Pairs Trading
Pairs Trading
Pairs Trading
/%0"1$+%2*3%45647%
(-+89%:+";9<% =>.$%?@@5%
AB-8%C$+8-*.<% ($D+>"+E%F44G%
0"-+8%A+"H-./<%%0$+;*+I".J$%*;%"%K$#"9-L$%
C"#>$%M+D-9+"/$%K>#$%
!"#$%&#'(")%*+,'+$%-+..(/(%
01..1#2%34%&+('52#$$)%6#.(%789++.%+:%;#$#/(2($')%<$'(=$#'1+$#.%
-($'(=%:+=%>1$#$8(%
?4%&((='%@+AB($9+=,')%6#.(%789++.%+:%;#$#/(2($')%<$'(=$#'1+$#.%
-($'(=%:+=%>1$#$8(!
"#$%!&'&()!*'+!,(!-./+0.'-(-!/$1#.21!*#')3(!4).5!1#(!
6.*$'0!6*$(+*(!7(%(')*#!8(1/.)9!:0(*1).+$*!;'&()!<.00(*1$.+=!
"##$%&&''()*+,-&./'#(.+#0121314
Pairs Trading: Performance of a Relative Value Arbitrage Rule
Evan Gatev
Assistant Professor
Boston College
William N. Goetzmann
Edwin J. Beinecke Professor of Finance and Management Studies
Yale University
K. Geert Rouwenhorst
Professor
Yale University
Abstract
We test a Wall Street investment strategy, “pairs trading,” with daily data over 1962-2002.
Stocks are matched into pairs with minimum distance between normalized historical prices. A
simple trading rule yields average annualized excess returns of up to 11 percent for self-
financing portfolios of pairs. The profits typically exceed conservative transaction costs
estimates. Bootstrap results suggest that the “pairs” effect differs from previously-documented
reversal profits. Robustness of the excess returns indicates that pairs trading profits from
temporary mis-pricing of close substitutes. We link the profitability to the presence of a
common factor in the returns, different from conventional risk measures.
We are grateful to Peter Bossaerts, Michael Cooper, Jon Ingersoll, Ravi Jagannathan, Maureen O’Hara, Carl
Schecter and two anonymous referees for many helpful discussions and suggestions on this topic. We thank the
International Center for Finance at the Yale School of Management for research support, and the participants in the
EFA’99 Meetings, the AFA’2000 Meetings, the Berkeley Program in Finance and the Finance and Economics
workshops at Vanderbilt and Wesleyan for their comments.
1
Introduction
Wall Street has long been interested in quantitative methods of speculation. One popular
short-term speculation strategy is known as “pairs trading.” The strategy has at least a twenty-
year history on Wall Street and is among the proprietary "statistical arbitrage" tools currently
used by hedge funds as well as investment banks. The concept of pairs trading is disarmingly
simple. Find two stocks whose prices have moved together historically. When the spread
between them widens, short the winner and buy the loser. If history repeats itself, prices will
converge and the arbitrageur will profit. It is hard to believe that such a simple strategy, based
solely on past price dynamics and simple contrarian principles, could possibly make money. If
the U.S. equity market were efficient at all times, risk-adjusted returns from pairs trading should
not be positive.
In this paper, we examine the risk and return characteristics of pairs trading with daily
data over the period 1962 through December 2002. Using a simple algorithm for choosing pairs,
we test the profitability of several straightforward, self-financing trading rules. We find average
annualized excess returns of about 11 percent for top-pairs portfolios. While pairs strategies
exploit temporary components of stock prices, we show that our profits are not caused by simple
mean reversion as documented in the previous literature. We examine the robustness of our
results to a wide variety of risk factors – including not only the widely used factors in the
empirical literature but also potential low-frequency institutional factors such as bankruptcy risk.
In addition, we explore the robustness of our results to microstructure factors such as the bid-ask
bounce, short-selling costs, and transactions costs. While some factors such as short-selling and
transactions costs affect the magnitude of the excess returns, pairs trading remains profitable for
reasonable assumptions over the sample period of study, as well as over a true out of sample test
2
of four years. We interpret the results of our analysis as evidence in favor of profitable arbitrage
in expectations that may accrue to market participants who possess relatively low transactions
costs and the ability to short securities. We also find evidence that points to a systematic factor
that influences the profitability of pairs trading over time. This unidentified latent risk factor has
been relatively dormant recently. The importance of this risk factor is correlated with the returns
to pairs trading, which is consistent with the view that the profits are a compensation to
We argue that our results reveal something about the mechanism and performance of
despite considerable theory about market efficiency, economists have little empirical information
about how efficiency is maintained in practice. In addition, despite the fact that hedge funds
have attracted an increasing amount of investment capital over the past decade, the study of
hedge fund strategies is in its infancy in the financial economics literature. This paper examines
the risk and return characteristics of one widely practiced active trading strategy.
One natural question to ask is whether our results imply a violation of equilibrium asset
pricing. While the documented profitability of the pairs trading rule is a robust result, it is not
inconsistent with all pricing models. Indeed the reversion in relative values we find is consistent
with a pricing model in prices developed and tested by Bossaerts (1988). Thus our paper at the
very least suggests that this class of models merits further empirical investigation.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 1 provides some background
on pairs trading strategy. The next section describes our methodology of constructing pairs and
calculating returns. The empirical results are described in section 3, and section 4 provides
3
1. Background of Pairs Trading
1.1 History
In the mid-1980's, the Wall Street quant Nunzio Tartaglia assembled a team of physicists,
markets. Tartaglia's group of former academics used sophisticated statistical methods to develop
high-tech trading programs, executable through automated trading systems, that took the
intuition and trader's “skill” out of arbitrage and replaced it with disciplined, consistent filter
rules. Among other things, Tartaglia's programs identified pairs of securities whose prices
tended to move together. They traded these pairs with great success in 1987 – a year when the
group reportedly made a $50 million profit for the firm. Although the Morgan Stanley group
disbanded in 1989 after a couple of bad years of performance, pairs trading has since become an
arbitrage strategies has also apparently affected profits. In a New York Times interview, David
Shaw, head of one of the most successful modern quant shops and himself an early Tartaglia’s
protégé, suggests that recent pickings for quant-shops have become slim – he attributes the
success of his firm, D.E. Shaw, to early entry into the business. Tartaglia's own explanation for
pairs trading is psychological. He claims, that “…Human beings don't like to trade against
human nature, which wants to buy stocks after they go up not down.1” Could pairs traders be the
investors? This is at least one possible – albeit psychological – explanation for our results,
1
Hansell, S., 1989, “Inside Morgan Stanley's Black Box,” Institutional Investor, May, p.204.
4
which is consistent with Jegadeesh and Titman's (1995) finding that contrarian profits are in part
common factors.
In our study we have not searched over the full strategy space to identify successful
trading rules, but rather we have interpreted practitioner description of pairs trading as
straightforwardly as possible. Our rules follow the general outline of first “find stocks that move
together,” and second “take a long-short position when they diverge and unwind upon
convergence.” A test requires that both of these steps must be parameterized in some way. How
do you identify “stocks that move together?” Need they be in the same industry? Should they
only be liquid stocks? How far do they have to diverge before a position is put on? When is a
position unwound? We have made some straightforward choices about each of these questions.
