossil fuel demand and an addiction that
increasingly becomes a more apparent reality.
While Korea is not considered a developing country by the OECD, it was
one about 30 years ago, and provides a growth template the rest of the devel-
oping world envies. Its burgeoning export model via state-favored chaebols
and policies provides a GDP high enough to import all the fuel necessary to
stoke its economy. In essence, the other places, Colombo and Bandung are
emblematic of emerging NICs (newly industrialized countries) that need
to keep the export model humming by way of fuel subsidies and exporting
low value-added agricultural and manufactured products. Purchasing power
in these countries is still too low to create serious sustainable demand for
higher-priced products if the economy has a downturn and their currencies
must be consistently devalued to aid in keeping economy activity afloat.
The fossil fuel addiction thus becomes a necessitated economic growth
‘right’ in these places. The economists (going back to Milton Friedman8)
did not have a clear plan for these energy issues in the advent of oversup-
ply and climate change, perhaps the market’s ‘invisible hand’ may not be
the best problem solver for public goods phenomena. Higher fuel prices
might force a change in lifestyle, such as using motorcycles and eating less
meat, for example, as economists predicted, but doing neither is liked,
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 41
and people will and do protest, sometimes violently if they are forced to
return to more austere times. No one likes to consider a forced change in
their lifestyle, in this era of CNN, Instagram, and Facebook, as an honest
solution to their country’s economic woes.
Thus, major problems are created with these situations in a developing
world that must be addressed due to increased fossil fuel addiction. First,
consider the big picture:
For a rethink, starting with the entire commodity export model and the
fossil fuels enabling it are in order. With 7.3 billion people on a planet of
dwindling resources, the lights are flashing red. Of course, at the time of this
writing, the world oil prices have collapsed to $30 a barrel, but that does not
mean more oil has been created. It is an economic cost of doing business. As
of early 2016, oil-rich economies such as Saudi Arabia and Russia are furiously
out pumping each other in hopes of driving out of business so-called mar-
ginal producers in the USA and Canada who, by using new technology, have
created more efficient extraction techniques with non-conventional shale oil
and tar sands.12 These latter techniques, while more efficient at extraction,
are also more polluting with groundwater and environmental degradation.
Unfortunately, cheap oil may only have the unintended effect of creating
further demand which will lead to more pollution in the long term.
For a primer, we consider the overall types of energy that are imme-
diately available to all on the planet, and their so-called greenhouse gas
emissions (GHG) mostly of CO2, CO, and CH4, which are respectively
carbon dioxide, carbon monoxide, and methane, as they all contain car-
bon atoms. See Figure 2.4. These are all non-renewable energies coming
from combustion of coal, oil, and natural gas. Their creation as a source
of energy took millions of years, and we are using it faster than it was pro-
duced and faster than it can ever be recreated.
Renewable energies come from the sun or from nature, namely wind
and water. While the energy is free, it costs money to collect and store
it. Renewables face many economic challenges. With the exception of
hydropower (dams), they don’t deliver the consistent baseline energy load
required to power national electricity grids. They are costly on the front
end to install. Additionally, some renewables, such as palm fronds or wood
chips, are burned as fossil fuels would be. In this case, carbon emissions are
still a process by-product.
Nuclear and geothermal energies aren’t truly renewable either but they
are treated that way since their natural scale is so immense.
Fig. 2.4 Worldwide energy profile and emissions, 2014 HSBC global research
report entitled, ‘Stranded Assets, What’s Next? (Used with permission)
44 W. HICKEY
Saudi Arabia), and the ‘realpolitik’ it has played, and continues to play, in
practically all world events. While the book is a fascinating read about the
people and politic involved in the oil business since its first commercial well
in the US State of Pennsylvania in the 1850s, it fails to address current envi-
ronmental trends and lurking depletion problems with oil. It also assumes
the world’s entire economy will be underpinned by its usage, well into the
twenty-first century and for the next several decades, lending immediate
impetus and credibility to even more long-term fossil-fueled mega-proj-
ects, exploration, and their vast financing arrangements required.
According to the International Energy Agency (IEA), oil usage sits at
93 million barrels per day or 34 billion barrels a year.14 As of 2016, this
usage has dipped slightly with a severe commodity downturn, but is fore-
casted to pick up again in the next few years due to developing country
growth.15 Most of this growth will be driven to 2040 by emerging India
and China, together accounting for almost 40 % of the world’s population.
Yet, oil is an exhaustible resource, it won’t be around forever and overall
world demand continues to grow (even in deflationary times). Most of the
so-called easy oil has already been discovered. Oil has become more ‘tight’
or harder to get at worldwide. Exploration now must be carried out in
inhospitable regions (like the Arctic) or politically unstable areas (such as
Congo or Turkmenistan) or in the deep oceans and seas (such as the gigan-
tic Tupi field off the coast of Brazil, or the newly found Eni Zohr field in
the Mediterranean also in deep water, off the Egyptian coast). This means
that oil is getting ever more costly to ‘lift’ or produce. Much field viability
in oil extraction is decided by lifting costs or by politics, (such as Russia
claiming most of yet unfounded Arctic sea reserves for itself). This means
the cost that is required to extract a barrel of oil from any given field, either
onshore or offshore, becomes prohibitively expensive. In essence, even
with utilization of fracking, oil (and gas) are still exhaustible resources, and
with world demand ever increasing, we will eventually reach the stage of
‘peak oil’ or what the IEA defines as ‘the maximum possible annual rate of
extraction of conventional crude oil, due either to physical resource con-
straints or above-ground political, economic or logistical factors’.16
Most big oil fields of today are in terminal decline under current Western
oil management practices. This means that under the ‘business as usual’
metrics of costs and utilizing Western-trained labor, they are no longer or
will no longer be profitable at some point. When an oil reservoir (or field)
goes into decline, though, it does not mean that the reservoir is empty.
There is still oil in the well. It does mean, however, that the pressure and/
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 45
Fig. 2.5 Selected country coal use in their overall electricity generation (Source:
IEA 2012)
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 47
CTL and GTL
Bill Paul, an energy consultant and writer in his book Future Energy has
written glowingly about the transition of conventional oil to unconven-
tional oil, namely coal-to-liquids (CTL), gas-to-liquids (GTL), and shale
oil (extracted via so-called fracking). In his book, Paul claims we are facing a
new era in energy demand where coal becomes the everyman fuel32 to make
new synthetic gasoline via the Fischer-Trope process, which was invented
by the Germans in the early 1900s and used successfully by Nazi Germany
during World War II and later by the South Africans under Apartheid, in
both cases for self-sufficiency due to international blockades. Both coun-
tries have enormous amounts of coal reserves. Paul then continues on with
tar sands (squeezing bitumen out of dirt), fracking or shale oil recovery (by
cooking rocks underground with high pressure), and concludes with LNG
(liquefied natural gas) by stringing together gas molecules to create liquids.
Many of Paul’s ideas are good, as they will employee and maintain con-
siderable workforce, there are no problems with that. The problem is circu-
lar systems. Paul’s efficiency and unconventional fossil fuels mandates still
tether us all to a carbon fossil-fueled model that does not seem to be able
to be broken. Consider that according to the IEA,33 if adding biomass into
the mix of current energy sources (burning palm fronds, leaves, and wood
pellets) then carbon-based energy intensity still comprises almost 90 % of
the world’s energy portfolio, leaving only 10 % of the world’s energy supply
to nuclear and other non-carbon-based energy source initiatives. This is an
extremely important dialectic to ponder. Oil, gas, and coal still rue the day.
CPO and Biomass
Biomass is (still) a relatively small contributor to the worlds overall energy
portfolio, despite the media attention to get us out of ‘fossil fuels’ and
into renewables. Biomass is a renewable and accounts for half the world’s
renewable energy profile, but while it is arguably not a ‘fossil fuel’, all bio-
mass does indeed contain a carbon chain. Simply put, if it burns, it releases
CO2. Biomass is popular in developing countries as it is readily available. A
significant type of biomass used in the developing world is CPO (crude
palm oil) due to its abundancy. Nonetheless, it is not a s erious energy com-
petitor simply due to its tiny economies of scale compared with fossil fuels.
In developing countries, corn has been used to produce ethylene to
mix with gasoline to reduce a reliance on foreign oil imports. Even though
50 W. HICKEY
ethylene is cleaner burning than crude oil, it still has an emissions foot-
print. But the real problem is in feedstock. Growing corn or other food-
stuffs to transfer to the energy portfolio runs the real risk of creating food
shortages elsewhere, especially in developing countries. In short, to fully
replace the fossil fuel portfolio component of the world’s entire crude oil
production with corn-produced ethylene, would require the development
of more farmland than is available on earth to meet this new challenge.
This is a huge impediment. We simply do not have enough agricultural
space to feed and fuel the planet.
can dry up, and so on but fossil fuels continuously generate power day in
and day out.
The largest problem is that most non-carbon- and non-nuclear-based
renewables are simply not up to the economies of scale needed to con-
tribute meaningfully to providing reliable power to the ‘baseload’.34 They
all suffer from either upfront costs, power reliability issues, or both. The
largest exception (and contributor) to the renewable energy portfolio is
hydropower or dams. Yet dams require a very long planning horizon and
vast regulatory approval processes, making the projects payback timelines
long and needing significant government financial backing to proceed and
commence. Dams and the electricity they generate contribute almost 2 %
to the world’s total energy portfolio.
Consider, for example, the gigantic Three Gorges dam in China. It gen-
erates a whopping 22.5 GW (gigawatts) of installed electrical power. Yet it
took nearly 10 years to build and will not pay back its costs of $26 billion
until 2022 at the earliest. The total project timeline to payback then is 20
years. This requires large government support and policy mechanisms to
enact it. Even with the dam online, China’s electricity generation growth
profile is still overwhelmingly ‘fossil fueled’ by coal.
Other non-carbon-based renewable, such as geothermal energy, solar
panels, and windmills still combined generate less than 1.5 % of the
world’s entire energy portfolio. Again, the reasoning is simple—costs.
Geothermal, like hydro, requires significant upfront investment and large
amounts of regulatory approval, including land acquisitions. Even after
commissioning, payback times can be long. Geothermal runs the added
risk of wells going dry (or a stop in generating steam). In that sense, geo-
thermal becomes a high-risk investment project.
Solar panels have come down in price considerably since their introduc-
tion in 1940. Solar panels convert sunlight to electrons and thus electric-
ity is created. The problem with solar is that it does not generate enough
electric intensity (power) to run air conditioners, refrigeration, and heat-
ing systems on a sustainably reliable level. While it can heat water, run
lights, and power home computers and cell phones, it is lacking. While the
panels have become cheaper, there are still installment and maintenance
issues, not to mention cloudy days. Recently, regulation has cropped up
regarding solar and net metering initiatives with power companies, as it
is affecting their profitability and sunk costs, especially with lower energy
prices due to economic downturns in commodity resources.
Harnessing wind power has been the darling of environmentalists for
several years now, and wind farms in Spain, Korea, and California have
52 W. HICKEY
Fig. 2.6 Energy production in China, 2015 as indicative of fossil fuel addiction.
(Source: EIA, 2015)
proven that it can indeed generate enough power for many homes in an
area. The problem with wind is costs for turbines and installation. This
creates a long payback time to profitability; despite the media attention
and political interest in clean wind power, hurdles remain as long as it is
more cheaper to buy a gallon of gasoline or burn a ton of coal on the front
end, though once the government subsidies are calculated, it will generate
electricity more cheaply (Figure 2.6).35
Solar
A core issue with all renewable sources is their baseline capacity, or reli-
ability to continuously generate robust power. Solar energy with its cost,
efficiency, storage, and unreliability (not every day are there blue skies) is
seven times or more expensive than using coal or nuclear to produce elec-
tricity.36 There are many moving parts with solar in developing countries
that are not readily apparent in particular the maintenance and upkeep of
panels for smooth transmission.
Wind
The problems with wind turbines are many. They are very costly and wind,
unlike burning coal or spinning uranium, is not constant. Turbines also
contribute to environmental degradation, blight on otherwise open land-
scapes and emit low frequency noise that can be quite annoying, even at
great distances.37 Additionally, wind power, due to both grid and reliability
issues, is not always profitable. A study in The Utilities Journal found that
84 % of western Denmark’s wind-generated electricity was exported (at a
revenue loss) in 2003. Of note is that Denmark’s multiplicity of wind tower
projects only serve 3.3 % of the nation’s total electricity capacity.38 Again,
Denmark, as a country without natural resources or big rivers, needs a fos-
sil fuel baseload to ensure a reliable and continuous power supply.
54 W. HICKEY
Hydro
Hydropower or dams require committed public investment to create.
Further, they have a significant damaging effect on the environment from
river basins to farmland with flooding, habitat destruction, and entire
community relocations. Transmission of the energy created also requires a
large public investment in grid expansion. To that end, dams require sig-
nificant government intervention and sponsorship, usually at the national
level, to get past (or push past) localized political objections, and with
attendant government guarantees on loans to build the dam.
Once a dam is created, however, its main selling point is that it can
generate enormous electric power more cheaply than fossil fuels and is
comparable with nuclear energy. Nonetheless, the environmental objec-
tions, in all but the most stalwart of authoritarian governments such as
Myanmar or China, have been growing. Due to this issue, dams are not
a good political option in many countries,39 though their jobs creation is
massive for large swaths of unskilled workers, mostly for digging, moving,
and the more low-skilled, labor-intensive parts of construction.
In short, wind, solar, and hydro, while all sounding very plausible and
impressive for reducing the carbon footprint, are more ad hoc sources
of energy for a total energy baseline. Renewables are heavily dependent
on government subsidies, tax breaks, and preferential policies to enact
their use on economies of scale level. Without these, they quickly become
non-competitive for electricity generation in relation to oil, nuclear, and
hydropower. What needs discernment is a detailed cost–benefit analysis
which includes long-term variables of the environment, finance, and man-
power sourcing against other types of fossil fuels. The point of this is not
to bash renewables, they are sorely needed on a planet under the loom-
ing shadow of climate change, but rather separating facts from fiction.
Consider Table 2.1, where discount rates are applied to determine cost of
money for doing long-term energy projects.
Geothermal Energy
The biggest problem for geothermal energy (electricity created via power
plants installed above natural steam wells and hot springs) is in the avail-
ability of skilled manpower for equipment, staffing, and transmission,
which is also an HRD mandate. Yet, gaining these vocational and man-
agement competencies is difficult. The second major problem is the huge
sunk costs for the installation of the power plant atop the steam source,
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 55
Table 2.1 Actual costs of electricity (US cents/kWh) where CCS is ‘carbon cap-
ture and storage’
Technology Region or country At 10 % discount At 5 % discount
rate rate
and accessible transmission lines for electricity in perhaps quite remote and
rugged areas, like mountain valleys or near, if not in, volcanoes. Generally,
hot steam springs are by their nature isolated and exist along seismic fault
lines, so more extensive electric power infrastructure needs to be built.40
Due to these factors, ‘Geo’ also requires significant government subsidies
and investment guarantees not to mention human and societal risk and
impact assessments. Cash-strapped governments will quickly avoid this
costly, but very environmentally friendly, type of renewable energy if they
can default to cheaper and more reliable fossil fuels.
A Hydrogen Cell?
Hydrogen-based power has been a wish list for a long time to power
many developed countries economies. Like certain renewable and nuclear
sources, it has zero carbon emissions in its production, and its only by-
product is pure water. Hydrogen is not really an energy source per se, as
gasoline or coal is, but more of a carrier source. Hydrogen fuses chemi-
cally with oxygen in a fuel cell or battery to create electricity41 by generat-
ing an electron flow across an anode.42 The electricity generated is then
fed to electric, not internal combustion, motors which run silently. The
56 W. HICKEY
hydrogen ions then react further with the air to combine to make water.
Unfortunately, a large amount of energy is expended in its industrial pro-
duction, splitting the hydrogen from water in the first place, and then
creating a reliable and efficient fuel cell for large-scale commercial use is
complicated, thus rendering it an impractical and expensive, though very
clean, fuel. In short, it is again simply not a practical fuel source today to
compete against the economies of scale required in a fossil-fueled world.
With that said, however, the eventual application of hydrogen as a fuel
source offers vast opportunities for skills development and jobs as the sun
eventually sets on fossil fuels. The opportunities to utilize a hydrogen-fuel
source from our vast oceans is large. Few know much about fuel cell cars
or commercial applications, and know less about the systems for extract-
ing, containing, and transporting crude hydrogen.
oil, coal, wind, and hydro, the scope of this contextual HRD challenge
that developing countries face cannot be underestimated. To fully utilize
nuclear technology, developing nations must embrace HRD.
After the March 2011 Tsunami, directly effecting the TEPCO (Tokyo
Electric Power Co.)/Fukushima NPP in Japan, the nuclear industry
came under severe international pressure to revamp its safety protocols.
Some countries (i.e. Germany) reacted to the disaster by declaring they
will phase out NP by 2022. This type of uncertainty going forward with
nuclear energy has had serious effects on future manpower sourcing needs
for the industry, and for HRD planning in particular.
Nonetheless, the demand for nuclear energy, especially in developing
countries with an insatiable need for inexpensive energy, continues to grow.
India, China and Russia are considering further NP expansion to their exist-
ing electric grids, which are now largely powered by heavily polluting bitu-
minous coal. South Korea has made the jump from developing to developed
NP in 50 years. Other countries, such as Indonesia, Malaysia, and even
Sudan are eager to create NP as a pillar to their largely fossil-fueled econo-
mies. Development of human resources (HRD) in these countries are at
different stages and with different needs. Much of this has already been dis-
cussed in existing International Atomic Energy Agency (IAEA) literature.44
India, with over a billion people, is going to potentially increase its NP
generation to 470 Gw by 2052 (a 70-fold increase over current capacity).
Indian per capita electricity consumption is about 600 KWh/Yr, but 5000
KWh/Yr are needed to surpass the poverty threshold. India estimates it
will need a workforce of 7000 nuclear engineers alone just for a planned
20 Gw increase in power to its existing nuclear output by 2020. India gets
less than 3 % of its electricity from nuclear, but it is, along with China and
Russia, one of the leaders in current new construction, boasting six of the
world’s 35 reactors under construction.
These are all very large numbers with high expectations for a country
such as India where previous deficiencies in construction projects have led
to huge cost overruns that were plagued by mismanagement (i.e. 2010
Commonwealth Games). HR development and research for NP in India
is mostly conducted by the Homi Bhabha National Institute in Mumbai
which is an umbrella for ten existing R&D and education institutes across
the country. Homi Bhabha utilizes a high bandwidth web for interactive
learning with its other institutions for real-time problem solving.45
China is planning for 80 Gw of installed nuclear capacity for electric
generation by 2020. Even if realized, this would only be about 5 % of the
total Chinese grid electric output. China’s NP is vertically integrated, from
58 W. HICKEY
100
20000
80
Capacity & Demand (MW)
60
15000
40
20
10000
0
-20
5000
-40
0 -60
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
2024
2025
2026
2027
2028
2029
2030
Fig. 2.8 Sudan power plan forecast with nuclear option (Source: Sudan Atomic
Energy Commission (SAEC) used with permission)
60 W. HICKEY
Fukushima
No discussion about NP is complete without mentioning the events
that transpired on March 11, 2011 at the TEPCO NPP operation in
Fukushima, Japan. This was predated by two other NPP disasters in the
USA in 1979 (Three Mile Island) and later, Chernobyl, in the then Soviet
republic of Ukraine. The Three Mile Island disaster was a nuclear reactor
meltdown caused by a loss of coolant52; in Chernobyl, a reactor was com-
promised which led to several steam explosions, and a radioactive cloud
forming which traveled over much of eastern and central Europe. While
Three Mile Island was not life threatening, Chernobyl killed several work-
ers, significantly increased local cancer rates, and caused 350,000 people
in Ukraine to be relocated, with unknown long-term consequences to
several national populations. Its final cleanup costs were gigantic, and the
negative press put NP on its back foot for more than a decade.53
The Fukushima Daiichi NPP accident, unlike Three Mile Island and
Chernobyl, was caused by two external factors, first a major earthquake
occurred off the coast of Japan, followed by a 15-meter-high tidal wave of
water striking the NPP complex. The magnitude-9 earthquake did little
to the NPPs themselves; they shut down, but the ensuing flood of water
disabled the backup power generators and all electrical circuitry. With the
ensuing loss of power and without coolant, three of the six total reactors
at the complex melted down, releasing large amounts of radioactivity into
the atmosphere and surrounding seawater. Uncontrolled fission contin-
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 61
The IAEA has actually showcased much new learning and HRD best
practice in a 2006 document entitled Knowledge Management for Nuclear
Industry Operating Organizations.57 The two key HR issues it highlights,
and which are indicative of NP today, are:
Fig. 2.9 A knowledge map of methods for explicit, implicit, and tactical knowl-
edge building
(Source: IAEA, 2006)
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 63
a year, it would not solve all HR issues for NP in regard to human perfor-
mance problems and systems.59
Harmonization of standards and processes will enhance self-reliance
and energy security for NPP. There are sharing platforms, but these do
not carry the weight of an internationally accepted standard.
As China moves up the value-added chain to exporting NPP technol-
ogy to developing countries to foster political ties, the lack of a world
standard (such as ISO) for specifications and procedures could prove
problematic if using third country contractors for integrating, enhancing,
or upgrading NPP technology. This is also emblematic of why Russia can-
not easily change its Soviet past. For example the issue of storing spent
fuel is also a necessary component of any nuclear energy development
program. Japan already is working on HRD processes at its non-nuclear
proliferation laboratory to address concerns smaller countries may have in
regard to spent fuel handling and business practices for fuel cycle storage.
Alternatively, a large developing country, say in not using a world-accepted
storage protocol and poor oversight enforcement, could decide to store
spent fuel in poor conditions. In short, lowered or uneven standards carry
tremendous hazardous societal cost and considerable safety risks with any
NPP. Harmonization of all standards is not optional without this, the
developing world cannot be responsibly introduced to nuclear power.
Fig. 2.10 Growing global energy demand with breakout for China and India
(Source: EIA, 2012)
electric consumption, then total fossil fuel percentages decrease across the
board.60 Norway is a lone standout, generating nearly all of its domestic
electricity from hydro (dams) via its various fjords61 despite being a major
exporter of fossil fuels. See Table 2.3.
Transition energies, like natural gas, is still a fossil fuel. Carbon-based
renewables, such as biomass and wood pellets, are also polluting and not
‘clean’ from a combustion standpoint. Clean renewable sources of energy
such as wind, solar, and geothermal can have a larger risk profile than
the benefits received in terms of either cost or safety or both. Cleaner?
Definitely yes, cheaper and more reliable? Despite all the considerable mass
marketing from government and environmental agencies, no. Hydropower
can definitely deliver the economies of scale cheaply, for r eliable baseload
power, but while very clean, carries huge environmental and destructive
social costs (people and animal relocations and obliterations).
Finally, NP, when safely and efficiently utilized, is the paramount
emblem of a country’s HRD. Nuclear is all about technology and safety,
but most developing countries cannot utilize the manpower needed to
engage either. If they can though, nuclear energy provides the best way
forward for growing energy demand in the developing world. While car-
rying some risk, it is cheap and it is clean, and it is reliable. The world will
need to seriously address NP in the future as an offset to increasing carbon
emissions from fossil-fueled cultures.
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 65
Angola 44 49 94 6 -0-
South Korea 86 <1 86 -0- 13
China 91 1 92 8 (Hydro) 1
Tanzania 70 <1 ~70 30 -0-
(Hydro)
Malaysia 93 4 97 3 (Hydro) -0-
Mexico 93 <1 93 6 (4 1
Hydro)
Ecuador 81 <1 82 17 -0-
(Hydro)
Nigeria 19 80 99 1 -0-
Oman 80 N/A >80 -0- -0-
Egypt 96 N/A 96 4 (3 -0-
hydro)
Indonesia 78 18 96 4 -0-
India 73 22 95 4 1
Brasil 60 N/A 60 39 1
(Hydro)
Developing 74 14 88 >9 >1
Group Avg.
Average World 87 2 88 8 (7 4
(BP) Hydro)
UK as Control 87/86 2/N/A 89/86 3/N/A 8/7
BP /EIA
Notes
1. Freese, B. (2004) Coal: A History. Penguin Books.
2. See: http://www.uncoverenergy.com/liquid-gold/
3. Our Industry, Petroleum 5th Ed. (1977) The British Petroleum Company.
Printed by Staples Printers Kettering.
4. Stefanenko, R. (1983). Coal Mining Technology: Theory and Practice.
Society for Mining Metallurgy.
5. See MCA-Tanzania Mathematika study and also Sudan Atomic Energy
Commission baseload study.
6. Traffic jams are a part of life in Indonesia, now effecting all cities. http://
regional.kompas.com/read/2013/01/19/07251778/Pagi.Ini.Sistem.
4.in.1.di.Gerbang.Tol.Pasteur
7. Sri Lanka, 13th Ed. (2015) Lonely Planet Publications, Pty.
8. Friedman, M. (1978). The Energy Crisis: A Humane Solution’ In The
Economics of Freedom. Cleveland: Standard Oil Company of Ohio.
9. In recent Paris, 2015 Climate Change Accords, India stated it will burn
even more coal than before to power its developing economy. And
Petrominer. 2010. Petrominer Monthly Magazine No. 01 Vol XXXVII.
10. Converting to gas, why not? The Jakarta Post, retrieved from: http://
www.thejakartapost.com/news/2012/01/26/converting-gas-why-not.
html
11. Leggett, J. (2006). Half Gone: Oil, Gas, Hot Air and the Global Energy
Crisis. Portobello Books.
12. Klein, N. (2014) This Changes Everything. Allen Lane, pp. 143–144; this
gives analysis on unconventional fracking and tar sands.
TYPES OF ENERGY AND USAGE 67
13. Yergin, D. (2008) The Prize: The Epic Quest for Oil, Money and Power.
Simon and Schuster: New York.
14. http://www.iea.org/aboutus/faqs/
15. World Energy Outlook, EIA 2016 URL: http://www.worldenergyout-
look.org
16. Ibid.
17. Deffeyes, K. (2001) Hubbert’s Peak: The Impending World Oil Shortage.
Princeton University Press.
18. For 2016 production freezes and cuts, see: http://oilprice.com/Energy/
Oil-Prices/Why-OPEC-Production-Freeze-Could-Pave-The-Way-For-
Actual-Cuts.html
19. Oil and Gas Journal, 2013. http://www.ogj.com/articles/print/vol-
ume-111/issue-12/special-report-worldwide-report/worldwide-
reserves-oil-production-post-modest-rise.html
20. http://www.worldcoal.org/coal/uses-of-coal/coal-electricity/
21. h t t p : / / w w w. t h e g u a r d i a n . c o m / w o r l d / 2 0 1 5 / n o v / 0 4 / c h i n a -
underreporting-coal-consumption-by-up-to-17-data-suggests
22. World Resources Institute (2012) http://www.wri.org/blog/2012/11/
new-global-assessment-reveals-nearly-1200-proposed-coal-fired-power-
plants
23. Annual Energy Review 2011 (2012) Coal section, 195–215 (accessed at:
https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/annual/pdf/aer.pdf November
5, 2015).
24. http://www.nrdc.org/globalwarming/files/coalmining.pdf
25. World Nuclear Association (WNA). Comparison of GHG emissions of
project life cycles.
26. Coal Hard Facts: Cleaning It Won’t Be Dirt Cheap (2009) http://online.
wsj.com/article/SB123751110892790871.html
27. Germany has changed to renewable under its ambitious Energiewende pro-
gram, but the politics of coal is still an ‘Achilles Heel’, see http://www.
nytimes.com/2015/12/04/world/europe/germany-may-offer-model-
for-reining-in-fossil-fuel-use.html?_r=0
28. Klein, N. (2014) ibid. Particularly pointed critique of the fracking technol-
ogy to get the world to a ‘transition state’ between traditional fossil fuels
and renewables is really a ‘null choice’. P. 200.
29. GE has best technology available for burning gas more efficiently in a
CCP. See https://powergen.gepower.com/resources/knowledge-base/
combined-cycle-power-plant-how-it-works.html
30. For a precise definition of ‘baseload’, see the Energy dictionary: http://
www.energyvortex.com/energydictionary/baseload_plant.html
31. LNG and Mitsubishi. See http://asia.nikkei.com/Business/Companies/
Mitsubishi-Heavy-tests-waters-with-floating-LNG-power-plants
68 W. HICKEY
These actions, led by Saudi Arabia, created a new ‘oil standard’ replacing
the dollar’s previous ‘gold standard’ that had been ended in 1971; the pet-
rodollar was born, oil then became a supporting currency to the dollar and
propped up the dollar’s value immediately.7 Today, practically, all global oil
transactions are settled in dollars. Recently, China has attempted to make
inroads into this system with their currency, the yuan, in Ecuador, Russia,
and Iran, but they are miniscule compared to total trade volumes in dollars.
Essentially, the theory is that the US dollar’s value is determined and
supported by oil under a relationship few in the world can grasp. Whereby
a US-centric ‘car culture’ with the most advanced interstate road system
in the world that is used to service ‘urban sprawl’ and suburban expansion
became addicted to the ‘All- American fuel’ and the role that oil is and con-
tinues to play in world events.8 Gasoline, kerosene (jet fuel), and heating
oil account for 80 % of the breakdown of all US oil consumption. In other
words, US growth and economic activity is predicated on oil consumption.
The conventional thinking then is that when oil prices are low, the US dollar
gains in strength (as we are seeing today in 2015), conversely, when oil prices
are high, the US dollar weakens considerably (as it did in 2005/2006).9 This
is because higher oil prices in USA create a large current account deficit to
pay for oil imports. Recent technological gains in producing oil and gas such
as ‘fracking’ have made the USA more energy independent and have now
created the USA as an energy exporter, which would lend economic credence
that a current account surplus would tend to push up a nation’s currency.
The Petrodollar
This phenomena of trade surpluses due to oil continues to this day even
under the guise of ‘Sovereign Wealth Funds’, where previously known as
petrodollars, then later as ‘petrocurrency’ which is the surplus currency
earned by petroleum exports and products, from any oil-exporting nation,
usually denominated in dollars or some other hard currency. It is esti-
mated that trillions in petrodollar wealth have been created, which in turn
has underpinned the value of assets and derivatives worldwide. The very
recent collapse in oil and commodity prices have tested petrodollars and
the sovereign wealth funds that save and invest them. The trend has been
that the petrodollar is essentially the world’s currency.10 If distilled further
and used as a proof, oil is the world’s real currency.
The outcomes of this dollarization of oil have been far reaching and
profound. It has enabled big producers of fossil fuels to develop significant
74 W. HICKEY
‘war-chests’ of foreign exchange (mostly dollars) that has enriched them and
bloated their GDPs, in tandem with foreign investors who also invest to gain
an interest in richly rewarding fossil fuel projects. In the early 1970s, these
surpluses of dollars were recycled into commercial banks, bonds, and equi-
ties of mostly developed nations and in the USA, in order to earn higher and
more stable returns that their own developing countries could not provide.
In the decades of the 1970s and 1980s, these petrodollars were circulated
outside of their home countries, but unfortunately, this plethora of money
rarely made impacts locally. By 1981, the current account surpluses of all
OPEC members amounted to over $450 billion, a vast and staggering sum.11
What is again important to note here for the purposes of this book is that
while financially prudent, these investments did little or nothing to aid in the
human and social development of their own people, at least on internation-
ally accepted scales of development. It has only been recently, with declining
reserves, and many mouths to feed, that countries have reassessed this.
It also allowed the US dollar seigniorage over local currencies from
oil-exporting nations. This means that the dollar became the real store of
wealth of financing in these countries, subjected to US economic policy.12
This system also then provided significant benefits to the US economy.13
SWF have existed in various forms since the 1950s. In fact, ‘Petrodollars’
in the Middle East oil economies became the logical predecessor to SWF.
Many in the oil-rich countries in the Middle East that held these dollars
from the last oil boom in the 1970s were inconsistently invested, in turn,
leading to capital losses with no real impact in long-term national benefits.
ENERGY AS THE ‘NON-DEVALUING’ CURRENCY: A STORE OF WEALTH... 75
This was a painful lesson these countries learned with the collapse of oil
prices in the mid-1990s, and sought not to repeat it by seeking out stron-
ger performing investments in other, usually Western, countries to diversify
portfolio risks. Only recently have SWF emerged as the mega-managers of
large national capital reserves and diversely held foreign portfolio assets.
Nonetheless, any country holding a capital surplus, not a deficit, of energy-
or natural resource-related revenues including downstream revenue activity
(such as in Singapore, China, or S. Korea with refined fossil fuel products for
sale), can then also become a net producer of wealth14 via an energy-backed
currency, that being either the physical resource, such as crude oil or the
know-how resource to process the commodity such as smeltering, polyvinyl
extrusions, or high-end refining capacity, including the ability to transport
or store the refined material/finished product. Unlike a fiat currency, which
has no physical asset backing like a gold standard or other commodity, a
currency backed by real assets can produce a significant national economic
advantage. A new store of wealth is created. This wealth needs to be invested
in order to earn returns. But where the wealth is invested is the key. We live
in an information-intensive world. Investment returns must be considered
along the spectra of knowledge development, and the funding to increase
that said development then becomes a paramount driver.
SWF: A Definition
SWF, at their core then, are from surplus funds that invest the savings of
governments or retirees in various forms, mostly through foreign vehicles.
As of 2013,15 SWF were conservatively valued worldwide at around 6 tril-
lion dollars. In physical form then, SWF are massive state-owned investment
vehicles of stocks, bonds, property, precious metals, and other financial
instruments that include private equity. This number has no doubt fallen
significantly since then due to crashing commodity prices since 2015 and
large SWF holders such as Norway and Saudi Arabia are now partially cash-
ing out with so-called redemptions to keep funding their various social obli-
gations.16 Nonetheless, SWF still represent significant pools of wealth due
to oil and gas activities from mostly developing countries, even in an eco-
nomic downturn. There are many SWF under different names and man-
dates, from Kazakhstan to Iran to Singapore to Norway and the Middle
East, with most, but not all, such as China, in oil-producing countries.
