Ilippo Ontanelli
Ilippo Ontanelli
Ilippo Ontanelli
TRADE LAW:
WHAT GETS SAID IS NOT WHAT’S HEARD
FILIPPO FONTANELLI*
I. INTRODUCTION
* PhD, Sant’Anna School of Advanced Studies (Pisa); LLM Hauser Global Scholar, NYU
2010; Trainee clerk, International Court of Justice, 2010/2011. Email: < [email protected] > .
Many thanks are due to Robert Howse, Fabrizio Cafaggi and two anonymous referees.
1
Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World
Trade Organization, Annex 1A, opened for signature 15 April 1994, entered into force 1 January
1995.
2
Agreement on Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary Measures, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing
the World Trade Organization, Annex 1A opened for signature 15 April 1994, entered into force
1 January 1995.
3
T Buthe, ‘The globalization of health and safety standards: delegation of regulatory authority
in the SPS-Agreement of 1994 agreement establishing the World Trade Organization’ (2008) 71
L and Contemporary Problems 219.
4
The literature on this issue is vast. See, for instance, H Horn and JHH Weiler, ‘European
Communities—Trade Description of Sardines: Textualism and its Discontent’ in H Horn and PC
Mavroidis (eds), The American Law Institute Report 2002 (CUP 2005) 251, 260; M Livermore,
‘Authority and Legitimacy in Global Governance: Deliberation, Institutional Differentiation and
the Codex Alimentarius’ (2006) 81 New York UL Rev 766, 786–789; Y Bonzon,
‘Institutionalizing Public Participation in WTO Decision Making: Some Conceptual Hurdles and
Avenues’ (2008) 11 J of Intl Economic L 751, 775ff; J Scott, ‘International Trade and
Environmental Governance: Relating Rules (and Standards) in the EU and the WTO’ (2004) 15
Eur J of Intl L 307, 310; R Howse, ‘A New Device for Creating International Legal Normativity:
The WTO Technical Barriers to Trade Agreement and ‘International Standards’’ in C Joerges and
EU Petersmann (eds), Constitutionalism, Multilevel Trade Governance and Social Regulation
(Hart Publishing 2006) 383, 391.
5
Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties, adopted 23 May 1969, entered into force 27
January 1980, 115S UNTS 331 (‘VCLT’), preambles are listed in art 31(2) among the elements
useful for the analysis of the context of a treaty, and often international courts and tribunals use
them as a shortcut to determine what the purpose of an instrument is. See eg C Schreuer, ‘Diversity
and Harmonization of Treaty Interpretation in Investment Arbitration’ in M Fitzmaurice, O Elias, P
Merkouris (eds), Treaty Interpretation and the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties: 30 Years
(BRILL 2010) 129, 131 (referring to investment arbitration): ‘The most frequent way to find a
treaty’s object and purpose was to look at the preamble.’ With respect to the purpose of the
European Convention of Human Rights see, in the same book, G Letsas, ‘Intentionalism and the
Interpretation of the ECHR’, ibid., 257, 260, referring to the seminal Golder case (Golder v United
Kingdom [1975] 1 EHRR 524).
6
See LR Helfer, ‘Regime Shifting in the International Intellectual Property System’ (2009) 7
Perspectives on Politics 39; ‘Regime Shifting: The TRIPs Agreement and New Dynamics of
International Intellectual Property Lawmaking’ (2004) 29 Yale J of Intl L 1. Although some
features of Helfer’s model apply to the present study (eg the consequential importance of the
differences between the regimes, with respect to the binding force of their norms or the design of
their law-making procedures), in this study the regime-shift expression applies to the norms rather
than to the actors, and merely depicts the migration of international standards into the realm of
international trade law.
7
For a more detailed description of the Codex Commission and its activity, see RA Pereira,
‘Why Would International Administrative Activity Be Any Less Legitimate? A Study of the Codex
Alimentarius Commission’ (2008) 9 German LJ 1693, 1695ff.