We put positions on at a two-standard deviation spread, which might not always cover
transactions costs even when stock prices converge. Although it is tempting to try potentially
more profitable schemes, the danger in data-snooping refinements outweighs the potential
insights gained about the higher profits that could result from learning through testing2.
As with all filter rules using historical asset pricing data, data-snooping is a potential
concern. One approach to the data snooping issue is to test the results out-of-sample. We
completed and circulated the first draft of the working paper in 1999, using data through the end
of 1998. The time lag between the first analysis and the present study gives us an ideal hold-out
sample. Using the original model, but the post 1988 data, we found that over the 1999-2002
2
Froot and Dabora (1999) consider “twin” stocks that trade in different international markets to examine issues of market
integrationon.
5
period, the excess return of the fully invested portfolio of the top twenty pairs averaged 10.4
percent per annum, with an annual standard deviation of 3.8% and a large and significant
Newey-West-adjusted t-statistic of 4.82 – consistent with the long-term, in-sample results of our
original analysis. We were careful not to adjust our strategy from the first draft to the current
draft of the paper, to avoid data-snooping criticisms. Not only does this additional four-year
sample suggest that the results were not simply an artifact of the earlier sample period, over
which pairs-trading was known to be popular, but it also suggests that the public dissemination
of the results has apparently not affected the general risk and return characteristics of the
Asset pricing can be viewed in absolute and relative terms. Absolute pricing values
securities from fundamentals such as discounted future cash flow. This is a notoriously difficult
process with a wide margin for error. Papers by Bakshi and Chen (1997) and Lee et al. (1997),
for example, are heroic attempts to build quantitative value investing models. Relative pricing is
only slightly easier. Relative pricing means that two securities that are close substitutes for each
other should sell for the same price – it does not say what that price will be. Thus, relative
pricing allows for bubbles in the economy, but not necessarily arbitrage or profitable speculation.
The Law of One Price [LOP] – and a “near-LOP” is applicable to relative pricing – even if that
price is wrong.
Ingersoll (1987) defines the LOP as the “proposition ... that two investments with the
same payoff in every state of nature must have the same current value.” In other words, two
securities with the same prices in all states of the world should sell for the same amount. Chen
6
and Knez (1995) extend this to argue that “closely integrated markets should assign to similar
payoffs prices that are close.” They argue that two securities with similar, but not necessarily
matching payoffs across states should have similar prices. This is of course a weaker condition,
and subject to bounds on prices for unusual states, however it allows the examination of “near-
efficient” economies, or in Chen and Knez’ case, near integrated markets. Notice that this
theory corresponds to the desire to find two stocks whose prices move together as long as we can
We use an algorithm to choose pairs based on the criterion that they have had the same or
nearly the same state prices historically. We then trade pairs whose prices closely match in
historical state-space, since the LOP suggests that in an efficient market, their prices should be
nearly identical. In this framework, the current study can be viewed as a test of the LOP and
near-LOP in the U.S. equity markets, under certain stationarity conditions. We are effectively
testing the integration of very local markets – the markets for specific individual securities. This
is similar in spirit to Bossaerts’ (1988) test of co-integration of security prices at the portfolio
level. We further conjecture that the marginal profits to be had from risk arbitrage of these
temporary deviations are crucial to the maintenance of first-order efficiency. We could not have
The pairs trading strategy may be justified within an equilibrium asset-pricing framework
with non-stationary common factors like Bossaerts and Green (1989) and Jagannathan and
Viswanathan (1988). If the long and short components fluctuate with common non-stationary
factors, then the prices of the component portfolios would be co-integrated and the pairs trading
7
strategy would be expected to work. Evidence of exposures to common non-stationary factors
The space of normalized, cum-dividend prices, i.e. cumulative total returns with
dividends re-invested, is the basic space for the pairs trading strategies in this paper. The main
observation about our motivating models of the CAPM-APT variety is that they are known to
imply perfect collinearity of prices, which is readily rejected by the data. On the other hand,
Bossaerts (1988) finds evidence of price co-integration for the US stock market. We would like
to keep the notion of the empirically observed co-movement of prices, without unnecessarily
restrictive assumptions, hence we proceed in the spirit of the co-integrated prices literature.
More specifically, our matching in price space can be interpreted as follows. Suppose that prices
where # it denotes a weakly dependent error in the sense of Bossaerts (1988). Assume also that pit
is weakly dependent after differencing once. Under these assumptions, the price vector pt is co-
integrated of order 1 with co-integrating rank r = n-k , in the sense of Engle and Granger (1987)
and Bossaerts (1988). Thus, there exist r linearly independent vectors {$q}q=1.. r such that zq =
$q`pt are weakly dependent. In other words, r linear combinations of prices will not be driven by
the k common non-stationary components pl. Note that this interpretation does not imply that
the market is inefficient, rather it says that certain assets are weakly redundant, so that any
deviation of their price from a linear combination of the prices of other assets is expected to be
8
To interpret the pairs as co-integrated prices, we need to assume that for n » k, there are
co-integrating vectors which have only two nonzero coordinates. In that case the sum or
difference of scaled prices will be reverting to zero and a trading rule could be constructed to
exploit the expected temporary deviations. Our strategy relies upon exactly this conclusion. In
principle one could construct trading strategies with trios, quadruples, etc. of stocks, which
would presumably capture more co-integrated prices and would yield better profits.
The assumption that a linear combination of two stocks can be weakly dependent may be
interpreted as saying that a co-integrating vector can be partitioned in two parts, such that the
two corresponding portfolios are priced within a weakly dependent error of another stock.
Given the large universe of stocks, this statement is always empirically valid and provides the
The risk of bankruptcy is one reason why the returns on individual securities cannot be
taken as stationary. Sensitivity of the pairs trading to the default premium suggests that the
strategy may work because we are pairing two firms, the first of which may have a constant or
decreasing probability of bankruptcy (short end), while the second may have a temporarily
increasing probability of bankruptcy (long end). The “surprise improvements” in the short end
are then followed by improvement in the long end if that stock survives. In other words, the
source of the profit is the improving ex-post (non)realization of idiosyncratic bankruptcy risk in
the long (loser) stock. In such case, we would expect to have asymmetry in the profits from the
3
Note that the case n » k corresponds to the standard finance paradigm where in the large universe of n stocks, expected returns
are driven by a few, namely k common factors. This paradigm is supported by existing empirical work, e.g. see Connor and
9
long and the short components, with most of the profits coming from the long end4. We test long
2. Methodology
Our implementation of pairs trading has two stages. We form pairs over a twelve-month
period (formation period) and trade them in the next six-month period (trading period). Both
twelve months and six months are chosen arbitrarily and have remained our horizons since the
In each pairs-formation period, we screen out all stocks from the CRSP daily files that
have one or more days with no trade. This serves to identify relatively liquid stocks as well as to
facilitate pairs formation. Next, we construct a cumulative total return index for each stock over
the formation period. We then choose a matching partner for each stock by finding the security
that minimizes the sum of squared deviations between the two normalized price series. Pairs are
thus formed by exhaustive matching in normalized daily “price” space, where price includes re-
invested dividends.
