John Favaro: I. The Wisdom

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

John Favaro

The Crowd: Wisdom or Madness?

John Favaro

Viareggio, 10 April 2010

Introduction

A few years ago a brother gave me a book on musical temperament. Reading the book
inspired the topic of my lecture in 2003. This year, instead of a book leading me to the
topic of my lecture, it‘s the other way around: the topic of my lecture led me to a book.

With the rise of the Internet, Wikipedia, and social networking, the idea of talking about
―collective intelligence‖ had been percolating in my mind for quite a while. Finally I
decided to talk about it this year, and that led me to read a book called The Wisdom of
Crowds by James Surowiecki – so now you know where part of the title of this lecture
came from. It turned out that the title of that book was partly a homage to another book,
called The Madness of Crowds. And there you have it, the title of this year‘s lecture –a
homage to a homage. In any case, it does capture the essence of a question I want to
talk about today: are we collectively smart or stupid?

I. The Wisdom
The Wisdom of Crowds starts out with a story about a country fair in England where a
crowd correctly guesses the weight of a cow. But before I get to that story, I want to
dwell a moment on the story that really had me spellbound: the story of this guy‘s life.
I‘m not talking about the author of the book. I‘m talking about the man who reported on
the cow-weight-guessing at the fair. His name was Francis Galton.

Francis Galton and Vox Populi

Peter Bernstein has written, ―Francis Galton was one of those men of a Victorian age
who roamed the earth as if he owned it.‖ The Victorian Age – what a time that was! If
you were lucky enough to be born into the right circumstances and had your wits about
you and a solid dose of intelligence, the world really was your oyster. Francis Galton
certainly fit the bill. He was a half-cousin of Charles Darwin, no slouch himself.
Darwin‘s trip to the Galapagos Islands inspired Galton to travel to Africa, where he had
his own share of adventures. One of his hobbies was admiring beautiful women and
running up check marks on cards grading each woman he saw (he determined that the
most beautiful women in Britain were in London, the ugliest in Aberdeen). While in
Africa, he encountered the Hottentot tribe. The curvaceous figures of the women
astonished him so much that he was dying to take the measurements of one of them.
But he was understandably worried that a tribesman would grant him his wish (of
dying, that is) if he caught him wrapping his arms around one of the women, measuring

John Favaro Tel +39 050 55 60 74


Via Gamerra, 17 Fax +39 050 6143 1145
56123 Pisa - Italy [email protected]
www.favaro.net/john
John Favaro
tape in hand. So he surveyed her – literally. He casually paced off several meters from
where she was standing, and then used his surveying instruments to triangulate his
measurements from a safe distance, thereby managing to obtain her dimensions without
ever touching her (thereby saving himself a lot of trouble).

In other words, he was a genuine English eccentric. I have a friend and colleague who
loves to collect stories about English eccentrics (another fan of English eccentrics is the
author Bill Bryson). One thing they seem to have in common is an extraordinary
intellect. Galton could read any book by the time he was four. He didn‘t just dabble in
several scientific disciplines, he produced important results in them. In mathematics he
invented the concept of ―correlation,‖ a keystone of modern statistics, and the concept
of ―reversion to the mean‖ (ditto). You may not immediately recognize the term, but
―reversion to the mean‖ is actually ingrained in our everyday lives. Every time you say
―this rain has to stop sometime‖ you‘re invoking reversion to the mean. Every time you
say, ―what goes up must come down,‖ you‘re invoking reversion to the mean.

Galton liked to study late into the night, and to keep himself awake he invented a
machine that would douse him with water if he dozed off. He also invented a device
that would allow him to read underwater, and almost drowned in his bathtub one day.
He was also the proud inventor of fingerprinting. It was he who got the idea that all
fingerprints were unique and did not change throughout a person‘s life, and therefore
would be useful for forensic purposes. On the somewhat darker side, he was also the
inventor of eugenics, the study of heredity in human intelligence that gave Adolf Hitler
some really nasty ideas several decades later. (To be fair, it doesn‘t seem that he shared
Hitler‘s point of view, but things are admittedly somewhat fuzzy in the historical
record.)

I said earlier that the reason Galton got into Surowiecki‘s book was that story about
guessing the weight of a cow at a country fair. As you can see from the episode with the
Hottentot women, Galton loved to measure things. It turned out by a stroke of luck that
the various guesses made by the people had been written down on cards and saved. So
suddenly Galton had a mass of data on his hands – irresistible for one of the founding
fathers of modern statistics. (In statistics they have a saying: ―Without the data, yo‘
chatta‘ don‘t matta‘‖). He took the guesses (just under 800 of them) and calculated the
average. Then he noted in an article he wrote in Nature magazine in 1907:

According to the democratic principle of ―one vote one value,‖ the middlemost estimate expresses
the vox populi ...

(The title of the article was ―Vox Populi,‖ too.) In other words, as Surowiecki put it,
―That number represented, you could say, the collective wisdom of the … crowd. If the
crowd were a single person, that was how much it would have guessed the ox
weighed.‖

The crowd had guessed 1,197 pounds. The right answer turned out to be 1,198 pounds.
With typical English understatement, Galton summed it up with:

This result is, I think, more creditable to the trustworthiness of a democratic judgment than might
have been expected.

-2-
John Favaro
Certainly more than he might have expected. As the inventor of eugenics, whose goal
was essentially to weed out inferior intellects from the population, he must have been
shocked that those inferior intellects got it spot on.