There are also nascent ideas for SWF in places such as Myanmar, Congo,
Nigeria, and even Indonesia, which is now a net oil importer, but oddly
76 W. HICKEY
has rejoined OPEC. But these ideas are hamstrung due to the extreme and
incipient corruption at high executive levels and that exists in many of these
countries. The main commonality with all SWF is that they are using sur-
plus cash assets to generate high financial returns to cover social expenses.
Returns that are generated usually, but not exclusively, from developed
countries abroad, in the USA, Switzerland, and the UK. The ‘short shrift’
then is in generating better human capital assets domestically.
Norway (a developed country) holds the largest sovereign wealth fund
in the world, valued conservatively at over $900 Billion, but down recently
due to cratering oil prices. While the exact portfolio composition is secret,
it is estimated that Norway’s ‘Government Pension Fund’ holds 1 % of all
global equities.17 Most of this wealth was derived from its North Sea oil
fields, in operation since 1962, but it is also derived by the human capital
that its major state-owned oil company, Statoil, has developed over the
years and now exports services abroad. Statoil and Norwegian engineers
are world renowned for successfully developing offshore oil projects in
much of the developing world.18 The Norwegian Sovereign wealth fund
also excludes investing in companies that violate human rights, produce
armaments, or cause considerable economic damage to the environment.19
In short, the Norwegian government has taken the aspects of HRD at an
early stage of its wealth agglomeration to a much higher level than most
other oil-producing countries in the world and have provided a bench-
marked model of creating human capital from oil. As a model, it can be
directly applied to other countries and it should be.
Unfortunately, many developing countries are far removed from using
their resource wealth for the advancement of their own people such as
in Norway. (As we shall see in the chapter on localization, Chapter 7,
Norway is also a pre-eminent localization story and has created a human
development template many countries, developing and developed, should
consider and be inspired by.)
Generally, the problem is that SWF look to invest their funds outside
their countries for more stable and greater financial returns at the expense
of their own citizens. This would have made sense 30 years ago when
human development indexes were not as well understood and the world
did not have instantaneous communications via cell phones and the inter-
net, but not today. We exist in the information age. Only countries that
develop their people to globally benchmarked standards of competence
and ability will be able to succeed. In this aspect, energy wealth can be
translated into real human capital in short order. It’s not really about
currency, it’s about policy. Human resource policy must be reflected in
the proceeds obtained from the resource that their citizens own. On the
ENERGY AS THE ‘NON-DEVALUING’ CURRENCY: A STORE OF WEALTH... 77
surface, no one would disagree that this ‘substance problem’ arises in the
processes and procedures that are tightly held by finance.
There are several prolific researchers of SWF who utilize differing defini-
tions of what an SWF is precisely. The Peterson Institute’s Edwin Truman
qualitatively defines SWF as ‘separate pools of international assets in the forms
of cash and equities mostly held emerging economies, with the governments
of these economies having more direct control of the international reserves
than in developed countries’.20 Simon Johnson, a former vice-director of
the International Monetary Fund (IMF), quantitatively defines SWF as a
‘secretive vehicle to manage accumulated excess foreign exchange reserves,
or foreign money from exports due to current account surpluses’.21 Ashby
Monk is currently a co-director at Oxfords SWF Project, which attempts
to influence world SWF policies, prefers to use the IMF definition of SWF,
‘vehicles that typically help fund socio-economic progress…or… industrial
policies that might raise… potential output growth’ and focuses more on the
best practices, growth, and financial processes involved with them.22
Financial Relevance
Understanding the mechanisms behind SWF is core to the financial implica-
tions of energy and HRD. Two types of SWF exist: Commodity based (the
largest type, based on oil or mining reserves, and primarily what this book
considers which exist in countries like Malaysia, Kazakhstan, and Australia)
and Non-Commodity SWF based on overall export surpluses, such as
what exist in China or that Korea have in light industry and technology, or
based on downstream value-added services, such as oil, coal, and gas-based
chemicals, medicine, and polyvinyl chlorides, or in the massive financial ser-
vices used to conduit the energy-trading businesses, that an Asian hub like
Singapore provides. For this book, we limit the discussion to commodity
(energy)-based SWF in developing countries better yet for education direc-
tives in ‘emerging economies’, such as Angola, Kazakhstan, or Myanmar.
During the first economic crisis of 2007/08, SWF discussion in largely
disappeared with developing country governments trying to maintain
immediate economic stability. This has also happened again, with the
recent oil slump of 2014/15, but during that abatement time, and with
worldwide energy growth, the discussion of what to do with commodity
revenues took center stage. An obvious suggestion was national economic
diversification. Brazil became notable for this at the time.23
Perhaps then, we must consider that the best development of a country’s
citizens in the information age is not best reflected in financial returns such
as CAPMs (Capital Asset Pricing Models), WACCs (Weighted Average
78 W. HICKEY
Controversy
Many developed nations have large sovereign debts due to the defi-
cit financing of high social expenditures in the form of ‘entitlement’ pro-
grams and are in dire need of outside resources—which are primed for
ENERGY AS THE ‘NON-DEVALUING’ CURRENCY: A STORE OF WEALTH... 79
Frameworks for SWF
We consider three frameworks for monitoring and standardizing SWF
which have been proposed to promote better investment actors on the
world stage, these standards are aimed at developing countries who have
had, or continue to have, poor records of corruption and transparency or
both. It may be mentioned that most holders of commodity-based SWF,
with the exception of Norway, also have compromised human rights
records. None of the standards, as follows, considers human rights.
80 W. HICKEY
The Santiago Principles These are the Generally Accepted Practices and
Principles (GAPP) that responsible holders of SWF worldwide agreed to
participate in as signatories in Chile in 2007. There are 24 GAPP sub-
sections, which, like the Truman Scorecard, can essentially be broken
down into four general areas: a stable financial system, transparency and
disclosure of holdings, economic and financial risks, and risk management
and accountability. Some SWFs, such as Norway’s national pension fund,
are highly accountable and self-policed, others, such as Iran’s, are non-
compliant and have shown indifference toward these principles altogether.
Table 3.1 SWF standards matrix where green is strong, yellow is weak, red is
non-existent (Source: W. Hickey)
A Rainy Day
The overarching and consistent ideal then behind the SWF is for a rainy-
day fund, or for when the oil or other resources run dry and a country’s
future generations will largely need to make due on their own initiatives.
‘Future generation employment’ (if not engagement) is a consistent theme
then among the foundation of all SWF for their legitimacy. Somehow this
approach may be misguided: the rainy day is actually here today. Putting
money in higher risk foreign investment vehicles, especially in an era of his-
torically low capital returns (due to a world growth slowdown, low oil prices,
and arguable deflationary forces) is shortchanging their citizens. It would
then seem that, and according to the research,31 highly centralized pools
of money in developing countries tend to attract corruption, not dilute it.
Simply, any SWF scoreboard, benchmark, or general principle must
clearly enshrine a component of HRD to its ideal assessment in today’s
world. Simply, some countries have no justification in seeking ‘higher capi-
tal returns’ elsewhere when their people largely remain unskilled, unde-
veloped, and with a nowhere future of bleak poverty unveiled in front of
them. Especially, if these countries, rich in resources, are the recipients of
any donor ‘aid’ and WB/IMF loans at substandard interest rates. It just
82 W. HICKEY
tax policies and investment breaks, and labor mobility simply cannot be
decided on a one-size-fits-all dimension of sovereignty. Before developing
countries with large SWF seek a direct financial payback in foreign lands,
perpetuating in most instances the North–South phenomena, they must
direct their investments inward toward developing their own and poten-
tially their near neighbor’s people. This last point cannot be overstated.
The overarching goal of any SWF policy then must be to increase edu-
cation and human capital in resource-rich countries that have attendant
serious poverty and inequality gaps. And if human capital development
is the true mission, perhaps then developed countries could be less suspi-
cious of the SWF investments on their own soil and more accommodating
of their actual design.
in assets would be lost if 80 % of the carbon was kept in the ground. These
are not precise numbers however and reflective of the ‘Pareto effect’.
Savings Gluts
As Joachim Fels, Global Economic Advisor for PIMCO, tells it, the world
now faces a long-term secular ‘savings glut’ (alongside of an oil glut and a
general money glut). This means that people, burned by the financial crisis
of 2009, want to save more money and not invest. In our consumption-
driven economy, that is not good as it depresses prices, inflation, and
demand stays low.
This weak economy aspect has large implications of course for HRD:
Workers skills deteriorate, weakened labor force participation, finally
job layoffs and as Fels puts it, ‘lowered animal spirits’ (or motivations,
required for risk-taking in business and entrepreneurial activity).42
Another issue that Fels brings up is the world suffers from overcapacity,
whereby too many things being created for too few buyers. Investors in
old-line businesses would rather save their money than to commit more
capital to these redundant ventures. Fels is a great believer in macro-
economics, meaning that global trends will eventually dictate what will
happen locally, and he is not alone in this belief; Ray Dalio, whom we
mention in Chapter 10, also believes that world economics is governed
by business cycles, and George Soros believes in reflexivity in the money
system. Added to low oil prices and central banks printing more and
more money, this all leads to falling prices and demand, global growth
slows. Lower oil prices do lead to some economic benefit in net import-
ing countries, but overall, world economies stagnate. In other words,
a deflationary world is created. Why buy something today if it will be
cheaper tomorrow?
In a world of deflation, people rush to put their money into vehicles
and investments that will earn them any return or the so-called ‘search
for yield’. In so doing, they increase their risk profiles enormously. When
investing becomes more dangerous with greater volatility and losses of
capital implied, people save their money instead. This is part of a secular
cycle, also known as ‘secular stagnation’,43 where savings rates are heading
out of the developing world (similar to SWA) and into investments in the
expense of the developed world, to most notably the US markets. From
economies that desperately need money to improve their people and for
capital projects to economies that already have a plethora of savings, and
will pay a low, but stable rate of return.
86 W. HICKEY
The safeguard sought here is return ‘of’ capital, not return ‘on’ capital.
Both Japan and Switzerland, both countries with stable economic systems
and desirable currencies, have bolstered this deflationary trend by having
their central banks set negative interest rates. Meaning that banks must
now pay their central bank if they hold onto cash. The ideal is to stimulate
economic activity, but the results are not clear.44
The bottom line in all of this is that stagnating economies mean low
demand, which translates into less jobs and risk to the incumbent jobs that
exist. If the situation persists long enough, permanent joblessness is the
result, and people expect governments to come to the rescue.45 Coming to
the rescue means propping up prices and employment, in short, repeating the
current economic growth model of buying and selling products to increase
growth that is tried and true, it’s all the politicians know and how they react.
Finance dictates the terms and their course of action is directed to its remedy.
We can also see that energy via fossil fuels is also an inextricable com-
ponent of the economic growth recipe, reinforcing the previously stated
fact the world and all its ad hoc undertakings run on oil, and its underly-
ing demand/cost structure. Nothing is ever mentioned in these scenarios
with Central Banks about investing in people for the long term via stra-
tegic education initiatives. It is all about financial instruments (bonds and
equities), tangible commodity prices (oil), and interest rates, today. None
of this then is really reflective of human development or using the sav-
ings glut for the advancement of society but rather perpetually fueling the
consumption-driven models of finance.
Nonetheless, the lure of fossil fuels, even in an era of down prices, is just
too strong for the finance industry to resist. Like flies drawn to sugar, cer-
tain investment houses, such as hedge fund Blackstone, look to increase
their investments in oil and gas in a downturn, not devise new sources
of alternative energy. John Studzinski, Blackstone’s managing director of
strategy, in a recent interview on Bloomberg, glowingly spoke of its $9
billion investment in distressed fossil fuel reserves.50
The financial industry has hindered innovation, undid pollution rules
and laws that have protected consumers, and slowed changes that may
affect its bottom line. As former Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
Chair Sheila Baird pointed out, it’s a culture of ‘cognitive capture’ where
governments listen more to the markets and the people that run them
with far too much cozy behavior, as opposed to any mainstream trends or
needs,51 including tectonic changes that have real effects on world popu-
lations and economies.52 A paradigm shift is required to understand that
real value is created in people not in paper. This is especially challeng-
ing in developing countries without an appreciation of human talent, but
rather of physical assets. The real key is not in creating more paper monies,
backed or not backed by assets, but in creating ‘know-how’ societies that
will create more wealth over time.
The tight and intricately woven link then between finance and energy
has also recently wreaked havoc with banks who have predicated and col-
lateralized many of their fossil fuel-based loans to oil and mining compa-
nies with the assumption of a return to high prices and accessing (burning)
these reserves into the future in other words, a quick return to business as
usual. Low oil prices trigger ‘mark to market’ or inventory write downs of
much lower collateralized values of their loans. This is an important issue.
If the prices of energy commodities goes to low, it could trigger demand
for immediate paybacks on many of these loans, or in essence a ‘short
squeeze’. However, that could bring the entire financial industry down if
loans cannot be repaid due to these ‘distressed positions’.53
88 W. HICKEY
industries. In 2008, the US Treasury had to bail out banks due to col-
lapsing home prices, whereby banks had lent money based on inflated
bubble values of housing. This time, a crash in world commodity prices
on a sustained level could trigger an even worse response if the (or any)
government again has to bail out its banks.56
Of course, none of this has not escaped the notice of the US Government
either, due to being burned in the past with banks that are ‘too big to fail’,
they are now scrutinizing portfolios of banks to determine if significant
risks exist in their portfolios due to energy loans. The outcome then is that
in times of low energy prices, banks will reduce their overall exposure to
energy projects.
Unfortunately, this creates a binge and purge situation for HRD: with
few oil and gas development projects on line with low prices, domes-
tic employment suffers, conversely, prices will soar in the future when
demand eventually picks up again due to a dearth of supply available, a
finite pool of workers will create an inelastic market of available talent.57
This is especially notable after the last major oil crash of 1989, when whole
sectors of the oil business went offline, experienced people were forced to
retire, and a corporate moratorium on new hiring was frozen. This set the
stage for soaring oil prices in 15 years’ time, with an ensuing decade long
oil boom and created a scarcity of talent for new project availability.
Fig. 3.1 Derivatives and risk management in the petroleum, natural gas, and
electricity industries (Source: EIA 2002/Hickey)
Many things can affect the crack spread and it is a complicated business
treatise to all but the most well versed in the world of energy and finance.
In short, bad weather, shortages, political upheaval, seasonal fuel adjust-
ments can all cause volatile gaps or lags between what a product originally
costs and what it can actually sell at. What is important to know for human
development is that these types of derivatives can (and have been) manipu-
lated to influence pricing and should not be used to cheat people out
of their resources via financial engineering or gimmickry. Tankers can be
turned around in the middle of the ocean, refineries can be shut down for
‘maintenance’, high-speed trading can tip off select investors before the
many.60 ‘King finance’ looms large in energy trading today but it should
not be in the way of the information-intensive future.
itive advantage to all countries, particularly those that are export dependent
with a low-cost labor advantage. Planes fly on kerosene. Ships run on bitu-
men. Cars run on gasoline. Power plants (non-nuclear) run predominately on
coal and diesel. This is the situation that confronts us in 2015 going forward.
World governments then are so compromised and complicit with fossil
fuels and their use that they simply cannot walk away from them without
leaving their economies worse off as the true costs of energy are hidden in
a Byzantine labyrinth of producer and consumer subsidies promoting the
addiction. These subsidies then become a form of currency in their own
right, like food stamps or welfare payments, to give an economic boost
to economies that cannot change due to incumbent political structural
issues, such as high-employment costs, low levels of education, decrepit
infrastructure, and aging populations.
Simply, if the true costs of energy were passed on to their lower income,
developing country clients, the economies would become prohibitively
expensive for investment, and thus non-competitive. Unemployment
would soar, and social instability would occur. The consumption model
of macro-economic free market policies envisioned by the late economist
Milton Friedman assumes continuous availability of cheap energy with
market mechanisms ‘sorting it all out’ based on supply and demand.61
We consider Friedman’s glowing viewpoint about fossil-fueled energy and
economics in the 1978 BP funded presentation, ‘The Energy Crisis: A
Humane Solution’ in Milton Friedman’s The Economics of Freedom:
Day by day it becomes more evident that the oil we happily possess in excel-
lent quality and abundance is the mainspring of modern material civilization
… Oil in truth stands not beside but entirely above all other commodities.
It is the material source of the energy of the country, the universal aid, the
factor in everything we do … It can be no matter of surprise that year by
year we make larger draughts upon a material of such myriad qualities—of
such miraculous powers.
This neo-liberal economic philosophy, almost 40 years old now, has also
shaped the energy policies of many developing countries, and continues
to do so today.
Divestment
However, not all is always sacred in the world of fossil fuel finance.
Recent trends that have acknowledged climate change as a looming and
life-changing threat to all mankind and the latitudinal environment as
92 W. HICKEY
we know it on the planet have spurred loud cries for divestment in fossil
fuels. The issue of divestment carries huge financial consequences. Pension
funds, hedge funds, mutual funds, and ETFs (Exchange Traded Funds, all
encompassing or linked to financial ‘derivatives’) have vast holdings in
fossil fuels and the utility companies that process them to generate power.
Nor is divestment in fossil fuels a straightforward proposition. As
HSBC puts it, in a recent report ‘to boycott all products derived from
fossil fuels is extremely difficult. Coal, oil and gas are used for 75.6 % of
global power generation. Oil meets 95 % of transport fuel requirements.
Fertilisers, petrochemicals, construction materials are all highly dependent
on fossil fuels, as are domestic heating and cooking.’62 In other words,
and as stated in Chapter 1, the world is so hooked on fossil fuels that it is
next to impossible to extricate them from use and by extension, finance.
So many feed and derive existence from unfettered extraction and use of
fossil fuels, that any change will be slow, if at all.
A wholesale divestment from fossil fuels could depress prices of these
equities by lowering the capital expenditures for operations and stall
mega-projects needed for more economic growth. This would reflexively
lower dividends and returns from these industries, and the attendant high
salaries and employment generated would also suffer. In fact, this is what
is happening right now as 2016 begins.
Two key words that the fossil fuel industry seeks to avoid are stranded
assets. These are assets that become albatrosses for companies: they lose
their value and stop generating payments. In the case of oil and coal, they
are reserves (proven and probable) that remain in the ground, due to either
policy regulations, lack of demand, or low commodity prices/high fossil
fuel lifting costs. For example, many companies have IRR (internal rates of
return) that must be met in order for a project to proceed. If the world oil
price stays at average $50 bbl. and the lifting costs for a barrel of tar sands
‘dilbit’ in Saskatchewan CN are ~$80 bbl. the project is no longer profit-
able and is a money loser. It will be shuttered, and if prices do not rebound
for a long time, stranded. This has actually happened recently in the case of
Shell with a tar sands project.63 We will see in the chapter on Integration,
Chapter 10, how lower-priced local labor may be able to mitigate some
of these issues, nonetheless, they should be used as a step toward human
development prerogatives and not an extension of the fossil fuel model.
Nonetheless, divestment in fossil fuels is then necessary for protect-
ing the planet and to force the transfer to get to non-carbon-based
ENERGY AS THE ‘NON-DEVALUING’ CURRENCY: A STORE OF WEALTH... 93
Net Metering
While derivatives based on fossil fuels as an asset class that are abstractly
held by the financial industry are well understood, a more relevant and
tangible level of energy as a new currency that could possibly benefit the
individual directly as opposed to the conglomerate, is the concept and
application of ‘net metering’. In net metering the individual energy b uyer’s
utility meter ‘spins backward rather than forward’.64 This is in essence cre-
ating your own energy and feeding it back into the system getting paid for
what you create65 or a bankable energy credit.66
Mostly, this is energy creation via alternatives, such as solar or wind
power, as most people do not have the economies of scale necessary on
an individual investment level (or regulated level) to drill for oil or start
a coal mine on their own. Net metering will not pay a household’s entire
electric consumption bill, but can make a significant dent in it. It depends
on how the utility pays the individual producer for the energy, a retail rate
(the most consumer beneficial) or a market rate, more the norm, where
ENERGY AS THE ‘NON-DEVALUING’ CURRENCY: A STORE OF WEALTH... 95
Analysis
The world’s addiction to fossil fuels has profound effects on a country’s
economies and financial systems, in terms of economic competitiveness,
investment, and development. It has enriched oil-producing countries so
much that they now seek investment vehicles for their vast wealth in the
96 W. HICKEY
Notes
1. Yergin, D. (2008) The Prize: The Epic Quest for Oil, Money and Power.
Simon and Schuster: New York.
2. Freese, B. (2004) Coal, A Human History. Perseus: Cambridge MA p. 44.
98 W. HICKEY
46. Mukunda, G. The Price of Wall Streets Power. Harvard Business Review,
June, 2014.
47. Wall Street Journal. http://www.wsj.com/articles/j-p-morgan- sounds-
fresh-warning-on-energy-losses-1456243537 accessed on Feb. 24, 2016.
48. http://www.wsj.com/articles/energy-lending-caught-in-a-squeeze-
1443050639
49. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-10-07/four-ways-
the-oil-price-crash-is-hurting-the-global-economy
50. http://fuelfix.com/blog/2015/02/23/blackstone-to-pour-9-billion-into-
struggling-energy-industry/
51. http://www.americanbanker.com/bankthink/schapiros-promontory-
move-latest-signal-of-too-much-coziness-1057980-1.html
52. Thurow, L. (2003). The Future of Capitalism, 2nd Ed. New York: Wm.
Morrow & Co.
53. http://www.businessinsider.co.id/jefferies-third-quarter-results-2015-9/#.
ViW4WScaySM and http://www.bloomberg.com/news/videos/
2015-10-19/jamie-dimon-to-ceos-don-t-make-earnings-forecasts-
54. http://static.macquarie.com/dafiles/Internet/mgl/com/macquarietris-
tone/publications/energy-lender-price-survey/energy_lender_price_sur-
vey.pdf?v=33
55. JP Morgan Commodity Trading Exit, see: http://www.cnbc.com/
id/100900230
56. Too big to fail and other issues: http://www.wsj.com/articles/
energy-lending-caught-in-a-squeeze-1443050639
57. Gray, K. and Herr, D. (1998). Workforce Education: The Basics. Allyn
and Bacon, New York.
58. http://blogs.wsj.com/drivers-seat/2013/02/25/why-are-gasoline-prices-
soaring-blame-the-crack-spread/
59. EIA (2002) Derivatives. http://www.eia.gov/oiaf/servicerpt/deriva-
tive/chapter3.html
60. Moors, K. (2013) Green Energy Report, http://www.theenergyreport.
com/pub/na/are-the-special-few-manipulating-oil-prices
61. Friedman, M. (1978). ‘The Energy Crisis: A Humane Solution’ In The
Economics of Freedom. Cleveland: Standard Oil Company of Ohio.
62. HSBC Report, Stranded Assets: What’s Next? (April 2015).
63. http://www.theguardian.com/business/2015/oct/28/shell-halts-carmon-
creek-oil-sands-project-in-alberta-canada
64. World Bank (2011) Green Energy and Renewables online course.
65. http://science.howstuffworks.com/environmental/green-science/net-
metering.htm
66. Ibid., Net Metering.
67. http://yaleglobal.yale.edu/content/sovereign-debts-fossil-fueled-world
68. A contentious issue, but the World Bank is still funding coal- fired power
plants in developing countries.
CHAPTER 4
Key Takeaway—Unless HRD also sits at the table as an equal with eco-
nomics and finance, to address climate change issues meaningfully, it will
be difficult to wean the planet from the fossil fueled model.
Climate change is a real and looming issue in the world of tomorrow
we face today. It is now an undeniable scientific fact due to the long-held
use and abuse of the unmitigated burning of fossil fuels, accumulating
since the dawn of the Industrial Age, which is generally accepted by sci-
entists as around 1850.1 Global warming has already been accepted by
some of the biggest users and subsequent abusers, such as Exxon Mobil,
Shell, and even the US military.2 Even so, HRD must play a large part in
educating people of its reality and pending danger if fossil fuel combus-
tion is left unmitigated. People need to be informed about how this could
change their lifestyle and threaten their very existence, for the future, they
will need to consider carbon taxes, policy changes, and lifestyle changes,
all linked to their energy usage.3
Changing climate has the potential to severely alter life as we know it
on earth without any mitigation or intervention today. Being addicted to
a fossil fuel dependency, underpinned by tectonic financial forces will be a
significant challenge moving forward. If one listens to CNBC, Bloomberg,
or Fox News, there is no problem with using fossil fuels into perpetuity as
economic growth and wealth is predicated on it. Alternatives and special
TV shows on changing the fossil fuel model (such as biomass or geother-
mal) are a nice distraction, but, as previously demonstrated, these fuels
simply cannot meet the economies of scale needed to move the world’s
economic, military, and commercial activity.
Finance and investment issues (as discussed in Chapter 3) still underpin
so much of the world’s fossil fuel activity and their derivative value is ulti-
mately determined on burning those oil and coal reserves into the future.
Especially, in regard to the derivatives traded on world financial markets
underpinned by fossil fuels and their investors. It’s a messy situation with-
out an easy answer. There is so much invested that these interests have spent
millions of dollars the past several years to create ‘consensus gap’, between
the public and scientists about the threat and reality of climate change.
They have also created a very partisan political divide on the issue, mostly
the USA, turning mainstream conservatives against any types of carbon
regulation, be it at the gas pump, airlines, or with coal-burning utilities.4
Exploration in pristine and remaining natural habitats on the planet
are now on the list for fossil fuel exploitation. Consider the Artic, the
Antarctic, the South China Sea, far Eastern Siberia, Hudson’s Bay, Papua
New Guinea, the upper Amazon Basin, and central African countries, many
of these latter jungles are considered as the earth’s ‘lungs’ by environmen-
tal and climate scientists. These places are also home to many diverse bio-
logical species that fossil fuel production could destroy or severely impair.
Consider what has happened in Ecuador, Nigeria, the Caspian Sea, and
Kalimantan (Indonesia) with substandard fossil fuel extraction efforts over
many years that have left native peoples and the environment worse for the
wear via pollutants and toxic contaminants.
Fig. 4.1 Life cycle of greenhouse gas emissions based on electricity generation
source (Source: Used with permission by HSBC)
104 W. HICKEY
sometime in the future, and as stated in our financial Chapter 3, this busi-
ness model creates an enormous wealth extension effecting stocks, bonds,
derivatives, pensions, national economic budgets and currency values.
So much of the world’s financial system and the people all interlinked to
it, direct and indirectly, are predicated on this number. Contrasted with
number two, we quickly see we don’t have enough earths atmospheres,
5 of them to be correct, to contain all the carbon released if 100 % of the
reserves were burned. It simply cannot be allowed to happen. Yet the
financial industry gives significant pushback for any attempt to lower this
number. Someone, somewhere will have to absorb the losses.
According to Bill McKibben, ‘This number describes the amount of
carbon already contained in the proven coal and oil and gas reserves of the
fossil-fuel companies [both international and state owned], and the coun-
tries (think Venezuela, Russia, or Kuwait) that act more like fossil-fuel
companies and less like nations. In short, it’s the fossil fuel we’re currently
planning to burn.’
There is also another number that is not part of the ‘scary three’, the
350 parts per million (PPM). According to NASA scientist James Hansen,
an average of 350 ppm of CO2 molecules in the atmosphere is still a safe
level to stabilize climate changes.7 Historically, the world has been at aver-
age 275 ppm. Keeping CO2 PPM levels under 350 PPM is of some para-
mount concern for climate scientists. According to Hansen et al., the only
way to keep the world’s atmosphere under 350 ppm CO2 is if,
An initial 350 ppm CO2 target may be achievable by phasing out coal use
except where CO2 is captured and adopting agricultural and forestry practices
that sequester carbon. If the present overshoot of this target CO2 is not brief,
there is a possibility of seeding irreversible catastrophic effects.8
In April 2014, CO2 levels around the world hit an average of 400 ppm
continuously for the first month in recorded human history with projected
2+ ppm increase each year, and quite possibly since the Pliocene era of the
early mammals. This is significant. As carbon levels build up in the atmo-
sphere, we are being warned they create heat-trapping gasses that will soon
reach a tipping point of no repair pushing us far past 2° to as high as a 6°
Celsius world average increase.9 Yet the dilemma between fossil fuel usage
(which is exploding) and climate change is still tolerated and justified by so
many man-made institutions (some which even agree it is happening, like
the CIA). Carbon continues to accumulate in the atmosphere at alarming
THE CLIMATE CHANGE CONUNDRUM 105
levels. Countries are hooked on fossil fuels (even with economic slow-
downs), governments promote and subsidize them, economic planning
and investment decisions are tethered to them, culture and convenience
prioritizes them. Yet, climate related issues continue to grow worse and
will take international outcry to force real changes in fossil fuel models,
which is changing the world and no longer a mere ‘belief system’.
Government has generally been of no help. It is too compromised
with monied interests of the fossil fuel industry. US President Obama and
the US State Department (under John Kerry) have taken the political
position that while global warming is the greatest threat facing mankind
today, something like the Keystone XL pipeline might go through (even
if it obtusely adds to climate change) in order to meet the short-term
economic and political demands of many institutionalized actors (big
oil, construction labor unions, politicians up for re-election, etc.).10 In
essence, while fossil fuels are interwoven in all of the world’s economies,
global warming is considered a man-made violation of natural laws, mean-
ing physical laws or laws of nature. Additionally, destroying the planet for
future generations, while seemingly preachy, would be considered a gross
violation of human rights if measured by attrition in future generations.
Renowned scientists, the IPCC, NASA, OSHA, and other non-political
actors (though the political right have made many claims that these groups
are also political actors) have noted that a continual buildup of greenhouse
gasses is slowly destroying (or permanently altering) the planet we live on.
Yet economic growth models in all the world’s countries (as discussed in
Chapters 2 and 3) predicated on their burning even more carbon to boost
activity and consumption.
In this sense, unabated and continuous usage of fossil fuels in this day
and age, ‘enslaves’ much of the world. While both major political parties
have labored long and hard to keep the extremely contentious issues of
climate change out of national political debate, such as in the US 2012
Presidential election, and among foreign countries in order to maintain
their compromises with big oil.
Today, global warming is an immediate and clear threat to mankind. An
alarm has been sounded. It has the propensity to change the finite world as
we know it, into an overheated planet that will violate the laws of nature.
The stakes are too high. Without real changes in fossil fuel usage, the con-
sequences will not be good, and humanities story could end in tears. We
are not speaking about merely implications on a race of people or group
of nations, but about enslavement of the planet and life as we know it.
106 W. HICKEY
given, but what about countries that do not cooperate or their ‘closed bor-
ders’ to anything smacking of foreign infringement on sovereignty masks an
extreme domestic abuse of fossil fuels (such as China and India underpinning
economic growth on unscrubbed coal emissions) while giving platitudes at
world climate conferences and Group of 20 meetings about the necessity of
dealing with CO2 reductions, but having no intention to seriously deal with
these issue that impact not only their neighbors but also mankind.
It should be pointed out that any type of ‘contingent sovereignty’ then,12
such as a stronger country’s influence over a weaker country or failed state
(i.e. Kenya and Somalia, or the USA and Iraq), should be about equal ben-
efit for both and not about the strong-armed dictates of righting wrongs
and defending a given country’s definition of human rights abuses. In fact,
contingent sovereignty has been criticized as more of a device to license
invasion than to address serious domestic concerns in neighbor countries.13
There is also the concept of ‘condominium’ where two countries control
sovereignty over a given area, but this has only been used with small coun-
tries and would no doubt be anathema to big countries like India, China,
and the USA which have far too many competing interests.
This system is not perfect however, and while the EU does enforce
fossil fuel emissions within its borders, the lack of uniform ETS around
the world doesn’t (namely US market enforcement via a strong regulat-
ing actor such as the SEC or US Treasury if any US dollars are involved
in credit transfers), and subsequently voluntary adherence can be gamed,
ignored by non-subscribing countries, and promote wrong incentives.
The code word for world enforcement is thus a legally binding ETS or
what the UN calls a certified emissions reduction unit.16
Carbon credits can be ‘gamed’ by cheating on projects to reduce emis-
sions. For example, when the carbon credit market first began in the EU
in 2005, too many surplus credits issued by the EU to their member states
diluted the credits value. It meant that initial surplus credits (allowances)
were sold too cheaply to heavy polluters which allowed them to have
windfall profits. These surplus credits are still floating around in the sys-
tem, as there is no way to ‘reign them in’ when economies need to make
adjustments such as for slowing economic activity.17
Non-subscribing countries such as India or China can continue to
wantonly pollute, without adhering to any enforced ETS system and thus
negating the entire ETS schematic if the rest of the world does not follow.
Promoting the wrong incentives, such as in China, mean that way-
ward economic planning rewarded developing countries with low emis-
sions carbon credits for not doing anything. What happened was that
certain industrial firms in China were rewarded to produce excess green-
house gas emissions in order to destroy them at the end of the process or
a ‘low-hanging fruit’ strategy as it was known to be called. In return, they
received valuable carbon offsets (or carbon credits) from the UN. The
cost of destroying the greenhouse gas was $0.20 per ton, yet the value of
the credits received by the UN on the open market was $8.80 per ton,
giving the firms a gross profit of $8.60 per ton to perversely manufac-
ture pollution and then destroy it. This behavior sparked outrage among
climate change advocates and brought the entire ETS/ CDM into ques-
tion in its current form.18 It was clearly a matter of misplaced economic
intentions and failure of UN bureaucrats to understand the system was
being gamed.