We use this approach because it best approximates the description of how traders
themselves choose pairs. Interviews with pair traders suggest that they try to find two stocks
whose prices “move together.” In addition to “unrestricted” pairs, we will also present results
by sector, where we restrict both stocks to belong to the same broad industry categories defined
by Standard & Poors: Utilities, Transportation, Financial and Industrials. Each stock is assigned
Korajczyk (1993) for references, which generally finds less than ten common non-stationary components.
eree for this example.
10
to one of these four groups, based on the stock’s SIC code. The minimum-distance criterion is
Once we have paired up all liquid stocks in the formation period, we study the top 5 and
20 pairs with the smallest historical distance measure, in addition to the 20 pairs after the top 100
(pairs 101-120). This last set is valuable because most of the top pairs share certain
characteristics, which will be described in detail below. On the day following the last day of the
Figure 1 illustrates the pairs trading strategy using two stocks, Kennecott and Uniroyal in
the six-month period starting in August of 1962. The top two lines represent the normalized
price paths with dividends re-invested, and the bottom line indicates the opening and closing of
the strategy on a daily basis. It is clear why these two firms paired with each other. They
generally tended to move together over the trading interval. Notice that the position first opens
in the seventh trading day of the period and then remains open until day 36. Over that interval,
the spread actually first increased significantly before convergence. The prices remain close
during the period and cross frequently. The pair opens five times during the period, however not
always in the same direction. Neither stock is the “leader.” In our example, convergence
occurs in the final day of the period, although this is not always the case.
We select trading rules based on the proposition that we open a long-short position when
the pair prices have diverged by a certain amount, and close the position when the prices have
reverted. Following practice, we base our rules for opening and closing positions on a standard
deviation metric. We open a position in a pair when prices diverge by more than two historical
11
standard deviations, as estimated during the pairs formation period. We unwind the position at
the next crossing of the prices. If prices do not cross before the end of the trading interval, gains
or losses are calculated at the end of the last trading day of the trading interval. If a stock in a
pair is delisted from CRSP, we close the position in that pair, using the delisting return, or the
last available price5. We report the payoffs by going one dollar short in the higher-priced stock
Because pairs may open and close at various points during the six-month trading period,
the calculation of the excess return on a portfolio of pairs is a non-trivial issue. Pairs that open
and converge during the trading interval will have positive cash flows. Because pairs can re-
open after initial convergence, they can have multiple positive cash flows during the trading
interval. Pairs that open but do not converge will only have cash flows on the last day of the
trading interval when all positions are closed out. Therefore, the payoffs to pairs trading
strategies are a set of positive cash flows that are randomly distributed throughout the trading
period, and a set of cash flows at the end of the trading interval which can either be positive or
negative. For each pair we can have multiple cash flows during the trading interval, or we may
have none in the case when prices never diverge by more than two standard deviations during the
trading interval. Because the trading gains and losses are computed over long–short positions of
one dollar, the payoffs have the interpretation of excess returns. The excess return on a pair
5
The profits are robust with respect to this delisting assumption. A potential problem arises if inaccurate and stale prices
exaggerate the excess returns and bias the estimated return of a long position in a plummeting stock. To address this potential
concern we have re-estimated our results under the extreme assumption that a only a long stock experiences a -100% return when
it is delisted. This zero-price extreme includes among other things, the possibility of non-trading due to lack of liquidity. Since
selective loss on the long position always harms the pair profit, this extreme assumption biases the results against profitability.
However, pairs trading remains profitable under this alternative: for example, the average monthly return on the top-20 pairs
portfolio is 1.32% with a standard deviation of 1.9%.
12
during a trading interval is computed as the reinvested payoffs during the trading interval6. In
particular, the long and short portfolio positions are marked-to-market daily. The daily returns
on the long and short positions are calculated as value-weighted returns in the following way,
where r defines returns and w defines weights, and the daily returns are compounded in order to
obtain monthly returns. This has the simple interpretation of a buy-and-hold strategy.
committed capital and the fully-invested return, i.e. the return on actual employed capital. The
former scales the portfolio payoffs by the number of pairs that are selected for trading, the latter
divides the payoffs by the number of pairs that open during the trading period. The former
measure of excess return is clearly more conservative: if a pair does not trade for the whole of
the trading period, we still include a dollar of committed capital as the cumulative return in our
calculation of excess return. It takes into account the opportunity cost of hedge funds of having
to commit capital to a strategy even if the strategy does not trade. To the extent that hedge funds
are flexible in their sources and uses of funds, computing excess return relative to the actual
capital employed may give a more realistic measure of the trading profits.
We initiate the pairs strategy by trading the pairs at the beginning of every month in the
sample period, with the exception of the first twelve months, which are needed to estimate pairs
for the strategy starting in the first month. The result is a time series of overlapping six-month
trading period excess returns. We correct for the correlation induced by overlap by averaging
6
This is a conservative approach to computing the excess return, because it implicitly assumes that all cash earns zero interest
rate when not invested in an open pair. Because any cash flow during the trading interval is positive by construction, it ignores
the fact that these cash flows are received early, and understates the computed excess returns.
13
monthly returns across trading strategies that start one month apart as in Jegadeesh and Titman
(1993). The resulting time series has the interpretation of the payoffs to a proprietary trading
desk, which delegates the management of the six portfolios to six different traders whose
3. Empirical Results
Table 1 summarizes the excess returns for the pairs portfolios that are unrestricted in the
sense that the matching stocks do not necessarily belong to the same broad industry categories.
In section 3.5 we will consider sector-neutral pairs strategies. Panel A summarizes the excess
returns of pairs strategies when positions are opened at the end of the day that prices diverge, and
closed at the end of the day of price convergence. The first row shows that a fully-invested
portfolio of the five best pairs earned an average excess monthly return of 1.31% (t-statistic =
8.84), and a portfolio of the twenty best pairs 1.44% per month (t = 11.56). Using the more
conservative approach to computing excess returns, using committed capital, gives excess
returns of 0.78% and 0.81% per month respectively. Either way, these excess returns are large in
an economical and statistical sense, and suggest that pairs trading is profitable.
The remainder of Panel A provides information about the excess return distributions of
pairs portfolios. There are diversification benefits from combining multiple pairs in a portfolio.
As the number of pairs in a portfolio increases, the portfolio standard deviation falls. The
diversification benefits are also apparent from the range of realized returns. Interestingly, as the
number of pairs in the strategy increases the minimum realized return increases, while the
maximum realized excess return remains relatively stable. During the full sample period of 474
months, a portfolio of 20 pairs experienced 71 monthly periods with negative payoffs, compared
14
to 124 months for a portfolio of 5 pairs. The decrease in the standard deviation, and the increase
of the lower end of the return distribution is also reflected in an increased skewness coefficient.