Finding the USS Scorpion

Surowiecki recounts another impressive story regarding a lost submarine. On 22 May


1968 the USS Scorpion (SSN-589), a Skipjack-class submarine of the United States
Navy, disappeared in the Atlantic, for reasons that remain unclear today. Now, the
Atlantic Ocean is a big place; and when ships sink, often the simplest thing to do is just
leave them there rather than go looking for them. After all, the Titanic sank in 1912 but
they didn‘t go looking for it until 1985. Same with the German Battleship Bismarck: it
went down in 1941, and they got around to looking for it in 1989. But the Scorpion was
different: it was a nuclear submarine – and you can‘t just leave a nuclear submarine
lying around. So they had to find it, period.

But as I said, the Atlantic Ocean is a big place. The Navy knew the last position of the
submarine before radio contact was lost, but not much else – especially since they
didn‘t know why it went down. Now, normally you would expect that the Navy would
gather up the best experts they could find and pick the most plausible solution offered
by one of them. Dr. John Craven, who was in charge of the search operation, decided on
a different tack. For starters, he decided to use something called Bayesian Search
Theory. This was not a coincidence: two years earlier, another nuclear device (this time
a hydrogen bomb) had been lost when a B-52 plane had crashed in Palomares, Spain,
and Bayesian Search Theory had been developed to help find it. (For my part, I find it
rather unsettling that the military loses so many nuclear devices.)

Then, instead having specialists work together, Dr. Craven assembled the broadest
multi-disciplinary team he could find – people who knew something about all kinds of
different fields – and had them, independently of each other, guess what happened to
the submarine. He even used bottles of whiskey as prizes in the guessing game. Using
the Bayesian Search Theory, he collected all these guesses together and pieced them
into a composite picture that was, ―roughly speaking, the group‘s collective estimate of
where the submarine was.‖ As Surowiecki stresses, the estimated location didn‘t
correspond to any of the individual guesses. None of these people individually had
enough wisdom to guess right. But putting them all together: they found the submarine
less than 200 meters away from where their collective estimate said it would be.

Collective Intelligence

How the heck did they do it? That is what has everybody so excited. Somehow, some
way, it appears that a crowd of diverse, independently acting people possesses
something called collective intelligence – an intelligence that is even more intelligent
than the most intelligent individual in that crowd; and there are attempts being made
everywhere to harness that collective intelligence.

A prestigious example is the Center for Collective Intelligence at the Massachusetts


Institute of Technology. Here they have launched a number of projects to try to exploit
collective intelligence in some very surprising applications. For example, one project
has the title The Climate Collaboratorium: Harnessing Collective Intelligence to
-3-
John Favaro
Address Climate Change Issues. Another is called Collective Intelligence In
Healthcare, and ― … focuses on harnessing the collective intelligence of medical
professionals, researchers, and others to provide better healthcare for individual
patients.‖ Yet another is entitled Collective Prediction, whose purpose is ― … to make
accurate predictions about future events such as product sales, political events, and
outcomes of medical treatments.‖ Let‘s talk about that last one now.

Prediction Markets

The lesson from Galton‘s cow-weight-guessing story is that a crowd can make a better
guess than an individual. An obvious way to harness this phenomenon is to put the
crowd to work in an area that, by its very nature, always involves guessing: predicting
the future. It turns out that this is a huge business. There are so-called prediction
markets today for just about anything. They are also called event derivatives. (You have
just heard the word derivative for the first, but not the last time, in this talk.)

Some are familiar, such as horse-racing handicapping and election polls. The most
famous operation is the Iowa Electronic Markets run by the University of Iowa. Others
are less familiar, but no less successful. The Hollywood Stock Exchange is a virtual,
Web-based game where the players effectively make predictions about things like box
office success of films and this year‘s Oscar winners. They always seem to do better
than the ―experts‖. In 2007, they managed to predict 32 of the 39 major-category Oscar
nominees and 7 out of 8 top-category winners. Corporations are very interested in
harnessing the power of prediction markets to find out whether their products will sell.

But the oddest prediction market of all involved the military. On September 11, 2001,
over and above the obvious human tragedy, the Pentagon also got a black eye for not
seeing it coming, in spite of all its intelligence-gathering mechanisms. So they decided
to try a more innovative approach and proposed the creation of what they called the
Policy Analysis Market. It would be a prediction market like others, in the sense that it
would be freely open to the general public; anybody could participate. But the topics
didn‘t involve Hollywood actors or horses. Rather, they involved questions like ―Will
the leader of Syria be assassinated?‖ ―When will the next terrorist attack in Baghdad
occur?‖ Officially, the Policy Analysis Market was called ―a market in the future of the
Middle East,‖ and any kind of possible political development in the Middle East was
fair game for a bet.

One thing they didn‘t expect was the enormous backlash from all sides. Senator Ron
Wyden stated in a press conference that ―the idea of a federal betting parlor on
atrocities and terrorism is ridiculous and it‘s grotesque.‖ Others objected that betting on
things like assassinations could actually create ―assassination markets‖ that would
encourage some to try and make the predictions come true. The Pentagon finally gave
up on the idea – much to the chagrin of Surowiecki himself, a big supporter.

The interesting thing is that policy analysis markets as such didn‘t disappear as a
consequence, they just migrated into the private sphere. Today, commercial prediction
markets like Intrade allow bets on events like the capture of Osama Bin Laden or
whether Iran will be bombed – very much the kind of thing envisioned for the original
Policy Analysis Market.