Pricing of carbon credits is another matter. Spot carbon credit prices
fluctuate widely from around $13 a ton in California to $6 a ton in China
to $9 a ton in South Korea. There is an entire school that believes carbon
trading mechanisms will work much better if a commodity carbon price
can be had and adhered to. Since different countries are playing by differ-
ent rules, unlike a commodity price for oil, which is priced in US dollars
110 W. HICKEY
Fig. 4.2 Climate change policies since 2005 (Source: Used with permission by
HSBC)
and agreed to worldwide, on a globally agreed level, this seems a long way
off for carbon abatement. See Figure 4.2.
A better method of determining the upfront value of carbon emissions
is perhaps direct taxation. This can be better enforced within the frame-
work of the sovereign and its unique economic circumstances and does
not need international cooperation or government guarantees into the
future to develop a ‘market’. In this case, the carbon price is well defined.
The USA
Much of the world then sits and waits for the USA to come onboard and
‘do something’ about climate change. Yet, despite all the impetus for glo-
balization, the USA clings tightly to its tradition of isolationism (use of the
English system, for example, in a world where most have long since con-
verted to the metric system; the world’s most popular game is soccer, but
the USA rarely engages it professionally). What the world is really seeking
when they speak of the USA ‘doing something’ about climate change is
USA’s legal muscle and political ‘enforcement’ of patchwork rules and
fines in a multipolar world that countries and regions, like the EU, cannot
enforce by themselves. If not raw physical enforcement, such as confisca-
tions and jail time, then financial enforcement via revoked licenses, per-
mits, and access to banking systems but most importantly, access to US
dollars. The USA can control much of the rest of the world via the finan-
cial mechanism as so many countries use the US dollar as the lifeblood
of their economies (as stated in Chapter 3) and this requires congruent
access to the US banking system. An infringement of US rules and laws
THE CLIMATE CHANGE CONUNDRUM 111
can bring about penalties or outright banishment from the world’s finan-
cial system, as happened with Argentina, Iran and Russia, which has had
the consequence of bringing those countries’ economies to their knees
and continues to do so.
This type of coerced, US led ‘global enforcement’ of the rules for emis-
sions levels, carbon taxes, carbon pricing, and CDMs will give businesses,
investors, and legal systems the certainty they desire going forward. Smaller
countries like Australia, Japan, and Holland, and economic regions, such
as the EU or ASEAN, cannot alone bring the sheer economic power of the
USA to the table by themselves.
However, this big stick approach may not work in a world of media and
internet penetration as well (or as poorly) as it once did in the early twen-
tieth century. Additionally, there is nationalistic pushback from countries
such as China, India, and Russia who consider themselves equal ‘world
powers’ and don’t want to utilize a foreign financial system or be pushed
around by a neo-colonial or post-Soviet oppressor. The USA and China
are the two biggest emitters of CO2 today. Expecting the world’s largest
economy, alongside the second one, where both are heavily dependent
on the fossil fuel model (e.g. car culture, coal-fired power plants, con-
sumptionomics) to do something first, especially with the US ultrapower-
ful oil and utility lobbies (and ‘Chindia’s’ coal-fired economies), may be
misguided and essentially a dead end. Observers can all see through this
and the hypocrisy involved: An Environmental Protection Agency and an
Executive Branch promising to address climate change but highly com-
promised with a fossil fuel industry lobbyists that promote jobs, competi-
tiveness, and considerable economic growth. A Beijing or Delhi covered
in smog from burning coal, but economically tethered to this same inferno
in order to sustain the economic growth underpinning the social stability
their governments crave.
We offer no ‘better way’ forward at this time except that education and
consequently, empowerment, undergirds much of the necessary change to
confront climate change. Improvement in the world’s current systems and
that change will be necessary to get to renewable, non-fossil fuel, clean
alternatives. As stated in Chapter 2, renewable alternative energy such as
wind, solar, geothermal, and hydropower are all great ideas for a progres-
sive society that is willing and able to invest in its future, but these cannot
overcome the ‘bang for the buck’ and economy of scale that oil, gas, and
coal can provide to turbocharge economies. It’s as simple as that.
Those who say they have an answer with new clean technology, renew-
able energy, or a new system probably don’t. If they actually do, they are
112 W. HICKEY
most of the time stopped in their tracks by costs. This is also especially
true of nuclear, which generates practically no carbon emissions, but sunk
costs, land acquisitions, and spent fuel storage, all require significant state
financial backing, mostly to insure and indemnify against risks of melt-
down, plant closure, and disposal sites. Even if a private investor were to
undertake these costs, they would also be opening themselves up for vast
legal liability if anything would go wrong.
To get to ‘win’ on climate change will require nations bridging various
perspectives, in addition to overcoming the Westphalian bias of implied,
and perhaps illusory, domestic independence. Yet, US domestic demands
(such as fully enfranchised democracy building or allowing currencies to
float) pushed in other regions and countries must not be so great that they
alienate tradition, culture, and mindsets (such as the Chinese historically
wedded to the dynastic system or the Indian Hindu system of fiefdoms
and tribute); conversely, other countries must not be so restrictive in their
claim to sovereignty that they close off channels to constructively working
with neighbor countries to mitigate an effective response to these chal-
lenges before they become crises.
Thus the real conundrum with a response to global warming is getting
all players civil societies and their elites, especially heavy polluters, namely
the USA, China, and India, onboard to collectively tackle this issue head-
on as an existential threat of today, not an abstract problem of tomorrow.
This is all a very tall order, perhaps overtly idealistic (especially in coun-
tries like China that are bereft of democratic processes and outlaw mass
organization movements) and one the world does not have the luxury of
delaying much longer.
Today’s structure of international law and political power based on
outdated Westphalian principles also raises enormous obstacles in obtain-
ing unanimous or near-unanimous consent within sovereign countries to
partake of collective international action in dealing with the public goods
problem of global warming. Failures to obtain a consensus are many, while
the successes are few. Integrating transparent solutions into the framework
of domestic institutions is the real challenge in any collective undertaking
to come to grips with climate change.19 Being continuously trapped in a
non-cooperative situation with developing countries free riding on devel-
oped country, ‘solutions’ may prove fruitless in the long term and too late
to stem the tide of climate change damaging the planet.
However, in closing, it must be pointed out that empowerment
through education and getting civil society involved is crucial and can go
THE CLIMATE CHANGE CONUNDRUM 113
a long way toward seeding new ideas and systems that may not be appar-
ent today but will make change tomorrow. This is not to say these things
will magically happen under current educational systems. They probably
won’t. The elites and the wealth they have invested in fossil fuels have a
stranglehold on our fossil-fueled economy. It will require further educa-
tional investment, investiture of civil society, and hands-on application to
precipitate change.
Notes
1. The year 1850 is generally acknowledged by scientists as the beginning of
the industrial era, or baseline for anthropic global warming, AGW, which
burned fossil fuels en masse for economic growth activities.
2. https://finance.yahoo.com/news/official-ny-probes-exxon-peabody-
213139102.html?bcmt=comments-postbox
3. Plutzer, E., et al, Climate confusion among U.S. teachers, Science, Vol.
351: 6274 February 12, 2016, pp. 664–665.
4. Mann, M. (2013) The Hockey Stick and the Climate Wars: Dispatches from
the Front Lines. Columbia University Press, New York.
5. Naomi Klein’s 2014 book This Changes Everything by Allen Lane, effec-
tively tells one all they need to know about what the world is up against
regarding inaction on climate change from a socio-economic paradigm.
114 W. HICKEY
Only the enormity and economies of scale of energy resources can pro-
mulgate the revenues necessary to raise living standards for vast num-
bers of low- and semi-skilled people in the developing world. While this
problem is acknowledged, the mechanisms of how to do this efficiently
and effectively, despite numerous efforts by governments, aid programs,
NGOs, civil society, and companies are still not sufficient and sorely lack-
ing. A large amount of foreign labor and expertise is required to develop
in-country resource production, yet locals stay largely unengaged in these
businesses, with wide unemployment percentiles reflected in their societ-
ies. Localization has a host country’s citizens developed, engaged, and
meaningfully employed in the core economic drivers of their economy on
a competitive level. HRD incorporates four disciplines in its foundations:
management (including HR and Project Management), education (with
curriculum design), economics (competitiveness), and communication
(with cultural awareness). Programs, research, and policies (governmen-
tal, corporate, and NGO) that enable and foster a holistic HRD mindset
(as opposed to an engineering mindset) by way of specific human resource
performance metrics and mechanisms are paramount to help the local
population develop skills, knowledge, content, and services for extractive
resources.
It is not only about skills; it is about engagement and the level of engage-
ment via opportunities available to use the skills gained. This is human
Fig. 5.1 The apex of human capital development is ideas, not finance or techno-
logical black boxes (Source: Hickey 2012)
HUMAN RESOURCE DEVELOPMENT: THE MEANS ARE THERE 117
• Recruitment
• Succession Planning
• Business Planning
• Compensation
• Training and Development
• Change and OD
120 W. HICKEY
Table 5.1 Various instructional systems design methods for designing curricula/
instruction (Hickey)
Design method Key Utility Effectiveness Cost
DACUM (Developing a Can train a large local Medium results Moderate (in
curriculum) audience many things in a house)
process based on their
feedback and various inputs
Benchmarking Uses best practices of Medium results Moderate
various operations methods (travel)
around the world to get to
optimal results
Delphi Interviews with High results Expensive
managers and supervisors to (available
understand ability, managers)
competency, and critical
incidents in certain key
positions for higher
performance.
Off the shelf Buying pre-designed Poor Cheap (in a
training available on the book/CD)
market, criterion but not
culturally referenced
Focus groups Similar to DACUM, but not Moderate (if Moderate
fully criterion based, specific topic) (availability)
depends on brainstorming
or storyboarding
the system. They know the ‘ins and outs’ to get things done timely, with
the least resistance, and without stepping on toes. These are the types of
employees who are truly ‘hi-performance’. In short, the Delphi method is
the best way to design training quickly for results performance for specific
tasks, short of a full job competency. It is also the most risky in political
terms. There will always be bosses in their position due to political inter-
ference or nepotism seeking to protect their incompetence under threat of
retribution. The Delphi method cuts through the opaqueness of politics
and deals with the exact tasks at hand to get to key results.
Other methods are politically acceptable but not as effective for human
performance. DACUM, Focus Groups, SWOT analysis, and benchmark-
ing will all yield moderate results. The methodology is criterion output
related, but due to political or proprietary concerns, participants may not
fully divulge core aspects of the job in the first two. SWOT analysis is an
124 W. HICKEY
(Source: Hickey)
Once the training has been delivered, it needs to (or should) be evalu-
ated. Many energy companies in their government-approved contracts or
CSR obligations are only required to provide training. The relevance, qual-
ity, consistency, and formative/summary evaluation of that training can
become a secondary concern that shortchanges the participants. Especially,
if as noted, if there are various economic disincentives (reimbursements,
proprietary controls, and costs) or management issues in contention.30
Donald Kirkpatrick used four levels of evaluation to determine if the
training was effective or not, with each level getting consistently more
difficult to evaluate. In the past few years, especially in regard to placate
shareholders or host governments, a fifth level or ‘training return on
investment’ or ROI has been added by HRD practitioners such as Jack
Phillips (see Table 5.3).31
As most of these countries rich in resources are developing and cultur-
ally ‘high context’ societies, going along to get along becomes the norm.
Facilitators who can be the most personable and agreeable are the ones
defining training success.32 Political reasons also keep this process in place
to get the work trainers must be connected, accountable, and agreeable to
various corporate actors. Outsiders without relationships, unless installed
for specific industrial reasons, generally are not welcome. Maintaining
overall harmony is what matters.33
This is a key point of the constancy of oil and mining companies: alike
insiders, or what Edgar Schein at MIT defined as the ‘engineering mindset’
HUMAN RESOURCE DEVELOPMENT: THE MEANS ARE THERE 127
Table 5.3 Kirkpatrick’s four levels of training evaluation with ROI at fifth level
with interpretation
Evaluation level Method to assess or measure Individual/organizational
evaluation impact
1.Satisfaction A smiley face. Did the Very high for the participant
Easy to measure respondent like the way the Negligible for the organization
facilitation was administered?
2. Learning A test or administered High for the participant
Assessment required evaluation. Assessing if the Moderate for the organization
participant absorbed methods
and actions from the training
3. Job Was the learning transferred Moderate for the participant
Moderate ease of back to the participants’ job Some organizational importance
use timely or on a timeline?
4. Organization Did the job skills acquired create Some for the participant
Difficult to measure noticed change in the Crucial for the organization
department or organization?
5. ROI The incorporated changes Negligible for participant
Very difficult to produce greater revenues (capacity)
‘precisely’ measure streams and thus higher profits Very critical for the organization
(Source: Hickey)
but the exact outcomes are never attained, nor is the empowerment that
should be afforded to the participants for obtaining these skills.
An extension then of training that is inside the company but paid for by
the public then becomes an issue of who’s domain is it. A situational tug-of-
war still exists in many engineering mindset39 companies that training should
not be centralized, but at the departmental level where competent engineers
and technicians in their relevant fields exist. Turf battles have ensued, with
the ultimate outcome being the centralized HRD function only existing
for safety and generally English language/basic computer skills training.
Without transparency and a centralized HRD manager overseeing the train-
ing, costs in departments can become inflated and training redundant (other
departments administering the same thing) without any higher supervision.
This also allows organizational silos to form, where one department does
not speak with or has a rivalry with another department. The neutered HRD
department in oil and mining companies then exists as a mere employment
‘holding function’ for engineers nearing retirement, accountants who make
too many spreadsheet errors, and permanent employees in state-owned
companies who are subpar and can’t be fired. HRD gets a bad name for
irrelevance and other department leaders control parallel T&D departments.
Fig. 5.4 ‘KSA’ (Knowledge, Skills, Attitude) competency conceptual with tech-
nical terms (Hickey)
impact of that job on the rest of the company. A few examples should suf-
fice to explain the extremely high value of competency development for the
investors in very specific proprietary activity in oil and mining.
Some large oil companies have developed a full competency profile and
assessment for some core positions in regard to political advertisement
of local citizen advancement to the host government but also to poach
the best and brightest talent from these countries for their own corporate
talent bank portfolios. This is usually not apparent to many but the top
corporate executives.
In upstream oil, for example, two core positions emerge that can be
transferred to oil operations anywhere around the world. Reservoir man-
ager and the LBE (Lead Board Engineer) both of which are also very
proprietary positions. The skills gained in both are cutting edge and carry
a high tangible value for the organization.
RMG or the reservoir management group, is considered the ‘brain
trust’ of upstream oil operations. RMG is critical in assessing the well
size, pressure, and quality of the oil in situ or in the ground. It is one
of the most sensitive and proprietary of all an oil company’s domains, a
brain trust if one wills. Training in RMG is costly and usually high tech.
Most postings from a company’s headquarters in Houston, London, or
Milan are with training consisting of very specific computer, statistical,
and modeling skills that are held tightly as proprietary. Conservatively, this
132 W. HICKEY
Conceptually and theoretically then, and within its most linear human
capital application, that being with defined competencies and assessed train-
ing needs, there is no impediment to developing any workforce in today’s
information-intensive world to a benchmarked standard of any other work-
force in dealing people of a similar baseline intelligence to build the skills on.
HRD Effectiveness
Practically speaking though, many management and political issues can
muddy the water with the learning and development processes. Consider
some issues that were observed by the writer in mostly Asian and former
Soviet developing countries, that impinged on training and educational pro-
grams that were being utilized or about to be utilized. The following are
some actual quotations stated to the researcher anonymously since 1997,
when working as an HRD consultant in several developing countries in Asia.
and
• If they train me to do it, then I’ll have to do it, and I won’t be paid
anymore for doing it!
• Political. This training is put forward by the top managers as they
promised their friends (a vendor licensed to give McCovey’s 7 Habits)
some business. (Indonesia)
• Environmental. People don’t want to attend company training after
work as they just want to spend time with their families (and the
company won’t authorize training during normal production work
hours) (Kazakhstan),
and
The points above are to demonstrate that while training and develop-
ment are core to HRD in a mechanistic sense, and that most agree they are
very necessary, ‘training’ can be hindered or mitigated for all types of rea-
sons unless a few things are put into play. Many of the reasons are also par
utility from Hertzberg’s ‘hygiene factors’, or incentives of punishment, or
threat to induce particular behaviors42:
These are just some concerns. Not all are listed. But in driving to
an effective localization effort and integration, the dross and impurities
need to be cleared off the table for effective HRD to really seed. Once it
becomes objective, is led from the top, meets the right physical conditions
for learning, and is reflected in rewards for the learning, then training can
move forward with certainty.
Unfortunately, all the above quotes were in developing countries,
mostly China, these are the countries and places most sorely in need of
human development. Non-learning encumbrances become du jour among
participants, and thus weaken the training initiatives. It is also noted that
these are all ‘micro-economic’ effectiveness issues affecting a training
effort. We will see in the localization chapter how ‘meso-economic’ issues
can affect the training on an organizational and indeed, ‘macro-economic’
national level.
HUMAN RESOURCE DEVELOPMENT: THE MEANS ARE THERE 135
Notes
1. Becker, G. (1993). Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with
special reference to education (2nd ed.). New York: Columbia University Press.
2. Coleman, J.S. (1990) Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA:
Belknap.
136 W. HICKEY
23. Hickey, W. (2001). A survey of current and future training needs in Tianjin
(T.E.D.A.) China, Spring 2000. Performance Improvement Quarterly
14(2), 60–69.
24. Gray, K. and Herr, E. (1998), ibid., pp. 175.
25. Crozier, M. has written considerably on never underestimating people or
even societies to game entire systems.
26. How does directional drilling work? In Rigzone, training section, see
http://www.rigzone.com/training/insight.asp?insight_id=295&c_id=1
27. Chevron advertisement on Bloomberg, 2015.
28. Covey, S. (1989) The 7 Habits of Highly Effective People, Free Press. ISBN
0-7432-6951-9.
29. Rothwell, W. and Kazanas, H.C. (1994), ibid.
30. Mager, R. and Pipe, P., ibid.
31. Phillips, J. J. (1997) Handbook of Training Evaluation and Measurement
Methods (Improving Human Performance) 3rd Ed. Routledge, Taylor, and
Frances: London. ISBN: 978-0884153870.
32. Hickey, W. (2001) ibid.
33. Hampden-Turner, C., and Trompenaars, F. (2000). Building cross-cultural
competence. New Haven: Yale University Press.
34. See Preece, J. ‘Lifelong learning and development: a perspective from the
“South”’ Compare: A Journal of Comparative and International Education
39.5 (2009) and see 23 Oct. 2009 and also William Easterly’s work in
‘White Man’s Burden’.
35. Kenneth Blanchard and Philip Kotler are considered as gurus in their fields
of Organization, Behavior and Marketing, respectively, and command high
speaking fees as motivational speakers.
36. Dr. Laurie Bassi claims that Motorola training also yielded high returns on
training investments for many things, see http://www.agilevelocity.com/
blog/training-return-investment/
37. Wm. Rothwell presentation on Beyond Training and Development, Jakarta,
Shangri La Hotel, May 2009.
38. EITI or Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative has identified avenues
for corruption, see www.eiti.org
39. Schein, E. (1999) Process Consultation, 2nd Ed. Prentice- Hall. ISBN-10:
0201067366.
40. Intangible rewards are non-monetary based, but give one a feeling of
accomplishment or ‘pride in work’, see Daft, R. (2016) Management, 12th
Ed., Cengage Learning. See chapter on compensation. ISBN-10:
1285861981.
41. Interviews with Chevron and Exxon Mobil operation managers in
Kazakhstan and Indonesia, April–May 2006.
42. Hackman, J. R. and Oldham, G. R. (August 1976). Motivation Through
the Design of Work: Test of a Theory. Organizational Behavior and
Human Performance 16 (2): 250–279.
138 W. HICKEY
43. Deming, W.E. (1986). Out of the crisis. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
44. Lawler, E. III (1971). Pay and organizational effectiveness: A psychological
view. New York: McGraw-Hill.
45. Senge, P. (2006) The 5th Discipline: The Art of the Learning Organization,
2nd Ed., New York: Doubleday, and Senge, P. (2002). Human capital in
21st century organizations. In: Management: Inventing and delivering its
future. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
46. McLagan, P. (1989). Models for HRD practice. Alexandria, VA: ASTD
Press.
47. Rossett, A. (1998). A handbook for performance analysis. New York:
Pfieffer & Co.
CHAPTER 6
Energy Ownership
Introduction
Ownership in resources creates empowerment in them. This empowerment
devolves via control in citizen’s resources underneath their feet as opposed
to detached ownership by faraway central governments and foreign inves-
tors who have limited stake in local outcomes. They must take control
of their resources to make the decisions that will affect them directly. It
is important to note that we are speaking mostly of non-renewable fos-
sil fuels, coal, oil, and gas, not transient forms of energy such as a steam,
wind, fission, or sunlight that are more ambiguous in ownership structures
and constitute little of natural resource endowment. Will countries con-
tinuously burn their natural resources wantonly for fast economic gains to
engage more actively in the ‘consumption model’ of economic activity,1 or
will they take a go slow approach, realizing that the more they use impairs
their future generations both financially and environmentally?
With ownership comes responsibility. This requires some soul searching
that won’t be found on Madison Avenue, K Street, or Canary Wharf, as
it is not in their financial interest to promote citizens’ rights. Citizens and
grassroots society initiatives will require burden-sharing2 and responsible
development of fossil fuels in situ no matter how unpalatable this is to the
elites, financial services, and fossil fuel industry. In this aspect, much of the
problem of aggregated fossil fuel usage and the by-product of emission
are rooted in so-called ‘sovereignty’ of nations. A medieval construct of
of this work, but in short, key points emerge that clearly indicate these
laws formulated centuries ago are not in keeping with modern times in
the information society we live in today, complete with rising living stan-
dards, shrinking resources, and burgeoning populations all demanding
wealth redistribution. In both cases, the Magna Carta or ‘Great Charter’
and then later the Westphalian Peace formulated in what is now modern
Germany were not really about helping the denizens of specific locales, but
rather about protecting the rights of those with power and their wealth
in specific local. In the case of the Magna Carta, it was barons (the ‘elites’
in today’s parlance) who were questioning the ‘Divine Right of Kings’ to
rule over them unquestioningly4 (in this case, demands for higher taxes
to finance wars and land confiscation for those who disagreed, namely the
payers of the wars). The barons would have certain rights, and those rights
would be enforced by neutral courts, not monarchies.5
borders and was mutually reinforcing to uphold this order by all adherents
was created. Today, the concept of Westphalian nation-states system is
being openly challenged by some, however, not for promotion of ‘climate
change’ issues or assisting warn-torn countries with their refugee popula-
tions, but rather for raison d’être military interventions (ISIS), trade trea-
ties (TPP), and territorial claims (South China Sea). The elites are still in
charge. Most people have accepted the context of today’s Westphalian
system as a core given or undeniable proof. For example, every economic,
historical, and political text has framed the nation-state as the least com-
mon denominator of the last 350 years. That has not always been the
case; however, some even question if the sovereign state framework in
this Information Age era is relevant.9
Westphalia is an old concept that has gained traction mostly by enforce-
ment for elite reasons denuded from the Magna Carta in 1215 and is
very incapable of addressing the problem of a global public goods prob-
lems (climate change, refugee populations, etc.) that no one wants to take
responsibility for. Essentially then, under the Westphalian system, there
is no economic or political mechanism for resolving world encompass-
ing technological and economic realities. What happens when these issues
impinge on others’ rights outside the ‘neat and clean borders’ of a nation-
state? This must change in the Information Age of our twenty-first century.
Peaceful relations, under North’s theory of natural state, serves to ben-
efit the elite actors of a society the most, as they then can enjoy and pro-
tect their status. The main problem with the Westphalian system today, as
with most laws written before the emerging Industrial Age, is that they
laid a foundation for colonial extractive practices of resources that specifi-
cally benefited elite interests.10 This became a logical successor to, the raw
mercantilism of the Spanish conquistadors and later the Dutch and British
East Asia companies, in that it created the concept of the state as an inde-
pendent entity, above and beyond criticism of its own domestic or internal
affairs. Whereby the internal structure shields and maintains introspection
of system as a whole, in other words, the system of nation-state exclusivity
in domestic decision-making becomes self-reinforcing.
The advent of the European Union in 1993 and the Maastricht Treaty11
whereby European countries are willing to cede some sovereignty for a
better regional cohesion is an initial attempt to break away from age-old
Westphalian dogma, yet itself is loaded with contradictions and weak spots
that the latest wave of Middle Eastern refugees has brought to a head.
Enduring unity while pushing back against diversity in old-line nation-states
ENERGY OWNERSHIP 143
Globalization and Sovereignty
We must then consider a twenty-first-century perspective of sovereignty
that is not strictly grounded in a seventeenth-century Westphalian under-
standing of ‘nation-states’ free from any foreign influence or directive and
thus totally autonomous, but rather ‘sovereignty’ in a context of today’s
‘Globalization’ issues. In short, globalization impinges severely on many
international themes and issues that cut across borders: climate change,
currency wars, beggar-thy-neighbor protectionist policies, product dump-
ing, human migration issues, and labor issues. Globalization thus affects
all facets of modern man, some in direct apposition to Westphalia.
In the long run, the context of globalization is multi-planar. It is not
merely a linear economic construct of one country impinging on (such
as China dumping cheap steel on Japan) another, upgrading another
144 W. HICKEY
On the other end of this spectrum, Singapore due to its ‘structural’ strate-
gic location and hub for oil investing in Malaysia and Indonesia is home to
the third largest refinery operations in the world. We take this issue further
with HRD and energy with a case study of Sri Lanka refinery potential in
Chapter 10.
Objectivist–Subjectivist (objective knowledge or a created construct).
We could consider this as in gold mines of SA/Namibia as objective
knowledge of resources in situ and an entire community that was found
on development of this industry. Other objectivist areas to consider would
be the Middle East for oil or Central America for banana plantations.
A subjectivist construct would be Silicon Valley in California, USA, as a
technology hub ‘place to be’, another area would be the telecom cluster
in Finland that is now in decline.
The point is that all three paradigms, in the age of globalization, encom-
pass sovereign issues, and not only contribute to academic theories but
also can strongly influence all political decisions and thus policy creation
or realpolitik, which in turn influences and drives outcomes for better or
worse. These paradigms are not discrete at either anchor, there is no doubt
some in between areas, such as in the bipolar case of Singapore, where an
iconoclast leader drove one point concerning a world-class financial hub,
but also infrastructure and location was conducive for significant global oil
and gas refinery operation.
It is important to consider this construct in today’s Information Age
which supposedly supplants the nation-state as the bedrock of social orga-
nization and creator/protector of nationalization. Preparing the seedbed
or mindset then for socialization requires a deeper understanding for real
transformation to occur, again, far past limited Westphalian constructs of
sovereignty, and colonial (or neo-colonial) mindsets which tend to rein-
force a North–South thinking and thus neglect (at the least stagnation, at
the worst, incipient corruption) in most developing countries. Consider
the social issues created on these five interrelated aspects about a polarity
of old paradigms in today’s global setting versus change for new processes,
and the decision-making challenges of each for policy makers. These
groupings are discrete and not necessarily interrelated or even correlated.
Geography–Island Nations, such as Indonesia versus Block/Landlocked
Countries, such as Congo?
Production–Reshaping (outsourcing) or centrality of manufacturing
(physical cluster, like Canton).
146 W. HICKEY
Competitive Theory
Without modern energy services and production, a country’s economic
competitiveness is doomed. Harvard University professor Michael Porter13
has argued that countries must use whatever competitive advantages lie at
their hands to get ahead. Especially in an age where renewable energy
remains costly/uncompetitive and seven-eighth of the world’s energy
source is still carbon based.
In lieu of HRD initiatives, consumer fuel subsidies, while long an
imperfect transfer mechanism, have become de facto most citizen’s only
tangible constitutional right then to the resources that lay beneath their
feet, relegated in positive law (legislated) and via implementation in pari
passu (meaning altogether, lockstep) distribution. There are two types of
fuel subsidies that need reflection.
Consumer subsidies are legally and structurally different than fossil fuel
producer subsidies. Consumer subsidies are the government subsidizing
retail energy purchased of oil, coal, and electricity. They are a haphazard
extension by legacy into a country’s citizens partaking of their own resources.
Producer subsidies are not devolved from constitutional law but are
instead a political contrivance using government largess, contractual
promises, and tax breaks to promote industry for a nation’s economic
ENERGY OWNERSHIP 147
Worldwide, consumer subsidies for fossil fuels stand at over $400 bil-
lion.18 However, this does not take into account what undefined fuel
producer subsidies do, which, hidden politically, arguably account for con-
siderably more economic activity. Consider the 2 × 2 of what direct and
indirect produce subsidies constitute in Table 6.2.
Removing the consumer subsidy alone will not immediately promote
a ‘societal comeuppance’ to payment of ‘market prices’ without further
addressing producer subsidies also.19 It will only serve to make the most
marginalized more miserable and hopeless, those without access to educa-
tion and capital. The fact that people are willing to protest, riot, and risk
life and limb in street battles with the police when their subsidies are taken
away, on the recommendation of anonymous, supra-national ‘actors’ who
Table 6.1 Discrete social issues groupings of today’s issues facing sovereign
identity
Social issues groupings A B
have no idea of the totality of the implications involved, shows this despera-
tion in action.20 Disenfranchisement of a right based on the consequence of
taking away a subsistence measure is what is the actual issue here and now,
and not an abstraction. This is the real ‘market economy’ in action: people’s
day-to-day economic survival and subsistence is immediately threatened.
The citizens of these countries are thus much more sensitively attuned
and certain of this immediate removal outcome than the experts in the
IMF, WB, UN, and IEA. These institutes suggest that governments (usu-
ally ones bereft with incipient corruption and cronyism) should abolish
the consumer subsidy and no doubt leave their citizens even further in an
economic abyss. In this case, the ‘market’ does clearly anticipate the out-
come reality: ‘cut the subsidy, and costs will rise’. Consider this comment,
for example, about need for Nigeria’s fuel subsidy in absence of other
remedies by Nigerian journalist Aneibo Nwamu.21
Producer subsidies22 on the other hand are the unseen, the underwater
part of the iceberg, and arguably, the larger and more perfidious of the
two as their effects are more macro-economic, with large financial effects
on future generations that perpetuate the indemnity to foreign financial
interests many developing countries face. Producer subsidies come in two
forms: direct and indirect.
Direct producer subsidies, for example, are overt financial support by
a government for the coal industry to create jobs; tax exemptions and
payback concessions for the oil industry; government grants for develop-
ment of LNG processing plants; tacit military support for oil- and gas-
producing nations, domestic and foreign.
Indirect producer subsidies foster fossil fuel dependence: larger air-
ports, five lane toll roads, taller bridges, port expansions. In other words,
infrastructure that enables and addicts societies further to the product.
Producer subsidies in total also ensure world political dependence on fos-
sil fuels. Koplow et al.23 point out that developed countries heavily utilize
producer subsidies, with the amounts largely unknown as systematically
endemic.
150 W. HICKEY
Table 6.3 Constitutional Articles of five countries and US State of Alaska regard-
ing natural resources ownership (Source: Adapted from CIA Worldfacts, Hickey)
reflective of the domestic standing of the legal paradigm48 and thus mis-
guided in principal. The position then taken is vested in the mandate that
the government’s goal is to serve the majority. No matter how much waste-
ful, inefficient, or polluting that fuel subsidies violate natural laws (more
subsidies naturally mean more pollution), they are still the only ensured
artifice under positive law within the sovereign’s constitution. Furthermore,
normative law theory lends support to positive law because of its rational
nature, extended to individual micro-economic activity. In essence then,
positive law for the fuel subsidies trumps natural law as espoused by the
economists. They simply have no legal standing. Of course, a weak regula-
tory framework and compromised institutions can lend distortion to the
concept of ownership in many developing countries.49 That fact is obviously
pointed out in studies about foreign investment contributing to endemic
corruption, rent-seeking activity, and looting of a country’s resources.50
In fact, psychologically also, many feel entitled to this right of ownership
in their own resources, as per this quote in Venezuela in February, 2014.
Further then is the issue of global warming and climate change. There is
currently an economic disconnect between a subsistence threat to peoples’
immediate survival, which is in the moment, and climate change, which
while also a threat is more ethereal and abstract to many and can appear
an elitist concept. If citizens have an actual ownership quotient in their
resources or anything of value, they will be more inclined to husband and
conserve that resource. This also lends to the formation of trust and stew-
ardship of resources.52 So much has been written about environmental and
agricultural stewardship that this reasoning could naturally flow to the fuel
subsidy. While the entity of the sovereign state is powerful and accepted as
the common denominator in all economic arguments, we are in an infor-
mation age. When people can readily see where money is appropriated,
trust is built, leading to stronger social capital formation.53
It may well be argued that even if consumer fuel subsidies do ‘ben-
efit the rich more than the poor’,54 they can still contribute holistically
to economic activity. This creates jobs and labor mobility where there
may be none if fuel was much more expensive and demand suppressed.
A 2014 article in The Economist55 about fuel subsidies tends to demonize
the rich as benefitting unfairly and recommends cash transfer programs,
ENERGY OWNERSHIP 155
which have been problematic with corruption in the past, as a better trade-
off. For economists to gain legitimacy on this issue, suggesting a value-
added proposition on the transfer mechanism from current ambiguous
ownership to one in defined specificity is crucial.
One other criticism of the Norway or State of Alaska revenue-sharing
model is that both places are tiny, homogenous populations that do not
have the ethnic, tribal, and cultural divides that mega-populated develop-
ing countries such as India, Nigeria, and Indonesia do. Another criticism is
that consumer fuel subsidies waste valuable state funds that could be used
in other areas. However, neither argument should preclude a citizen’s
constitutional rights or indirect dismantling of them by foreign actors, no
matter how ‘well intentioned’ the guise under a truly Westphalian system.