Since pairs trading is in essence a contrarian investment strategy, the returns may be
biased upward due to the bid-ask bounce (Jegadeesh (1990), Jegadeesh and Titman (1995),
Conrad and Kaul (1989)). In particular, our strategy sells stocks that have done well relative to
their match and buys those that have done poorly. Part of any observed price divergence is
potentially due to price movements between bid and ask quotes: conditional on divergence, the
winner’s price is more likely to be an ask quote and the loser’s price a bid quote. In Panel A we
have used these same prices for the start of trading and our returns may be biased upward due to
the fact that we are implicitly buying at bid quotes (losers) and selling at ask quotes (winners).
The opposite is true at the second crossing (convergence): part of the drop in the winner’s price
can reflect a bid quote, and part of the rise of the loser’s price an ask quote.
To address this issue, Panel B of Table 1 provides the excess returns when we initiate
positions in each pair on the day following the divergence and liquidate on the day following the
crossing. The average excess returns on the fully-invested portfolios and on committed capital
drop by about 30-55 and 20-35 basis points respectively. While the excess returns remain
significantly positive, the drop in excess returns suggests that a non-trivial portion of the profits
in Panel A may be due to bid-ask bounce. It is difficult to quantify which portion of the profit
reduction is due to bid-ask bounce and which portion stems from true mean reversion in prices
due to rapid market adjustment. None-the-less, this difference raises questions about the
economic significance of our results when we include transactions costs. We will return to a
detailed discussion of this issue in section 3.3. Unless stated otherwise, the remainder of the
paper will report results for pairs strategies that open (close) on the day following divergence
(convergence).
15
3.2 Trading Statistics and Portfolio Composition
Table 2 provides a summary of the trading statistics and composition of the pairs
portfolios. What are the characteristics of the stocks that are matched into pairs? How often
does a typical pair trade? Because pairs trading is an active investment strategy, it is important
to evaluate the profitability relative to the trading intensity of the portfolios. As mentioned
before we use a two standard deviation trigger to open a pairs position. The second line of panel
A in Table 2 reports the average price deviation of the 2 standard deviation trigger. For the top
five pairs, the position typically opens when prices have diverged by 4.76% or more. This is a
relatively narrow gap in prices7. The trigger spread increases with the number of pairs in the
portfolio, because the standard deviation of the prices increases as the proximity of the securities
in price space decreases. The next lines of Panel A also shows that on average almost all pairs
open during the six-month trading period, and on average more than once. Of the top 5 pairs, on
average 4.81 open during the trading period, and the average number of round trips per pair is
2.02. The average duration of an open position is 3.75 months. This indicates that pairs trading
strategy.
capitalization and industry membership. In terms of size, the average stock in the top 5 and top
20 pairs belongs to the second and third deciles from the top; 74% of the stocks in the top 20
pairs belong to the top three size deciles using CRSP breakpoints, and 91% come from the top
five size deciles. About two-thirds of the pairs combine stocks from different size deciles (i.e.
“size mixed pairs”), and the stocks in mixed pairs differ on average by a single decile.
7
The optimal trigger point in terms of profitability may actually be much higher than 2 standard deviations, although we have
16
average, 71% of the stocks in the top 20 pairs are utility stocks, despite the fact that Utilities
represent a fairly small proportion of the stocks in the whole sample. This is not surprising
perhaps, because utility stocks tend to have lower volatility and tend to be correlated with
interest rate innovations. The strategy does not always match stocks within sectors. The
percentage of mixed sector pairs ranges from 20 per cent for the top 5 pairs to 44 per cent for
pairs 101-120. Given the predominance of utilities among the top pairs, it is fair to ask whether
the profitability of pairs trading profitability is limited to the utility sector, or whether pairs
strategies are also profitable in other sectors of the market. We address this question in section
3.5.
Table 1 shows that the average monthly excess return of unrestricted pairs strategies falls from
1.44%, for the top-20 portfolio, to 0.90% per month if we postpone the trades to the day
following the crossing. This drop in the excess returns implies an estimate of the average bid-ask
spread and hence the transactions costs of trading in the sample. While actual transactions costs
may be different, it is informative to know whether the trading profits are large enough to
Suppose the extreme case where the prices of the winner at the first crossing (divergence)
are ask prices and the loser are bid prices. If the next day prices are equally likely to be at bid or
ask the delaying trades by one day will reduce the excess returns on average by half the sum of
the spreads of the winner and the loser. If at the second crossing (convergence) of the pairs the
winners is trading at the bid, and the loser at the ask, waiting one day will reduce the excess
returns on average again by one half of the sum of the bid-ask spreads of both stocks. In this
17
extreme case, waiting a day before trading reduces the return on each pair by the round-trip
transactions costs in that pair. Because we trade each pair on average 2 times during the six-
month trading interval, the drop in the excess returns of 324 basis points per six-months by
waiting one day reflects the cost of 2 round-trips, which implies a transactions costs of 162 bp
per pair per round-trip. This may be interpreted as an estimated effective spread of 81 bp. The
effective spread for the all-pairs portfolio is 70 bp. This indirect estimate is higher than the
transactions costs reported by Peterson and Fialkowski (1994), who find that the average
effective spread for stocks in the CRSP database in 1991 was 37 basis points, and is consistent
with the trading costs estimated by Keim and Madhavan (1997). Since 91% of the stocks in the
top 20 pairs belong to the top 5 deciles of CRSP stocks, it is possible that the effective spread is
Do our trading strategies survive these transactions costs? The profits on our trading
strategies in Table 1 range from 437 to 549 basis points over a six-month period. If the prices
used to compute these excess returns are equally likely to be at bid or ask, which seems a
reasonable assumption, we have to correct these excess returns to reflect that in practice we buy
at the ask and sell at the bid prices. In other words, we have to subtract the round-trip trading
costs to get an estimate of the profits after transactions costs. Our conservative estimate of
transactions costs of 162 bp times 2 rounds trips per pair results in an estimate of 324 bp
transactions cost per pair per six-month period. This gives average net profits ranging from 113
to 225 bp over each six-month period. Comparing these profits to the reported standard errors,
costs of pairs trading strategies. An important question in this context is whether the trading rule
that we have used to open and close pairs can be expected to generate economically significant
18
profits even if pairs trading works perfectly. Because we use a measure of historical standard
deviation to trigger the opening of pairs, and since this estimated standard deviation is the
smallest among all pairs, it is likely to underestimate the true standard deviation of a pair. As a
consequence, we may simply be opening pairs “too soon” and at a point that we cannot expect it
to compensate for transactions costs even if the pair subsequently converges. Results that are not
reported here suggest that this is indeed the case for some of our pairs.