8
The Conference of Food and Agriculture Organisation (FAO), in 1961, and the World
Health Organization (WHO) Assembly, in 1963, adopted the resolutions establishing the Codex
Commission. They also adopted the Statutes and Rules of Procedure for the Commission.
9
See art 1 of the Codex Statutes, available at < http://www.fao.org/DOCREP/005/Y2200E/
10
y2200e02.htm > . See ibid art 2.
11
Under the Rules of Procedure, the Commission has one chairperson and three vice-
chairpersons to be elected at each annual session, a secretary appointed by the FAO and the WHO,
and some regional Coordinators (Rule V). The chairpersons, together with seven member
representatives, form the Executive Committee, which shall report to the Commission (Rule VI).
The Rules of the Commission can be amended with the vote of two-thirds of the members (Rule
XIII). See the full text of the Rules at < http://www.fao.org/DOCREP/005/Y2200E/y2200e03.
htm#TopOfPage > .
12
The full procedures for the adoption of standards are encompassed in the Procedures for the
Elaboration of Codex Standards and Related Texts adopted by the Commission, available at
< http://www.fao.org/DOCREP/005/Y2200E/y2200e04.htm#TopOfPage > .
13
For a recent and comprehensive description of the process, see S Henson and J Humphrey,
The Impacts of Private Food Safety Standards on the Food Chain and on Public Standard-Setting
Processes (Paper for FAO/WHO May 2009) 24ff.
14
See the FAQ page of the Codex website < http://www.codexalimentarius.net/web/faq_gen.
jsp#G11 > : ‘General Question 11: Are Codex Standards mandatory? Answer: Codex texts are
voluntary and non-binding . . .’.
2. ISO
The International Standard Organization, in turn, is a prima facie hybrid actor.
It is a federation of national standard-setting bodies, which can differ markedly
in terms of structure; whereas some among them are governmental agencies
(for instance the French Association Française de Normalisation ‘AFNOR’),
others are private bodies (such as the British Standard Association, or the US
American National Standards Institute, a private organization composed of
private members and officials of federal agencies).18 ISO was established in
1947 under the form of an association governed by Swiss corporate law. ISO’s
primary stakeholder is the industry sector, which provides expertise both to
governmental and private domestic bodies.19
15
Available at < http://www.fao.org/DOCREP/005/Y2200E/y2200e05.htm#TopOfPage > .
16
For instance, full acceptance of a standard implies that food not conforming therewith shall
not be distributed under the name or description laid down in the standard (see Principle 4A.i).
17
According to the taxonomy of GK Hadfield, ‘The Public and the Private in the Provision of
Law for Global Transactions’ in V Gessner (ed), Contractual Certainty in International Trade:
Empirical Studies and Theoretical Debates on Institutional Support for Global Economic
Exchanges (Hart Publishing 2009) 238, Codex standards would rank as public under some criteria,
but they would still have a ‘private ordering’ aspect, since ‘legal obligations based in private
ordering derive exclusively from the intent and consent of the obligated party to be bound.’ (240).
See also D Vogel, ‘Private Global Business Regulation’ (2008) 11 Annual Rev of Political Science
261, 265 (regarding ISO regulations). Similarly, F Cafaggi, Product Safety, Private Standard
Setting and Information Networks (Working Paper 2008/17 EUI 2008) 10, refers to technical
standards as ‘privately produced’ when compliance is voluntary. For a distinction between private
regulation, co-regulation and ex-post recognized self-regulation see F Cafaggi, Rethinking Private
Regulation in the European Regulatory Space (Working Paper 2006/13 EUI 2006). Not
surprisingly, as Pereira (n 7) notes, there is no consensus regarding the nature of the Codex. See
B Kingsbury, N Krisch and RB Stewart, ‘The Emergence of Global Administrative Law’ (2005) 68
L and Contemporary Problems 15 (CC is a hybrid body); A Herwig, ‘Transnational Governance
Regimes for Foods Derived from Bio-Technology and their Legitimacy’ in C Joerges, I-J Sand and
Gunther Teubner (eds), Transnational Governance and Constitutionalism (Hart Publishing 2004)
199, 204; J Pauwelyn, ‘Non-Traditional Patterns of Global Regulation: Is the WTO ‘Missing the
Boat’?’ in Joerges and Petersmann (n 4) 199, 208–215(CC is essentially a public body).