Fungibility of Money
The Future
At the time of this writing in early 2016, consumer fuel subsidies are being
phased out in many countries such as Nigeria, Venezuela, and Indonesia,
specifically due to pressure from foreign actors. Nonetheless, producer sub-
sidies, a systematic issue, are still intact. As the price of oil and commodities
has cratered in early 2016, the impact on national coffers has been negligible,
creating in essence a zero-sum game.59 Nonetheless, phasing out consumer
fuel subsidies does nothing to negate the constitutional ascription citizens
have in their resources. It only makes it more obligatory for a transparent shift
that the wealth from mobility to development becomes more transparent.
156 W. HICKEY
Summary
Industrialization has brought considerable and tectonic change to the world
and those resource-rich developing countries in particular. The construct of
the 17th century Peace of Westphalia, which was preceded by the medieval
era Magna Carta, was first about protecting elite interests and then later about
protecting their interests inside very discrete borders, devoid of religious inter-
ference or imperial overtones. That world no long exists. We are now in an
interconnected age which effects everyone across all borders, all the time.
Today, people clamor for higher standards of living worldwide. In many
developing countries with weak institutions, consumer fuel subsidies are the
only quotient that is the ‘tangible proof’ of ensured constitutional owner-
ship rights that citizens have in their country. However unpalatable this
ENERGY OWNERSHIP 157
Table 6.4 Using the GTZ (Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit, 2009)
and IEA (2011) studies on economic aspects developing nations with fuel subsi-
dies, Canada as control
Country Primary resources Consumer Fuel taxes as GDP per GINI
location (o) = fuel compared to US capita in coefficient
Offshore. (n) = subsidy petrol/diesel tax 2011 USD (WB )
Onshore rate (IEA (GTZ, 2009) (IMF 2013) Where 0 =
2011) perfect
equality
Source: Compilation of GTZ (2009),63 IMF and IEA (2011) statistics regarding GDP and
fuel subsidies (Hickey)
APPENDIX
Notes
1. Nair, C. (2009) Consumptionomics: Asia’s Role in Reshaping Capitalism
and Saving the Planet. Oxford: John Wiley & Sons.
2. Moeller, J. (2010) How Asia Can Shape the World, ISEAS: Singapore.
3. North, D., Wallis, J.J.; Webb, S. Weingast, B., (2007) Limited Access
Orders in the Developing World: A New Approach to the Problems of
Development. World Bank Working Paper Series (WPS4359), p. 20.
4. http://www.historylearningsite.co.uk/medieval-england/magna-carta/
5. Holt, J.C. (1992) Magna Carta p. 449.
6. Henry Kissinger (2014). ‘Introduction and Chapter 1’. World Order:
Reflections on the Character of Nations and the Course of History. Allen
Lane. ISBN 0241004268.
7. Risse, M. (2006) What to Say About the State, Social Theory and Practice,
Vol. 32, No. 4 (October) p. 671.
8. Risse, M. (2006) ibid.
9. Ibid., p. 698.
10. Easterly, W. (2006) The White Man’s Burden, London: Oxford University
Press.
11. http://www.cvce.eu/obj/characteristics_of_the_treaty_on_european_
union-en-beec7a53-4023-412d-a1ab-2c31b6a3c39d.html
12. China has recently built an airstrip capable of handling bombers in the
hotly contested Spratly islands and had warned off other countries from
approaching to near these new ‘developments’.
13. Porter, M. (1998) On Competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
14. Hickey, W. (2013). Fossil Fuel Subsidies Help Asia Roar. Yale Global
Online,March,15,http://yaleglobal.yale.edu/content/fossil-fuel-subsidies-
help-asia-roar
15. IEA, OPEC, OECD, and World Bank (2010) Analysis of the Scope of
Energy Subsidies and Suggestions for the G-20 Initiative, joint report pre-
pared for submission to the G-20 Leaders’ Summit (Toronto, June 2010).
Indeed, the study showed that removing the consumer subsidy (p.8,
would cause a minus 3.4 percentage points drop in GDP, a CPI increase
of 4.3 % and an unemployment increase of 2.3 % in the first five years). See
http://www.oecd.org/site/tadffss/49006998.pdf
16. Ellis, J. (2010) Global Subsidies Initiative, Untold Billions, Geneva: Global
Subsidies Initiative, 3.
17. Sachs, J. (2010) Common Wealth: Economics for a Crowded Planet.
Penguin, New York.
160 W. HICKEY
18. IEA (2011) World Energy Outlook: Executive Summary, Paris: International
Energy Agency.
19. Koplow, Doug, Cynthia Lin, Anna Jung, Michael Thone, Lucky Lontoh,
and Chris Charles. (2010). Mapping the Characteristics of Producer
Subsidies: A review of pilot country studies. (Geneva: Global Subsidies
Initiative), August, and Ellis, J. (2010) ibid., OECD (2011), Koplow, D.
(2009) Measuring Energy Subsidies Using the Price-Gap Approach: What
does it leave out? (Geneva: Global Subsidies Initiative of the International
Institute for S ustainable Development), August. URL http://www.oecd.
org/env/cc/oecdandiearecommendreformingfossil-fuelsubsidiestoimpro
vetheeconomyandtheenvironment.htm, Steenblik, R. and Wigley, K.
(1990). ‘Coal policies and trade barriers’. Energy Policy 18 (5) 351–367,
and Braithwaite, D., et al. (2010). Fossil Fuels – At What Cost? Government
support for upstream oil and gas activities in Indonesia. (Geneva: Global
Subsidies Initiative of the International Institute for Sustainable
Development). This has been a constant drumbeat from the OECD, IMF,
and WB economics crowd.
20. Trying to remove fuel subsidies in Nigeria, India, and Indonesia over the
past several years has resulted in rioting and transportation shutdowns. See
Hickey, W. (2012) Time to End Fuel Subsidies? Yale Global Online. URL
http://www.yaleglobal.yale.edu/content/time-end-fuel-subsidies
21. http://leadership.ng/columns/360949/much-fuel-subsidy.
22. Koplow, et al. (2010). ibid.
23. Koplow, et al. (2010), ibid.
24. All major international studies by (IEA, OPEC, OECD, World Bank,
2011) follow this thinking. In IEA, OPEC, OECD, and World Bank
(2010) Analysis of the Scope of Energy Subsidies and Suggestions for the
G-20 Initiative, joint report prepared for submission to the G-20 Leaders’
Summit (Toronto, June 2010).
25. 1993 Nobel Prize economist Douglas North has written about a nation’s
institutions promoting better economic development. See: North, D.
(1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance.
New York: Cambridge University Press.
26. Pinto, P. and Zhu, B. (2009) Fortune or Evil? The Effects of Inward
Foreign Direct Investment on Corruption, Saltzman Institute of War and
Peace Studies (SIWPS) Working Paper No. 10.
27. This is especial problematic in Nigeria. See http://www.vanguardngr.
com/2012/01/fuel-subsidy-removal-tips-for-efcc/. Additionally, North
has written on this issue of elite actors controlling societies and institutions
from the beginning of recorded history for their interests, not denizens.
28. Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1999) ‘Rents, competition and corruption’.
American Economic Review 4, 9, 982–994.
29. Taverne (1996). ibid.
ENERGY OWNERSHIP 161
opinions/2013/12/23-mexican-energy-reform-opportunities-historic-
change-negroponte
48. http://www.economist.com/news/finance-and-economics/21593484-
economic-case-scrapping-fossil-fuel-subsidies-getting-stronger-fuelling.
49. North, D. (1990), ibid.
50. Pinto and Zhu, (2009), ibid.
51. http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/10617632/Venezuelans-fume-as-
government-signals-end-to-free-petrol.html
52. Coleman, J.S. (1990) Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA:
Belknap.
53. Krishna, A. (2000) Creating and Harnessing Social Capital. Pp.71–93 in
Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, edited by P. Dasgupta and
I. Serageldin. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
54. Koplow, et al. (2010), ibid.
55. http://www.economist.com/news/finance-and-economics/21593484-
economic-case-scrapping-fossil-fuel-subsidies-getting-stronger-fuelling
56. Yet, even drastically falling oil prices in Feb. 2016 have not seen a subsidy
dividend materialize.
57. Shankar Gopalakrishnan (December 24, 2007). ‘POSCO: More a Curse
than a Blessing’. Economic Times.
58. Article 297.1 in The Constitution of India 1949 reads: 297. Things of
value within territorial waters or continental shelf and resources of the exclu-
sive economic zone to vest in the Union (1) All lands, minerals and other
things of value underlying the ocean within the territorial waters, or the con-
tinental shelf, or the exclusive economic zone, of India shall vest in the Union
and be held for the purposes of the Union.
59. Big savings on fuel costs in Indonesia, Nigeria, and India have failed to
produce any real societal benefit, though these promises were made by
incumbent politicians such as Modi and Jokowi.
60. Developing countries, according to Grubb and Depledge (2001), cur-
rently have no binding obligations.
61. Paris Climate Conference, Dec. 2015. Outcomes, see the EU’s http://
ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/international/negotiations/paris/index_
en.htm
62. From Marcus Garvey in Grant, C. (2008), Negro with a Hat: The Rise and
Fall of Marcus Garvey and His Dream of Mother Africa. New York: Oxford
University Press to Mao-Ze Dongs “Great Leap Forward” in Chang, J.
and Halliday, J. (2006) Mao: The untold story. London: A. Knopf, many
cases of industrial nationalization.
63. GTZ (Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit, 2009) International
Fuel Prices, 6th Ed. Berlin: Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation
and Development.
CHAPTER 7
Localization
What Is ‘Localization’?
Localization, simply put in its most general definition, means getting local
citizens to do the jobs that are held by many foreign expatriates in a host
country. It is also called ‘nationalization’ in some countries, and is spo-
radically applied to nations by the oil and gas industry to moniker good
feelings, such as Angolization (Angola) or Yemenization (Yemen).2 It is
localized management development in regard to high-tech industry, labor-
intensive manufacturing, and resource mining (pejoratively: oil and gas
extraction) content.
Research shows that the issues of localization are increasingly significant
in today’s world. The mechanics of localization are not well understood,
nor have any world standard to model. Countries that have not truly local-
LOCALIZATION 165
ized (such as Nigeria, Saudi Arabia, Russia, etc.) host a spectrum of social
problems and confrontational issues regarding their citizens and foreign
investment entities, at the least, pent up social instability (i.e. Venezuela);
and at worst, terrorism leading to outright civil war (i.e. Yemen, Libya).
Conversely, certain resource-rich Western countries and regions (Norway,
UK, State of Alaska) have used their considerable oil wealth for social
reform and jobs creation projects. This tends to benefit populations at
large under transparent public policies.
Countries seeking to compete for a share of the world’s high skills/
high-wage production in the information age must invest in the skills of
their people.3 This is not an optional issue. One explanation of poverty
and unemployment then is that they result from insufficient (and inef-
ficient) amounts of allocated human capital investment.4 In order to avoid
long-term impoverishment, countries need to develop their people (HR)
or human resources in areas that will ultimately give them a comparative,
if not outright competitive, advantage in today’s world economy. A macro
policy issue then is how to develop a countries management talent: either
holistically (via production, economic diversification, education, and safety
issues) or specifically (development of oil and gas professionals and techni-
cians for core knowledge content in upstream and downstream aspects).
Economically then, and, as discussed in Chapter 6, Ownership, or who
really ‘owns’ the natural resources of a country or a windfall investment?5
Elites tend to make power grabs for resources, excluding other stakehold-
ers. How accountable are the elites? Windfall revenues that accrue from
natural resources, particularly ones arising from capital-intensive industries
(i.e. oil and gas), have been associated with high levels of black and gray
market corruption, weak public institutions, and poor social policies.6 This
situation has been dubbed as ‘resource curse’.7 A partial explanation for
this is that large amounts of natural resources create leaders who are firstly
concerned about maintaining foreign investment, rather than any respon-
sibility with their constituencies.8 Consider that the converse can also be
true: countries with a paucity of natural resource endowments and high
rates of education (Japan, Ireland, Singapore, etc.), often have demon-
strated impressive rates of economic growth, and have excelled at politi-
cal transparency9 leading to democratic initiatives and more importantly,
sustained social capital.
Top management teams which are dominated by accountants and
engineers (a common HR pattern in developing country FDI projects for
energy and resources) like to prioritize cost-cutting and standardization/
166 W. HICKEY
procedures. But those priorities cannot be absolute, and are often damag-
ing to the very nature of service and service delivery that these same host
nations are trying to create. It is a major barrier to authentic development
of services management/marketing, true service culture, HR systems, and
authentic service quality.
Localization then, in a technical sense, has made host country’s citizens
developed, engaged, and meaningfully employed in the core economic
drivers of their economy at a competitive level.10 HRD incorporates four
academic disciplines in its foundations: management (including HR and
Project Management), education (with curriculum design), economics,
and communication (with cultural awareness).11
Programs, research, and policies (governmental, corporate, and NGO)
that enable and foster a holistic HRD mindset, as opposed to an engineer-
ing mindset,12 by way of specific human resource performance metrics and
mechanisms, are paramount to help the local population develop skills,
knowledge,13 and the awareness of the products and services created from
the extractive resources. It is not only about skills; it is about engagement,
and having opportunities available to utilize the skills gained. This is
human capital then on a very cognizant level.14
To foster development, action learning (via coaching, mentoring, self-
directed, internships, etc.) with ensured full-time hiring placements must
be incorporated in the educational curricula. Part of this action learning15
cost must be placed on the investing entity which is unpopular among for-
eign investors.16 This will ensure a commitment to technology and know-
how transfer, which in turn feeds empowerment. In exchange, universities
and poly-tech centers need to upgrade courses to meet market-driven skills
needs. Education is only one factor of the human development equation,
yet it is the most relevant to HRD metrics and interlinks strongly with
other areas.17
In the 1950s and 1960s, the British government was gradually closing
down the British Empire. Many former colonies in Asia and Africa were
moving toward independence and nationalist governments. With varying
degrees of success, the British administration then moved to localize their
administrations before independence.
We consider that in the early 1950s, in British ‘Malaya’, ‘Malayanization’
was notably well managed. This may be due to the fact:
–– Malaya was one of the most prosperous colonies in the British
Empire, with tremendous stocks of rubber, tin, and agricultural
products. Oil would be yet to have its heyday.
–– Many of the UK’s best-qualified colonial government officials
served in Singapore and Malaya. Additionally, the UK had learned
something from losing India in its crown portfolio.
–– There was strong pressure for transparency. Nationalization pres-
sures in a multiethnic Malaya were strong as were border issues
and redrawing them, particularly with Indonesia.
The British colonial administration then was fighting a very serious
communist guerilla insurgency in the 1950s, backed largely by Maoist
China. To ‘win hearts & minds’, an authentic political solution was
needed, to back up and justify the military solution. Therefore, through
the 1950s the British administration regularly and openly promised the
people of Malaya that they would soon get independence, plus national
developments to match. These promises were believed, and bought loyalty;
and correspondingly then there was a particular obligation of the British
to deliver on these promises to Malayans.
Later, these lessons would be imparted to the British hold in Hong
Kong, up until the handover to China in 1997. Did the British authorities
localize the administration of the colony of Hong Kong significantly, that
being well enough to carry over British traditions and legal administra-
tion? Did the last Hong Kong governor, Chris Patten, negotiate ener-
getically with China to preserve the localization achievements in Hong
Kong?18 These questions can be answered affirmatively.
168 W. HICKEY
products. Expatriate labor and staff can become extremely costly in com-
petitive industry seeking to make inroads in new markets. Consider that
fact that GE, Siemens, Motorola, and Abbott Laboratories all had their
own ‘localization’ plans in place in China in the 1990s to utilize local
Chinese managers, and reduce expat staff, as soon as possible. In these
cases, it was not the host country seeking localization for nationalistic
reasons, but investors seeking localization for cost factors.
Again we have to consider who really ‘owns’ the natural resources of a
country, despite constitutional proclamations? Elites tend to make a grab
for resources, excluding other stakeholders. How accountable are the
elites held?
Additionally, the apartheid government of South Africa (SA) from
1950 to 1985 had a clear policy of resisting independence (localization) in
its very large UN-mandated territory ‘South-West Africa’ (now Namibia).
In effect, South-West Africa became a fifth province of SA. This allowed
SA’s giant De Beers company to extract, at lower cost, and as a monopoly,
colossal quantities of diamonds from hundreds of kilometers of Namibia’s
beaches and the Orange River delta.
An analogous dispute started in Western Australia (WA), where the
economy was enjoying a long natural resources boom fueled mainly by
growing demand from China, Korea, India, and Japan for gas, oil, iron,
diamonds, uranium, and iron ores in huge quantities. Many of the agree-
ments were put in place, for up to 30 years.
In December 2006 the state premier of WA (West Australia), Alan
Carpenter, sent a message to the global oil companies who were extract-
ing and exporting WA gas to the before-mentioned Asian countries.
Paraphrased, Carpenter said: ‘In the far north of our state you are very
profitably extracting and exporting our gas to Asia. We assisted you to
start up [using Australian taxpayer funding]. The scale of your operations
now are enormous, and growing. Meanwhile, in the far south of our state,
the Collie power station which supplies 90% of WA’s electricity, urgently
needs a strategic conversion from coal to gas fired. I propose that you
divert just 10% of your gas extraction and sell it, at cost, to the State of
Western Australia, as your contribution [social obligation] to our state
development. Reasonable, considering how we have welcomed you into
WA.’ The response? The WA private sector and some of the mass media
fell on Carpenter’s head like a ton of bricks. He was accused of being
‘naive’, of ‘not understanding business’, and other name-calling such as
being a socialist.20
170 W. HICKEY
Measured Outcomes or the criterion of ‘what should be’21 are a key part
of any successful localization endeavor, as opposed to various subjective
measures which are currently desired by most foreign oil and mining com-
panies and their respective host governments. Measured outcomes are
criterion-referenced rubrics,22 and can be measured formatively (changes
made during a process) or summarily (endgame results) after a project has
been completed.23
LOCALIZATION 171
Subjective outcomes are not strategic and can be changed at will, politi-
cally manipulated, or expediently ignored to boost profits in the short
term. An example of subjective outcomes is found in many corporate
management localization plans (Figure 7.1), as it can be seen from this
actual ‘strategic intent’ that no discernible outcomes are derived, only a
never-ending wheel of ‘development’. No summative results are gained or
embedded.
A true outcome variable of a successful localization then would be in
the actual employability of the individual across all spectrums of a multi-
national company’s operations. (I.e. sending a local Ecuadorean geolo-
gist to Exxon Mobil’s Chad field operations or a local Indonesian project
manager to Shell’s headquarters in the Hague, for employment not more
training.) Short of these milestones, other more detailed rubrics would
be to fully develop locally skilled talent to certain prescribed interna-
tional standards of operation, for example, an API (American Petroleum
Develop sample
Focus on actual description of the
performance; Strategic Staffing right employees
flexible – Define
compensation Transfer right
requirements for people from
system and
competencies/ right places
advantages Retention Hiring
help retain hi- skills and
pot employees
Right people with
Monitor Right skills in Right Develop skills and
performance places at Right time competencies
Institute) certified pipe fitter or underwater welder for upstream oil opera-
tions or TAFE (Technical and Further Education) for coal mine develop-
ment and safety planning.24 While these certifications are required to work
in a US (or Australian) field operation for safety reasons, they are not
required in Kazakhstan or Nigeria. But, in fact the companies are spend-
ing millions of dollars (see section on PSC reimbursements) on measuring
existing ‘organizational capabilities’.
These reports consistently find that while a shortage of Western man-
agement skills exists in developing countries with resources, they offer
no applicable mechanisms to close those skills gap to the international
standards. These reports are largely written by US/EU engineers and field
technicians, bereft of any HRM input or outputs, or with even an under-
standing of the local culture. At the least this is defined as g eocentrism,
where certain regions, such as Korea, China, and Japan are lumped
together into one ‘learning unit’ by a multinational company, at the worst,
raw ethnocentrism, where only technicians and operators from the invest-
ing country can ‘do things correctly’.
Part of the problem is that the foreign management teams assessing
these human resource deficiencies are trying to introduce a paradigm of
Western thinking into a developing country culture, without an under-
standing of that culture and its acceptance readiness. Research has pre-
viously demonstrated any HR-imposed solutions devoid of cultural
relevance will have narrow results (see Figure 7.2), have demonstrated the
power of cultural relevance in regard to increasing evaluation outcomes.25
It is of interesting note that corporate-wide management development
‘wheels’ are usually devoid of any cultural relevance and follows Model ‘A’
of a non-corybantic, ethnocentric evaluation.
Geert Hofstede’s individual/collectivist dimension is frequently cited
in most management literature as a cultural value, however in rapidly
changing international work environments, ‘collectivism’ is now an old
paradigm. More relevant and contemporary work on this has been done
by Fons Tromenpaars and Charles Hampden Sydney-Turner26 regarding
overall individual’s societal perceptions of universalism/particularism.
That being the ‘West’ carries evaluation of programs as black and white,
developing countries in particular Asia, carry more ‘gray’ areas. Much of
this has also been discussed in the long-term work of Harry Triandis et al.,
concerning the transfer of learning across varied cultural audiences.27
LOCALIZATION 173
Competencies of Localization
Source: W. Hickey
services. In this case, offshore oil fields and all its attendant workforce issues
of exploration, production, shipping, machinery, maintenance, and services
being translated through educational policy to promote local engagement.
Left to their own devices, original investing oil companies would have
(and actually wanted to as they previously had in the Middle East and
Asia) imported their workers and equipment from Texas, Netherlands,
and the UK to work on these industries whilst the local Norwegians raised
sheep and continued to make low-grade textiles for export, completely
bereft of what economic activity was happening off their shores, yet very
much inside Norwegian territorial waters.
The key to Norway’s localization success was that the Norwegian gov-
ernment policy mandated for investing oil companies to transfer skills and
know-how to Norwegian citizens. For example, the oil education hub of
Stavanger arose. Promoted by the government with institutes that were
oil and gas concentric for the offshore oil industry servicing Norway. Not
just any technology would do, it had to be specific, and relevant, for the
oil and gas industry in regard to how it fit Norway. The policies of the
Norwegian government from early on were tightly focused on building
domestic capacity. Yet, strategic leaders also knew that oil companies could
be capricious, that their interest in the North Sea might change over time,
and therefore, any government participation had to be balanced with the
interests of the international companies, namely financial.
The establishment of Statoil, Norway’s state-owned oil company, from
the beginning reflected this: Statoil’s prime directive was to specify licens-
ing conditions and to promote technology transfer from foreign com-
panies to domestic entities. From the initial operations, the Norwegian
government sought to reward operators and producers who were mean-
ingfully contributing to Norway’s long-term domestic capacity building.
There were economic concerns that if development of Norway’s newly
found oil reserves were left purely to the markets’ ‘invisible hand’, the
Norwegian economy could be overwhelmed and collapsed by hot money
inflows, that is, the situation of the Dutch Disease (where huge and unmit-
igated foreign money drives up the value of the local currency, everything
becomes imported, and local industry and initiative withers due to non-
competitive currency and workers). This is also an endemic problem in
developing countries that has occurred from the outset, such as Nigeria,
Angola, Ecuador, and arguably, today’s Russia. Countries then become
one-sector energy economies subject to the market’s ups and downs of
volatile commodity prices, such as are we are seeing today.
LOCALIZATION 179
Essentially, Indonesia has been exporting raw ores and coal for
so long without any further value-added enhancement to these
resources in situ that is, in Indonesia, it is now difficult to change
this situation of resource over-exploitation and by allowing compa-
nies in other countries like China or Australia to process them. These
countries also need to be clearly aware that with emerging economic
nationalism, the old days are essentially over.
Simply put, this law in its current form does not create added value
for Indonesia’s huge mineral reserves without using the right people
with the right skills. Simply mandating a value-added component on
the raw resources by increasing taxes and export duties alone can’t
and won’t do it. The same results will occur, but only more messy
with higher costs. The big mining companies threatening to move
their operations and layoff multitudes of workers (which they did
to win a step back from this law for certain companies in 2015).
Gold exports, for example, were supposed to be fully refined, but
PTNNT and PTFI, were absolved at the last moment, mostly due to
the political clout they carried with employment.
One might ask, why are the big companies so reluctant to use local
smelters on a wholesale basis? There could be several reasons: quality
of ingots produced and impurity of content, fear of losing manage-
ment control (i.e. proprietary issues) if any technology or know-
how is transferred without safeguards, entrenched corruption, and
payoffs in the commissioning part of the smelter, or fear that the
government may renege or backtrack on previous promises that pro-
vided a certainty to investors when the original contracts were made.
In the case of PTFI, these agreements were made in the 1960s, over
40 years ago in very different economic and political times, on very
generous, non-transparent terms, under a dictatorship, that cared
about promulgating itself, not the interests of its citizens.
186 W. HICKEY
But times have changed. Indonesia, with its huge, largely unskilled,
youthful population, and exhaustible resources, simply cannot afford
to give away its future under deals that were struck with unelected
dictatorships years back. Conversely, they can’t expect investors to
come and invest if the terms are bad. There has to be a balance.
Enactment of 2014 export ban had one mining institute (Fraser in
Canada) ranking Indonesia as the worst place in the world for min-
ing investment, yet mining is a core industry in Indonesia. Enforcing
a law that does not recognize the importance of human resources in
itself, and only focuses on tangible product and financial returns will
do damage to Indonesia’s economy (think the Great Leap Forward)
in the long term, however, doing nothing, and giving too many
‘exemptions’ to certain big previously mentioned mining players
only reinforces the status quo of colonialism from old times.
Fig. 7.3 The five stages of Norway’s localization planning (Source: MIT Working
Paper, Black Gold to Human Gold, IPC MIT-IPC-06-004, used with
permission)
Clusters or Hubs?
One such issue is the development of ‘clusters’, as championed by Harvard
University professor Michael Porter where fixed geographic areas that
pool talent and agglomerate industry in one region, and business must go
to them, or are regions hubs, where people, capabilities, and information
flow from one region to another depending on economic and exogenous
demands and conditions? As Gereffi and Sturgeon have noted, ‘hubs are
open to the full force of the global economy, both positive and negative,
190 W. HICKEY
in ways that clusters are not. Hubs learn faster and more broadly, but
experience the turmoil of globalization more acutely than places that are
less well connected to global value chains.’34 Perhaps the entire issue of
cluster development needs a rethink. Meaning, firms must act locally, but
strategize globally, and must be mobile with ideas and people.
Spatial Sectoring
An important part of competitiveness is where do the people come from? This
affects the energy business as much as any high-tech or pharmaceutical busi-
ness. In many developing countries, the best and brightest come from the
big cities with the highest per capita wealth, best institutions and infrastruc-
ture, and most cosmopolitan outlook on things. Think Beijing as China,
Bangkok as Thailand, or Nairobi as Kenya. Nonetheless, this outlook works
to alienate and economically disadvantage people in remote areas, usually
where the oilfield, mine site, or wind farm are located. Development of
local populations is what localization is saying. If localization is only about
developing the affluent and well off in big city capitals to order around the
less advantaged in more remote areas of a country, it misses the mark.
Spatial sectoring means that the localization effort must be truly
‘spread out’ to benefit as many people from the resources as possible.
Unfortunately, this is not being done. The best and brightest at a remote
coal mining site in SA tent to be from Cape Town, or at a gas well in
Sakhalin in Siberia are from St. Petersburg. The ideal is to empower those
that are from those areas. To spread the wealth around. This will result
poverty alleviation through well-paying, decision-making jobs that no
‘aid’ program from the UN or WB can mollify. Again, any spatial sectoring
plan must be in the investment policy, with incentives for operationalizing.
Cultural Issues
Geert Hofstede’s IBM studies from the 1970s35 clearly demarcated cul-
tures and ways of doing things in different countries along his four cultural
dimensions, even countries in the same region. However, Hofstede’s stud-
ies during that era did not touch on the developing countries in Africa,
the former USSR, China (outside Taiwan), or even India. Unfortunately,
like spatial sectoring, investors and policy makers can tend to overlook
culture as a ‘cost’ not in creating wealth from the diversity.36 A geocentric
viewpoint can result that will have negative if not disastrous results on
LOCALIZATION 191
Conceptual Analysis
It can be readily seen then that for countries wanting to participate in
some type of localization effort, be it educational, policy, or economic, or
all the above, many factors must be considered. Additionally, localization
is not an ‘end-all, be-all’ process, it is ongoing.
The Bane of Localization Effectiveness: PSAs, Reworks, and Turnkeys
The PSA Agreement: A Contractual Disincentive for Management
Localization
There are many issues, financial, economic, business, and political
involved in the oil and gas business regarding proprietary technology
transfer and the overall development of local citizens. Oil and gas projects,
from exploration, to processing, to development, to first production then
field maturity are capital intensive and operationally demanding. What
many may not fully grasp is that the HR issues are actually negotiated
192 W. HICKEY
and gas companies can claim before any profitability accrues for the local
side (meaning no revenue for local coffers until foreign investors are reim-
bursed); they also demonstrate an over-reliance on expatriates with no
incentive to create localized management structures:
Mining Reworks
Lifting costs in mining, that are for the actual cost of mining, remov-
ing, and cleaning coal or ores for shipment, are not transparent and are
closely held as proprietary information by mining companies (most nota-
bly coal and gold mining) in order to reduce taxes and obligations to local
community (CSR) sustainability projects (including local jobs creation)
and to boost profits. The higher the lifting costs, the lower the taxation
base on the resources, resulting in an increase in investor rates of returns.
‘Averaging’ of lifting costs can be used to disguise true profit margins and
crimp localization resources. For example, it may only cost $2 to lift a ton
of coal in one part of a mine, and $12 to lift a ton of coal in another part.
196 W. HICKEY
As these costs are not weighted, the average is $7/ton. The government
collects tax on the difference between the final sales price of a ton of coal
and the average ($7) total cost of production input. If most of the mine
site costs less than $7/ton to mine, the residual difference is not taxed or
assessed, meaning a hidden windfall for the mining company.
The direct effect on HRD, is made clear in a context of absolute versus
comparative advantage. Not all mining extraction on a site is equal. Mining
companies (oil companies also) farm out more difficult production areas of
their sites to contractors. The large mining multinationals and their state
partners have complete discretion over the site. They mine the easiest parts
for their own benefits, this is absolute advantage. Technologies, skills, and
outlays for this type of mining are minimal, and require low-skilled labor.
However, they tender the more difficult and challenging areas to contrac-
tors, usually foreign, who have the most up-to-date techniques, skills, and
technology in mining. As contractors, they employ (and import) their own
people in these sensitive proprietary areas. They are usually under no obli-
gation to hire or develop local people for the more challenging know-how
required. Considering the fact that many large producing mines in devel-
oping countries have ruling elites or government officials involved in their
ownership, it does not behoove the government regulators to investigate
and audit mine activity or processes more closely than necessary.45
Turnkey Projects
Turnkey projects are simply that, the host country contracts with a foreign
entity to build a plant, a refinery, a dam, and so on, where the client merely
goes in and ‘turns the key’ upon commissioning. Turnkey’s are also well
noted in infrastructure projects. All work processes, technology transfer, and
employment are tightly controlled by the investing entity, many times a for-
eign state actor such as a Chinese dam builder or French NPP builder. When
the project is finished, all the investor does is simply go in and turn the key
to run it. FMC or ‘Full Maintenance Contracts’ administered by foreign
corporations in developing countries would also be considered prima facie
evidence of a turnkey: all skilled labor and technicians are from the outside.
In many energy and infrastructure (roads, port building, railway) projects
in the developing world, highly skilled foreigners and costly content are uti-
lized against national budgets via soft loans, foreign government grants, and
lines of credit, from supra-national banks such as the Asian Development and
WB.46 Many of these developing countries can only repay if locals have the
LOCALIZATION 197
Jobs Creation
The energy business in many developing countries has historically parceled
out jobs based on patronage, family connections, and political connec-
tions. This worked out just fine in a world of high energy prices and no
concerns about competency.49 But times change. High oil and coal prices
cannot be counted on to stay that way, as we are currently witnessing with
$30 a barrel oil in early 2016. Cost-cutting becomes part of competitive-
ness. Nationalization initiatives demand companies hire local workers, on
empowered levels, as opposed to importing armies of foreign workers to
do the actual work. The key component of robust localization effective-
ness then is found in local jobs creation and the scalability/ sustainability
of this initiative. There are many moving parts to jobs creation in devel-
oping countries (education, politics, investment, regulations). We should
also consider some successful case studies of jobs creation.
Education is by and far the largest baseline component in and for any
sustainable localization effort toward jobs creation. Who provides this
education, and how it is different from rote training are critical ques-
tions. Education is a long-term process, whereas training is short term.
Nonetheless, a baseline expectation of educational ability must be set to
build on training and mentoring initiatives. However, if the baseline work-
force skills level is not in place (such as in a jungle village in Tanzania or a
hamlet in India) all kinds of problems will then emanate in getting a local-
ized workforce up to speed. For the purposes of this book, we consider
that in any working-age, localized population the majority have completed
what would be deemed a fully completed primary education, or to the 6th–
8th grade level in Western terminology as the baseline. Of course this is
recognized as the ideal, and may not be probable in the before-mentioned
scenarios. Without this assumption, however, it will be profoundly dif-
ficult to set forth any type of localized engagement with say, uneducated
tribesmen in Tanzania living atop a uranium mine or an indigenous people
group in the Amazonian rain forest in eastern Ecuador near a hydro power
station. These latter people groups will only have rudimentary Western
levels of education if at all, never mind language skills. Simply, the cost
of fully re-educating these people groups is simply not practical. This has
been a thorn in the negotiations with foreign investors in remote places,
where the investors expect the government to assume responsibility for
LOCALIZATION 199
68.2 65.7
50.0 34.8
50.0
8.3
Top Top Middle Middle Supervi- Supervi- Professi- Professi
Others Others Workers Workers Total Total
mangmnt mangmnt mangmnt mangmnt sors sors onals onals
2001 dec-2005 2001 dec-2005 2001 dec-2005
dec-2001 dec-2005 dec-2001 dec-2005 dec-2001 dec-2005 2001 dec-2005
Expats 5 7 20 30 123 87 319 270 9 0 0 0 476 394
CIS 0 0 2 0 68 33 167 145 10 10 174 97 421 285
Kaz 5 7 2 16 410 318 931 1477 263 275 745 661 2356 2754
Fig. 7.4 Actual figure of localization of positions in major central Asian energy company workforce, 2005 where:
expatriate (white), contractors (scarlett), locals (blue) (Source: W. Hickey, 2006)
LOCALIZATION
201
202 W. HICKEY
Depleted Mines
Mining is a capital-intensive activity. While there are many technical
nuances with mining, in general, once an underground mine, be it for coal
or ores, fills with water, it is generally left unworkable, for the machinery,
unless the water can be pumped out continuously, usually at great costs.