There is a second reason why our trading strategies require “too much” trading. We open
pairs at any point during the trading period when the normalized prices diverge by two standard
deviations. This is not a sensible rule towards the end of a trading interval. For example, suppose
a divergence occurs at the next to last day of the trading interval. The convergence has to be
substantial in order to overcome the transactions cost that will be incurred when we close out the
position on the next day (the last day of the trading interval). Unreported results suggest that this
The pairs formation process thus far has been entirely mechanical. A computer stock has
the opportunity to match with a steel firm, and a utility with a bank stock. This does not mean
that these matches are likely. As shown in Table 2, the fraction of mixed pairs is typically well
below 50 percent. Common factor exposures of stocks in the same industry will make it more
likely to find a match within the same sector. Also, firms that are in industries where cross-
sectional differences in factor exposures are small or return variances are low are more likely to
end up among the top ranking of pairs. For this reason it is perhaps not surprising that many of
the top pairs match two utilities. Are the profits to pairs trading consistent across sectors? We
examine the returns on pairs trading where stocks are matched only within the four large sector
19
groupings used by Standard and Poor’s: Utilities, Transportation, Financials, and Industrials.
The results are summarized in Table 3. As in Table 1, the pairs are traded with a one-day delay
before opening and closing a position in order to minimize the effect of the bid-ask bounce on
trading. The monthly excess returns for the top 20 pairs are the largest in the Utilities sector, with
1.08% (Newey-West t =10.26). The profits for the other industry groups are somewhat lower,
but all statistically significant, with the average Transportation, Financials, and Industrials top 20
pairs earning 0.58% (NW t = 4.26), 0.78% (NW t = 7.60) and 0.61% (NW t = 6.93) respectively
Table 3 also gives a more detailed picture of the return distributions and trading
characteristics of the pairs trading strategies by sector. It shows that the excess return
distributions of the sector pairs portfolios are generally skewed right and exhibit positive excess
kurtosis relative to a normal distribution. The conclusion from these Tables is that pairs trading is
profitable in every broad sector category, and not limited to a particular sector.
To provide further perspective on the risk of pairs trading, Table 4 compares the risk
premium of pairs trading to the market premium (SP500), and reports the risk-adjusted returns to
pairs trading using two different models for measuring risk. Table 5 summarizes value-at-risk
The top part of Table 4 compares the excess return to pairs trading to the excess return on
the SP500. Between 1963 and 2002, the average excess return to pairs trading has been about
twice as large as the excess return of the SP500, with only one half to one third of the risk as
measured by standard deviation. As a result, the Sharpe Ratios of pairs trading are between 4 and
6 times larger than the Sharpe Ratio of the market. Goetzmann et al. (2002) show that Sharpe
20
Ratios can be misleading when return distributions have negative skewness. This is unlikely to
be a concern for our study, because our Table 1 showed that the returns to pairs portfolios are
positively skewed, which – if anything – would bias our Sharpe ratios downward.
In order to explore the systematic risk exposure of the pairs portfolios, we regress their
monthly excess returns on the three factors of Fama and French (1996), augmented by two
additional factors. The motivation for the additional factors is that pairs strategies invest based
on the relative strength of individual stocks. It is therefore possible that pairs trading simply
exploits patterns in returns that are known to earn significant profits. For example, Jegadeesh
(1990) and Lehmann (1990) show that reversal strategies that select stocks based on prior one-
month return earn positive abnormal returns. We control for this possibility by constructing a
short-term reversal factor measured as the excess return of stocks in the top 3 deciles of prior-
month return minus the return on stocks in the bottom three deciles8. If pairs strategies sell
short-term winners, and buy short-term losers, we expect the exposures of pairs portfolios to be
positive to the reversal factor. The second additional factor controls for exposure to medium-
term return continuation (Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)). To the extent that pairs trading sells
medium-term winners, and buys medium-term losers, the pairs excess returns will be negatively
correlated with momentum. To examine this possibility, we include a momentum factor in our
Table 4 shows that only a small portion of the excess returns of pairs trading can be
attributed to their exposures to the five risk factors. The intercepts of the regressions show that
risk-adjusted returns are significantly positive, and lower than the raw excess returns by about
10-20 bp per month. Because pairs strategies are market-neutral, the exposures to the market are
small and with one exception insignificant. Exposures to the other two FF factors, the difference
8
The construction is similar to Carhart’s (1997) momentum factor, but the performance-sorting horizon here is one month.
21
between small and big stocks (SMB), and the difference between value and growth stocks
(HML), are not significant and the point estimates alternate in sign. The exposures to
momentum and reversals have the predicted signs, and more than half are statistically significant.
As can be expected, some of the winner stocks that a pairs strategy shorts are short-term winners
while others are medium-term winners. Similarly, the losers are evenly divided between short-
term and medium-term losers. Overall the exposures are not large enough to explain the average
returns to pairs trading. The significance of the risk-adjusted returns indicates that pairs trading is
fundamentally different from simple contrarian strategies based on reversion (Jegadeesh (1990)
and Lehmann (1990)). The next sections provide further evidence to support this view.
The bottom of Table 4 shows the results of regressing the pairs returns on an alternative
set of risk factors suggested by Ibbotson: the excess return on the S&P 500, the U.S. small stock
premium, the U.S. bond default premium and the U.S. bond horizon premium. Although the risk
exposures are generally not significant, the signs of coefficients are positive across all portfolios.
Thus, when corporate bonds increase in price relative to government bonds, the pairs portfolios
make money. There are a range of possible explanations for this pattern. Relatively cheaper
borrowing rates by arbitrageurs may force stock prices closer to equilibrium values, or common
factors affecting convergence in both stock and bond markets may be responsible. The
portfolios also appear to be sensitive to shifts in the yield curve, i.e. when long-term spreads
decrease, pairs trading is more profitable. At first glance, the sensitivity to term-structure
measures may be explained by the presence of interest rate sensitive Utility stocks in many of the
top pairs. However, interest rate movements also seem to matter for the more broadly diversified
pairs portfolios. In sum, the pairs portfolios seem to have low exposure to various sources of
systematic risk. The R-squared of most regressions is low, indicating that the portfolios are
nearly factor-neutral. This may be expected since they are constructed in a way that should
22
essentially match up economic substitutes.
Table 5 reports both monthly and daily value at risk [VAR] measures to summarize the
quantiles of the empirical distributions of the pairs’ excess returns. Panel A shows that the worst
monthly loss over the almost 40-year sample period was 12.6 % for the top five pairs portfolio,
and 8.2% for the top 20 portfolio. On average, only once in every hundred months did these
portfolios lose more than 4.32 % and 1.94 % respectively. Panel B shows that on its worst day,
the top five portfolio recorded a 10.08 % loss, compared to a 6.72% loss of the top-20 portfolio.
On average, once every hundred days did these portfolios lose more than 1.24 % and 0.65 %
respectively.
The VAR is useful because it provides a gauge to the potential leverage that could be
applied to these strategies. A five-to-one leverage ratio applied to the top 5 pairs would appear to
have been adequate to cover the worst monthly loss in the 40- year period. Although the lessons
of recent history have taught us not to rely too heavily on historical VAR measures for gauging
capital needs for exploiting convergence strategies, the pairs portfolios seem to be exposed to
Figure 2 shows the monthly performance of the top 20 pairs, based upon the next-day
trading rule. Pairs trading was very profitable in the 1970's and 1980's, and then had a span of
more modest performance, when the returns were sometimes negative. Figure 3 compares the
cumulative excess returns of the top 20 one-day-waiting strategy the cumulative excess returns
of investment in the S&P 500 index. The smooth index of the pairs trading portfolio contrasts
dramatically with the volatility of the stock market. Pairs trading performed well over difficult
times for U.S. stocks. When the U.S. stock market suffered a dramatic real decline from 1969
through 1980, the pairs strategy experienced some of its best performance. By contrast, in the
mid-90s the market performed exceptionally well, but pairs trading profits were relatively flat.
