The Real Business Cycle Model: 1 Historical Introduction
The Real Business Cycle Model: 1 Historical Introduction
Spring 2013
1 Historical introduction
• Modern business cycle theory really got started with Great Depression
• You may have seen something like an Aggregate Demand / Aggregate Supply model in ECON
1B
• “Real business cycle model” tried to remedy these deficiencies, especially in terms of “micro-
foundations”
• “New-Keynesian” models blend some of the logic of the Keynesian model with the from-first-
principles approach of the RBC
Key questions
• Positive: what causes economic fluctuations?
1
ECON 52, Spring 2013 2 THE RBC MODEL
– RBC approach: no, the internal mechanisms are stable but there are exogenous distur-
bances (“shocks”) that move things around
– Maybe the existence of shocks is a fundamental feature of a market economy?
– Do we lose understanding if we model the shocks as exogenous?
• RBC is a “Real” model as opposed to “nominal”: no role for money or nominal variables
• Since RBC is a version of the Neoclassical model, First Welfare Theorem holds. What should
we do about business cycles?
• Households
s.t.
a1 = w0 (1 − l0 ) − c0 + (1 + r0 ) a0
c1 = w1 (1 − l1 ) + (1 + r1 ) a1
a0 given
2
ECON 52, Spring 2013 2 THE RBC MODEL
r0 = r0K − δ
r1 = r1K − 1 (because the world ends after t = 1) (5)
• Market clearing
Lt = 1 − lt
K 1 = a1
• Equilibrium conditions:
3
ECON 52, Spring 2013 2 THE RBC MODEL
• The Williamson textbook (ch. 10) tries to do a graphical version of this system of equations,
which I find hard to follow
θ 1+
v (l) = l
1+
1. Define some basic values for the exogenous variables and call that “normal” (e.g.: middle
of the business cycle)
2. Compute the values for the endogenous variables: c0 , c1 , l0 , l1 , K1
3. Suppose an exogenous “shock” moves one or more of the exogenous variables
4. Compute the values for the endogenous variables: c0 , c1 , l0 , l1 , K1 in response to the
shock
5. Ask: does this look like what we see in business cycles?
• In particular, we should check whether in the model it’s true that output, employment,
consumption, investment and productivity more or less move in the same direction when
there is a shock.
4
ECON 52, Spring 2013 3 PRODUCTIVITY SHOCKS
3 Productivity shocks
• Consider a shock to A0 in the production function
• In the equations:
• Shock improves the marginal product of labour, which raise wages (other things being equal)
• Graphically, you can see this as an increase is labour demand (but remember that other
things change as well)
• Adjust by ↑ c0 , ↑ L0 , or both
• Suppose:
– Shock is temporary
– Income effect exists but is small
– Substitution effect is strong
5
ECON 52, Spring 2013 3 PRODUCTIVITY SHOCKS
– Y1 goes up for two reasons: direct effect of shock on productivity and additional labour
input
– K1 goes up (you can see this from resource constraint) - households smooth consumption
by building capital for tomorrow
– output
– productivity
– hours worked
– consumption
– investment
• Booms are times when households choose to work more in response to temporarily high
wages
• Symmetrically, recessions are times when households choose to work less in response to
temporarily low wages
3. Assume that the Solow residuals are an accurate measure of a series of exogenous
technological shocks
4. Simulate the response of the model when you ask it to respond to the shocks the you
estimated from the data
5. Compare GDP, etc. in the model to the same variables in the data
2
• Result: the model generates (explains?) about 3
of the fluctuations in GDP that we observe
in the data.
6
ECON 52, Spring 2013 3 PRODUCTIVITY SHOCKS
• If people aren’t working because there is a recession, this is an efficient response to the fact
that productivity is low today: people take time off when productivity is low and work harder
when productivity is high
• To be precise: competitive markets are an assumption of the model and whenever we have
competitive markets the FWT holds
• BUT the model does say that it is possible to observe fluctuations in GDP, etc. in a world
where there is nothing “wrong” (i.e. no inefficiency)
• Observing fluctuations does not prove that there is something wrong that should be fixed
• (But it’s also possible that this is the wrong model and in the right model business cycles
are indeed inefficient)
• The only thing the government should do about a recession is to try to improve productivity
– Encourage competition
– Lower transaction costs
– Promote innovation
– All of these things are desirable anyway, not just when there is a recession
– Remember we talked about this being a very important number when we talked about
the effects of taxes
– A high elasticity of labour supply is an important ingredient of BOTH:
∗ the argument that taxes have large effects
7
ECON 52, Spring 2013 4 OTHER SHOCKS
• Cyclicality of wages. In general, the model does better on quantities than on prices.
• No unemployment?
4 Other shocks
Impatience shocks: sudden decreases in β
• Has some appeal because it means households want goods now rather than later, an effect
that is important in Keynesian models, as we’ll see later
• In the equations:
• If ↑ c0 , this implies ↓ L0 !
• This shock DOES NOT produce the “co-movement” of business cycles: consumption goes up
but output, investment and hours of work go down!
8
ECON 52, Spring 2013 4 OTHER SHOCKS
Laziness shocks
• Suppose households temporarily don’t want to work, i.e. the marginal utility of leisure goes
up
• (You could also think of the opposite: households temporarily don’t mind working)
• In the equations:
• Adjust by ↓ L0
• Maybe other things that “look” like laziness: disruption in labour markets, prices not adjust-
ing...
9
ECON 52, Spring 2013 4 OTHER SHOCKS
Y1 = F (K1 , L1 ) + e1
• In the equations:
• Adjust by ↑ c0
• Therefore ↓ L0 and ↓ K1
• Future wealth makes households consume more, but also work less and invest less, so it
DOES NOT produce the “co-movement” we observe in business cycles.
Y1 = A1 K1α L11−α
10
ECON 52, Spring 2013 5 CONCLUSION
• Either way, the shock DOES NOT produce the “co-movement” we see in business cycles.
Uncertainty
• Uncertainty is also about how people think about the future
• Instead of pessimism (“the future will be bad”), uncertainty is about (“I don’t know what the
future will look like”)
Y1 = F (K1 , L1 ) + e1
• Under standard preferences, uncertainty will lead to higher expected marginal utility of
consumption, i.e.: E [u0 (c1 )] rises.1
• Again, no “co-movement”
5 Conclusion
• Productivity shocks and laziness shocks could, in principle, generate “business cycle” co-
movement
11
ECON 52, Spring 2013 5 CONCLUSION
v 0 (1 − L0 ) = FL (K0 , L0 ) u0 (c0 )
Unless something happens to v or FL , consumption and hours of work will move in opposite
directions! Consumption and leisure are normal goods.
• The alternative explanation is that there are some market imperfections missing from our
model
• Other shocks combined with market imperfections could be part of the story.
v 0 (1 − L0 ) = FL (K0 , L0 ) u0 (c0 )
12