LOCALIZATION 203
Renewable Energy
Conversely, renewable jobs are generally about maintenance and not the
production aspect of energy. They require strong vocational skills in order
to setup, repair, clean, and reassemble solar panels, wind turbines, biomass
plants, and mini-hydro plants.
204 W. HICKEY
Table 7.2 Skills levels required for various types of energy production projects
Source: Hickey (2015)
a
Key inputs to calculating ‘total costs’ include capital costs, fuel costs, fixed and variable operations and
maintenance (O&M) costs, financing costs, and assumed utilization rate for each energy type
US Energy Information Administration, Annual energy outlook 2015, April 2015, DOE/EIA-0383 (2015)
The methods to train and develop huge swaths of people via HRD is there
if the political will is there, and political will that is reflected by initiatives
that promote this. The Information Age has ensured that access to infor-
mation is there. Crowdsourcing and derivatives has ensured that the financ-
ing is there. All of this is possible. Consider the magnitude of jobs created
via upstream the British Government itself has encapsulated, through its
own UK Oil and gas industry (OPITO58), key facts about the significant
number and quality of jobs created in upstream oil alone. OPITO is the
UK arm for training and development in the North Sea oilfields. It could
be held as a model for most of the concepts of this research if economic
and political processes were transparent in developing countries. OPITO
also develops workers for the ‘downstream’ parts of the UK oil and gas
business and claims worldwide standards. Here is the description in their
own words ‘provides the strategic perspective for workforce planning and
skills development for the oil and gas sector across the UK, develops the
standards for those working across lifelong learning and is the voice of
employers in this industry on training issues’ (Fig. 7.5).
Finally, PSAs are not necessarily joint ventures (JVs). While the Tengiz
Chevron consortia in Kazakhstan calls itself a JV, the secrecy aspects of the PSA
would tend to mitigate a true JV arrangement. As such, the true value a PSA
provides to a host government and the localization of its management poses
some deep questions. Steensma et al., and Inkpen and Beamish have researched
extensively about the inherent instability of JV arrangements when the value of
those partnerships for the host side long-term is called into question.59
‘The industry in 2010 is providing employment for 440,000 people across the whole country:
· The exploration for and extraction of oil and gas from the UKCS accounts for around 340,000 of these, comprising:
o 32,000 directly employed by oil and gas companies and their major contractors
o 207,000 within the wider supply chain
o 100,000 jobs supported by the economic activity induced by employees’ spending.
· In addition, a thriving exports business is estimated to support a further 100,000 jobs.
· Whilst the oil and gas industry provides work across the whole of the UK, Scotland benefits the most with 45% of jobs.
21% are in South East England, 6% in North West England, 5% in West Midlands and 5% in Eastern England.
· Each £1 billion spent on the UKCS supports approximately 20,000 jobs.
· Jobs in the UK oil and gas industry are highly skilled and well rewarded. 2008 salaries averaged circa £50,000 a year
across a broad sample of supply chain companies, with the Exchequer benefing by £19,500 per head in payroll taxes.’
And
‘The industry helps to make the world go around. … enabling emerging economies to get off the ground. It's not just an
interesting industry. It's essential. …. Oil and gas is vital to the environment, water, food, power generation, and the
pharmaceutical and chemical sectors. In total, this industry provides employment for around 380,000 people. Many livelihoods
are dependant on the ef forts of trained and skilled technicians.’
Fig. 7.5 UK Oil and gas industry Jobs (OPITO 2011) from their own Home
webpage
Table 7.3 Meso, Macro, and Micro levels of empowerment in a ‘best practices’
localization scenario
Level Empowerment ideal Core identity
Inverse Succession
According to William Rothwell, in HRD parlance, SP or succession plan-
ning is all about who will replace whom or by making provision for the devel-
opment and replacement of key people over time.60 Most foreign-invested
energy and resource companies have detailed plans not only designating
which foreigner will replace another foreigner in the organization, but
also which local (sometimes a token political appointment) will replace a
LOCALIZATION 207
foreigner. This makes good press and is good for warm feelings with gov-
ernment desperate to see its own people advancing in strategic industry.
But this is the Information Age, no longer the twentieth century.
Appeasement is a low threshold strategy, it will not empower local popula-
tions on a long-term spatial level. We expand the strategy then spatially.
Consider a hypothetical ‘XYZ’ oil company from France that has operated
in Vietnam for the past 50 years, drawing considerable wealth and influ-
ence in Vietnam from an offshore oilfield that now represents 18 % of its
total revenue generation portfolio from all upstream projects worldwide.
In other words, XYZ has considerable stake in this operation. A closer look
at XYZ’s board of directors’ portfolio has shown various turnovers of for-
eign directors from the USA, Germany, New Zealand, and so on for the
past 50 years, many countries which have either no upstream production
or even limited downstream (gas stations) representation. No one from
Vietnam has ever been represented on the BOD.
Here is the key to this idea: Since the upstream operation means so
much in terms of overall economic viability to XYZ, and they have set
a precedent by using directors from other third-party countries, it then
becomes a foundational and imperative corporate policy that a director
with voting power is placed on the board who is from Vietnam, not merely
an émigré, but an actual citizen of Vietnam with interests and ties to that
country. This in its kernel, is ‘inverse succession’. Locals being developed
not merely to do a few vocational and supervisory tasks but inversely, to
run and decide on key corporate governance decisions at the highest strategic
levels. Therefore, since Vietnam plays such a large part in the investor port-
folio, this would be only normal, and accepted if XYZ had similar counter-
parts theoretically in Australia or Norway operations. What we are really
saying is that in the Information Age, the North-South problem is dead.
As such, countries will simply have to get it into their collective knowl-
edge that building current and relevant educational outlets in their own
countries with their own wealth is a much better long-term proposition than
making bankers in Swiss, USA, or on Canary Wharf richer. It is noted that
some sovereign wealth funds do declare that their intention and mandate is
to use the incipient wealth for local development and education, but they
intend to do that only off the proceeds derived (interest and dividends) from
Western investments, not touching the principal. They simply cannot afford
to play that game in today’s Information Age, they need to use the funding
to develop their people here and now, not a rainy day far into the future.
Investments in foreign lands with high broker and transactions fees are not
sure fire either. Markets can (and do) go down, risky investments can sour,
and a deflationary world can generate less than stellar dividends, but relevant
education can and will be an incremental source of value-added activity to any
society. Holistically, then, bets on developing a societies endogenous human
capital will lead to better economic benefits than trusting a nations resource
wealth to the vagaries of the financial markets in distant Western countries.62
Summary
‘Localization’ is a pre-eminent political topic of concern among many
developing countries in the world today. Even countries rich in resources
have a negative record with developing their people to perform voca-
tional and management tasks to internationally accepted standards. Many
of these encumbrances are due to political, proprietary, and contractual
agreements which fail to mandate precise educational outcomes for local
people. ‘Competence’ then is generally not defined nor prepared by HR
professionals, but is expediently designed by politicians, economists, and
industrial technicians. Without an educationally relevant theoretical frame-
work, localization effectiveness initiatives will continue to be misguided,
costly, moving, and garner negative publicity. Historically, there is a reli-
ance on expatriates congruent with a lack of HRD mechanisms to define
the outcomes that will develop and empower local citizens.
Until recently, and now with a worldwide slump in oil and commodity
prices, resource-rich countries in a world of increasing commodity demand
were seeing rising GDP’s and living standards. Crude oil, followed by gas,
and coal/ores, are by and far the current drivers of the economies of many
resource-rich developing countries. Nonetheless, due to the secrecy and elite
control of the resource extractive business in general, most of the local popula-
tion is excluded in the decision-making or operations of this business. Work,
technical directives, and leadership aspects are controlled and delivered by for-
210 W. HICKEY
eign officers, engineers, and even foreign leaders,63 not merely from foreign
secondees, but also from their contractors. This is done to encourage invest-
ment and protect technology transfer/proprietary information but is also at
the expense of management development. Most importantly, under current
PSA regimes, investment outlays by the foreign investors are fully reimburs-
able by the host country side out of the first production or profit oil, with
little, if any, input by HRD. Yet, these reimbursables also include key HR areas
of expatriate compensation, usage of foreign contractors, personnel train-
ing, and attendant administrative overhead (including possibly fines for non-
compliance). In short, developing countries are already paying for foreigner
investors to ‘localize’ them, but without a robust say in the process, by way
of any forensically audited cost self-regulation or any discernible societal out-
comes. These reimbursable efforts can promote conflicts of interest without
any localization derived. Kazakhstan, Angola, Nigeria, Ecuador, and Russia
to list a few are all in a similar quandary. Namely: localization is without real-
ized outcomes; is determined by non-HRM professionals in engineering and
finance; and is still heavily dependent on foreign technology and know-how.
Engagement of HRD professionals then is paramount to any non-ethnocentric
localization initiatives, especially in today’s Information Age as a type of ‘rule
of engagement’ in developing countries with natural resources but also vast
hordes of unskilled citizens.
Development of local talent then is not a case of ‘good choices versus
bad decisions’. It is a case of meeting needs and compromise in a new world
paradigm of large population groups with a need to be more engaged in
their in situ resources. However, this demands financial support, responsi-
bility, and technology transfer with the oil majors to realize these outcomes.
By all accounts, ‘tokenism’ is seemingly apparent with many localization
initiatives politically mandated simply in order to gain public goodwill, but
without any agreed upon development goalposts. Localization must also be
considered past the individual at the micro level of development. Holistic
localization also requires community development in lagging areas at the
meso level, and economic development that is measured at the macro level.
It requires all three actors: government, investors, and locals (as individual
and community, what is also known as gemeinschaft and gesellschaft) work-
ing together to derive a robust outcome for all.
Most localization initiatives today are still stymied by age-old colonial
practices, hegemony, and contractual impediments that tend to reward
the signers, but not the stakeholders in the contracts. Breaking old mind-
sets, especially regarding the one-dimensional world of profits and finance
versus a twenty-first-century era of people development is now more
LOCALIZATION 211
criterioned goals (e.g., in a world of rising oil prices, it is easier to pay fines
as a business cost, though right now oil prices are falling), in fact, and ironi-
cally, even under some PSA agreements, fines are considered as a fully reim-
bursable operations expense.64 Meaning, fines paid by the investing entity
will ultimately be reimbursed by the host government and it’s citizens any-
way, this is essentially robbing Peter to pay Paul.
Even without reimbursements, fines allow for a default mechanism for
the companies, and mitigate tech transfer and domestic content use at
the expense of localization initiatives. Likewise, secret usage of sovereign
wealth funds can significantly co-mingle the residuals for other things (such
as for wasteful public works projects: i.e. large statues, presidential palaces,
grand fountains, etc.). This type of spending also tends to attract significant
corruption, while neglecting necessary spending on real human resource
needs. While SWFs from oil and resources are standard investment vehicles
in many parts of the world, and it is beyond the scope of this work to discuss
them in detail, one thing that is correlated with these SWFs is that the more
transparency and public involvement, the faster relevant human and social
development funding can be obtained and utilized.65 Of course it is no coin-
cidence either the most successful SWFs (i.e. Norway) exist in established
democracies, and many developing countries are far from this ideal.
Expatriate costs for labor and services, as discussed under the current
PSA regime, are also fully reimbursable by the host government as an
‘operations expense’. This is counter-productive to any robust localization
initiative as skills then become an object of abstract value66 to the foreign-
invested resource companies: which operate on rotational shifts with their
home employees. As such, a work permit should go with the foreign worker,
never with the position.67 Whether or not the expatriate work permits will
still be as prized if locals are truly developed remains a future study, but in
short, work permits, or the right to employ their nationals, are the main tool
foreign companies covet even with a full reimbursement scheme in place.
This is most critical: as long as the resource extraction companies would be
paying this fee, and not being reimbursed, they will use considerably more
cost effective discretion in what expatriates they send.
One quid pro quo would be to attach work permit fees toward local
managerial development.68 The cost of a one-year work permit would be
approximately what it takes to develop one professional worker for the
resource extractive business. Under selected methods accounting prin-
ciples (line itemed, not aggregated), the work permits would be exempt
from any reimbursable, thus the resource extraction companies would
LOCALIZATION 213
need to be very selective on the front end about whom they are sending
to do the overseas job. As local professionals and specialists are developed,
there would be less and less need to use these expatriate experts and man-
agers. Over time, localization would measurably occur, and at a faster pace.
This would work to the benefit of all parties concerned. Unfortunately, at
times, money from these type of programs has been diverted to govern-
ment coffers in unrelated departments to fill other financial holes.
Additionally, and as a further incentive for the resource extraction com-
panies, it is recommended letting them have the prerogative to appoint a
certain percentage of trainers and professors to local polytechnical schools
and universities in order to train and mentor future workers to standards
they deem ‘best practice’ (This is also a hallmark of the Norwegian model
of localization: learning input from investors). These ‘foreign expert’
costs and fees might then in turn be guaranteed by the local side. Finally
any work permits should be reserved specifically for resource managerial
positions, with a high enough fee, in order to avoid any ambiguity in their
overall disbursement or value (i.e. using work permits to bring in Chinese
manual laborers, Indian road builders, Turkish construction workers, or
Sri Lankan pipe layers) short of developing the local workers.
While the governments of many countries exhibit a desire for locals to
be developed, they do not always require that those venues will be hon-
ored via any legal mandate or distribution of assets that requires funding
for a specific academic entity or technical development center with atten-
dant, employable outcomes (meaning empowered outcomes). While there
is the exception of perhaps ‘fines’ for lack of that development, as already
stated, it is usually easier for the resource extraction companies to just pay
the fines (with the possibility of a later reimbursable) in order to protect
intellectual property (IP) than to actually invest in the education of a local
wherefore adherence (control) of any IP may be compromised. Thus,
as a pretext, developing countries’ governments, with natural resources,
should be the ‘insuring’ foundation for any human development initia-
tives. It should not (and does not need to be) left to the international
business education efforts of the UNDP, WB, EU GTZ, USAID, IMF,
and other Non-governmental Organizations (NGOs) operating there.69
In fact, some research has shown that an over-reliance on these type of
NGO welfare programs may foster dependence and impede skills develop-
ment incentives70 in situ. In addition to this, and perhaps in overall con-
summation to this point, true HR professionals need to be engaged and
consulted in these issues. Shell petroleum engineers, USAID b ureaucrats,
214 W. HICKEY
Notes
1. Wei, Z. & Moller, D. (2004) Localization: How Multinational Corporations
Survive and Develop in China, Accessed from http: http://www.btmbei-
jing.com/contents/en/business/2004-06/coverstory/localization on 03
Mar 2007; Fitz-enz, J. (2000) The ROI of human capital. New York:
Amacom.
2. TCO Business Plan, (2006).
3. Becker, G. (1993) Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis,
with special reference to education (2nd ed.). New York: Columbia University
Press.; Thurow, L. (1999) The Future of Capitalism. New York: Wm.
Morrow & Co; Fitz-Enz, 2000, ibid.
4. Kuralbayeva, K. (2001) The Dutch disease: symptoms and policy implica-
tions for Kazakhstani economy. Central Asian Journal of Management,
Economics and Social Sciences.
5. Research; Horton S. (1999) ‘Is Kazakhstan taking reform seriously?’
Keynote presentation delivered at the Columbia University School of
International and Public Affairs Conference ‘Kazakhstan’s Economic
Development After the Russian Crisis’, New York 29th April.
6. Southern Methodist University, 1980. Macguire Energy Institute unpub-
lished monograph on resource ownership.
7. Birdsall, N., Pinckney, T., and Sachs, R. (2001) Natural resources, human
capital, and growth in R.M. Anty, R.M. (eds.) Resource, abundance and
economic development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.; Karl, T. (1997).
The paradox of plenty: oil booms and petro-states. Stanford: University of
California Press.and Gelb, A. (1988) Oil windfalls: blessing or curse?
New York: Oxford University Press for the World Bank.
8. Mikesell, R. (1997) ‘Explaining the resource curse, with special reference
to mineral-exporting countries.’ Resources Policy 23, 4, 191–199.; Sachs,
J.D. and Warner, A.M. (2001) ‘The curse of natural resources.’ European
Economic Review 45, 4–6, 827–38.
9. Kuznets, P. (1988) ‘Why does overcrowded, resource-poor East Asia suc-
ceed – lessons for the less developed countries.’ Journal of Economic
Development and Cultural Change 36, 3, Supplement (April).
10. Porter, M. (2001) On competition, 2nd Ed. Cambridge: Harvard University
Press.
LOCALIZATION 215
11. Bennis, W. (1969) Organization development: Its nature, origins, and pros-
pects. Addison-Wesley.
12. Schein, E. (2001). Organizational culture and leadership. 3rd Ed.
New York: Jossey-Bass.
13. Gilbert, T. (1978). Human Competence: Engineering worthy performance.
New York : Pfieffer.
14. Becker, G. (1993), ibid.
15. Knowles, M. (1975). Self-directed learning: A guide for learners and teach-
ers. Cambridge University Press.
16. Kwok, C. and Taldesse, S. (2006) The MNC as an agent of change in host
country institutions: FDI and Corruption. Journal of International
Business Studies, 37, 767–785.
17. Argote, L. (1999) Organizational Learning. Norwell, MA: Kluwer
Academic Press.
18. Patten, C. (1999) East and West, Pan Books, UK.
19. Saudi Aramco, the state oil company of Saudi Arabia, has gone on an
aggressive upgrade programs to wean itself of crude oil exports only, but is
it too little too late in a world of falling oil prices? See http://www.sau-
diaramco.com/en/home/about/strategy.html
20. McLure, M. (2009) Royalties for Regions: accountability and sustainabil-
ity. Discussion Paper 09.05, Business School The University of Western
Australia and Australian Parliamentary Debates (Hansard), August 16,
2006, p. 4751.
21. Rothwell & Kazanas, (1994) ibid.
22. Gilbert, T. (1978), ibid.
23. Posavac and Carey, (1997). ibid.
24. API and TAFE are accepted benchmark standards used in oil and mining
operations worldwide.
25. Hickey, (2004), An evaluation of foreign HR consulting company effec-
tiveness in China. Performance Improvement Quarterly 17, 1, 81–101.,
and Kluckhohn, F. and Strodtbeck, F. (1961). Variations in Value
Orientations. Evanston, IL: Row & Peterson.
26. Hampden-Turner, C., & Trompenaars, F. (2000). Building cross-cultural
competence. New Haven: Yale University Press. And Hofstede, G. (1991).
Cultures and organizations: Software of the mind. Berkshire, U.K.:
McGraw-Hill.
27. Bhagat, R., Harveston, P., and Triandis, H. (2001) Cultural variations in
the cross border transfer of organizational knowledge: an integrative
framework. Academy of Management Journal 27, 204–220.
28. Argote, L. (1999) ibid.
29. Milkovich, G. & Newman, J., ( 1993) Compensation, 4th Ed. Boston,
MA: Irwin
216 W. HICKEY
30. A large part of the baseline for forming an effective localization model is
found in the MIT working paper study: Hatakenaka, S., Westnes, P.,
Gjelsvik, M., Lester, R. (2006) From Black Gold to Human Gold. MIT
Working Paper Series, MIT-IPC-06-004 in particular pp. 18–23.
31. MIT-IPC-06-004, ibid.
32. Henan Power, from China was the main contractor on this plant, with
Poyri engineering from Finland providing oversite and risk assessment in
2009. The plant had many fits and starts before commissioning.
33. Hickey (2012) article in The Jakarta Post regarding the 2009/4 mining
law and localization, HRD.
34. Gereffi, G. and Sturgeon, T. (2004), ‘Globalization, Employment, and
Economic Development: A Briefing Paper’, MIT Industrial Performance
Center Working Paper 04-006.
35. Hofstede, G. (1991). Cultures and organizations: Software of the mind.
Berkshire, UK: McGraw-Hill.
36. Hampden-Turner, C., & Trompenaars, F. (2000). Building cross-cultural
competence. New Haven: Yale University Press.
37. Dave, B. (2003) Kazakhstan: countries in transition. New York: UNDP
Publication.
38. Kwok, C. and Taldesse, S. (2006) The MNC as an agent of change in host
country institutions: FDI and Corruption. Journal of International
Business Studies, 37, 767–785.
39. World Markets, (2002).
40. Easo, J. (2015) Production Sharing Agreements – Practice and Trends,
Issue. 13: 5-10, in NOTES FROM THE FIELD: An English Law
Perspective on the Oil & Gas Market, retrieved from URL :
www.andrewskurth.com.
41. Jennings, D., Feiten, J., and Brock, H. (2000) Petroleum Accounting:
Principles, Procedures and Issues (5th ed.), A Price Waterhouse Coopers
(PWC) Handbook. Denton, TX: Professional Development Institute.
42. Rutledge, I. (2004) The Sakalhin II PSA: a production “Non-Sharing”
agreement. Sheffield Energy and Resource Information Services (SERIS)
43. Tsalik, S. (2003) Caspian oil windfalls: who will benefit? New York: Open
Society (Soros) Institute.
44. Johnston, D. et al. (2001) Kashagan and Tengiz – Castor and Pollux.
PetroMin Magazine 15 December.
45. Birdsal N., et al. (2001) ‘Natural resources, human capital, and growth’ in
R.M. Anty, R.M. (ed) Resource, abundance and economic development.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
46. Stiglitz, J. (2003) Globalization and It’s Discontents. New York:
W.W. Norton and Co.
47. Brautigam, D. (2009) The dragons gift: the real story of China in Africa.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
LOCALIZATION 217
48. Pinto, P. and Zhu, B. (2009) Fortune or Evil? The Effects of Inward
Foreign Direct Investment on Corruption, Saltzman Institute of War and
Peace Studies (SIWPS) Working Paper No. 10.
49. Mikesell, Raymond F. Explaining the resource curse, with special reference
to mineral-exporting countries. Resources Policy, Vol. 23. No. 4, 1997.
50. Altbach, P. and McGill-Peterson, P. (eds.) (2007) Higher Education in the
New Century. Washington, D.C,: Sense Publications.
51. Consider case of BP in Gulf Deepwater Horizon blowout in 2010, BP,
while ultimately held responsible, went to great lengths to distance itself
and assign blame to, its main drilling contactor, Halliburton, and their
sub-contractor, Transoceanic, who apparently did shoddy, under
inspected,casing work that caused the undersea blowout! Deepwater
Horizon Marine Casualty Investigation Report (PDF) (Report). Office of
the Maritime Administrator. 17 August 2011. Retrieved December 29,
2015.
52. Richy Lam and Leonard Wantchekon, Dictatorships As A Political Dutch
Disease, (Yale University, Center Discussion Paper no. 795, January 1999).
53. h ttp://finance.yahoo.com/news/strippers-suffering-low-oil-prices-
225403708.html.
54. There are many quid pro quo’s in the extractive industry beyond the scope
of this book to discuss, as they deal with corruption. Nonetheless, mine
operations depend significantly on kickbacks and bribes to get going. The
author has no illusions to this. Simply, elites at times will rather shut down
a mine (or oil well) than work constructively with local communities to
create employment opportunities. These problems are more reflective of
the society, it culture, and its hierarchy as opposed to any secular job cre-
ation efforts. See: Dahl, Robert A. (1971) Polyarchy: Participation and
Opposition. New Haven: Yale University Press, see also Managing Bribery
and Corruption Risks in the Mining and Metals Industry (2013) Ernst and
Young Global Marketing.
55. Chaplin, D. et al., (2012) Evaluation of the Millennium Challenge
Corporation’s Electricity-Transmission and Distribution Line- Extension
Activity in Tanzania: Baseline Report, Mathematica Policy Research:
Washington.
56. World Bank (2002) Empowerment Sourcebook.
57. See standardized WB economic definition of what is ‘Empowerment’.
World Bank (2002).
58. http://www.oilandgasuk.co.uk/employment.cfm.
59. Steensma, K. et al. (2005) The evolving value of foreign partnerships in
transitioning economies. Academy of Management Journal 48, 213–235.
and Inkpen, A. and Beamish, P. (1997) Knowledge, Bargaining Power,
and the Instability of International Joint Ventures, Academy of Management
Review 22, 177–203
218 W. HICKEY
China
Growth and Demand
China, with nearly 1.4 billion more affluent and job-hungry people and
a $10 trillion-plus economy which until very recently exhibited double-
digit growth, simply cannot be ignored in world events. Currently, it is the
world’s second largest economy behind the USA and is scheduled to sur-
pass it to become the world’s most dominant and number one economy
by 2035. Its external trade balances dictate currency and budget move-
ments in many smaller countries. It exports manufactured goods to the
advanced economies while simultaneously importing millions of tons of
raw commodities from the emerging world, in particular developing Asia,
sub-Saharan Africa, and South America. As a main driver of demand in
said developing world, it deserves a chapter in itself to reflect this, but it
is not only about commodity inputs and finished product outputs. China
seeks to be a player on the world stage in its ascent, through both its finan-
cial clout and its prowess with infrastructure projects.
Nonetheless, not all is rosy. China still faces many energy hurdles with
domestic pollution issues, substandard exported energy turnkey practices
in developing countries, and utilizing Chinese workers in many foreign-
invested projects in host countries with large unemployment issues, not
to mention attendant environmental issues such as CO2 emissions and
smog.1 If China tries to develop living standards to the same level as the
USA or EU, we would need approximately 1.5 planet earths to meet the
demand. If India is also a factor in and uses as much energy per capita as
the USA, their combined consumption would be 14 times greater than
the USA.2 It is also noted that we have now reached a stage where the
amount of resources needed to sustain earth’s population far exceeds what
is available at current growth rates. ‘Growth at all costs’ may prove det-
rimental to the planet. It is critical that China embrace HRD early in
its growth curve, both domestically and in foreign-invested projects for
world stability. Simply, the world cannot be tested to meet the resource
demands of a ‘consumptiononomics’-based Asia, unless energy inefficien-
cies and pollution are addressed.3
Voracious Chinese demand for commodities such as oil and gas in
other developing countries has moved world energy and commodity mar-
kets forward without pause. While energy intensification has been declin-
ing in the USA and EU for several years now, due in part to smarter
efficiency choices and pollution standards, China’s carbon footprint
(mostly from fossil fuels) has grown enormously.4 China’s foreign invest-
ments increased 1000 % between the years 2005 and 2013, earning it
friends and allies worldwide because of its economic largesse. Most of
these investments were in the natural resources sector, oil, gas, and coal5
and not surprisingly, in politically unstable countries with weak economies
and repressive, autocratic regimes such as Sudan, Sierre Leone, Sri Lanka.
Countries that many Western companies tend to avoid. In fact, China is
so important in the world’s energy profile that most IEA publications
now include a separate chapter or a section on China alone, similar to this
chapter. China’s enormous appetite for resources, in a finite world where
Western countries have already obtained most of the low-hanging fruit,
has driven them to invest in some of the most undeveloped and politically
risky of the developing countries: Angola, Burma, and landlocked Bolivia,
to name a few.
Dambisa Moyo says it best about China’s commodity need ‘To satisfy
China’s population and prevent a crisis of legitimacy for their rule, leaders
in Beijing need to keep economic growth rates high and continue to bring
hundreds of millions of people out of poverty. And to do so, China needs
arable land, oil and minerals.’6
China has large stocks of coal reserves in the center of the country that
serve to meet its entire domestic demand obligation. Yet, despite being the
world’s fifth largest oil producer and producing over 4 million barrels a day,
it cannot keep up with its fast-rising demand of over 8 million barrels a day.
The sustained demand in economic growth have caused China’s oil imports
CHINA 221
The collective might of the SOEs (not only in China but also around
the world) is formidable. In China, the top 120 SOEs by size account
for nearly $3 trillion of state wealth, though their share in China’s GDP
has recently shrunk. It is noted that much of the utilized SOE portfolio
is energy- and utility-concentrated, including the telecom and banking
industry, which, if extended, can be considered as ‘soft’ infrastructure.
All are very content specific and complementary to any large energy and
infrastructure projects in Asia: power generation, transmission, commu-
nications, and (least not) financing. To that end, China’s state capitalism
model may be considered as providing a complete ‘vertically integrated’
structure in regard to infrastructure investment endeavors.
China’s SOEs, as mentioned, suffer significantly from HRD deficien-
cies. They can be quite top-heavy with management; redundant, nepotis-
tic, and overmanned with staffing; stuck in status quo strategies, with slow
to change operations; and overall financially under-performing. However,
their greatest virtue is in providing a source of political stability through
employment across all skills levels; as such, they justify political support and
garner preferential subsidies not given to more dynamic private businesses.
Further, working for an SOE, particularly in China, is the stated aspira-
tion of many of China’s best and brightest university graduates, includ-
ing those from schools such as BEIDA, Tsinghua, Jiaotang, or Fudan
Universities. For these graduates, working at an SOE is a career builder,
from development and SP to political office. Many large SOEs now send
their top managers to pursue MBA degrees, and many standing Central
Committee members have previously held senior positions in SOEs.
One-Belt One-Road
This is the new Chinese-led ‘Silk Road’ initiative in an integrated Eurasia,
similar to the medieval era ‘Silk Road’ that Marco Polo traveled on. The Silk
Road today is actually bidirectional or two-pronged. OBOR is an overland
route through Western China, India, and Central Asia onward to Turkey
and Europe, Figure 8.2. And a sea route that passes through South East
Asia, with ports of call via Myanmar, Bangladesh, and Sri Lanka into the
Middle Eastern Arab countries and Egypt and on to Europe. In the for-
mer overland case, the OBOR expansion will require huge investments in
pipelines, roads, and electrical infrastructure, and in the latter, maritime,
significant port expansion, and upgrades will be required. This behemoth
Eurasian expansion venture would connect over 4 billion people with a need
for $800 million in infrastructure improvements each year until 2020.17
226 W. HICKEY
Fig. 8.2 OBOR, One-Belt One-Road (一带一路): Across Asia into Africa and
Europe (red lines) with Ocean Trade Routes (blue line)(Map Source: CIA Factbook,
Public Domain)
both perceived as too slow and beholden to Western interests. China has
chosen to go its own way with its Chinese majority controlled AIIB with
a seed capital of $50 billion expected to reach $100 billion with commis-
sioning of its first projects.19 It should be noted that the AIIB however is
not the only funding mechanism for foreign-invested mega-infrastructure
projects. Funding will also be devolved from China’s Development Bank
(CDB) and its massive SWF, China Investment Corporation or CIC (see
Chapter 3) [中国投资有限责任剬司]. The point is that China will main-
tain its position as an Asian paymaster and create a regional hegemony in
Eurasian development that cannot be ignored.
As of this writing, early 2016, the AIIB has signed up nearly 60 con-
tributing participant countries, including the great Western powers of the
UK, France, and Germany, who were formerly China’s colonial masters.
The USA and Japan have up until now steadfastly refused to join, though
cracks are showing between the two holdouts. Namely, the infrastructure
demand projects will require vast amounts of machinery and expertise, and
low growth, economically stagnant developed countries would be passing
up a golden opportunity their vast industries cannot afford to squander.
The AIIB is therefore a vehicle for China to gain respectability to claim
global relevance and to counterbalance the IMF, WB, and ADB, all of
which China has been frozen out of the decision-making processes by a
lack of voting power. The AIIB would serve as a substitute for allegedly
discriminatory WB/IMF/ADB investment patterns that are historically
biased toward Western ‘investment’, most notably in regard to human
rights and environmental issues. In fact, there is deep concern among
environmentalists that the AIIB will green-light and approve many coal-
fired power plants in Asia that the WB has previously banned.20
Yet, despite all the altruistic exuberance and political rhetoric about
advancement of developing Asia, the creation of an AIIB addresses two
macro-economic problems that reflect on China’s emerging internal
capacity and domestic challenges. These two related issues cannot be
solved independently and serve to highlight the Chinese Communist
Parties (CCPs)’ interest in maintaining its role as a stable leader for a one-
party state, while providing an outlet for deploying China’s massive capital
reserves. They are:
(or with unemployment that is no more than 5.2 % of the total available
workforce). Domestic economic and political stability are thus the main
drivers and what is really at stake. Employing Chinese workers in Chinese-
invested projects, particularly turnkey projects or power plant kits,25 run-
ning the gamut from airports to power plants to roads to bridges26 in
Indonesia to Nigeria to Sri Lanka, then becomes the ‘prime directive’ not
quarterly profits. In fact, money-losing projects have been tolerated by
China to gain political clout and influence abroad.27
The percentage of Chinese workers used alongside host developing coun-
try nationals in Africa, South America, and South Asia varies widely. What
is known is that Chinese investment in energy and infrastructure mega-
projects is daunting overall. Many factors can affect workforce utilization:
politics, local labor laws, a work permit regime, more importantly, enforce-
ment of the rules and regulation, sourcing of skilled labor and labor costs.