-4-
John Favaro
Democracy

It‘s all very nice that the aggregating mechanisms of collective intelligence can be
harnessed for horse racing, acting award ceremonies, and the like. But why not apply
them to the noblest purpose of them all? Let‘s go back to that sentence of Francis
Galton where he talks about the ―…the democratic principle of ‗one vote one value‘ …‖
Because in the end, this is what democracy is all about, isn‘t it? The people‘s choice,
vox populi. And what could be more important than making democracy work as
effectively as possible, so that the best collective choice is made by the people? And
that brings us to the subject of the aggregating mechanism for political choices of the
crowd: voting.

Galton reminds us that at the heart of democracy is the simple principle ―One Person,
One Vote.‖ But that simple principle obscures a question with a surprisingly
complicated answer: ―What is the best way to implement the voting process?‖

Many of you will have voted in the regional elections here in Tuscany two weeks ago
[28 March 2010]. As usual in Italy, there were many parties on the ballot, and I‘m sure
that at least some of you didn‘t vote for the person you really wanted, because of a
classic voting dilemma that might be called the ―outsider‖ dilemma. It goes something
like this: ―I know that my candidate doesn‘t really have a chance, so if I vote for my
candidate, I‘m throwing away my vote – or worse, I‘m playing into the hand of the
candidate I really don‘t want to win – so I‘m going to vote for this other candidate
instead, who isn‘t the one I really want, but is better than the one I really don‘t want.‖
The classic outsider presidential candidate in the United States for many years was
Ralph Nader, the consumer rights crusader, and many people who would have liked to
vote for him did not, for exactly the reasons I outlined above.

This problem of ―not wanting to waste your vote‖ manifests itself in many ways. Last
month [March 2010] people were pretty shocked when the historic U.S. health reform
bill passed in the House without one single Republican vote. Aside from the obvious
partisan issues, there was a feeling that the voting system itself is broken, so there‘s a
lot of interest right now in finding better ways to vote. A few weeks ago [24 March
2010] New York Times columnist Thomas Friedman suggested introducing the
Alternative Vote – which is actually known under a variety of names: Instant Runoff
Voting, the preferential ballot, and ranked choice voting. The basic idea is that you can
list more than one candidate, in order of preference. It has been in use in Australia, for
example, for many years (although several readers reminded Friedman that another
essential characteristic of voting in Australia is that it is compulsory).

Alternative Voting is only one of several different voting systems – exhaustive ballot,
contingent votes, two round systems, and others. The point is that it‘s not just the
collective intelligence of the crowd that matters, it‘s how you aggregate their choices in
the best way to produce the best result. And as I said, where could that be more
important than in our political systems?

Ants

Prediction markets and elections provide an example of harnessing the collective


intelligence of human beings. But the classic examples of collective intelligence that
-5-
John Favaro
everybody is more familiar with are found in the animal world. Insects like ants and
termites build these amazing structures by just following simple rules that they
instinctively know. A well-known phenomenon is called the ―Ant Spiral of Death‖.
This happens when ants get lost for some reason. A lost ant obeys a simple rule like
―follow the ant in front of you.‖ But when they‘re all lost, they sometimes just end up
forming a circle by following that rule, and keep walking and walking, sometimes for
days, until they literally drop dead from exhaustion.

But normally their innate rules work very well, and allow them to create structures of
jaw-dropping complexity and sophistication. There are several videos on YouTube that
show excavations of large ant colonies by researchers. In one such video the narrator
remarks,

[After weeks of excavations], at last they begin to see the structure of the city-state. There are
subterranean highways connecting the main chambers, and off the main routes are side roads. The
paths branch and lead to many fungus gardens and rubbish pits. The tunnels are designed to ensure
good ventilation and provide the shortest transport routes. Everything looks like it has been
designed by a single architect, a single mind, but of course that isn’t true. This colossal and
complex city was created by the collective will of the ant colony – the super-organism. The
structure covers 50 square meters and goes 8 meters into the earth. In its construction, the colony
moved 40 tons of soil. Billions of antloads of soil were brought to the surface. Each load weighed
four times as much as the worker, and in human terms, was carried a kilometer to the surface. It is
the equivalent of building the Great Wall of China. It is truly a wonder of the world.

Emergence

The giant ant colony is an example of what is called emergent behavior. Through the
individual behavior of numerous ―agents‖ (e.g. ants), a kind of collective behavior
emerges that can only be associated with the whole – the super-organism, as the
narrator above called it. Here, too, the military has poked its head through the window
to see if there is anything it can make use of. Sure enough, there is active research going
on in the military on what is known as swarming.

A swarm of insects is an object of envy to military aviation planners. We‘ve all seen
how they move around in formations that compose and recompose themselves without
any seeming instructions from anywhere. How does their ―command and control‖
system work? The Air Force would like to know, and it would like to harness it for its
own use. They have this idea of creating swarms of Unmanned Aerial Vehicles (UAVs)
that they send out into the field against the enemy. Like insect swarms, there would be
lots of them (thousands); they would be self-sufficient; their behavior would not be
entirely predictable; and they would be resistant to individual losses.

If you‘re nervous about the idea of a bunch of deadly air vehicles swarming around,
with nobody sure about just what they‘re going to do next, you‘re in good company.
The military‘s biggest problem is convincing people this won‘t get out of control.