23
Perhaps after its discovery in the early 1980's by Tartaglia and others, competition decreased
opportunity. On the other hand, pair trading might simply be more profitable in times when the
Two additional explanations may account for the temporal variation in profitability. The
first is the long-term trend in transactions costs over the history of our sample. The early part of
the analysis represents a period with high fixed commissions. These frictions might have
prevented the rapid convergence of relative prices. The secular decrease in transactions costs
may have attracted more relative value equity arbitrage. This is becoming increasingly so with
the introduction of more sophisticated trading technologies and networks. The second
explanation may be the rise in hedge funds in the period since 1989. The TASS hedge fund
database reports that hedge fund assets rose from $4 billion in 1977 to $137 billion in 2000, with
the most dramatic growth after 1992. While this database does not capture proprietary trading
operations of investment banks, it does suggest that risk arbitrage activities have grown
significantly in the last decade of our sample period. Of the $137 billion in hedge fund assets in
2000, $119 billion employed “Market Neutral” “Relative Value” or “Arbitrage” strategies, all of
which may potentially impact pairs trading operations. Thus, it is possible that lower
transactions costs and large inflows of investment capital to relative-value arbitrage have
together decreased the rate of return on pairs trading, at least in the simple form we test in this
paper. In section 3.8 we will revisit this issue, and show that in contrast to the raw returns, the
risk-adjusted return to pairs trading has been relatively stable over time.
strategy. The results of Table 4 showed that the returns to pairs are positively correlated with –
24
but not explained by – short-term reversals documented by Lehmann (1990) and
Jegadeesh(1990). In this section we further explore whether our pairs trading strategies are
particular, we conduct a bootstrap where we compare the performance of our pairs to random
pairs. The starting point of the bootstrap is the set of historical dates on which the various pairs
open. In each bootstrap we replace the actual stocks with two random securities with similar
prior one-month returns as the stocks in the actual pair. Similarity is defined as coming from the
same decile of previous month’s performance. The difference between the actual and the
simulated pairs returns provides an indication of the portion of our pairs return that is not due to
reversion. We bootstrapped the entire set of trading dates 200 times. The results are summarized
in Table 6. On average we find that the returns on the bootstrapped pairs are well below the true
pairs returns. In fact, the excess returns to the simulated pairs are slightly negative, and the
standard deviations of the returns are large relative to the true pairs, which is a reflection of the
fact that the simulated pairs are poorly matched. The conclusion from the simulations confirms
the conclusion from the factor regressions, that the pairs strategy does not merely reflect one-
month mean reversion. In addition, in the next section, we will show that the long and short
portfolios that make up a pair do not provide equal contributions to the profitability of the
strategy. These three findings combined strongly suggest that our pairs trading strategy seems to
capture temporal variation in returns that is different from simple mean reversion.
There are at least three reasons to separately examine the returns to the long and short
portfolios that make up a pairs position. First, the separate returns provide further insight into the
question of mean reversion. If pairs trading simply exploits mean reversion, one would expect
25
the abnormal returns to the long and short positions to be equal because the opening of a pair is
equally likely to be triggered by either stock. Second, if the excess returns are predominantly
driven by the short position, it becomes important to examine whether short-sale considerations
might prevent arbitrageurs from competing away the profits. Finally, the risk exposures of the
two portfolios can provide further clues at to the reason for the profitability of pairs – or example
the possibility that the long and short portfolios have different exposures to common non-
stationary risk factors such as bankruptcy risk9. The returns and the risk exposures of the
The Table shows that much of the pairs risk-adjusted excess return comes from the short
portfolio, which contains the stocks that have increased in value relative to their counterparts
prior to opening of the pair. By contrast, the alphas of the long portfolio containing the stocks
that decreased in value relative to their counterparts are smaller, and insignificantly different
from zero for the top-5 and top-20 portfolios. The asymmetry of the results provides further
evidence that the returns to pairs are not due to simple one-month mean reversion. And because
much of the abnormal return comes from the short position, which experienced an increase in
relative value prior to opening, it is unlikely that the returns are driven by a reward for unrealized
bankruptcy risk. The robustness of our results to the cost of short sales will be discussed in
section 3.9.
Table 8 summarizes the profitability of pairs trading when we spit the sample period at
the end of 1988. A comparison between the two top halves of the two panels shows a drop in the
raw excess returns to pairs trading. For example, the excess return of the top-20 strategy drops
9
We thank a referee for suggesting this explanation.
26
from 118 bp per month to about 38 bp per month. Has increased hedge fund activity arbitraged
away the anomalous behavior of pairs since the pre-1989 period? Inspection of the risk adjusted
returns shows that this is not the case: the average risk-adjusted return of the top-20 portfolio
drops by about a third from 67 to 42 basis points per month, but remains significantly positive in
both sub-periods (t = 4.41 and 3.77 respectively). Changes in the factor exposures and factor
volatilities can explain only part of the lower returns in the early part of the sample, but not the
Are the positive risk-adjusted returns to pairs trading a general failure of our risk model?
In other words, are there reasons to believe that the risk adjusted pairs returns are a compensation
for an omitted (latent) risk factor? Inspection of the correlation between disjoint pairs portfolios
provides some support for this view. Moreover, this latent risk factor seems to have been
relatively dormant over the second half of our sample, which can account for the lower recent
profitability of pairs trading. The full-sample correlation between the excess returns of the top-
20 and the 100-120 pairs portfolios is 0.48. Because there is no overlap between the positions of
these portfolios, the correlation indicates the presence of a common factor to the returns.
Moreover, the correlation is 0.51 over the profitable pre-1988 period but much lower (0.18) over
the lower excess return post-1988 period. These correlations are not driven by the 5
“systematic” risk factors we considered, because the correlations of the residuals from the factor
regressions are very similar to the raw correlations. In particular, the correlation between the
residuals is 0.41. The respective sub-period FFMR correlations are 0.42 and 0.20. This is
further illustrated in Figure 4, which shows that the rolling 24-month correlation between the two
These results suggest that there is common component to the profits of pairs portfolios
27
that is not captured by our conventional measures of systematic risk. The common component
was stronger during the first half of our sample, which is consistent with higher profits (abnormal
returns) than in the second half of our sample when the factor was more dormant. These results
are consistent with the view that the abnormal returns documented in this paper are indeed a
compensation for risk, in particular the reward to arbitrageurs for enforcing the “Law of One
Price”.