Take Sri Lanka, for example, emerging after 32 years of civil war, skilled
and literate workers are scarce and expensive. Most Sri Lankans with engi-
neering backgrounds go abroad,28 especially to the Mid-East (Kuwait, Saudi
Arabia, Oman). In Sri Lanka, as in Vietnam, Indonesia, Ecuador, and African
countries, many Chinese firms import workers from low-skilled laborers to
highly skilled technical and managers from China. Any discussion about
Chinese investment and HRD in host countries must start with Africa, where
China is actively investing in natural resources and getting much in return.29
An extreme example, but possibly not the only one, would be China’s
workforce in Equatorial Guinea, an area rich in resources but scant in
development. This particular example was for a roadbuilding project, not
an energy project per se, but the mechanics should suffice. In this situ-
ation, 90 % or 3782 workers were all Chinese, and the other 10 % were
from regional African countries.30
Deborah Brautigam in her book The Dragons Gift has seemingly gone
to great lengths to show and aggrandize that Chinese companies invest-
ing in Africa are ‘no different than others’ and that Western governmental
propaganda is generally skewed in the negative against Chinese compa-
nies. On the face, this research may be correct, but there are a few outlier
issues to consider in how this information is being ‘spun’:
All that the Chinese are profiting greatly from commodities in Africa
as Western countries have not taken up the slack. She states clearly
that the Chinese are Africa’s friend, and that most Africans view
Chinese investment favorably. ‘China’s African role is wider, more
sophisticated and more businesslike than any other country’s at any
time in the post-war period’, Moyo writes and that Western govern-
ments have largely avoided working with Africa.31 See Table 8.1.
However, both Brautigam and Moyo, and even Scott Pegg, do not
look at China through a lens of HRD and as a potential long-term driver
of societal advancement in Africa, but rather as an outcome of respon-
sible and transparent business decisions driven by finance and investing for
commodities (and in building the necessary infrastructure necessary to get
access to those commodities).33 In other words, it is the Friedman’s trickle-
down model blindly accepted. Nothing is written about any type of HRD
in the Chinese investment schema on the front end with any localized
policy initiatives, that is, the preparation of workforce educational man-
dates before investment is given, beyond merely social outreach. Again,
the financial imperatives of FDI, investment, and trade seem to outweigh
all else in the investment calculus of both sides. Unfortunately, China’s
state capitalism model will defy capitalist rules, simply because their model
of investment is not capitalist but politically driven for stability.34
In Brautigam’s view, if Chinese investment is only channeled cor-
rectly and transparently, corruption can be mitigated, beneficial stan-
CHINA 233
dards upheld, and then good things will flow toward jobs creation. Nor
is anything mentioned about climate change or carbon reduction targets,
of which Africa is a growing and potentially gigantic contributor. Moyo
in her book, for example, only considers jobs and social development
as a third leg of an outcome of responsible Chinese investment, behind
economic imperatives and finance.35 Neither writer (perhaps due to the
economic discipline of it all) may not clearly reflect that we are in the
Information Age, competitiveness is defined by know-how and creativity,
not in how many natural resources a country has. If the latter were the
case, places like Congo and Burma would be the exemplar, not Singapore
and South Korea. Neither writer perhaps has ever lived in China to wit-
ness how runaway growth has an effect on unskilled citizens in that coun-
try under a one-party state, and how winners and losers are created with
economic development. They assume that HRD will naturally flow with
more and more investment. That may be a by-product, but it is certainly
not ensured. Jobs will only flow as long as there is commodity demand,
and set in government investment policy, and what quality of jobs will
ultimately determine a country’s place in the development order. For real
endogenous development, HRD must be mandated.
As far as can be observed, China’s resource-hungry investment model
attendant with its turnkey style of infrastructure development is not
actively promoting any information transfer in Africa (or any country) at
this time. It’s all about accessing resources with as little conflict as possible,
in areas that were previously prone to violent conflict, on China’s terms
for China’s long-term advancement. In this sense, Brautigams title of her
book The Dragons Gift may have been more prescient than ever realized.36
What we do know is that China has many hungry mouths to feed
and will for the near future. As China’s economic model of investment
via state-owned companies is about stability and not profits, a very dif-
ferent expectation of mission and vision results that is not driven by a
quarterly profit/loss statement but rather long-term access and utiliza-
tion of resources. China also has no mandated constraints unlike many
Western-backed institutions investing in developing countries from dem-
ocratic countries with governmental (International Finance Corporation
or EXIM, the Export Import Bank) or WB backing for CSR issues to
promote anything other than self-interest. It is not interested in CSR nor
development of locals, though it has issued good press.37
The Chinese government constantly stresses non-interference in other
countries’ ‘internal affairs’ (presenting a quid pro quo code for other
countries to not get to question China’s human rights record). Heavily
indebted countries with spotty human rights and environmental records
234 W. HICKEY
thus need China’s money, not the other way around. In China’s case,
that self-interest is in job creation for its (not the others) vast population
to create stability for the one-party state. The entire situation presents
an opportunity for resource exploitation without any changes in current
systems of governance or bad behaviors by unelected governments. China
needs to employ its masses, other countries have resources. On the surface,
it becomes a beneficial, symbiotic relationship. But it is certainly not bur-
densharing when one considers host country populations left behind or
locked-out of the work processes.
Chinese projects abroad, then, come with various strings attached, mostly
that being direct employment for their own SOE workers. Practically, all of
the developing countries China has invested in for both energy and infra-
structure projects have severe unemployment or underemployment issues.
Yet, their host governments continuously look askance, as they need the
development, financing, and expertise to complete the technology trans-
fer that is on the table, human resources and HRD are ignored. We con-
sider a few areas from developing regions around the world with Chinese
energy investment where the facts have been enumerated and tallied.
Ecuador
Over 1000 Chinese engineers and workers are building a dam in the
Amazon jungle with $2.2 billion in Chinese financing. Discussion is also
underway for China to build a $7 billion refinery complex in Manta on the
Pacific. Nonetheless, Ecuadorean workers have complained bitterly to the
Correa government about poor working conditions, unsafe conditions,
and low wages with no avail.38
South Sudan
South Sudan, the world’s newest country as of 2015 and flush with proven
oil reserves, accounts for 5 % of China’s total crude oil imports. China has
invested over $10 billion in South Sudan. Nonetheless, South Sudan still
remains a war-torn nation with a population of 4 million living mostly in
poverty that is constantly in need of humanitarian handouts. Its popu-
lation is largely bereft from its natural resources, and Chinese govern-
ment sees no need to intervene in this. Except for the fact that China has
recently sent 700 troops under the guise of UN peacekeepers to protect
its oil investments and workers.39
CHINA 235
Indonesia
A better example of China’s non-transparency regarding HRD may be
found in Indonesia, which has several Chinese-financed mega-projects for
energy and infrastructure. While Indonesia is also a developing country, it
is a newly emerging democracy with a vibrant free press, that has reported
on these issues and the Indonesian government’s inability to reign them
is due to bureaucratic inertia and elite interference in projects. A large
Chinese-financed hydro in West Java has been found clandestinely employ-
ing large numbers of Chinese workers, not only engineers but also down
to the ranks of manual labor. Indonesia is a large country with significant
unemployment problems among its own people.40
Sri Lanka
In order to gain some type of hegemonistic foothold in the Indian Ocean,
and to offset Indian and US interests, China has been particularly active in
Sri Lanka under the Rajapaksa era. Key Chinese-invested projects included a
Puttalam (Norcholai) coal-fired power plant, Colombo port expansion and
new TV tower, and a Hambantota deepwater port/international airport.
The leader who agreed to much of the Chinese investment in the mid-
2000s, Mahindra Rajapaksa, was upended in Feb. 2015 elections due to his
families’ perceived corruption and deep ties to all things China. Nonetheless,
the many projects he authorized are sunk investments by China of which
terms the original agreements are now being revisited by the new leadership.
The Norcholai coal power plant in Sri Lanka was built using a $455
million soft loan from China’s EXIM bank. Much of the construction
work was carried out by the China National Machinery Import and
Export Corporation, an SOE. In the entire project review report, there
is not a single mention of employment for locals, technology transfer, or
training.41 After extreme criticism in the press about a lack of employ-
ment opportunities in this project, the government responded by creating
a ‘tourism authority’ in the area to employ 15,000–20,000 locals.42 On
the economic scale, though, tourism jobs are far below the compensation
levels of any project for energy or infrastructure related employment.
What is important to note is that all the above Chinese projects listed
also utilize a plethora of Chinese labor with little quantifiable skills
transfer into a country largely beset with high levels of unemployment.
Immigration officials, similar to Indonesian ones, were accused of look-
ing the other way while Chinese workers arrived on tourist visas and took
away needed jobs from locals.
236 W. HICKEY
China Summary
China has emerged quickly to become a giant on the world stage for
both energy consumption and, conversely, emissions of carbon. With so
many people, high growth is expected for several years to come and world
demand for commodities driven by China’s development is du jour antici-
pated, any economic slowdowns will only be temporary.
Chinese leaders with their largely engineering mindsets and insular
focus on domestic political stability at all costs cannot afford to ignore
CHINA 237
HRD and only consider host country politics as purely, devoid of for-
eign interference, if they seek to be perceived as a sustainable actor on
the world stage. If China continues to do so, at the least they will be
perceived as opportunists, taking advantage of the economic woes of ‘beg-
gar nations’ with unlimited natural resources but limited know-how and
capital; with no allegiance to the host people or local culture as long as the
resources are flowing. At the worst, they will be regarded as new ‘hege-
monists’, transplanting the imperial British, and now the USA, as the new
reckoning power on the block who will use their neo-colonial practices for
maximum economic viability, including employing and developing their
own people first, in a type of inverse ‘human capital mercantilism’.
The former scenario gives some hope for HRD inputs, but the lat-
ter only reinforces the North–South problem, or should we say a new
‘East-South problem’ where developing countries are lackey nations, ripe
to be exploited for the pickings, by newly emerging economies with all
types of human rights, workplace, and environmental abuses. This may
sound overly harsh, but many of the leaders in China today grew up under
the socially brutal Cultural Revolution in the 1960s, where ‘Chairman
Mao’ flippantly told US Secretary of State Henry Kissinger in 1973 that
even if 500 million Chinese were killed in a nuclear strike by the West, he
still had another 500 million to throw into battle.48 These were dark times
of political excess in China, that never were seriously addressed or revisited,
unlike the US ‘Flower Power’ generation of the early 1970s or the removal
of the Berlin Wall in Germany in 1989, with the fall of the Soviet Union.
These macro identity issues certainly then feed into micro issues of eco-
nomics, consumption, and human rights, all issues which contextually deal
with the effectiveness of HRD. In short, any serious HRD initiative in a
host country has to be underpinned by significant human rights initiatives
and, of course, an appreciation of human resources. China currently does
have the high level technology and the ability available for infrastructure
and resource extraction, all the hardware if you will, but the mindset for
an appreciation of HRD, or software, seems lacking not only in China but
also in many other developing countries.
If the overarching view among China’s leadership is that it is now China’s
time to exploit as they were exploited in the past, it doesn’t say much for
future people development, but rather a ‘get even’ national mentality that
will seek to correct past injustices. This is not exaggerated. Recent actions by
China in the South and East China Seas, and statements from hardline mili-
tary generals and political mouthpiece newspapers such as Zhongguo Remin
Ribao Zhongguo Remin Ribao, (人民日报) have shown they are willing to
challenge the world’s Western-ordered status quo with the world powers and
238 W. HICKEY
Notes
1. Regarding China’s severe smog, see http://phys.org/news/2015-11-
china-smog.html
2. Nair, C. (2011) Consumptionomics: Asia’s Role in Reshaping Capitalism
and Saving the Planet , Oxford: John Wiley & Sons.
3. Nair, C. (2011) ibid.
4. http://www.iea.org/statistics/statisticssearch/report/?country=China&
product=indicators
5. http://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2015/07/24/business/interna-
tional/the-world-according-to-china-investment-maps.html?_r=0
6. Moyo, D. (2012) The Winner Takes All. China’s Race for Resources and
What it Means for the World. Basic Books and Brautigam URL http://www.
chinaafricarealstory.com/p/chinese-workers-in-africa-anecdotes.html
7. EIA, (2013) World Energy Statistics https://www.eia.gov/beta/interna-
tional/analysis.cfm?iso=CHN
8. Citing: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.CD?page=6
9. IEA, (2011). World Energy Statistics.
10. See Citing: http://image.guardian.co.uk/sys-files/Guardian/documents/
2011/02/10/CarbonWeb.pdf and http://www.huffingtonpost.com/
2014/12/05/a-handful-of-countries-co_n_6274064.html
11. In fact, the one-child policy has now been discontinued as of Oct. 2015 due
to a noticeable projection of a decline in the working-age population.
12. Many sources are readily available for all these statistics: http://www.abc.
net.au/radionational/programs/ockhamsrazor/there-are-not-enough-
resources-to-support-the-worlds-population/5511900 and http://news.
nationalgeographic.com/news/2014/09/140920-population-11billion-
demographics-anthropocene/ and http://news.nationalgeographic.com/
news/2014/09/140920-population-11billion-demographics-anthropo-
cene/
CHINA 239
13. http://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2015/07/24/business/interna-
tional/the-world-according-to-china-investment-maps.html
14. http://www.theguardian.com/world/2015/jan/08/china-venezuela-
20bn-loans-financing-nicolas-maduro-beijing and http://thediplomat.
com/2015/01/will-china-save-venezuela/
15. State Capitalism, The Economist 1/21/2012. (7 sections).
16. Contractor, F. (March, 2014) Reminbi Undervalued? Think Again. Yale
Global Online, URL: http://yaleglobal.yale.edu/content/renminbi-
undervalued-think-again
17. China US Focus (2015) http://www.chinausfocus.com
18. Hickey, W. (April, 2015) Nations Line Up to Join China-Led Infrastructure
Bank. Yale Global Online, http://yaleglobal.yale.edu/content/
nations-line-join-china-led-infrastructure-bank
19. Ashrad, S. (2015) AIIB – the Beginning of Economic Challenge to the
U.S. http://www.chinausfocus.com/finance-economy/aiib-the-beginning-
of-economic-challenge-to-the-u-s/
20. The World Bank cuts off funding for coal (2013) in Washington Post, July
17 article The World Bank cuts off funding for coal. How big an impact will
that have?
21. The Economist in its formidable work on ‘state capitalism’ Special Edition,
1/21/2012, has mentioned this issue.
22. This subject is very well worn among China watchers and economists. It
has not truly happened yet. See any of former Morgan Stanley’s Asia
Chairman and now Yale Professor, Stephen Roach’s work. http://www.
project-syndicate.org/commentary/china-embraces-its-new-growth-
model-by-stephen-s--roach?barrier=true
23. Xie, A. (Dec. 2015) For China’s struggling economy, 2016 may be worse
than 2015. South China Morning Post. URL: http://www.scmp.com/
comment/insight-opinion/ar ticle/1892643/chinas-struggling-
economy-2016-may-be-worse-2015
24. Economist, (2012) ibid.
25. Interview with Poyry General Manager in Puttalam, Sri Lanka, regarding
commissioning of the Chinese built Norcholai coal-fired power plant in 2009.
26. The Suramadu Bridge, connecting east Java with Madura island in Indonesia
if from a Chinese kit and took six years to build it. In ‘Suramadu, Power
Plants, and Trade Deficit, special report: China’ TEMPO, Sept. 27, 2015.
27. This is the case in the Hambantota airport in Sri Lanka and Chinese-
invested energy projects in Libya, where egomaniac leaders authorized
wasteful projects that China underwrote and still demands payment for.
28. Nisha Aruntilake, IPS Research fellow at a conference on Sri Lankan
Migration, Remittances, and Development 2009, in http://www.ips.lk/
events/workshops/4_5_09_development_nexus/island.pdf
29. Moyo, D. (2012) The Winner Takes All ibid.
30. Moyo, D. (2012) ibid., p. 3.
240 W. HICKEY
31. Brautigam, D. (2009) The Dragons Gift: The Real Story of China in Africa.
Oxford: Oxford University.
32. Announced in 2015, see http://venturesafrica.com/china-to-invest-
26bn-in-equatorial-guinea/
33. Pegg, S. (2012) Social responsibility and resource extraction: Are Chinese
oil companies different? Resources Policy 37(2) pp. 160–167. Sachs, J.
Common Wealth, also Moyo, D. Ibid., in URL: http://www.americanout-
look.org/dambisa-moyo-on-china-in-africa.html
34. Again, the Economist Special Edition (1/21/2012) about State Capitalism
tends to reinforce this viewpoint.
35. Moyo, D. (2012) ibid. and http://www.ted.com/talks/dambisa_moyo_
is_china_the_new_idol_for_emerging_economies#t-8018
36. Brautigam, D. (2009) ibid.
37. Pegg, S. (2012) ibid. and Jiang, J. and Sinton, J. (2011) Overseas Investments
by Chinese National Oil Companies, IEA (Int. Energy Agency, Feb.).
38. For many developing countries, see http://www.nytimes.com/2015/
07/26/business/international/chinas-global-ambitions-with-loans-and-
strings-attached.html?_r=0
39. http://oilprice.com/Energy/Crude-Oil/Violence-In-South-S udan-
Threatens-Chinese-Oil-Investment.html
40. Chinese Workers: Laboring Under Dubious Pretenses. Cover Story,
TEMPO English, Sept. 6, 2015, pp. 16–21.
41. See more on Chinese Investment in Sri Lanka since 2006, Democratic
Socialist Republic of Sri Lanka, Ministry of Plan Implementation,
Department of Foreign Aid and Budget Monitoring, Infrastructure Unit,
‘Project Review Report: Norcholai Power Plant Project’, July 27, 2006.
42. Media Center for the National Development of Sri Lanka, 2010.
43. Taylor, I. (2009). China’s New Role in Africa. Lynne Rienner Publishers.
ISBN: 978-1-58826-636-1.
44. Pegg, (2012) ibid., p. 166.
45. Tull, D. ( 2006). China’s engagement in Africa: scope, significance, and
consequences. Journal of Modern African Studies, 44(3), pp. 459–479 and
Taylor, I. (1998). China’s foreign policy toward Africa in the 1990s,
Journal of Modern African Studies 36, 3: 443–60.
46. Interview in Sri Lanka, ibid.
47. API and TAFE are the benchmarked international standards for oil and
mining projects, respectively.
48. Halliday, J. and Chang, J. (2005) Mao: The Unknown Story. Jonathon
Cape Publishers.
49. Napoleon quote to Sir Stamford Raffles (founder of Singapore) on a stop-
over at his exile in St. Helena in the South Atlantic, 1825, from Klingaman
W. and Klingaman, N. (2014) The Year Without Summer, 1816.
St. Martin’s Griffin: New York.
CHAPTER 9
bills can also blur the lines when time comes to authorizing the actual
procurement under secretive contractual conditions.16 Additionally, cen-
tralized contract signing power in the hands of a few people or one person
without technical expertise in a field to provide any type of oversight or
checks and balances can be easily manipulated by insiders.17
This type of ‘business as usual’ system then, institutionalized under a
neo-colonial extractive mindset of little involvement of host government
(i.e. at a racist baseline translation: locals, dumb; foreigners, smart), and
without any forensic auditing (where a third party actually reviews and
evaluates what was given) or educational evaluation (see HRD evaluation
section, Chapter 5) is ripe for all kinds of mischief and perfidy. This is
not to say that training does not have its applicability for a department, it
does, but it is generally not at a knowledge function, rather a rewards and
compensation function. This is an important distinction, as using training
as an incentive and not criterion-referenced goal in the organizations
capability process distort outcomes and violate the legitimacy of HRD.18
As this writer was told, ‘don’t do training here [on location], because
nobody will go to it, make it in some exotic locale or far off place, then
everyone will want to go’.19 Training then becomes synonymous with paid
vacations. Nonetheless, even if everyone goes and has a good time, the
training may not be necessary for any of the aforementioned reasons. As a
ubiquitous ‘client’ makes all final and authorized management decisions,
as stated, tenders are usually non-existent under a PSC.
Furthermore, the ‘client driven model’ world of oil, gas, and coal pro-
duction, so-called lootable resources controlled by elites,20 does nothing
to seriously enlist and develop local employees, but promotes patronage
and nepotism within the current neo-colonial framework. This is especially
reinforced in developing countries.21 Processes need to be clearly audited
forensically. What is the work? Can the employee actually do the work to
a world prescribed standard? If not, can they be trained to do it?22 And
further redefined frequently to reduce opportunities for corruption. Why
is this work being done? Who was contracted for it and why? What end
value does this work provides and to whom? Could this work have been
done more cheaply somewhere else in the organization or by tendering
work out to bid?. National policies call for ensuring that HRD will pro-
mote strategic investment as opposed to abusive investment (i.e. strip min-
ing, tar sands) and limit governmental interference (mainly local/ regional
governments) in an overall national development schematic.23
CORRUPTION AND THE CLIENT DRIVEN ENERGY MODEL 245
It should be noted that most oil and mining companies are required
by host governments to return some of their profits to the community via
CSR (corporate social responsibility) or obligatory localization initiatives.24
Nonetheless, these plans are sorely devoid of metrics to empower or gainfully
employ local populations. They are more about public relations and ‘meeting
the letter’ as opposed to the spirit of the law. Box ticking ensues, with not real
outcomes evaluated. Without empowerment (i.e. opportunities) these plans
are about social responsibility in word only. Further, these plans can be heavily
manipulated and filtered by both the state and corporate entities involved for
political reasons whereby little development progress is actually made.25
The EITI
The issue of the EITI or Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative, should
be considered here. EITI was founded in 2006 mostly in regard to taxation,
corporate accountability, and governmental transparency, here is its guiding
principle, from its own webpage:
3.5 billion people live in countries rich in oil, gas and minerals. With good
governance the exploitation of these resources can generate large revenues
to foster growth and reduce poverty. However, when governance is weak,
it may result in poverty, corruption, and conflict. The Extractive Industries
Transparency Initiative (EITI) aims to strengthen governance by improving
transparency and accountability in the extractives sector.
alone will translate into better civil society and by extension, develop-
ment.29 This approach, while well meaning, is misguided. HRD requires
specific goals and linkage to resources, not just platitudes.
One aspect, however, buried deep in the reports regarding EITI and
audits is that while the final numbers tally on what companies pay and
what governments actually receive may reconcile, the devil is in the details.
There are significant shortcomings, and weaknesses in the types of finan-
cial accounting used in the processes. These deficiencies in law, taxation,
cost accounting, and PSAs can lead to short changing the society. All
meaning inadequate public management of the data with outdated or mis-
understood IT causes informational deficiencies. Of a special note is the
‘high unit costs’ of production in resource extraction. This gets to the core
of the PSA discussed in Chapter 7, where reimbursements on expensive,
untendered parts and services, including training, question the real value
to the host country of these expenses.30
Minimizing Corruption
Corruption is not going to go away or disappear anytime soon, no matter
how good the public initiatives or slogans to stamp it out are. The money
is just too large, especially in regard to energy mega-projects with secre-
tive financial terms to handicap corruption opportunities. The old adage
of crime pays rings true. However, the most brazen corruption (bribery,
rent-seeking, graft, nepotism)31 can be minimized or ring-fenced if proper
containment is in place that reduces the opportunities for corruption, see
Figure 9.1. HRD must not be used as a conduit enabling corruption to
flourish via ethereal and ambiguous practices, but rather as a guiding force
for human development.
This book expresses a different path forward than the EITI in deal-
ing with corruption in addition to the ‘naming and shaming’ initiatives
and through publication of financial transactions (following the money),
that is, having mandated and educational initiatives and empowered hiring
outcomes embedded in all investment contracts with initial workforce
assessments. Of course this can only be via a national policy promoting
this. As stated in Chapter 7, Norway had utilized this model creating a
strong policy that ensures relevant know-how transfer via aligned institu-
tions, investors, and local hiring outcomes for a ‘Norwegians first’ policy.32
Without an implemented policy to promote localization, much of the dis-
cussions in this book are pointless and it becomes an idealistic treatise. It
CORRUPTION AND THE CLIENT DRIVEN ENERGY MODEL 247
simply cannot be the same old business as usual model being promulgated in
today’s information world. Educational outcomes and hiring empowerment
must go hand in hand, they cannot be detached, exclusive silo domains, or
corruption will maintain its foothold (i.e. participants get the education, but
are still passed over for insiders with ‘connections’) as corruption seeks out
gaps and thrives on information deficiencies in a well-protected and insular
system. As mentioned consistently in this work, outcomes can only be had
or insisted upon if a knowledgeable educational expert also sits at the table
as an equal during the contract negotiations with the leaders, engineers, and
finance people. This is the only way forward in the information age as was
discussed in Chapter 7. Proxies for education alone can’t do this, the infor-
mation age demands that education directly be heard.
Empowerment means there is an ensured hiring placement once the
skills are derived and obtained. This is a ‘defined outcome’. Skills in this
case means not only cognitive and psychometer skills, but also the affec-
tive (attitude) skills that round out the job competency. In this case, the
248 W. HICKEY
companies cannot default and claim they simply cannot find anyone quali-
fied due to cultural differences, or other subjective reasons, and so on that
are essentially ascribed to affective differences in culture, when the real
goal all along is not bringing in qualified people but in securing in-house
proprietary advantages. In the long run, this will also have significantly
more impact than playing the same financial game of aggregate unaudited
line-item expenditures (which can be manipulated) on a balance sheet.33
Thus while transparency is important to identify where the money is going,
to be truly effective it must be formatively audited with the workplace actions
in processes as ever changing metrics and subject matter validity are constant.
Transparency alone is not enough, nor is education, both must be under-
pinned by empowerment, namely an ensured job placement once the skills
(affective, cognitive, and psychometer) are demonstrated. If employees are
truly hired based on skills and technical proficiency then, it will increase orga-
nizational efficiency and lower operating costs. Of course this is the ideal, and
entrenched interests with old ways of doing business (and enjoying the many
perks from these old ways) will not want to update this or change the ways of
the ‘client driven model’ in any form if they simply don’t have to.
Summary
To sum up then, corruption is as old as mankind, it cannot be stopped
overnight, or with any well-intentioned programs bereft of mandates and
enforcement. Left unchecked or unmitigated, corruption has horrible
consequences. It shortchanges societies. It benefits a few well-connected
insiders (elites) but fuels inequality and conflict over resources, trapping
large and uneducated population groups in a never-ending vicious cycle
of demoralizing poverty. The sums of money involved, and gaps in pro-
cedures and authority will always provide opportunities for corruption or
the blurring of ethical lines. HRD, due to its ethereal nature under lead-
ers with a mindset of engineering and finance, cannot simply be allowed
as another channel for other non-technical ‘activities’ in an organization.
Only with a robust national policy initiative where HRD (educators and
development people) sit at the negotiation table as equals with finance, regu-
lators, and engineering can HRD be prioritized and appreciated. Norway is
one such model that prioritized HRD and localization. On the world’s least
corrupt country index, Norway sits very high. Publishing financial transac-
tions in an index, such as EITI initiatives, is only one way to minimize cor-
ruption. Education is also a valid design. To truly ‘ringfence’ corruption, in
CORRUPTION AND THE CLIENT DRIVEN ENERGY MODEL 249
particular for HRD, relevant education that is clearly aligned with business
drivers must be utilized,34 and then empowered hiring outcomes ensured by
policy. That being, people with the appropriate job competencies and skills
are assured an actual job placement in the organization and not passed over
due to cultural or political issues. Then the overall system becomes more
transparent and fair to all. Trust is built, which leads to social capital forma-
tion, eventually driving corruption into the corner.
Notes
1. Michael Ross, ‘Does Oil Hinder Democracy?’ (World Politics (53: 3), April
2001), pp. 325–61, Karl, T. (1997). The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and
Petro-States. Stanford: University of California Press., and Mikesell, R.
(1997) Explaining the Resource Curse, with Special Reference to Mineral-
Exporting Countries’, Resources Policy 23(4).
2. Leonard Wantchekon, ‘Why do Resource Dependent Countries Have
Authoritarian Governments?’ (Yale University Research Papers, December
12, 1999); and Gelb, A. et al. (1988) Windfall Gains: Blessing or
Curse? (New York: Oxford University Press).
3. EITI, (2011). Achievements and Strategic Options. Final Report,
Scanteam: Oslo, Norway, p. 170.
4. Dave, B. (2003) Kazakhstan: Countries in Transition. UNPAN Report,
p. 3.
5. See: http://www.nytimes.com/2015/08/09/business/international/
effects-of-petrobras-scandal-leave-brazilians-lamenting-a-l ost-dream.
html?_r=0 and http://www.forbes.com/sites/kenrapoza/2015/04/04/
how-much-of-brazils-economy-got-lost-in-petrobras-scandal/#469863
75432c.
6. Freeport and international copper and gold producer, has large operations
in Indonesia. Recently its president and speaker of the Indonesian house
were implicated in a corruption scandal. In Tempo English, url: http://
en.tempo.co/read/news/2016/01/19/056737369/Freeport-Indonesia-
President-Director-Maroef-Sjamsoeddin-Resigned.
7. See: http://www.reuters.com/article/us-venezuela-politics-idUSKCN0VB26F.
8. Azerbaijan devaluation: http://www.theguardian.com/world/2015/
dec/22/azerbaijan-currency-plummets-oil-price.
9. The largess is questionable. Even with collapsing oil prices below $28 a
barrel, the good times continue: http://www.bloomberg.com/news/
articles/2016-02-12/the-oil-industry-got-together-and-agreed-things-
may-never-get-better.
250 W. HICKEY
Peace Studies (SIWPS) Working Paper No. 10 and Pinto and Zhu, 2009;
and see Luo, Y. (2006) ‘Political Behavior, Social Responsibility, and
Perceived Corruption: A Structural Perspective’, Journal of International
Business Studies, 37: 747–766.
24. Some mining and oil companies are required to give back a portion of their
profits to local communities. Nonetheless, oversight can be lax, and cor-
ruption ensues. For example, one tribal chieftain because the conduit for a
major coal companies entire social obligation disbursement. This can cre-
ate patronage and kickbacks.
25. Papua province in Indonesia is home to rich mining resources, the govern-
ment under President Jokowi has stressed development of this area and
people power, however regional authorities in this area are not always so
inclined to honor these central government mandates. See: http://www.
thejakartapost.com/news/2015/12/30/jokowi-presses-ahead-with-
papua-tour-despite-violence.html
26. EITI, p. 8.
27. EITI, p. iv.
28. Civil Society Legislative Advocacy Centre.
29. EITI, (2011) Final Report, p. 193 Scanteam, Norway.
30. EITI, ibid., p. 190 and p. 185 concerning PSCs. And Rutledge, I. (2004)
The Sakalhin II PSA: A Production ‘Non-Sharing’ Agreement. Sheffield
Energy and Resource Information Services (SERIS). URL (consulted July
2011): http://www.bothends.info/mfi/dos3-SakhalinPSA.pdf.
31. Ades, A., and Di Tella, R. (1999) ‘Rents, Competition and Corruption’.
American Economic Review 4(9): 982–994.
32. Gylfason, T. (2008). ‘Norway’s wealth: Not just oil’ URL: http://www.
voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/1199.
33. http://www.transparency.org/topic/detail/oil_and_gas.
34. This comes from Porter’s Diamond model, where HR is one facet of clus-
ter competitiveness. Porter, M. (1998) On Competition. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press.
CHAPTER 10
The Interface
and that societal gainshare aligns with their long-term interests as well. The
interface consists of a new rework of the energy business for better human,
environmental, and eventual social capital development.2 An interface cre-
ates a new, first-step roadmap toward viewing energy as a strategic and rich
prerogative toward societal development that must be front and center of
an advanced socio-dynamic mindset. The interface is about integration of
change into processes, in this case, energy and human development in the
context of today’s Information Age.
Simply put, like DNA strands, human resources needs to be intertwined
with energy resources in today’s world, as it is more urgently needed than ever
before. As previously stated, only energy can deliver the necessary economies
of scale needed to lift the vast billions in poverty on our overcrowded planet
due to its enormous revenues and all-encompassing nature. In this case, this
energy source is still overwhelmingly, for better or worse, fossil fuels. As 88 %
of the world’s energy is still sourced from burning the carbon centered mol-
ecule, all economic and development issues and activity must inculcate all
aspects of fossil fuels, from gas to coal. At least for now. Renewables and
nuclear energy simply cannot deliver the aggregate baseload power reliably
that the world, and in particular developing countries, demand.
are limited access order or a natural state and have not moved into open-
access rule of law societies. This means transactions (contracts) are based on
personal relationships, not on a rule of law that enforces those contracts.4
Of course this construct by no way benefits the majority of society, only
selected people who have the ‘right’ then to form the contractual arrange-
ments that are recognized by the state (this is the situation most developing
countries find themselves in). In other words, it is the elites and their vested
interests (and military, as a complementary partner) that gain the most to
keep the social order of the nation-state in place in developing countries.
Perhaps a new formulation of governance and the governed will be the
result of future changes. It is highly possible that in a few centuries, many will
look back on the millennia of the developing nation-state and reconsider what
people thought about failed governance and self-determination then.
The problem with the nation-state then is in a system that forces them
to look inwards as opposed to outwards politically, socially, and economi-
cally. It doesn’t consider what its neighbors are doing in any collaborative
effort, but rather as a competitive one, for all things considered: money, mil-
itary power, resources, exports, and even currency values. Perhaps a reason
ASEAN and by extension the EU periphery states, like Hungary and Baltics,
are fundamentally weak is that they fail to address different motivations in
outside nation-states by tying them altogether in a regional cooperative.
For energy and HRD then to be predicated on a foundation of the
developing country nation-state contexted in an information-intensive
and mobile world may be working at cross-purposes. Again, this is not
expected to change anytime soon, and we make no illusions of that, but if
we are speaking of grandiose change to alleviate vast differences in much of
the world (poverty, skills, climate change initiatives) we must address root
causes, sometimes falling outside the system, but very much reinforces
it. Much of this is defined in Peter Senge’s groundbreaking book The
5th Discipline,5 where systems are extremely difficult, if not impossible, to
change without any outside intervention.
are very simple analyses of these great works and shouldn’t be taken out of
context, they were originally written for business management.