Indeed, this is the flip side of emergent behavior: it‘s not always a good thing.
Sometimes you don‘t want emergent behavior. Sometimes, when you combine things,
you just want them to do what they know how to do and nothing else. In my work in
safety-critical systems (e.g. automobiles, trains, space systems), emergent behavior is a
huge problem. Engineers are always worried that, even after putting a bunch of well-
-6-
John Favaro
tested components together in, say, a car, they‘ll interact in such a way that some totally
unexpected (and ruinous) behavior emerges out of the whole. You want your car to do
what you tell it to do. You don‘t want it to acquire a mind of its own.

Mitchel Resnick of MIT has created a programming system called StarLogo for
studying environments with lots of simple agents (ants, fish, termites, etc.) obeying
simple rules. StarLogo is based on the original Logo system, which was developed by
Seymour Papert of MIT for teaching children to program. It can be freely downloaded
from the Internet and has been successfully used in high school educational programs.
Based upon his work studying the ―massively parallel microworlds‖ of ants and the
like, Mitchel Resnick has written a book entitled Turtles, Termites, and Traffic Jams –
which brings me to the next subject.

Traffic

Three things have always puzzled me; after all these years, decades, sometimes even
centuries of research:

We still can’t predict the weather. Actually, we do finally have a plausible


explanation from Chaos theory regarding why this is the case (and why it will
always be the case). You can find a discussion of that in my previous lecture on
Chaos theory.
We still don’t know why we sleep. Incredibly, scientists still don‘t really know
why we need sleep. We sleep for a third of our lives and we still don‘t know
why! To a great extent, scientists have given up for now on the why, and are
instead concentrating on finding ways to make sure that we get enough of it.
We still don’t know what causes traffic jams.

I would have thought that, by now, people would have figured out what causes traffic
jams and done something about it. It turns out it‘s not that simple, and incredibly, there
are enormous academic disputes about just where the problem lies. There are a number
of perfectly respectable scientists who even say that traffic jams have no cause at all –
they just appear ―spontaneously‖.

If ants can (mostly) manage their traffic smoothly, why can‘t humans? A little reflection
yields an intuitive idea of the reason: the ants are all following some kind of common
set of rules that yields a high degree of coordination. But human drivers all have minds
of their own. Certainly they all have to follow the basic rules of traffic, but aside from
that, they pretty much do what they want to do. So one idea is to have drivers behave
more like ants – that is, get them to coordinate better.

The so-called automated highway system (also called a Smart Road) is an example of
this. They actually built one of these about 20 years ago, in Southern California. The
road had sensors built into it that basically took control away from the driver and gave it
to the cars. The result was that the cars all lined up beautifully and traffic flow was
smooth as silk.

The problem is that drivers don‘t like to give up their autonomy. They don‘t want the
road – smart or not – telling them what to do. They want to be in the driver‘s seat, so to

-7-
John Favaro
speak. So people are looking for ways to provide coordination without taking control
away from the driver. I have actually come into contact with projects in which they
have done this. The HIDENETS project, sponsored by the European Commission,
studied the concept of car platooning. This consists of cars connected with each other
with wireless communication so that each knows what the other is doing and they can
try to coordinate, kind of like a flock of birds. Time will tell how well that idea works
out – in the meantime we‘ll have to get used to sitting in those traffic jams.

We‘ve spent a lot of time so far talking about the different ways in which people are
harnessing the wisdom of crowds, whether in finding lost things, or predicting the
future, or getting traffic untangled. I think it‘s time to take a look at the other side now.

II. The Madness


We had that great British eccentric Francis Galton to introduce us to the wisdom of
crowds. And now we are fortunate to have his Scottish contemporary, Charles Mackay,
to introduce us to the madness of crowds. Was Mackay also an eccentric? Well, he
certainly shared with Galton the characteristic of being brilliant in a number of different
fields. In fact, in his life he was most famous for his songwriting (like the popular
Cheer, Boys, Cheer). He also wrote a dictionary of Lowland Scotch.

But he is known today for a book entitled Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the
Madness of Crowds, published when he was only 27 years old. The book is still in
print– in no less than six different editions. (And by the way, it is in the public domain
and you can download it free on the Internet; I did just that, and put it on my Kindle to
read.) The book gets off to a roaring start like this:

Men, it has been well said, think in herds; it will be seen that they go mad in herds, while they only
recover their senses slowly, and one by one.

So why is the book so famous? It actually covered a broad swath of topics that ranged
from witch hunts to alchemists to the crusades. But the part of the book that earned
Mackay immortality concerned economic bubbles. It‘s probably not surprising to most
of you that there is so much interest in financial craziness – after all, it‘s been in the
news a lot lately with the worldwide economic crisis. What may be surprising to you
(and it certainly was to me) is how long this craziness has been going on. Even without
the advantages of modern technology, transport, and communication, people have been
managing to create enormous financial messes for centuries.

One bubble described by Mackay involved the South Sea Company, which was
founded in 1711. The company had a monopoly on trading in Spain‘s South American
colonies and speculation in the company‘s stock eventually led to a huge crash. Then
there was the Mississippi Company bubble around the same time. This one also had to
do with speculating on the riches of New World colonies of European countries – but
this time the European country was France and the New World colony was Louisiana.
In any case, the result was the same: a huge crash and a lot of ruined lives.