Having identified and back-tested a filter rule, and subjected it to a range of controls for
risk, the question of the nature of pairs profits remains. Why do prices of close economic
substitutes diverge and converge? The convergence is easier to understand than the divergence,
given the natural arbitrage motivation, and the documented existence of relative-value
arbitrageurs in the U.S. equity market. However, this does not explain why prices drift away
from parity in the first place. One possible explanation is that prices diverge on random liquidity
First, there are explicit short-selling costs in the form of specials. Second, D’Avolio
(2002) argues that short recalls are potentially costly because they may deprive arbitrageurs of
their profits. This opportunity cost is reinforced by D’Avolio’s findings that short recalls are
more common as the price declines. For example, if the short stock is recalled when it starts to
converge downward, then the pair position is forced to close prematurely and the arbitrageur
does not capturing the profit from the pair convergence. We perform two tests for robustness of
The first test is motivated by the findings of D’Avolio (2002) and Getczy et al. (2002)
10
We are grateful to the editor Maureen O’Hara for pointing out this plausible explanation and for suggesting the way to test it.
28
that specials have minimal effect of large stocks. Correspondingly, we test for robustness of
profits by trading pairs that are formed using only stocks in the top three size deciles11. The
results, given in Panel A of Table 9, can be directly compared to those in Panel B of Table 1. The
comparison shows that the profits of the top-20 strategy drop by about 2 basis points per month,
but increase for the top 5 portfolio. Overall, the profits change little and remain highly
significant. This shows that the pairs trading profits are not driven by illiquid stocks that are
likely to be on special.
The second test is motivated by the evidence in Chen et al. (2002) and D’Avolio (2002)
that short recalls are driven by dispersion of opinion. We use high volume as proxy for
divergence of opinion and perform pairs-trading under recalls, where we simulate recalls on the
short positions, and subsequent closing of the pair position, on days with high volume. High
volume days are defined as days on which daily volume exceeds average daily volume over the
18months (both split-adjusted) by more than one standard deviation. Panel B of Table 9 shows
the profits of pairs trading with the high volume recalls. The profits decline slightly by 4-13bp
per month, yet they remain large and positive. For example, the top 20 pairs portfolio earns an
average of 85bp per month with short recalls, with a Newey-West t-statistic of 9.07. The results
Overall, the small effects confirm that the profits persist when trading pairs of large
stocks as well as when shorts are recalled. These results show that pairs trading profits are
robust to short-selling costs. For better-positioned investors, e.g. large institutions and hedge
funds, the pairs trading profits are likely to remain essentially unaffected by potential shorting
costs. Geczy et al. (2002) argue that for large traders, who have better access to most stocks at
“wholesale prices,” direct shorting costs of the rebate rate on short sales are low (4 to 15
11
Using large liquid stocks also mitigates the problem of stocks that are hard to short and can be overvalued, see e.g. Jones and
29
bp/year). The main implicit shorting cost stems from limited availability and is relevant mostly
for general retail investors. The impact of such potential short sales constraints on the
profitability of pairs trading by large investors is mitigated by our use of liquid stocks that trade
4. Conclusion
We examine a hedge fund equity trading strategy based on the notion of co-integrated
prices in a reasonably efficient market, known on Wall Street as pairs trading. Pairs are stocks
which are close substitutes according to a minimum distance criterion using a metric in price
space. We find that trading suitably formed pairs of stocks exhibits profits, which are robust to
conservative estimates of transaction costs. These profits are uncorrelated to the S&P 500,
however they do exhibit low sensitivity to the spreads between small and large stocks and
between value and growth stocks in addition to the spread between high grade and intermediate
grade corporate bonds and shifts in the yield curve. In addition to risk and transactions cost, we
rule out several explanations for the pairs trading profits, including mean-reversion as previously
documented in the literature, unrealized bankruptcy risk, and the inability of arbitrageurs to take
One view of the lower profitability of pairs trading in recent year is that returns are
competed away by increased hedge fund activity. The alternative view, taken in this paper, is that
abnormal returns to pairs strategies are a compensation to arbitrageurs for enforcing the “Law of
One Price”. We present two pieces of empirical evidence that supports this view. First, while raw
returns have fallen the risk-adjusted returns have continued to persist despite increased hedge
fund activity. Second, our results suggest that the change in risk-adjusted returns of pairs trading
Lamont (2002).
30
is accompanied by the diminished importance of a common factor that drives the returns to pairs
strategies. A further examination of the nature of this common factor and its link to the
31
References:
Bakshi, G. and Z. Chen, 1997, “Stock Valuation in Dynamic Economies,” working paper, Ohio
State University.
D’Avolio, G., 2002, “The Market for Borrowing Stock,” Journal of Financial Economics, 66,
271-306.
Bossaerts, P. and R. Green, 1989, “A General Equilibrium Model of Changing Risk Premia:
Theory and Evidence,” Review of Financial Studies, 2, 467-493.
Chen, J., H. Hong and J. Stein, 2002, “Breadth of Ownership and Stock Returns,” Journal of
Financial Economics, 66, 171-205.
Chen, Z. and P. Knez, 1995, “Measurement of Market Integration and Arbitrage,” Review of
Financial Studies, 8, 287-325.
Carhart, M., 1997, “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance,” Journal of Finance, 52, 57-
82.
Connor, G. and R. Korajczyk, 1993, “A Test for the Number of Factors in an Approximate
Factor Model,” Journal of Finance, 48, 1263-1291.
Conrad, J. and G. Kaul, 1989, “Mean Reversion in Short-horizon Expected Returns,” Review of
Financial Studies, 2, 225-240.
Fama, E. and K. French, 1996, “Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pricing Anomalies,” Journal
of Finance 51, 131-155.
Froot, K. and E. Dabora, 1999, “How are Stock Prices Affected by the Location of Trade?,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 53, 189-216.
Geczy, C., D. Musto and A. Reed, 2002, “Stocks are Special Too: An Analysis of the Equity
Lending Market,” Journal of Financial Economics 66, 241-269.
Goetzmann W., et al., “Sharpening Sharpe Ratios”, working paper, Yale School of Management.
Hansell, S., 1989, “Inside Morgan Stanley's Black Box,” Institutional Investor, May, 204.
Ingersoll, J., Jr., 1987, Theory of Financial Decision-Making, Rowman and Littlefiled, New
Jersey.
32
Jagannathan, R. and S. Viswanathan, 1988, “Linear Factor Pricing, Term Structure of Interest
Rates and the Small Firm Anomaly,” Working Paper 57, Northwestern University.
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, “Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers:
Implications for Stock Market Efficiency,” Journal of Finance, 48, 65-91.
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1995, “Overreaction, Delayed Reaction, and Contrarian Profits,”
Review of Financial Studies, 8, 973-93.
Jones, C. and O. Lamont, 2002, “Short-sale Constraints and Stock Returns,” Journal of
Financial Economics, 66, 207-239.
Keim, D. and A. Madhavan, 1997, “Transactions Costs and Investment Style: An Inter-exchange
Analysis of Institutional Equity Trades,” Journal of Financial Economics, 46, 265-292.
Lee, C., et al., 1997, “What is the Intrinsic Value of the Dow?,” working paper, Cornell
University.
Lehmann, B., 1990, “Fads, Martingales and Market Efficiency,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 105, 1-28.