The idea of systems thinking, however, is not new to resource extrac-
tion and economics issues. It was founded by Dr. Jay Forrester at MIT in
the 1950s who was later invited to the Club of Rome to ask if this system
could be used for modeling to predict availability of oil resources with eco-
nomic growth into the future.7 Namely, systems thinking states that the
structure of any system is just as important in predicting behavioral out-
comes as the individual actors themselves. The world is currently rooted in
a consumption-based system that heavily depends on fossil fuel resources
for all economic activity and future growth.
This is not idealism or hyperbole in any sense, but simply for real
change and cooperation to occur, the concept of the ultimate precon-
ception denominators of nation-state will eventually have to be put to
the test and challenged. Competitive advantage forces the zero-sum game
imperative (I win/you lose), as it pits countries against each other on a
national sense. The ‘Occupy’ movement of the past few years has ampli-
fied this issue of losers and winners.8 A question is, can we afford in the
world that we live in today to be training and educating people to ‘race
to the top’ or should we be educating people to ‘work together’ in a
very finite physical world with limited resources that is facing considerable
legacy problems of inequality and environmental degradation?9 ‘Working
together’ means effectively integrating HRD at the ‘micro level’ into the
system on a big picture ‘macro level’. This is done via the ‘meso level’ of
economic development. In other words, we are defining where exactly the
rubber of HRD meets the road of macro-economic activity.
The Tangibles
The Information Age
With the above said, we are now in the golden age of instantaneous infor-
mation. Information is power. Information is disruptive. Information is
dangerous. Ideas and media can be conveyed ‘virally’ from one corner of
the globe to the next instantaneously. People know all about politics, living
standards, culture, corruption, currency values, even blue prints for nuclear
bombs, and so on right away. Nothing is hidden in this era, if it is, it is not
obscured for long. There are no ‘Black Boxes’. Methods for making Apple
cell phones, Intel semiconductors, even Pfizer pharmaceuticals, like Viagra,
Celebrex, or Lipitor can quickly be disassembled, broken down, and re-
258 W. HICKEY
Global Warming
Which brings us to the high-noon showdown with climate change, the
looming elephant in the room in regard to changing old energy habits
versus the tried and true economic playbook of exporting raw materials
from developing to developed countries for value-added finished products
and services in place. The year 2015 was the hottest year in recorded
human history, and as of January 2016 the hottest January ever recorded.
As stated in Chapter 4, the world is hopelessly addicted to the fossil fuel
model and it’s all encompassing system, which is slowly and most assur-
edly destroying our planet, that is if we believe what the climate and envi-
ronmental scientists, not the politicians, are telling us. It’s not only them
telling us, even the major oil companies, insurers, and militaries of the
developed world are preparing for it.
Nonetheless, while the skills and urgency are there to develop renewable
and alternative sources of energy, the political willpower and investment/
financial crowd is lacking in its participation beyond merely ‘show efforts’
for publicity. In practically every developing country with resources, the
predominate FDI clamors for access to the natural resource business, not
investments in T-Shirt factories, handbag boutiques, or beach hotels.
They simply don’t care about those businesses on an economy of scale
level. Manufacturing highly competitive plastic accessories cannot nearly
generate the magnitude of profit an oil reservoir or open pit coal mine
260 W. HICKEY
can, when it comes to billion dollar investments. Money drives the mood,
urgency, and necessity.
The all-encompassing mindset of ‘financial returns’ then dictates the
pace and investment terms in energy resources predominantly. Oil and
coal are still being burned in enormous quantities every day, with more
demand expected. All of this is working at cross-purposes to climate
change initiatives, and the fact that the world is on its way to quickly burn-
ing through its carbon bank and blowing past 2o C. It is not being talked
about in IPCC circles either that 2.7 C is a now more realistic target as
most nations simply cannot slow down their fossil fuel addiction and are
betting their development on it anew.
Recently, an idea among the IMF, UN, and OECD that has been floated
is a carbon tax, with the proceeds going to help developing countries pre-
pare and deal with climate change. As discussed in Chapter 4, a possible
mechanism for dealing with global warming is a tax on carbon. On the
surface, this is an excellent idea. However, there are a few further caveats
that bear notice. Many developing countries have high levels of corruption.
Further, the trend is towards human development for the information age.
For a tax to be truly reflective and supportive of this issue, it must go to skills
building, not to high salaries and overhead administration for bureaucrats,
nor recycled back to Wall St. and other Western financial vehicles for ‘greater
returns’ as is happening with SWFs. Any climate change tax proceeds then
must have education specialists sitting at the table as equals, to ensure that
skills transfer for the development and awareness of climate change initia-
tives reach as many people as possible. Unfortunately, in countries with high
levels of corruption this may be too idealistic and unworkable. Additionally,
those in developed countries paying the tax have been well apprised of the
corruption in developing countries, such as Nigeria and Venezuela, and
would be loathe for their money to go to fund more malbehaviors and out-
right corruption. In fact the issue may be dead in the water.
As long as money and the status quo of the nation-states’ competitive-
ness depends on more exports of fossil fuels it will be perhaps impossible
to integrate new and renewable energies, with attendant mindset changes,
on a broad capacity scale. It’s certainly not a skills deficiency. People can
be trained to service and maintain these businesses to an exemplary level,
with many knock-on effect jobs, but the political willpower is still lacking.
Unfortunately, integrating this segment of new energy with people may
require several catastrophic events with a large loss of life to convince lead-
ers they MUST change their old ways.
THE INTERFACE 261
Labor Costs
Finance is all about showing one (and investors) the money. Development
of projects has been curtailed in some locales due to high development
costs. This is a tricky issue. Most of the world’s ‘easy’ oil and gas has
already been had over the past 50 years. Now, we are dealing with ‘tight’
(hard to get at) oil and unconventional oil and gas projects. Additionally,
much of the oil is in politically and environmentally inhospitable places.
For example, Mahakam, Tupi, and Sakhalin are all high-cost fossil fuel
megaprojects under the PSC (Production Sharing Contract) concept in very
remote areas near large, impoverished populations. Mahakam11 is a giant gas
block off the coast of eastern Kalimantan (formerly Borneo), Indonesia.
Tupi is the pre-salt deepwater offshore discovery in the Brazilian territory
of the Atlantic Ocean.12 Sakhalin in far Eastern Siberia near Kamchatka is a
major gas project, administered by Royal Dutch Shell.13 All three employ, or
will employ, high-cost, specialized, foreign labor that will be used to develop
and operate these projects. This foreign labor, under the PSC arrangement
will, business as usual, be reimbursed fully out of the production oil. Very
little money will flow straightaway to national coffers due to these expensive
front-loaded labor costs. Few will complain about this arrangement, or even
know whom to complain to if they wanted to.
A different way forward is proposed. Developing local talent to administer
and develop these projects on a dedicated, evaluated, and mandated time-
line with the international oil companies. Of course this has been proposed
before, specifically with some developing countries ‘industrial nationalization’
plans of the 1990’s but we add two additional conditions beyond ‘dedicated’:
evaluated (that means skills actually being transferred to locals) and mandated
(that means locals will actually be hired for empowered operational and main-
tenance jobs, not merely token or political jobs) on these projects. If this can
be successfully implemented, the labor cost savings via guaranteed reimburse-
ments to foreign specialists would be astronomical. But there is a deeper rea-
son: that being, the locals would now actually be engaged on a value-added
level in their own strategic industry. Idealistic? No. This is representative of
the Norwegian North Sea oil model. Possible? It will depend on how far the
national governments go to enforce and interpret ‘mandated’. This is a sticky
issue in many developing countries. Empowerment initiatives could backfire
in that they may create people emboldened to take on and challenge the gov-
ernment. In many cases, the same governments that are autocratic, arbitrary
and unresponsive to their people’s needs.14
262 W. HICKEY
State Capitalism
State capitalism,15 similar to fossil-fueled political mindsets, requires a
dearth of information and non-transparency to support its construct.
SOEs, are simply not competitive, by their nature are status quo, and
usually mediocre in performance when contrasted with for-profit com-
panies facing competition. Consider what happens to the share price of
a stock when a government nationalizes (takes over) a company (a bank,
an oil business, or a utility), the share price immediately collapses. Why is
that? In a stable business, the revenue streams are still maintained (such as
a utility providing electricity to households or savings services depositors
in a bank). Simply because the government takes an entity over, does not
mean that any underlying revenues dissipate. Nonetheless, the share price
collapses as investors signal lost faith in the company’s management, effi-
ciency, ability and performance. They simply do not trust a state-owned
management system to be as motivated, efficient, and competitive as a
comparable business in the private sector.16 A partial exception to this is
monopoly enterprise, for example, in oil, banking, utilities, insurance, or
telecommunications where a state-owned operator reaps enormous rev-
enue singularly, but customer expectations and service become distant
secondary concerns.
The very large and insidious corruption scandal that has recently
shaken Brazilian state-owned oil giant Petrobras would seem to confirm
much of investors’ skepticism about how hard change is in SOEs. Even
though Petrobras still is the monopoly player in the Brazilian oil business,
and retail customers pay millions of dollars every day for its product, its
share price has drastically collapsed, and there is now the real possibility
Petrobras may default on its bonds. In a publicly traded company, manage-
ment would have been thrown out and a house cleaning (firing employees
who were underperforming or unnecessary) would have ensued. But in
state-owned company, the positions and managers are largely protected,
the status quo continues above all else, and it is very difficult to fire or
remove workers. SOEs are simply a different animal regarding perfor-
mance and efficiency. Many SOEs exist or are mandated in the energy
and infrastructure sector, mostly on grounds of ‘national interest’ such as
PDSVA, the giant Venezuelan oil SOE. But the reality is that state-owned
companies, with enormous revenue flows due to monopolistic practices
and government favoritism, are all about employment for social stability,
not profits. Nepotistic employment promotes patronage and correspond-
THE INTERFACE 263
Education
Today, education has become the Fifth Column for changing age-old
held beliefs in energy finance, production, transmission, and use. We have
already demonstrated in Chapter 5, with HRD mechanisms, that short-
term training and competency development can close the know-how gap
for many direct job-related tasks and day-to-day management functions.
Yet, that does not answer questions concerning nationwide educational
mandates and overall political direction. The past several years have seen
education in much of the developing world become more of a feudal
stronghold than a way forward for societal development.17 Old methods
die slowly, if at all.
Educators who do not understand change or fast-moving information
technologies can become more inclined to hold onto their statist positions
as opposed to creating any student advancement initiatives. Stakeholders
(educators) then become more important than clients (students), which
is a classic problem of management/ownership asymmetry. Change is
necessary to bring these old systems (especially ones built on a colonial
past such as in Malaysia, Indonesia, Angola, or from a Marxist past, such
as the former USSR states) into the twenty-first century, but political
blockades are omnipresent. Teachers and educational administrations in
large state-run universities and colleges carry political clout with leaders
in national capitals, students do not. Change becomes necessary but is
demonstrably slow and painful with far too many impediments.
The importance of strategic and current secondary education for youth
development and their long-term opportunities from this development
cannot be overstated. Any national accreditation must be all about aiding
and abetting the strategic development of a nation’s youth in line with its
industrial drivers, or core industry in that society in order to highlight a
country’s real economy and for national development.
Sorely, this is not being done, some developing countries are putting
nationalistic directives on learning obscure languages, religion, or long-
264 W. HICKEY
held cultural beliefs that do not integrate at all with the demands of mod-
ern industry. Simply put, this may be politically well intentioned, but it is
economically destructive, and will stunt endeavors in creating value-added
capacity. Countries simply cannot afford educational development that is
not in tune with the current investment and economic drivers of the coun-
try, that being the energy and resource industry in most of them.
For example, in the coal industry, the FMC (Full Maintenance Contract),
outsources a plethora of long-term, well-compensated jobs to mining equip-
ment vendors for the maintenance of their equipment. These contracts are
not small numbers, and can be in the hundreds of millions of US dollars.
Most of the value-added and high-end proprietary maintenance techniques
are then held tightly by these vendors, usually Western foreign multination-
als which demand large dollar payments for machinery upgrade and upkeep.
Generally, only lower level vocational skills, such as cleaning, moving,
simple repairs, and replacing parts, are then transferred to locals, or the
‘crumbs off the table’. The reflexivity is that of a high reliance then on for-
eign equipment and vendors/contractors in national coal mining industries.
This money needs to be channeled more strategically: Away from turnkey
FMCs and to strategic development initiatives in the educational ministries
that are working in tandem with industrial patrons. It could be done, again,
if proper incentives toward strategic education are aligned correctly in a
national development policy, as we have seen in Chapter 7, Localization,
the Norwegian model of skills development insists on the longitudinal
transferring of industrial skills in the extractive contracts to Norwegians.18
Massification (market demand for higher education by the masses) of
education in the developing world, particularly in Africa, is thriving.19 The
youth of many in Asia and Africa are already speaking out about their
future needs.20 More strategic education is needed, and it is needed now.
One developing country that has done this particularly well is China,
which has insisted (and mandated) know-how and skills transfer initia-
tives in their universities with foreign investments across a vast spectra of
industry, not just energy.21
Yet, a narrow handful of elite schools cannot be the only provider for
empowered tertiary education initiatives for all in any given country.22
Populations and economies are growing exponentially (the world is on
track to hit 10 billion people by 2035!), which needs enlightened man-
power to maintain and create new ideas. This would also go a long way to
create value-added entrepreneurial activity, which many developing coun-
try government support. Without this ‘spreading the risk’, the economies
stagnate with any downturn in exports of commodity-based resources
THE INTERFACE 265
The Intangibles
Table 10.2 Tycoons who could positively influence energy policy and develop-
ment via an investment perspective (Source: Hickey)
Person Net individual worth (controls) Investing specialty
company
money, power, and politics and thus those that can seed real change is
undeniable (Table 10.2).
Warren Buffett26 has invested considerably in the fossil fuel industry
in the past several years. Recently he has divested from Exxon Mobil, not
because he is opposed to the fossil fuel model, but rather Exxon Mobil has
failed to yield better returns with collapsing oil prices. Buffett’s Berkshire
Hathaway corporation also has many other investments either in fossil
fuels or business that supports the fossil fuel industry. His investments
in alternative energy is lacking, to say the least, unless one considers a
company such as GE, which he is also heavily invested in, via their wind
turbines. It is doubtful that Buffett gives much thought to whether or not
the energy investment are fossil fuel or renewable, he is simply interested
in the financial returns. In spite of this viewpoint, Buffett still commands
a large world following, people listen to him.
Ray Dalio is an amazing investor. Dalio is the founder of the world’s
biggest hedge fund firm, Bridgewater Associates, which now manages
$155 billion27 and is considered one of the most 100 influential people in
the world today, not for fossil fuels or alternative energies, but for under-
standing business cycles in bull and bear (up and down) markets. Dalio is
most famous for his 2008 publication How the Economic Machine Works;
A Template for Understanding What Is Happening Now. George Soros
and his theorem on reflexivity in systems.28 Similar to Senge’s systems
thinking, Soros theory of reflexivity is about positive feedback loops that
can quickly become negative feedback loops due to mass psychology in
short order. Soros used this theory for much of his investing and it has paid
off well for him. In essence, societies become more knowledgeable about
the world and methods around them, causing specific predictable behaviors
268 W. HICKEY
Case Study: Sri Lanka and the Potential for a Downstream Energy
Development Hub
Sri Lanka is a former British colonial island nation and a developing
country in the Indian Ocean. It has recently elected a new leader after
several years of a destructive civil war between Sinhalese and Tamils.
They badly need to develop localized industry and Chinese investment
has been pouring in, unfortunately this investment is mostly turnkey
investment in power plants and infrastructure, with limited localization
effectiveness. Sri Lanka has no commodity-based natural resources out-
side of fishing, tea, and a very finite gem industry in its highlands.
Michael Porter’s concept of ‘cluster competitiveness’ suggests
development of strategic industry based on the diamond model of
(continued)
270 W. HICKEY
(continued)
human resources, government, policy, infrastructure, and economic
incentives for a given industry. In this case, it is Sri Lanka’s strategic
geographic position with its deepwater ports, highly educated engi-
neers, and growing world demand for refining capacity that would
place it in the win column for developing downstream refinery
business. The concept is to align effective workforce development
practices toward this, for both domestic consumption and export
of higher-value finished products. A proper benchmark would be
comparable refinery development in Singapore and Korea. Like Sri
Lanka, neither country has commodity-based resources. They must
use their know-how to succeed, and both their government’s poli-
cies have been favorable toward this. Singapore is the largest refiner
in Asia, and Korea has a burgeoning export model of polyvinyl
extrusions (plastics) from oil. These businesses can only be enacted
with knowledgeable employees. Sri Lanka is in an opportune time
in its history to do this, as it can only build up. Its location next to
India and with growing demand from other Bay of Bengal countries
makes this initiative a win/win for all. This growing demand pres-
ents a possible competitive advantage for Sri Lanka due to its strate-
gic location, knowledgeable employees, and low-cost labor.
Here are the potential benefits of developing a cluster competitive-
ness approach to refining in Sri Lanka, in short, many knowledge
competencies could be built that would create a national advantage:
‘Facebook’ Future
The fossil fuel model in developing countries depends on implicit gov-
ernment financial guarantees for investment outlays. This all sounds very
reasonable... in another era. In the twenty-first century, any resource-rich
developing state should not be in the business of guaranteeing reimburse-
272 W. HICKEY
ments on fossil projects or any other type of soft producer fuel subsidies for
energy. This is a core reason in that PSC’s are no longer relevant in today’s
knowledge age. Consider that the social networking site Facebook, received
a $100 billion market valuation when it went public based on the value of
an incipient idea only (that is very little tangible hardware was noted) in
2012.33 There was no predicated business model or any realized profits at
first. Facebook never received guarantees from any government entity to
produce anything. Their profits were never ‘assured’, it was a pure venture
capital (VC) arrangement. $100 billion is a lot of money, it’s more money
than the GDP of many developing countries, and many combined at that!
So how did Facebook ever garner this extreme market capitalization? It
was based on a ‘perceived future value’ of the project in the eyes of inves-
tors of a publicly traded company. To be clear, Facebook originally was
only an idea and algorithm that people were investing in at the time.
Not tangible capital equipment, realized cash flows on future commod-
ity resources, or bidding on territorial leases for deep-sea blocks offshore.
This is an important distinction: in energy cases, collateral is offered for
the investment, whereby Facebook (and many other players in the infor-
mation age: Google, Uber, Twitter, Baidu, etc.) was ethereal. They are only
offering ideas, in the ‘clouds’ and yet they can raise billions of dollars.34
As there was no measurable physical collateral (property, equipment, rolling
stock), perhaps all of Facebook’s tangible assets at the time could have filled
two rooms with computers and servers. The point being is that if the markets
are willing to assign astronomical, untested monetary values on entities with no
assets and no profits, how much more value should the markets assign to enti-
ties with collateralized assets, on needed finite, non-renewable energy products
that move the planet with a commodity price, as mentioned above?
That is the way it should be in investments with a transparent and level
playing field. Nonetheless PSCs tend to tilt the investment decisions toward
the worse, not the better, regarding transparency and cash outlays. In other
words, with government backstops in hand investors will then do things
they normally shouldn’t. Whether it be excessive risk-taking, or, untendered
bidding, or asymmetric information (information that insiders act on with-
out informing investors), or awarding eight-year contracts to questionable
vendors, good decisions are not manifest. By their nature then PSCs work
against competitiveness in any project, similar to state-owned companies,
where jobs are guaranteed for life, with little threat of repercussion for
incompetence or poor performance. Neither can stand forever when more
competent and motivated people are able to man the ship.
THE INTERFACE 273
So one might ask, what then exactly is the purpose of the PSC in the
information age we are in today, where good projects and ideas can attract
money on their own (without state guarantees) via VC (venture capital) or
eager investors (who are willing to take risks, albeit big ones)? Simply the
government guarantees are a remnant of an immediate post-colonial era,
and must be stopped. They are totally unnecessary in today’s information
era. It cannot be financial business as usual. Project guarantees also prevent
development of entrepreneurism (of which many governments today say
they strongly support in their educational institutions), localization (where
there is no need to create or develop local vendors if the same insiders are
consistently recycled), and CSR (if the same outcomes are already decided,
who cares?). Change is necessary, and not an optional pathway, restructur-
ing cannot occur if guarantees for old behaviors are in place.
We have got to get past the point of PSC’s being insurance for politi-
cal risks, as opposed to being reimbursements for actual cash outlays on
money-making projects that were made with good due diligence.
Insular Politics
The last barrier then to application of the interface is in overcoming politics
rooted in systems that are insular and stubbornly refuse to recognize (because
the system itself is self-contained and self-reinforcing) the emerging big pic-
ture of our world’s mega-trends: Overpopulation, climate change, youth
unemployment, human capital, and mobility. If governments continue to
ignore these vast and fast-moving paradigms in order to protect localized
elites and their interests, they only continue to perpetuate and calcify an old
system that has failed to change and cannot change on its own accord. In
the Information Age, such a mindset will be going directly against the civil
society trends it portends to represent. It requires political will and inter-
vention to change. Perhaps even scrapping the entire current system to deal
with leviathan public-goods problems.35 To be blunt, if not pithy, Britannica
no longer rules the Seven Seas: the sun sets. Americans cannot ‘have it all’,
without impinging on others’ very survival and subsistence. China is not
the center of the world, despite its name saying it is.36 Change is not easy,
but is necessary for the planet and humanities very survival. The tools are
there, but the political will is now required to utilize the tools and develop
mindsets necessary to accept reality.
As strange as it may sound to some, using highly intelligent incarcer-
ated prisoners may be a possible first step in creating ideas to deal with
274 W. HICKEY
climate change and systems rethink of the entire fossil fuel model when
processes and politics stymie change initiatives. Consider the following
when dealing with prisoners:
In many cases it took the entire resources of the state to bring one
individual to justice. This is a powerful statement. While the criminals
were eventually apprehended on the street, many had an ‘absolute’ advan-
tage one-on-one against any singular police officer. They could only be
brought in under a collective ‘comparative’ advantage by an entire police
effort. Trying to break the gridlock of the current system will require
outside ideas that are not part of the ongoing problem, systems and pro-
cesses that created them in the first place.
These criminals, especially those with a long-term incarceration, will have
no hidden short-term political agenda. They have no political constituency
to please, or a well-endowed benefactor. They are prisoners. Most have
nothing, and nothing to lose, thus they are a fully impartial, apolitical entity.
Consider that the incarcerated in a prison (a forced arrangement, not a
voluntary one) spend all their waking hours trying to figure out how to ‘break
the rules’, circumvent the rules, or bend the rules for their advantage. Their
mindsets become sharp for nuances and any weakness in the system. These are
the types of minds that are undistracted by many things, unlike those we have
in the daily civilian grind that take our attention away. If they can determine
softness or inconsistency in a system, then it may be possible to use this critical
incidencing for a ‘reframing’ of more relevant big picture issues.37
Of course, any use of criminals must be handled with the highest
security safeguards and control standards available. This is not to sug-
gest unrealistic idealism. Prisoners are masters at the art of deception and
manipulation. That is why any such proposed initiative must be tied into a
direct and immediate rewards system for them. This would serve to allevi-
ate ‘other’ nonconformist behaviors and gaming the system for some non-
technical outcome.38 To break out of the world’s endemic cycle of fossil
fuel use and pending climate change though requires unorthodox and
radical methods. This would definitely be one.
1. The world radically ramps up its use of fossil fuels to try to offset dis-
inflation (falling prices) due to overcapacity and angry unemployed
constituencies facing impoverishment or low economic growth. The
world gets further entwined with fossil fuels for economic survival.
There are simply too many mouths to feed. This is done via more
producer fuel subsidies, more fracking, more tar sands, and further
deepwater development. Developing countries with resources prom-
ise the moon to companies who can extract their resources, no skills
transfer or human development is required, only financial investment.
Airports are expanded, ports enlarged, highways lengthened, and
cheap oil still underpins developing countries’ export economies. It’s
all they know, due to structural deficiencies and political promises,
they simply cannot wean themselves off their capital investment mod-
els. Carbon emissions worldwide soar, as does more acidification of
the oceans, melting of the arctic, Greenland, and Antarctic sea ice.
Ancient glaciers on mountaintops disappear. Species go extinct.
Floods, storms, and wildfires increase around the globe exponentially,
as well as sea level rises, but governments are hamstrung in their
responses, falling back on the sovereignty argument that it is either
not their problem or will have deep negative effect on their economies
if they pull the plug on fossil fuels. Putting a price on carbon was a
nice idea for awhile, but like a world carbon tax, it can never be effec-
tively realized as long as a nation’s elites benefit from fossil fuel con-
cepts couched in seventeenth-century Westphalian sovereignty
exclusivity and neo-colonial practices.
2. The world muddles along in its current energy format of an ‘all of the
above’ energy portfolio mix. There is a surreal and uneasy compro-
mise between alternatives and fossil fuels that co-exists, one realizing
the way of the future, the other economic verisimilitude. Ships and
planes are still powered by oil but large Energiewiende39 type projects
for wind, hydro, and geothermal energy by select wealthy countries
(i.e. Germany and Korea) are actively utilized. Fuel subsidies still exist
for certain developing countries (i.e. Iran, Venezuela, and Nigeria).
Fossil fuel-burning cars with hungrier engines, clog more and more
roads in developing countries, yet, sales of electric cars in Western
markets are also on the rise. The use of photovoltaic solar panels
276 W. HICKEY
All three of the above scenarios are plausible, the first, of increased fossil fuel
usage being the most dire and pessimistic, but also very possible under a
finance-ruled world aggressively driven by a profit motive and domestic con-
cerns that outweigh all else for political stability. HRD is utilized here but in a
very pessimistic sense: the winner takes all society. The second scenario shows
a confused world muddling along, some rich countries implement green tech-
nology, developing countries cling to burning carbon. The last scenario is the
most idealistic. HRD is utilized here in a burden-sharing format,42 countries
work together to eliminate an existential threat to the planet, and to protect
future generations from both environmental catastrophe and extreme impov-
erishment. Cooperation between nation-states rues the day, sovereignty car-
ries some weight but is secondary to humanities very survival.
Which exact path the world will follow is unknown, what is known is
that one of these directions will definitely be traversed.43 It is most prob-
able that today’s scenario, doing little, or the current situation with fossil
fuels as predicated in scenario two, is the best predictor for the future. What
is happening today will be ongoing tomorrow. The status quo becomes and
is the default baseline position. Certain wealthy countries recognize the
threats and will act, with emission schemes and carbon taxes, but it is costly.
Developing countries will also react, not to the threat of climate change, but
for their own economic (and political) interests. Fuel subsidies will continue,
renewables will be shunned beyond token projects as too expensive.44 Not
much will change. The world will stumble along, climate change will slowly
grow worse, but the brunt of its effects will be on the developing countries
(problems that are out of sight, out of mind to most Western media), who
can least afford to aid their large populations, not on developed populations
who can ‘move to higher ground’ and set the tone for the information age.
Companies and governments will be reluctant to share technology or devel-
opment with competing players. HRD will stagnate, some places will excel
with human development, others will play catch up, some will backtrack,
but all will be dictated to by the investment dollar and beholden to the gods
of finance: pensions, stock returns, and national wealth funds. It becomes a
zero-sum world of winners and losers on the balance sheet.
The above three scenarios all also demonstrate future courses of political
action. Even choosing ‘none of the above’ is still making a choice. None
of these scenarios may be as far-fetched as they seem if one stands back to
ponder the landscape. Keeping the status quo of things requires minimal
278 W. HICKEY
about getting the information, but also in interpreting it.45 This can only
be done via empowered and relevant education, which must be mandated
and set in policy initiatives by governments under our current framework
of embedded and leveraged use of fossil fuels. Education must now sit
as an equal in today’s energy mix, which is still overwhelmingly carbon
based. This book proposes a way forward based on a new paradigm of
resource investment, development, and usage: The institutionalization of
strategic education in the energy mix for societal empowerment and stew-
ardship in natural resources. Policy has to set educational objectives into
the mix of Information Age energy investment methods. The below figure
sums up the entire body of work herein.
Notes
1. North, D. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic
Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.
2. Coleman, J.S. (1990) Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA:
Belknap.
3. ‘Violence specialists’ are a Douglas North construct, meaning police and
military to ensure safety and order, not necessarily the total society, but
those in particular in society with the most vested interests.
4. Ibid., p. 6.
5. Senge, P. (2006) The Fifth Discipline: The Art and Practice of the Learning
Organization 3rd. Ed. NY: Doubleday.
6. Deming, W. E. (1986) Out of the Crisis. Cambridge, MA: MIT Technology
Press.
7. Simmons, M. (2000) Revisiting The Limits to Growth: Could The Club of
Rome Have Been Correct, After All? An Energy White Paper. URL: http://
greatchange.org/ov-simmons,club_of_rome_revisted.html
8. The Occupy movement started on Wall St. after the financial crash of 2009,
protesting essentially, privatization of profits and socialization of losses.
9. Yamada, T. (2010) Restructuring the California State University: A Call to
Action. The NEA Higher Education Journal, Fall: 91–106.
10. Bozkurt, A., Akgun-Ozbek, E., Onrat-Yilmazer, S., Erdogdu, E., Ucar,
H., Guler, E., Sezgin, S., Karadeniz, A., Sen, N., Goksel-Canbek, N.,
Dincer, G. D., Ari, S.,& Aydin, C. H. (2015). Trends in Distance Education
Research: A Content Analysis of Journals 2009–2013. International
Review of Research in Open and Distributed Learning, 16(1), 330–363.
11. Tempo English. (Dec. 16, 2015) Total, Inpex Agree to Share 30 Percent
Stake of Mahakam Block. Economy and Business Section.
12. URL: http://www.offshore-technology.com/projects/tupi-oilfield/
280 W. HICKEY
25. A trim tab is a second, very tiny rudder affixed to the larger, main rudder
of a ship that creates a counterforce, making it easier for the pilot to turn
the gigantic rudder.
26. http://www.forbes.com/profile/warren-buffett/
27. http://www.forbes.com/profile/ray-dalio/
28. Soros, G. (2009) Soros: General Theory of Reflexivity, Financial Times,
10/26/2009, Global Economy section.
29. http://www.forbes.com/profile/david-koch/ and see Greenpeace, http://
www.greenpeace.org/usa/global-warming/climate-deniers/koch-indus-
tries/ where the Koch’s have poured nearly $80 million into denying climate
change science, and that climate change is a hoax.
30. The Koch’s have been notorious for this, in hostile denial of scientific find-
ings by IPCC, NASA, NOAA.
31. OECD URL: http://www.oecd.org/about/membersandpartners/list-
oecd-member-countries.htm
32. China seeks a military presence in the Indian Ocean. Sri Lanka could pro-
vide a strategic port of call.
33. Warren, O. (2012), Facebook IPO: A Touchstone Cultural Moment for
America? URL: http://www.kcrw.com/news-culture/shows/to-the-
point/facebook-ipo-a-touchstone-cultural-moment-for-america
34. We literally mean ‘Cloud Computing’, or storing masses of data via third-
party storage on the internet.
35. Peter Senge has suggested this on book tours for his work, The Fifth
Discipline. ibid.
36. These are all historically ethnocentric positions that these countries have
taken and can be a political barrier to a changing mindsets. Britain in eigh-
teenth century had vast colonialism, the USA in the 1980s under the
Reagan Revolution and China historically has taken the position it is the
center of the world, it name, Zhongguo, means ‘Middle Kingdom’.
37. Crozier, M. (1982). Strategies for Change, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
38. Crozier, (1982) ibid. Crozier understood completely man’s propensity, in
fact, mandate to beat the system.
39. Germany’s energy transformation, Energiewende. The Economist. Jul. 28,
2012 URL: http://www.economist.com/node/21559667
40. http://news.yahoo.com/electricity-firm-ceos-urge-clear-policies-low-car-
bon-042759926--finance.html
41. Thurow, L. (1996) The Future of Capitalism. Wm. Morrow and Co.: New York.
42. Moeller, J. (2010) Savvy and Foresight Will Be the Winning Commodities in
This Era of Scarcity. Yale Center for the Study of Globalization in The
Jakarta Post, 8/12/2010.
43. Bloomberg presented a “Future of Energy” summit with Nathan Bullock,
which discussed many hypotheticals, URL http://about.bnef.com/sum-
mit/agenda/
282 W. HICKEY
44. Indonesian renewable power, while mandated in law, is still a very tiny part
of its overall fossil-fueled energy portfolio. This is also the same for many
other developing countries: Malaysia, Brazil, Russia, SA.
45. Interpretation of big data and the ‘Internet of things’; is key in Rifkin, J.
(2011) The Third Industrial Revolution: How Lateral Power Is Transforming
Energy, the Economy, and the World, Palgrave Macmillan url: http://www.
thethirdindustrialrevolution.com
Bibliography
Ades, A., & Di Tella, R. (1999). Rents, competition and corruption. American
Economic Review, 4(9), 982–994.
Adeyeye, A., Barrett, J., Diamond, J., Goldman, L., Pendergrass, J., & Schramm,
D. (2009, September). Estimating U.S. government subsidies to energy sources:
2002–2008. Washington: Environmental Law Institute.
Altbach, P., & McGill-Peterson, P. (Eds.). (2007). Higher education in the new
century. Washington, DC: Sense Publications.
Anderson, R. O. (1984). Fundamentals of the petroleum industry. Norman:
University of Oklahoma Press.
Ang, A. (2010). The four benchmarks of sovereign wealth funds. Columbia
Business School and NBER Working Paper, 10/3 New York.
Argote, L. (1999). Organizational learning. Norwell: Kluwer Academic Press.
Asker, J., Collard-Wexler, A., & De Loecker, J. (2012). Productivity volatility and
the misallocation of resources in developing economies. Princeton University
Unpublished Paper, 12/Princeton.