-8-
John Favaro
But the most famous bubble described by Mackay occurred nearly a century earlier
than the other two, and this time a European country was able to make a perfectly good
financial mess all on its own, without any help from New World colonies.

The Dutch Tulip Mania

The economic bubble and crash that has the dubious honor of being the first on record
occurred in 17th Century Holland. Some things are so closely associated with a country
that we forget they weren‘t always there. It‘s hard to imagine Italy without the tomato
(in the region of Puglia where my wife is from, they call it oro rosso – red gold), but of
course it has only been there since the discovery of the New World. Likewise, think
―Holland‖ and the first thing that comes to mind is the tulip. But the tulip was only
introduced into Holland in the mid-16th century from Turkey. Tulips were soon a big hit
in Holland and everybody wanted them. Prices got higher and higher. In order to satisfy
demand, an exchange was created in which people could buy ―tulip futures‖ – contracts
on future deliveries of tulips. These first-of-a-kind financial ―instruments‖ were then
further refined as options – the opportunity but not the obligation to buy tulips. Options
are a form of – and here‘s that word again – derivatives.

By early 1637, a tulip contract was selling for more than ten times the annual income of
a skilled craftsman. But as we all know now from Francis Galton and the principle of
reversion to the mean, ―what goes up must come down.‖ In February 1637 the market
crashed, and a legend was born: the Dutch Tulip Mania.

To this day, financial bubbles – for example, the dotcom bubble in the late 1990s that
burst in the year 2000 – are commonly referred to as Tulip Mania.

To be fair, modern-day research into the Dutch Tulip Mania has led to other opinions
about just how maniacal it all was. For one thing, some think that the reporting wasn‘t
always unbiased; for example, it is thought that some reporters like Mackay might have
had a religious and moral agenda, and overhyped their stories to warn people about the
evils of financial speculation (we could probably use some of that today). Furthermore,
there are those such as Earl Thompson of the University of California at Los Angeles
who argue that not only was the Dutch Tulip Mania not maniacal, but on the contrary
could be explained in perfectly rational terms, as an excellent illustration of what is
known as the efficient market hypothesis. So what‘s that? It has a lot to do with the
(surprisingly) fascinating story of modern finance, which I‘d like to talk about now.

Efficient Markets

Economics was rocked to the core in the twentieth century, starting in its very first year.
In 1900, a young French mathematician named Louis Bachelier published his doctoral
thesis, called The Theory of Speculation. I have to admit that this time the person we are
dealing with is neither British nor eccentric (unless having a wine merchant for a father
and a poet for a mother counts), but young Bachelier certainly did have extraordinary
talent. His thesis involved something called Brownian Motion (named after the Scottish
botanist Robert Brown), which describes the motion of particles in a fluid. The
interesting thing about this is that in doing so, he anticipated the Nobel Prize winning
work of none other than Albert Einstein by five years – which is a pretty cool thing to
be able to say about your work. Bachelier used Brownian motion to study the
-9-
John Favaro
movements of stock markets; Einstein merely used it to prove the existence of atoms. In
addition, Bachelier‘s thesis involved the study of stock options, which we now know
from the Dutch Tulip Mania are a form of derivatives (that word again). He invented a
way of describing the value of options that still bears his name: Bachelier diagrams.

With his sophisticated use of Brownian motion and the like in his work, Bachelier could
arguably be called the father of ―mathematical finance,‖ which eventually came to
dominate most of the twentieth century, as we‘ll see. But the part of his work I want to
talk about now is a statement he made as a conclusion of his research.

Bachelier claimed that the movements of stock markets are random.

When you read that claim, your first thought is, ―Maybe Bachelier really was an
eccentric; no, maybe he was downright crazy.‖ Because it doesn‘t make any sense. It‘s
obvious to anybody that stock markets don‘t just wander around randomly like a bunch
of drunks; they move in response to real, significant events, like company reports,
mergers, acquisitions, all those things. They move in patterns. Only a fool would make
such an absurd claim as Bachelier‘s. And so he was ignored by pretty much everyone.

The years passed. A Great War devastated Europe (Bachelier himself was drafted into
the French Army as a private). We lived through the greatest financial madness of all
time and the subsequent stock market crash of ‗29, followed by the Great Depression.
Then the Second World War, which gave us, among much else, the electronic computer
(invented for military purposes, of course).

Then, in 1953, more than half a century after Bachelier‘s original work on the stock
market (Bachelier was dead by that time), a British fellow named Kendall, armed with
piles of stock market data (without which, his chatta‘ didn‘t matta‘) and all the modern
tools of computing, decided to go about finding and categorizing all the patterns in that
data. Who knows, maybe he even secretly harbored the hope of making some easy
money – there is an active branch of finance called technical analysis, which tries to
identify patterns in the stock market and exploit them for financial gain, and if Kendall
were able to identify and categorize all the patterns, he could be a step ahead of the
pack. Whether or not he had that in mind (unlikely, actually), Kendall took his piles of
data and ―crunched the numbers,‖ and then tallied up the grand total of patterns he had
identified.

Zero.

Not one single pattern. Nothing. After a lot of head-scratching, people began to
remember Bachelier‘s work. But this time they couldn‘t ignore it like before – they had
hard data that confirmed it. Stock market movements really are random.