Peterson, M. and D. Fialkowski, 1994, “Posted versus Effective Spreads: Good Prices or Bad
Quotes?,” Journal of Financial Economics, 35, 269-292.
33
Table 1: Excess Returns of Unrestricted Pairs Trading Strategies
Summary statistics of the monthly excess returns on portfolios of pairs between July 1963 and December 2002 (474
observations). We trade according to the rule that opens a position in a pair at the end of the day that prices of the
stocks in the pair diverge by two historical standard deviations (Panel A). The results in Panel B correspond to a
strategy that delays the opening of the pairs position by one day. All pairs are ranked according to least distance in
historical price space. The “top n” portfolios include the n pairs with least distance measures, and the portfolio
“101
34
Table 2: Trading Statistics and Composition of Pairs Portfolios
Trading statistics and portfolio composition of portfolios of pairs portfolios between July 1963 to December 2002
(474 months). Pairs are formed over a 12 month period according to a minimum distance criterion, and then traded
over the subsequent 6 month period. We trade according to the rule that opens a position in a pair on the day
following the day on which the prices of the stocks in the pair diverge by two historical standard deviations. The
“top n” portfolios include the n pairs with least distance measures, and the portfolio “101-120" studies the twenty
pairs after the top 100. Panel A summarizes the trading characteristics of a pairs strategy. Pairs are opened when
prices diverge by two standard deviations. Average deviation to trigger opening of pair is the cross-sectional
average of two standard deviations which panel B contains information about the size and industry membership of
the stocks in the various pairs portfolios.
Average price deviation trigger for opening pairs 0.04758 0.05284 0.07560 0.16888
Average number of pairs traded per 6-month period 4.81 19.30 19.41 1944.22
Average number of round-trip trades per pair 2.02 1.96 1.78 1.62
Standard deviation of number of round-trips per pair 0.62 0.40 0.27 0.16
Average time pairs are open in months 3.75 3.76 3.98 3.97
Standard dev. of time open, per pair, in months 0.80 0.45 0.38 0.17
35
Table 3: Industry Sector Pairs Trading
Summary statistics for the excess monthly return distributions for pairs trading portfolios by sector. We trade
according to the “wait 1 day” rule described in the text. The average number of stocks in the industry groups is as
follows: 156 Utilities, 61 Transportation, 371 Financials, and 1729 Industrials. There is no “20 after 100" portfolio
for the Transportation industry group. The t-statistic of the mean is computed using Newey-West standard errors
with six lags.
36
Table 4: Systematic Risk of Pairs Trading Strategies
Monthly risk exposures for portfolios of pairs formed and traded according to the “Wait One Day” rule discussed in
the text, over the period between June 1963 and December 2002. The five actors are the three Fama-French
factors, Carhart’s Momentum factor, and the Reversal factor discussed in the text. Returns for the portfolios are in
excess of the riskless rate. S&P 500 returns are calculated in excess of Treasury bill returns. The Ibbotson factors
are from the Ibbotson EnCorrr analyzer: The U.S. Small stock premium is the monthly geometric difference
between small company stock total returns and large company stock total returns. U.S. bond default premium is the
monthly geometric difference between total return to long-term corporate bonds and long term government bonds.
The U.S. bond horizon premium is the monthly geometric difference between investing in long term government
bonds and U.S. treasury bills. t-statistics are in parentheses below the coefficients and are computed using Newey-
West standard errors with 6 lags.
37
Table 5: Value at Risk of Pairs Trading
Monthly and daily value-at-risk percentiles of pairs trading strategies between July 1963 to December 2002 (474
months). Pairs are formed over a 12 month period according to a minimum distance criterion, and then traded
over the subsequent 6 month period. We trade according to the rule that opens a position in a pair on the day
following the day on which the prices of the stocks in the pair diverge by two historical standard deviations. The
“top n” portfolios include the n pairs with least distance measures, and the portfolio “101-120" studies the twenty
pairs after the top 100. The average number of pairs in the all-pair portfolio is 2057.
Value at Risk
1% -0.04320 -0.01943 -0.02236 -0.01994
5% -0.02142 -0.01002 -0.01293 -0.00877
10% -0.01516 -0.00577 -0.00756 -0.00614
25% -0.00460 0.00054 -0.00145 -0.00146
Probability of return below 0 0.35 0.23 0.28 0.32
Min. historical observation -0.12628 -0.08218 -0.04266 -0.02951
Value at Risk
1% -0.01236 -0.00647 -0.00653 -0.00327
5% -0.00710 -0.00398 -0.00400 -0.00202
10% -0.00504 -0.00293 -0.00288 -0.00149
25% -0.00239 -0.00133 -0.00130 -0.00071
Probability of return below 0 0.47 0.44 0.45 0.46
Min. historical observation -0.10079 -0.06723 -0.01987 -0.01069
38
Table 6: Returns to Random Pairs Sorted on Prior One Month Return
Bootstrap of random pairs traded according to the rule which opens a position in a random pair when the stocks in
the true pair diverge by two historical standard deviations and closes the position after the next crossing of prices.
The random stocks are selected within the same last-month performance decile on the day the position is opened.
The top panel gives summary statistics of the monthly excess returns on value-weighted portfolios of n pairs of
stocks where the position is opened immediately. The last column is a portfolio of all 120 top pairs. The bottom
panel summarizes the performance with 1 day waiting before the position is opened. The statistics are computed
over 200 replications of the bootstrapped sample.
39
Table 7: Returns to Long and Short Components of Pairs
Monthly risk profile for the long and short positions of the pairs portfolios formed and traded according to the “Wait One Day” rule discussed in the text. The
returns in the bottom half of the table are in exccess of the 30-day T-bill returns. The risk adjustment includes the Fama-French factors, as well as Momentum
and the Reversal factors discussed in the text. The t-statistics are computed using Newey-West standard errors with 6 lags. Absolute kurtosis is reported.
40
Table 8: Subperiod Analysis
Panel A: pre-1989
Monthly risk profile for portfolios of pairs formed and traded according to the “Wait One Day” rule discussed in
the text, over the two sub-periods 7/1963-12/1988 (Panel A) and 1/1989- 12/2002 (Panel B). The “top n” portfolios
include the n pairs with least distance measures, and the portfolios” 20 after top 100" has the pairs after the top
100 pairs. The average number of pairs in the all-pair portfolio is 2057. The t-statistics are computed using
Newey-West correction with six lags for the standard errors.
41
Table 9: Robustness to Short-selling Costs
Summary statistics of the monthly excess returns on portfolios of pairs. We trade according to the rule that opens a
position in a pair when the prices of the stocks in the pair diverge by two historical standard deviations. Panel B
reports the summary statistics for the rule that waits one-day before opening and closing the position. The “top n”
portfolios include the n pairs with least distance measures, and the portfolios ”20 after top 100" has the pairs after
the top 100 pairs. The average number of pairs in the all-pair portfolio is 2057. There are 474 monthly
observations, from 7/1963 until 12/2002. The t-statistics are computed using the Newey-West standard errors with
6-lag correction. Absolute kurtosis is reported.
42
Figure 1
43
Figure 2
44
Figure 3
45
Figure 4
46