Ball, J. (2009). Coal hard facts: Cleaning it won't be dirt cheap. The Wall Street
Journal, 20 March. http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123751110892790871.
html.
Bardhan, P. (1997). Corruption and development: A review of the issues. Journal
of Economic Literature, 35(3), 1320–1346.
Barrows, G. H. (1983). Worldwide concession contracts and petroleum legislation.
Tulsa: PennWell Books.
Beck, U. (2001). What is globalization? Malden: Blackwell Publishers.
Becker, G. (1993). Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with spe-
cial reference to education (2nd ed.). New York: Columbia University Press.
Belbin, R. M. (2004). Management teams: Why they succeed or fail (2nd ed.).
Oxford: Elsevier.
Bennis, W. (1969). Organization development: Its nature, origins, and prospects.
Reading: Addison-Wesley.
Berman, M. (2005). Economic development through state ownership of oil and gas:
Evaluating Alaska’s royalty-in-kind program. Anchorage: Institute of Social
and Economic Research, University of Alaska.
Bhagat, R., Harveston, P., & Triandis, H. (2001). Cultural variations in the cross
border transfer of organizational knowledge: An integrative framework.
Academy of Management Journal, 27, 204–220.
Birdsall, N., Pinckney, T., & Sachs, R. (2001). Natural resources, human capital,
and growth. In R. M. Anty (Ed.), Resource, abundance and economic develop-
ment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bourdieu, P., & Wacquant, L. D. (1992). An invitation to reflexive sociology.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bousquet, M. (2008). How the university works: Higher education and the low wage
nation. New York: New York University Press.
Bozkurt, A., Akgun-Ozbek, E., Onrat-Yilmazer, S., Erdogdu, E., Ucar, H., Guler,
E., Sezgin, S., Karadeniz, A., Sen, N., Goksel-Canbek, N., Dincer, G. D., Ari,
S.,& Aydin, C. H. (2015). Trends in distance education research: A content
analysis of journals 2009–2013. International Review of Research in Open and
Distributed Learning, 16(1), 330–363.
Braithwaite, D., Chandra, A., RL, P. D., Indriyanto, A., Lang, K., Lontoh, L.,
Wooders, P. (2010). Fossil fuels – At what cost? Government support for upstream
oil and gas activities in Indonesia. Geneva: Global Subsidies Initiative of the
International Institute for Sustainable Development.
Brautigam, D. (2009). The dragons gift: The real story of China in Africa. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
CARANA Corporation. (2005). Central Asian region business survey. McLean,
VA: CARANA.
Chang, H. J. (2008). Bad Samaritans: The myth of free trade and the secret history
of capitalism. New York: Bloomsbury Press.
Chang, J., & Halliday, J. (2005). Mao: The untold story. London: A. Knopf.
Chaplin, D., Mamun, A., Fraker, T., Buek, K., Chatterji, M., & D. Hankinson, D.
(2012). Evaluation of the millennium challenge corporation’s electricity-
transmission and distribution line-extension activity in Tanzania: Baseline
Report. Washington, DC: Mathematica Policy Research.
Cioni, A. (2004). Where’s my work permit? Almaty: Salans LLP Publication.
Clark, D. (2015). How much of the world’s fossil fuel can we burn? The Guardian,
25 March. http://www.theguardian.com/environment/keep-it-in-the-ground-
blog/2015/mar/25/what-numbers-tell-about-how-much-fossil-fuel-
reserves-cant-burn.
Bibliography 285
Clark, G., & Monk, A. (2009). The legitimacy and governance of Norway’s sov-
ereign wealth fund: The ethics of global investment. The Ethics of Global
Investment, 15 September.
Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Belknap.
Collier, P. (2008). Implications of changed international conditions for EITI. Oslo:
Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative.
Conger, C. (2010). How much fossil fuel is in the earth? Page 2. Discovery
News, 24 September. http://news.discovery.com/earth/global-warming/
how-much-fossil-fuel-is-in-the-earth1.htm.
Covey, S. (1989). The 7 habits of highly effective people. London: Simon & Schuster.
Crozier, M. (1982). Strategies for change. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Daft, R. (2016). Management (12th ed.). Boston: Cengage Learning.
Dahl, R. A. (1971). Polyarchy: Participation and opposition. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
Dapice, D. (2005). Dealing with a declining dollar – Part II. Yale Global Online,
9 February. http://yaleglobal.yale.edu/content/dealing-declining-dollar-–-
part-ii.
Dave, B. (2003). Kazakhstan: Countries in transition. New York: UNDP
Publication.
Davenport, C. (2014). Miami finds itself ankle-deep in climate change debate. The
New York Times, 7 May. http://www.nytimes.com/2014/05/08/us/florida-
finds-itself-in-the-eye-of-the-storm-on-climate-change.html?_r=0}.
Dean, P. (2000). Implications of culture and communication when doing business
in India and Pakistan. Performance Improvement Quarterly, 13(2), 3–5.
Deffeyes, K. (2003). Hubbert's peak: The impending world oil shortage (2nd ed.).
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Delios, A., & Beamish, P. (2001). Survival and profitability: The roles of experi-
ence and intangible assets in foreign subsidiary performance. Academy of
Management Journal, 44(5), 1028–1038.
Deming, W. E. (1986). Out of the crisis. Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
Dillman, D. (2009). Internet, mail and mixed-mode surveys: The tailored design
method (3rd ed.). New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Dominic, R. (2015). World faces third deflationary wave. Financial Times, 9 February.
http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/11932fc0-4ca1-11e5-9b5d-89a026fda5c9.
html#axzz3yDr41PHq.
Dossani, R., & Kenney, M. (2003). Went for cost, stayed for quality? Moving the
back office to India. Stanford: APARC Forum.
Duncan, R. (2005). The dollar crisis: Causes, consequences, cures. Chichester: John
Wiley & Sons.
Easterly, W. (2006). The white man’s burden. London: Oxford University Press.
Eaton, C. (2015). Blackstone to pour 9 billion into struggling energy industry.
Fuel Fix, 23 February. http://fuelfix.com/blog/2015/02/23/blackstone-to-
pour-9-billion-into-struggling-energy-industry/.
286 Bibliography
EBU (Eurasia Business Unit) Base Business Review. (2006). San Ramon,
CA: Chevron Publication.
Eddy, M. (2015). Germany may offer model for reining in fossil fuel use. New York
Times, 5 December. http://www.nytimes.com/2015/12/04/world/europe/
germany-may-offer-model-for-reining-in-fossil-fuel-use.html?_r=0.
EIA.gov/oiaf/ieo/coal.html (2010a) International Energy Outlook, U.S. Energy
Information Administration URL. 7 July 2011.
EIA.gov/emeu/aer/txt/ptb1110.html (2010b) World oil consumption index,
U.S. Energy Information Administration URL. 9 July 2011
EIA.gov/emeu/aer/txt/ptb1112.html (2010c) World coal consumption index,
U.S. Energy Information Administration URL. 9 July 2011
EIA.gov/emeu/aer/txt/ptb1115.html (2009) World natural gas consumption
index, U.S. Energy Information Administration URL. 20 July 2012.
Ellis, J. (2010). The global subsidies initiative | untold billions: Fossil-fuel subsidies,
their impacts and the path to reform. Geneva: Global Subsidies Initiative.
Fadillah, R.D. (2012). Converting to gas…why not? The Jakarta Post, 26 January.
http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2012/01/26/converting-gas-why-
not.html.
Faggio G., Salvanes, K., & Van Reenen, J. (2007). The evolution of inequality in
productivity and wages: Panel data evidence. CEP, London School of Economics
Discussion Paper, 07/821.
Fels, J. (2015). The three gluts. PIMCO, August. https://www.pimco.com/insights/
economic-and-market-commentary/macro-perspectives/the-three-gluts.
Fitz-enz, J. (2000). The ROI of human capital. New York: Amacom.
Freese, B. (2003). Coal: A human history. Cambridge, MA: Perseus.
Friedman, M. (1978). The energy crisis: A humane solution. In M. Friedman &
W. A. Wallis (Eds.), The economics of freedom. Cleveland: Standard Oil Company
of Ohio.
Friedman, T. (2008). Hot, flat, and crowded. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
Gao, Z. (1994). International petroleum contracts: Current trends and new direc-
tions. London: Graham & Trotman.
Geil, H., Bennis, W., & Stephens, D. (2004). Douglas McGregor, revisited:
Managing the human side of the enterprise. Toronto: John Wiley.
Gelb, A. (1988). Oil windfalls: Blessing or curse? New York: Oxford University
Press for the World Bank.
Gereffi, G., & Sturgeon, T. (2004). Globalization, employment, and economic
development: A briefing paper. MIT Industrial Performance Center Working
Paper, 04/006.
Gilbert, T. (1978). Human competence: Engineering worthy performance.
New York: McGraw-Hill.
GIZ. (2012). Deutsche Gesellschaft für Internationale Zusammenarbeit (GIZ)
GmbH. “Flash Survey – Gasoline Prices,” January.
Bibliography 287
Glaeser, E. (2012). What the US can learn from Australia’s coal mines. Bloomberg
Editorial. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-07-11/what-the-u-s-
can-learn-from-australia-s-coal-mines.html.
Glazer, E., Tracy, R., & Ensign, R.L. (2015). Energy lending caught in a squeeze.
The Wall Street Journal, 25 September. http://www.wsj.com/articles/
energy-lending-caught-in-a-squeeze-1443050639.
Goetsch, D., & Davis, S. (1998). Understanding and implementing ISO 9000.
Columbus: Prentice Hall.
Grant, C. (2008). Negro with a hat: The rise and fall of Marcus Garvey and his
dream of Mother Africa. New York: Oxford University Press.
Gray, K., & Herr, E. (1998). Workforce education: The basics. Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
Green, R. (2007). 33 strategies of war. London: Penguin Publishing.
Griffin, E. (2010). A short history of the British industrial revolution (pp. 157–183).
Hampshire: Palgrave MacMillan. http://www.academia.edu/1940258/
Why_was_Britain_first_The_industrial_revolution_in_global_context.
Grogan, J. (2010). Developing competencies for a global workforce. Workforce
Solutions Review, 42–43.
Grubb, M., & Depledge, J. (2001). The seven myths of Kyoto. Climate Policy, 1,
269–272.
GTZ (Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit). (2009). International Fuel
Prices (6th ed.). Berlin: Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and
Development.
Gylfason, T. (2000). Natural resources, education and economic development. In
Research paper for the 15th annual congress of the European Economic Association.
Bolzano, Italy, August 30–September 2.
Gylfason, T. (2001). Natural resources, education, and economic development.
European Economic Review, 45, 847–859.
Haber, S., & Menaldo, V. (2011). Do natural resources fuel authoritarianism? A
reappraisal of the resource curse. American Political Science Review, 105(1),
1–26.
Hackman, R. J., & Oldham, G. R. (1976). Motivation through the design of
work: Test of a theory. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance,
16(2), 250–279.
Hall, E. T. (1985). Hidden differences: Studies in international communication.
Hamburg: Gruner & Jahr.
Halliday, J., & Chang, J. (2005). Mao: The unknown story. New York: Knopf.
Hampden-Turner, C., & Trompenaars, F. (2000). Building cross cultural compe-
tence. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Hansen, J., Sato, M., Kharecha, P., Beerling, D., Berner, R., Masson-Delmotte, V.,
Pagani, M., Raymo, M., Royer, D.L., & Zachos, J.C. (2008). Target atmospheric
CO2: Where should humanity aim? Open Atmosphere Science Journal, 2, 217–231.
Hart, O. (1995). Firms, contracts and financial structure. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
288 Bibliography
Hatakenaka, S., Westnes, P., Gjelsvik, M., & Lester, R. (2006). From black gold
to human gold: A comparative study of the oil and gas industry in Stavanger
and Aberdeen. MIT Working Paper Series, MIT/06/004.
Haysom, K., & Kane, S. (2009). Negotiating natural resources for peace: Ownership,
control and wealth-sharing. Geneva: Centre for Humanitarian Dialogue.
Hickey, W. (1999). Benchmarking of MNC non-managerial salaries in Tianjin,
China. International HR Journal, 8, 1.
Hickey, W. (2000). Human performance issues in Chinese/Western equity joint
ventures. International HR Journal, 9(2), 43–46.
Hickey, W. (2001a). A survey of current and future training needs in Tianjin (T.E.D.A.)
China, Spring 2000. Performance Improvement Quarterly, 14(2), 60–69.
Hickey, W. (2001b). Education levels and learning needs among Chinese workers.
IVETA, 8, 33–44.
Hickey, W. (2004). An evaluation of foreign HR consulting company effectiveness
in China. Performance Improvement Quarterly, 17(1), 81–101.
Hickey, W. (2011). For Korean companies investing in Asia, manpower sourcing
and resource security are the a priori key. POSRI Chindia Quarterly. Vol. 4, Fall
2011, pp. 138–146.
Hickey, W. (2012). Time to end fuel subsidies? Budgetary balance and need to
develop alternatives, are reasons to end fuel subsidies YaleGlobal, 7 June.
http://www.yaleglobal.yale.edu/content/time-end-fuel-subsidies.
Hickey, W., & O’Lawrence, H. (2001). H1-b technology visas and their impacts on
international training efforts. In IVETA conference keynote. Kingston, Jamaica.
Hofstede, G. (1991). Cultures and organizations: Software of the mind. Berkshire:
McGraw-Hill.
Hofstede, G. (2001).Difference and danger: Cultural profiles of nations and limits
to tolerance. In M. H. Albrecht (Ed.), International HRM: Managing diversity
in the workplace. Malden: Blackwell Publishers.
Holt, J. C. (1992). Magna Carta. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Horton, S. (1999). Is Kazakhstan taking reform seriously? In Keynote presentation
delivered at the Columbia University School of International and Public Affairs
Conference “Kazakhstan‘s Economic Development After the Russian Crisis,”
New York 29th April.
Human Resources Practical Seminar, May, 2005. Atryau, KZ: TCO Publication.
IAEA. (2006). IAEA competencies listing. Knowledge management for nuclear
industry operating organizations. IAEA-TECDOC-1510.
IAEA. (2009). Draft nuclear energy series document: Workforce planning for new
nuclear power programmes. IAEA Nuclear Energy Series No. NG-T-3.10
Ibadildin, N. (2009). Oil and authoritarianism in Kazakhstan. In B. Ostrov (Ed.),
From silk road to oil slick: Kazakhstan reemergence to modernity. Norwalk:
EastBridge.
IEA. (2011). World energy outlook: Executive summary. Paris: International Energy
Agency.
Bibliography 289
IEA, OPEC, OECD, & World Bank. (2010). Analysis of the scope of energy subsidies
and suggestions for the G-20 initiative, joint report prepared for submission to
the G-20 Leaders’ Summit (Toronto, June 2010).
IEA, OPEC, OECD, & World Bank. (2011). Joint report by IEA, OPEC, OECD
and World Bank on fossil-fuel and other energy subsidies: An update of the
G20 Pittsburgh and Toronto Commitments. Prepared for the G20 meeting of
Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors (Paris, 14–15 October 2011)
and the G20 Summit (Cannes, 3–4 November 2011).
Ikenberry, J. (2004). Illusions of empire: Defining the new American order.
Foreign Affairs, March/April.
Inkpen, A., & Beamish, P. (1997). Knowledge, bargaining power, and the
Instability of International Joint Ventures. Academy of Management Review,
22, 177–203.
International Institute for Sustainable Development. (2012). A citizens guide to
fossil fuel subsidies in Indonesia. https://www.iisd.org/gsi/sites/default/
files/indonesia_czguide_eng_update_2012.pdf
International Monetary Fund. (2005). Guide on resource revenue transparency.
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Jennings D., Feiten, J., & Brock H. (2000). Petroleum accounting: Principles, pro-
cedures and issues (5th ed.), A Price Waterhouse Coopers (PWC) Handbook.
Denton: Professional Development Institute.
Jiang, J., & Sinton, J. (2011). Overseas investment by Chinese national oil compa-
nies: Assessing the drivers and impacts. Paris: International Energy Agency.
Jin, X. (1996). The relationship between organizational factors and the transfer of
training in the electronics industry in Shenzhen, China. Human Resource
Development Quarterly, 7(1), 55–76.
Johnson, S. (2007). The rise of sovereign wealth funds. Finance and Development
44, 3, September. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2007/09/
straight.htm.
Johnston, D. (1994a). International petroleum fiscal regimes and production shar-
ing contracts. Tulsa: PennWell.
Johnston, D. (1994b). Production sharing agreements. University of Dundee,
Centre for Petroleum and Mineral Law and Policy Seminar Paper, SP/19/94a.
Johnston, D., & Johnston, D. (2001). Kashagan and Tengiz – Castor and Pollux.
PetroMin Magazine, 15 December.
Kacowicz, A. M. (2007). Globalization, poverty, and the North–South divide.
International Studies Review, 9(4), 565–580.
Kaplan, R. S., & Norton, D. P. (1996). The balanced scorecard: Translating strat-
egy into action. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Karl, T. (1997). The paradox of plenty: Oil booms and petro-states. Stanford:
University of California Press.
290 Bibliography
Kawa, L. (2015). Four ways the oil price crash is hurting the global economy.
Bloomberg News, 7 October. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/arti-
cles/2015-10-07/four-ways-the-oil-price-crash-is-hurting-the-global-
economy.
Kelsen, H. (2007). General theory of law and state (trans: Wedberg, A.). Clark: The
Lawbook Exchange.
Kissinger, H. (2014). Introduction and Chpt 1. In World order: Reflections on the
character of nations and the course of history. London: Allen Lane.
Klein, N. (2014). This changes everything. New York: Simon & Schuster.
Klingaman, W., & Klingaman, N. (2014). The year without summer, 1816.
New York: St. Martins Griffin.
Kluckhohn, F., & Strodtbeck, F. (1961). Variations in value orientations. Evanston:
Row & Peterson.
Knowles, M. (1975). Self-directed learning: A guide for learners and teachers.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Koplow, D. (2009). Measuring energy subsidies using the price-gap approach: What
does it leave out? Geneva: Global Subsidies Initiative of the International
Institute for Sustainable Development.
Koplow, D., & Lin, C. (Forthcoming). A review of fossil fuel subsidies in Colorado,
Kentucky, Louisiana, Oklahoma, and Wyoming. Cambridge, MA: Earth Track
Koplow, D., Lin, C., Jung, A., Thone, M., & Lontoh, L. (2010a). Mapping the
characteristics of producer subsidies: A review of pilot country studies. Geneva:
Global Subsidies Initiative.
Koplow, D, C., Lin, C., Jung, A., Thone, M., & Lontoh, L. (2010b). Untold bil-
lions: Fossil-fuel subsidies, their impacts and the path to reform. International
Institute for Sustainable Development.
Kozlowski, R. (2015). California senate passes bill requiring CalPERS, CalSTRS
to divest from coal. Pensions & Investments, 3 June. http://www.pionline.
com/article/20150603/ONLINE/150609935/california-senate-passes-bill-
requiring-calpers-calstrs-to-divest-from-coal.
Krishna, A. (2000). Creating and harnessing social capital. In P. Dasgupta &
I. Serageldin (Eds.), Social capital: A multifaceted perspective. Washington, DC:
The World Bank.
Kronenberg, T. (2004). The curse of natural resources in the transition econo-
mies. Economics of Transition, 12(3), 399–426. Published by the European
Bank for Reconstruction and Development and by SITE, Stockholm School of
Economics.
Kuralbayeva, K. (2001). The Dutch disease: Symptoms and policy implications for
Kazakhstani economy. Central Asian Journal of Management, Economics and
Social Research, 2, 429–440.
Kuznets, P. (1988). Why does overcrowded, resource-poor East Asia succeed –
Lessons for the less developed countries. Journal of Economic Development and
Cultural Change, 36, 3, Supplement.
Bibliography 291
Kwok, C., & Taldesse, S. (2006). The MNC as an agent of change in host country
institutions: FDI and corruption. Journal of International Business Studies, 37,
767–785.
Lam, R., & Wantchekon, L. (1999). Dictatorships as a political Dutch disease.
Yale University, Center Discussion Paper, 795/99.
Lawler, E., III. (1971). Pay and organizational effectiveness: A psychological view.
New York: McGraw-Hill.
Leggett, J. (2006). Half gone: Oil, gas, hot air and the global energy crisis. London:
Portobello Books.
Lindblad, C. (2011). The decade ahead in oil and natural gas exploration.
Bloomberg Businessweek, 7 July. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/arti-
cles/2011-07-07/the-decade-ahead-in-oil-and-natural-gas-exploration.
Luo, Y. (2006). Political behavior, social responsibility, and perceived corruption:
A structural perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 37, 747–766.
Machmud, N. T. (2000). The Indonesian PSC: An investors perspective. Kluwer:
Den Hague.
Mager, R.F. (1990). Measuring Instructional Results, 3rd Ed. Atlanta: Center For
Effective Performance (CEP).
Mager, R., & Pipe, P. (1997). Analyzing performance problems (2nd ed.). Atlanta:
CEP Publishing.
Mann, M. (2013). The hockey stick and the climate wars: Dispatches from the front
lines. New York: Columbia University Press.
Marino, J. (2015). The energy sector shakeout is hammering Jefferies’ trading
business. Business Insider, Indonesia, 17 September. http://www.businessin-
sider.co.id/jefferies-third-quarter-results-2015-9/#.ViW4WScaySM.
Mathiesen, K. (2015). Climate change has left US exposed in Artic, say military
experts. The Guardian, 10 June. http://www.theguardian.com/environ-
ment/2015/jun/10/climate-change-has-left-us-exposed-in-arctic-say-
military-experts.
Mc Harg, A., Barton, B., Bradbrook, A., & Godden, L. (2010). Property and the
law in energy and natural resources. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
McEndree, D. (2016). Why OPEC production freeze could pave the way for
actual cuts. Oilprice.com, 17 February. http://oilprice.com/Energy/Oil-
Prices/Why-OPEC-Production-Freeze-Could-Pave-The-Way-For-Actual-
Cuts.htm.
McGregor, D. (1960). The human side of enterprise. New York: McGraw-Hill.
McKibben, B. (2012). Global warming’s terrifying new math. Rolling Stone, 19
July. http://www.rollingstone.com/politics/news/global-warmings-terrifying-
new-math-20120719.
McLagan, P. (1989). Models for HRD practice. Alexandria: ASTD Press.
McLure, M. (2009). Royalties for regions: Accountability and sustainability.
Hansard: Business School the University of Western Australia and Australian
Parliamentary Debates Discussion Paper, 05/09.
292 Bibliography
Mengistu, A., & Adhkirary, B. (2011). Does good governance matter for FDI
inflows? Evidence from Asian economies. Asia Pacific Business Review, 17(3),
281–299.
Merriam, S., & Caffarella, R. (1999). Learning in adulthood (2nd ed.). San
Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Merton, R. K. (1968). Social theory and social structure (2nd ed.). New York: Free
Press.
Mikesell, R. F. (1984). Petroleum company operations & agreements in the develop-
ing countries. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.
Mikesell, R. (1997). Explaining the resource curse, with special reference to
mineral-exporting countries. Resources Policy, 23(4), 191–199.
Milkovich, G., & Newman, J. (1993). Compensation (4th ed.). Boston: Irwin.
Moeller, J. (2010). Savvy and foresight will be the winning commodities in this era
of scarcity. Yale Center for the Study of Globalization in The Jakarta Post, 12
August.
Moeller, J. (2011). How Asia can shape the world. Singapore: ISEAS Publishing.
Mohamedbhai, G. (2003). Globalization and its Implications for universities in
developing countries. In G. Breton & M. Lambert (Eds.), Universities and
globalization: Private linkages, public trust. Paris: UNESCO/Université Laval/
Economica.
Mohsin, S., & Holter, M. (2015). Norway to start withdrawals from oil funds to
plug deficits. Bloomberg Business, 6 October. http://www.bloomberg.com/
news/articles/2015-10-06/norway-budget-proposes-boost ing-oil-spen-
ding-by-14-nrk-says.
Monk, A. (2013). The rise of sovereign development funds. Institutional Investor,
10 April. http://www.institutionalinvestor.com/blogarticle/3189172/Blog/
The-Rise-of-Sovereign-Development-Funds.html#.Vs851xC-2gs.
Moors, K. (2013). Green energy report. http://www.theenergyreport.com/
pub/na/are-the-special-few-manipulating-oil-prices.
Morrison, K. (2009). Oil, non-tax revenue, and the redistributional foundations
of regime stability. International Organization, 63, 107–138.
Moyo, D. (2012). The winner takes all: China’s race for resources and what it means
for the world. Philadelphia: Basic Books.
Mukunda, G. (2014). The price of wall street’s power. Harvard Business Review,
June.
Nair, C. (2011). Consumptionomics: Asia’s role in reshaping capitalism and saving
the planet. New York: Wiley.
Nikkei Asian Review. (2015). Mitsubishi heavy tests waters with floating LNG
power plants. Asia.nikkei.com, 19 September. http://asia.nikkei.com/
Business/Companies/Mitsubishi-Heavy-tests-waters-with-floating-LNG-
power-plants.
Nordhous, W. (1999). Global Public Goods and the Problem of Global Warming.
In Annual Lecture, The Institut d’Economie Industrielle (IDEI), Toulouse,
France.
Bibliography 293
Plutzer, E., McCaffrey, M., Hannah, A. L., Rosenau, J., Berbeco, M., Reid, A. H.
(2016). Climate confusion among U.S. teachers. Science, 351(6274), 664–665.
Porter, M. (1998). On competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Porter, M. (2001). On competition (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Harvard University
Press.
Porter, G. (2002). OECD workshop on environmentally harmful subsidies. Paper
presented at the OECD Workshop on Environmentally Harmful Subsidies,
OECD, November 7, Paris.
Posavac, E. J., & Carey, R. G. (1997). Program evaluation (5th ed.). Saddle River:
Prentice Hall.
Preece, J. (2009). Lifelong learning and development: A perspective from the
‘South’. Compare: A Journal of Comparative and International Education,
39(5), 585–599.
Ravillion, M. (2013). How long will it take to lift one billion people out of pov-
erty? Policy research. The World Bank, Development Economics Vice Presidency
Partnerships, Capacity Building Unit, Working Paper, WB/6325/13.
Rifkin, J. (1995). The end of work. New York: Putnam Books.
Rifkin, J. (2011). The third industrial revolution: How lateral power is transforming
energy, the economy, and the world. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Risse, M. (2006). What to say about the state. Social Theory and Practice, 32(4),
671.
Robinson, J. (2012). The rise of the petrodollar system: ‘Dollars for oil’. Financial
Sense, 23 February. http://www.financialsense.com/contributors/jerry-
robinson/the-rise-of-the-petrodollar-system-dollars-for-oil.
Ross, M. (2001). Does oil hinder democracy? World Politics, 53(3), 325–361.
Rossett, A. (1998). A handbook for performance analysis. New York: Pfeiffer.
Rothwell, W. (1994). Effective succession planning: Ensuring leadership continuity
and building talent from within. New York: AMACOM.
Rothwell, W. (1996). Beyond training and development. New York: AMACOM.
Rothwell, W. (1998). Mastering the instructional design process (2nd ed.). San
Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Rothwell, W. (2000). ASTD models for human performance improvement (2nd
ed.). Alexandria: The American Society for Training and Development.
Rothwell, W. J. (2005). Beyond training & development: The groundbreaking clas-
sic on human performance enhancement. New York: AMACOM.
Rothwell, W., & Kazanas, H. C. (1994). Human resource development: A strategic
approach. Amherst: Human Resource Development Press.
Rutledge, I. (2004). The Sakalhin II PSA: A production “Non-Sharing” agree-
ment. Sheffield Energy and Resource Information Services (SERIS). http://
www.bothends.info/mfi/dos3-SakhalinPSA.pdf.
Ryggvik, H. (2010). The Norwegian oil experience: A toolbox for managing
resources? Oslo: University of Oslo.
Bibliography 295
World Bank. (2001). Constructing knowledge societies: New challenges for tertiary
education. Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2002a). Chief calls for transparency in Kazakhstan. World Markets
Analysis, April.
World Bank. (2002b). Kazakhstan governance and service delivery: A diagnostic
report. Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2011). Energy renewables podcast. Narrator, Dan Kamman, Berkeley.
World Bank. (2014). What does it mean to put a price on carbon? Worldbank.org,
11 June. http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2014/06/11/
what-does-it-mean-to-put-a-price-on-carbon.
World Nuclear News. (2015). China looks forward to reactor firsts. WNN, 14
September. http://www.world-nuclear-news.org/NN-China-looks-forward-
to-reactor-firsts-1409157.html.
Worldwatch Institute. (2005). Global fossil fuels consumption surges. Worldwatch.
org. http://www.worldwatch.org/global-fossil-fuel-consumption-surges.
Yamada, T. (2010). Restructuring the California State University: A call to action.
The NEA Higher Education Journal, Fall, 91–106.
Yan, R. (1998). Short term results. Harvard Business Review, 5, 11, 61.
Yang, A. (2012). New global assessment reveals nearly 1,200 proposed coal-fired
power plants. World Resources Institute, 20 November. http://www.wri.org/
blog/2012/11/new-global-assessment-reveals-nearly-1200-proposed-coal-
fired-power-plants.
Yauch, B. (2010). Paying the polluters: The carbon credit way. Probe Inter-
national, 6. http://journal.probeinternational.org/2010/07/06/paying-the-
polluters-the-carbon-credit-way/.
Yergin, D. (2008). The prize: The epic quest for oil, money and power. New York:
Simon and Schuster.
Yin, R. K. (1993). Case study research, design and methods. Newbury Park, CA:
Sage.
Index1
E
Earth Institute, 8 G
Eastern Siberia, 102 gainsharing, 7, 24, 234
East-South problem, 237 Gantt charts, 20
economic nationalism, 156, 184 Garvey, Marcus, 156, 162n62
Ecuador, 64, 73, 102, 158, 198, 210, gas-to-liquids (GTL), 49
223, 230, 234, 236 GDP. See gross domestic product
Egypt, 4, 6, 182, 225 (GDP)
EITI. See Extractive Industries gemeinschaft, 210
Transparency Initiative (EITI) Generally Accepted Practices and
emissions trading system (ETS), 108, 109 Principles (GAPP), 80
enhancement, 10 Genuine Progress Indicator (GPI), 24
Eni Zohr, 44 Germany, 16, 46, 47, 49, 57, 106,
ETS. See emissions trading system 141, 143, 207, 227, 237, 275
(ETS) gesellschaft, 158, 162n63, 210
EU. See European Union (EU) GHG. See "green-house gas"
Eureka moment, 21 emissions (GHG)
European Union (EU), 38, 41, 58, globalization, 143, 144
109, 110, 188, 219, 222 global warming, 5, 8, 10, 15, 16, 27,
Extractive Industries Transparency 35, 39, 41, 46, 82, 97, 102, 105,
Initiative (EITI), 231, 245, 112, 154, 260, 268
246, 248 GPI. See Genuine Progress Indicator
Exxon (GPI)
Exxon-Mobil, 24, 94, 101, 171, gradualism, 228
174, 182 "green-house gas" emissions (GHG), 42
Greenland, 15
gross domestic product (GDP), 7, 16,
F 24, 39, 40, 74, 87, 147, 175,
Fels, Joachim, 85 209, 222, 224, 242, 271
Fifth Column, 263 GTL. See gas-to-liquids
302 INDEX
Sovereign Wealth Fund (SWF), 14, Tokyo Electric Power Co. (TEPCO),
28, 74–84, 95, 212, 227, 260 57, 60, 61
Sovereign Wealth Funds, 73–5, 95, training needs assessment (TNA), 117,
209, 211, 212 119, 128
Spain, 51, 95 Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), 17,
Sri Lanka, v, ix, 3, 39, 40, 41, 65, 145, 142, 228
148, 180, 181, 197, 200, 220, Tromenpaars, Fons, 172
222, 225, 226, 229, 230, 235–6, Truman, Edwin, 77, 78, 80
268–71 Tunisia, 6
standard oil, 24, 71 Turkmenistan, 44, 168, 236, 242
Statoil, 76, 178 turnkey projects, 23, 196–8, 229
STEM, 170
stranded assets, 92, 95
Studzinski, John, 87 U
Sub-Saharan Africa, 226 UK, 27, 63, 76, 95, 124, 143, 165,
succession planning, 2, 118, 119, 125, 178, 179, 194, 205, 227
164, 206, 224 Ukraine, 60
Sudan, 38, 57, 59, 65, 198, 220, 223, United States, 3, 24, 47, 110–13, 147
229, 234, 236, 242, 255 US CIA, 5
Suharto, 9 US State of Alaska, 27, 151, 152
sustainability, 7, 9, 21, 22, 25, 27,
187, 195, 198, 267
SWF. See Sovereign Wealth Fund V
(SWF) Vietnam, 5, 143, 206, 207, 230, 236
Switzerland, 76, 82, 86, 193
SWOT analysis, 123
Syria, 6, 16 W
Wall Street, 29, 86, 96
Weighted Average Cost of Capital
T (WACC), 77–8
Taiwan, 19, 25, 121 Western Java, 39
Taleb, Nassim, 8 Westphalia, 108, 112, 141–3, 145,
Tanzania, 4, 38, 64, 197, 198 150, 155, 157, 191, 199, 275
tarsands, 41, 45, 49, 92, 194, 244 World Bank, 1, 46, 81, 97, 149,
Technical and Further Education 150, 156, 177, 190, 196,
(TAFE), 172, 236 205, 213, 223, 226–8, 230,
Technology Institute of Bandung, 3 233, 236, 255, 269
Thailand, 1, 133, 180, 182, 190, 191
thermal coal, 5, 59, 94
third country national (TCN), 20 Y
Three Mile Island, 60 Yemen, 16, 164, 165
tokenism, 210 Yergin, Daniel, 15, 42