But knowing the fact didn‘t help people understand why it was true. Economists had to
wait another decade before the first plausible explanation arrived, which is still with us
today. It was provided by Professor Eugene Fama of the University of Chicago, and has
become known as the Efficient Market Hypothesis. Here‘s the basic idea. Think of the
stock market as a pond full of voracious, greedy piranha (come to think of it, the
analogy is probably pretty good from several points of view). When any new
information arrives – like a company reporting great sales, or acquiring another
- 10 -
John Favaro
company – that sort of thing, the piranha jump on the information, analyzing it, looking
at it from every perspective. They ―strip it to the bones,‖ leaving no fact undigested, and
then they act on it. If it‘s good news, they buy; if it‘s bad news, they sell. And here‘s the
important part: they not only act on the immediate information, but on all of its
implications for the future: after all, if you think a company‘s stock price is going to go
up in a month, why wait a month to buy it? You buy it now. The result is that the
market always reflects all the information that is currently available. Its next reaction
will be to the next new information, and of course, by definition, nobody knows when
that will arrive – in other words, the arrival of new information is random and thus so
are the market‘s movements.

So now you know why market movements are random. But the characteristic of
efficient markets that is relevant to this lecture is that this ―piranha pond‖ consists of
investors of all types, from all backgrounds, all shapes and sizes, all levels of
intelligence, all interpreting financial information from their own point of view and
drawing their own conclusions. Like a kind of large, sprawling financial democracy,
each investor, through the act of buying or selling a stock, is effectively casting a vote
that reflects his opinion of that stock‘s value. Sound familiar? Yes indeed, we are once
again back to the wisdom of the crowd, and a corollary of the efficient market
hypothesis is that the crowd of piranha, in its collective wisdom, gives us the best
possible estimate of the value of a stock – better than even the smartest individual can
do. Or, in layman‘s terms: ―you can‘t beat the market.‖

And that‘s why people are always so angry at professional money managers. Only the
smallest percentage of them ever manages to do better than you would by just spreading
your money around in the market. (The popular mathematician and author J.A. Paolos
calls that situation ―slightly scandalous‖ and it‘s hard to disagree with him.)

Behavioral Finance and the Human Factor

The efficient market hypothesis dominated finance for the second half of the twentieth
century, and reinforced the impression of stock markets as rational, well-functioning
investment mechanisms – the finest possible illustration of the Wisdom of the Crowd.
But a nagging question remained: if the stock market is so rational and wise, what about
all those things Charles Mackay was writing about? The Dutch Tulip Mania? The
Mississippi Company? For that matter, what about the Great Crash of 1929?

In the last decade of the twentieth century, some people began to question whether the
wisdom of the stock market hadn‘t maybe been a bit exaggerated, and its madness a bit
downplayed. One of those people was Robert Shiller, an economics professor from my
own alma mater, Yale University. Like Francis Galton, Shiller also preferred to work
with real data (instead of just chatta‘) and basically said, ―Okay, if stock market prices
are supposed to be the wisest estimate of the real value of companies, let‘s go verify
whether that has turned out to be true in the past.‖ After all, data was lying around from
over a hundred years of stock market activity and company financial reports. All he had
to do was compare them with each other to see whether the crowd had guessed right –
in retrospect, it‘s surprising that nobody had thought of it before. Sure enough: Shiller
found that, time and again, those ―wise‖ investors were way off the right estimate of a
company‘s real value. His explanation? Simple: human foibles – the madness of the
crowd.
- 11 -
John Favaro
Shiller became one of the leading proponents of a new discipline known as behavioral
finance, which explicitly acknowledges the influence in financial decision-making of
overconfidence, overreaction, and all those other quirks of humanity we know and love.
His comment: ―When we started doing behavioral finance we were total outcasts …
nobody appreciated us. I had tenure so I could do it …‖

In the year 2000, right at the very height of the dotcom boom, Shiller published a book
called Irrational Exuberance, warning about the current madness of dotcom investors.
(This madness was going on in Italy, too, by the way – one company was stampeded by
crazed investors desperately trying to buy its shares because it had a product with ―Net‖
in its name. It turned out that the product, WC-Net, was a detergent for cleaning toilets).
When the market crashed shortly thereafter, a lot of believers in behavioral finance
were born.

In 2005, Shiller published a revised version of Irrational Exuberance. This time he


included a discussion of the growing housing bubble. He pointed out, for example, that
median home prices in the United States had grown to be as much as nine times greater
than median income (remember that discussion about Dutch tulips costing ten times the
annual income of a skilled worker?). And as we now know, he was right – the madness
of the crowd had struck again and we are still now enduring its consequences. This time
the culprit wasn‘t the Internet. It was something far more sinister – that word again:
derivatives. The legendary American investor Warren Buffett has called derivatives
―financial weapons of mass destruction.‖ You may have also seen the news last month
[March 2010] that four banks were being put on trial for their handling of derivative
transactions with municipalities in Italy.

As a matter of fact, though, Shiller isn‘t against derivatives per se. He shares the view
of James Morgan, a columnist from the Financial Times, who said, ―A derivative is like
a razor. You can use it to shave yourself … Or you can use it to commit suicide.‖
Shiller is in favor of derivatives when they are used responsibly to diminish risk. But
derivatives can also be used for very wild and aggressive speculation, and seem to bring
out the worst madness in the crowd. Witness the mess the world is in right now.

The current financial disaster has thrown the field of economics into a serious identity
crisis. The century that began with brilliant economists like Louis Bachelier laying the
foundation for a rational, crystalline mathematical model of financial behavior ended
with brilliant economists like Robert Shiller tearing down that very foundation. In an
article last week [26 March 2010] in the New York Times, David Brooks discussed the
causes and nature of all this soul-searching among economists. The principal cause is
that so few economists saw the crash coming.

―Where were the intellectual agenda-setters when this crisis was building?‖ asked Barry
Eichengreen of the University of California, Berkeley, in The National Interest. ―Why did they fail
to see the train wreck coming?‖

I mean, it‘s pretty embarrassing when the worst economic collapse since the Great
Depression happens and nobody (except one or two like Shiller) foresees it. It kind of
makes you reflect. Right now, in the tug-of-war between the Mathematical Economists
and the Behavioral Economists, the behavioralists seem to have the upper hand. As
Brooks concludes,
- 12 -
John Favaro
Economics achieved coherence as a science by amputating most of human nature. Now economists
are starting with those parts of emotional life that they can count and model (the activities that make
them economists). But once they‘re in this terrain, they‘ll surely find that the processes that make up
the inner life are not amenable to the methodologies of social science. The moral and social
yearnings of fully realized human beings are not reducible to universal laws and cannot be studied
like physics.

In other words: human nature being what it is, there will always be a little madness
mixed in with the wisdom. And that has implications for the limits on how far we can
go with these ideas, as we‘ll see now.

The Wisdom of Corporations?

As I said earlier in this talk, people have been trying to harness the wisdom of the
crowds in many different fields, and the field of business and finance is no exception. In
fact, Surowiecki‘s book The Wisdom of Crowds was a New York Times bestseller not in
the general category, but in the business category; Surowiecki‘s hope and intention was
to inspire businesspeople to find ways to harness the ideas in the book. For example, he
outlined ways in which the ideas of collective intelligence could be used to produce
superior corporate decision-making processes.

I had the occasion in Rome exactly one month ago [10 March 2010] to meet a person
who is working in this area right now. Professor Michele Missikoff is a director of the
Laboratory for Enterprise Knowledge and Systems at the Italian National Research
Centers in Rome. He has been trying to raise awareness in Europe of the possibilities
for harnessing the power of the crowd in the enterprise. He is promoting a view that
each person in the enterprise can be considered as a valuable carrier of knowledge –
however partial and incomplete – that contributes to a collective, enterprise-wide
―wisdom‖ that is more powerful than anything any individuals could put together on
their own. This could lead to whole new ways of managing knowledge in the enterprise.

―Considering the importance of the enterprise in our economy, it‘s amazing that more
hasn‘t been done to try to make it function better,‖ he told me. ―The current economic
crisis has made authorities in the European Community more aware of the need to look
at enterprise improvement from an economic point of view rather than just a technical
point of view.‖

―So what‘s holding back progress?‖ I asked.

―The enterprise is the single most complex structure ever made by humans,‖ he
explained. ―The problem is that it‘s not just made by humans, it‘s made of humans. And
human nature being what it is … for example, it‘s not always easy to convince a
manager that he should relinquish his hard-earned right to make decisions to the
collective intelligence of some kind of group.‖ He shrugged his shoulders and smiled,
―That‘s just the way we humans are.‖

III. The Future


I mentioned at the beginning of this talk that I was originally led to this topic not by
reading a book, but rather by what I was seeing happen all around me. Examples of
- 13 -
John Favaro
trying to harness collective intelligence are everywhere now, especially on the Internet.
You don‘t have to look any farther than your home page on the Web for a great
example of this – that is, if your home page is Google, the famous search engine.

Did you ever wonder how Google actually finds the things you look for on the web?
Among all the web pages out there, how does it find the ones that are relevant to your
search, sort them and rank them so that you get the best ones? Simple: it uses a
technique for ranking pages imaginatively named … PageRank.

Now, you could be forgiven if you thought that the name stood for ―ranking pages.‖ But
you‘d be wrong. The ―Page‖ actually refers to Larry Page, one of the co-founders of
Google. He developed this technique while he was a student at Stanford University (by
the way, the work of an Italian, Massimo Marchiori at the University of Padua, is cited
as being one of the sources of inspiration for this technique). Another interesting fact is
that, although the name PageRank is a trademark of Google, the patent on the technique
is actually owned by Stanford University, and they made a bundle of money licensing
the exclusive rights to Google.

So how does this page-ranking technique work? Let‘s hear it from Google themselves:

PageRank relies on the uniquely democratic nature of the web by using its vast link structure as an
indicator of an individual page‘s value. In essence, Google interprets a link from page A to page B
as a vote, by page A, for page B. … Votes cast by pages that are themselves ―important‖ weigh
more heavily and help to make other pages ―important‖.

Democratic. Vote. Those words again! Yes, that‘s right; Google essentially harnesses
the wisdom of crowds to let the Internet itself tell you which pages are relevant to your
search.

Perhaps that‘s not so surprising, because the Internet is the most fertile ground you
could possibly imagine for harnessing the wisdom of crowds. And even less surprising
is that where it‘s all happening right now is in the social networks – the ultimate
aggregators of crowds.

There probably aren‘t three people in this room who aren‘t registered on Facebook
(Italy has one of the world‘s most enthusiastic Facebook communities). Last year I
introduced you to Twitter, who taught us that the burning question on everybody‘s
mind was ―What are you doing right now?‖

This year, we have gone one step further. Writing a couple of weeks ago [21 March
2010] in the New York Times, David Carr described the unnerving experience of sitting
in a bar in Austin, Texas, where suddenly about seventy people, all sitting in different
parts of the bar, got up out of their seats and rushed over to another bar. What made
them all suddenly move together as a group, like a swarm of bees?

At large events, people have always moved in groups to the next big thing. But … the ubiquity of
so-called ubiquitous presence — location-based services like Foursquare and Gowalla — meant
the hive suddenly knew what it was collectively doing. … It was striking to see the digital
location effect in the wild, with people reacting to an unseen dog whistle and moving en masse, on
command.

- 14 -
John Favaro
Ubiquitous presence? Location-based services? What on earth is he talking about? This
is the new frontier in social networking. The burning question isn‘t just ―What are you
doing right now?‖ any more, but also ―Where are you right now?‖ Social networking is
now morphing into geosocial networking. In geosocial networking, friends not only tell
each other what they are doing but where they are doing it.

But how do they do this? It has a lot to do with the concept of ubiquitous presence
mentioned above. This is a hot topic in the research programs of the European Union
right now, as a matter of fact. In its so-called Seventh Framework Programme of
Research, the term ―ubiquitous presence‖ is cited often, and refers to the idea of
everything being interconnected, from your refrigerator to your clothes to you yourself.
(Another name commonly used in association with the concept is the Internet of
Things.) But how do you connect you to others? Simple: your mobile phone.

Foursquare, one of the ―location-based services‖ mentioned above, works like this:
when a person enters a place (like a popular bar) he can check-in using his smartphone.
In that way, his friends all know where he is. Of course, Foursquare also finds out
where he is, and privacy issues immediately come to mind. Carr writes:

To someone not in their 20s whose location generally isn‘t that interesting to others … the idea of
handing over your privacy with both hands to strap on a digital ankle bracelet sounds profoundly
unattractive. … But to a younger cohort that lives on the grid, the location of people you know and
care about is vital information, the coin of the realm.

Like in a beehive, we are beginning to see new forms of emergent behavior in social
networks, like groups suddenly standing up in a bar and moving to a different place.
Like those cars coordinating with each other on the highways, think of this as a kind of
―human platooning,‖ where everybody knows where everybody else is. This kind of
collective, emergent behavior is also encouraged by services like Foursquare, who have
introduced game-like facilities and rewards into the service. For example, you can earn
badges by checking into places. And if you check in the most times to a popular place
(like a bar), you can be named ―mayor‖ of that place. These kinds of awards are
reminiscent of the whiskey prizes using in finding the submarine Scorpion, and in the
same way, they encourage the crowd to interact in all kinds of unexpected ways.

Furthermore, location-awareness is not destined to remain in the purely physical world.


As Carr writes:

… What if location became not just a physical place, but a digital one? The possibilities for old and
new media could be significant. ―The check-in is bigger than location,‖ said Yancey Strickler of
Kickstarter, a Web site that helps with fund-raising for media products. ―Think of media: Checking
into watching ‗Lost,‘ being declared the mayor of ‗The Brothers Karamazov‘ or earning a badge for
braving free jazz.‖

Recently, much larger social networking companies like Facebook and Twitter have
also announced that they will soon provide location-aware facilities. This means that
crowds will arise more and more often, with their members getting together and acting
in collective, emergent ways that we can‘t begin to predict. Where will all this end?
Once again I find myself at the end of a talk having to use the same old, tired line: Only
time will tell.

- 15 -
John Favaro
So I guess I didn‘t do a very good job of answering the question I posed at the
beginning of this talk: are we collectively smart or stupid? As usual, I ended up
equivocating: we‘ll always be a little wise, and we‘ll always be a little mad. But most of
all, more and more we‘ll be we. Unlike the individual, royal ―We‖ of Francis Galton‘s
beloved Queen Victoria, the ―we‖ of the future will be ever more connected,
interacting, self-aware, the ultimate universal swarm of humanity.

Resources

James Surowiecki, The Wisdom of Crowds, Anchor (August 16, 2005)

Charles Mackay, Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowds, with a
foreword by Andrew Tobias (1841; New York: Harmony Books, 1980). ISBN 0-517-
53919-5. Also available free on the Internet, e.g. www.manybooks.net.

Toby Segaran, Programming Collective Intelligence: Building Smart Web 2.0


Applications, O'Reilly Media; illustrated edition (August 16, 2007)

Don Tapscott, Anthony D. Williams, Wikinomics: How Mass Collaboration Changes


Everything, Portfolio Hardcover; Expanded edition (April 17, 2008)

Jeff Howe, Crowdsourcing: Why the Power of the Crowd Is Driving the Future of
Business, Three Rivers Press; unedited edition (September 15, 2009)

Richard Ogle, Smart World: Breakthrough Creativity And the New Science of Ideas,
Harvard Business School Press; 1 edition (June 5, 2007)

Keith Sawyer, Group Genius: The Creative Power of Collaboration, Basic Books (June
4, 2007)

Steven Johnson, Emergence: the connected lives of ants, brains, cities and software
(2002) Scribner, ISBN 0-684-86876-8.

Mitchel Resnick, Turtles, Termites, and Traffic Jams: Explorations in Massively


Parallel Microworlds (1997), MIT Press, ISBN 0262680939.

Peter Bernstein, Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk (1998), Wiley &
Sons.

Peter Bernstein, Capital Ideas: The Improbable Origins of Modern Wall Street (1992),
Wiley & Sons.

- 16 -

You might also like