18
Members can apply for full membership or for correspondent membership, which entitles
them to an observer status during the sessions of the Technical Committees.
19
The mixed membership, the associational model and the voluntary nature of the standards
adopted make it possible to consider ISO a hybrid regime, or even a private one. See for instance
B. ANIME
In order to understand a regulatory regime more fully, it is useful to divide
the regulatory process into phases, and to identify the subjects that are involved
in, or responsible for, each phase. In this section we adopt the ‘ANIME’
method, which is a step-by-step analysis of the regulatory process. based on the
following phases: Agenda-setting, Negotiation and adoption, Implementation,
Monitoring and Enforcement.23 This ANIME method is employed here to
J Clapp, ‘The Privatization of Global Environmental Governance: ISO 14000 and the Developing
World’ (1998) 4 Global Governance 295, 301 (ISO is a hybrid body); F Cafaggi, The Architecture
of Transnational Private Regulation (EUI Working Paper 2011/12) 9 (ISO is a private regulator).
20
For a full account of standardization procedures, see the ISO/IEC Directives ‘Procedures for
Technical Works’, available at < http://www.iso.org/directives > .
21
E Shamir-Borer, The Evolution of Administrative Law-Type Principles, Mechanisms and
Practices in the International Organization for Standardization (ISO) (Paper NYU Global Hauser
Colloquim 2006) 21.
22
For a limited set of matters, typically linked with environmental protection and corporate
social responsibility, the procedure has been gradually opened to include other stakeholders, see
N Roht-Arriaza, ‘Soft Law’ in a ‘Hybrid’ organization: The International Organization for
Standardization’ in D Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Non-Binding Norms
in the International Legal System (OUP 2000) 265.
23
See KW Abbott and D Snidal, ‘The Governance Triangle: Regulatory Standards Institution
and the Shadow of the State’ in W Mattli and N Woods (eds), The Politis of Global Regulation
(Princeton University Press 2009) 44, 63.
1. Codex Alimentarius
a) Agenda-Setting
The Rules of Procedure are clear in endowing any member of the Commission,
along with the Directors-General of the FAO and WHO, with the power
to propose the inclusion of an item in the agenda for a session of the
Commission.24 The proposed agenda is then voted by the Commission.25
c) Implementation
It is important to specify which substantial purpose the Codex standards
pursue, in order to examine the implementation phase, but it is not an easy task.
Several aims are listed among those belonging to the Commission, and each of
them would correspond to a different implementation stage, and a different
responsible actor. For instance, if the very purpose of the standards were the
24 25
See Rule V of the Rules of Procedure, (n 11). See ibid, Rule VI.
26
Namely, when the standards incorporate a maximum limit for residues of pesticide or
veterinary drugs, see Procedures for the Elaboration (n 12), Part 1, Step 2.
27
See the Principles Concerning the Participation of International Non-Governmental
Organizations in the Work of the Codex Alimentarius Commission, available at < http://www.
fao.org/DOCREP/005/Y2200E/y2200e09.htm#TopOfPage > . Such principles establish an
accreditation procedure, through which organizations having a particular connection with the
matters covered by the standards (in terms of expertise, competence, aims or subject-field) can
apply for the status of observers. See also the report International Non-governmental Organizations
in Observer Status with the Codex Alimentarius Commission, Report by the Secretariat (CAC/30
INF/2), available at < ftp://ftp.fao.org/Codex/CAC/CAC30/if30_02e.pdf > . It must be noted that,
according to official reports, industry-related NGOs hugely outnumber consumers’ associations,
see Pereira (n 7) 1709. See also, on participatory issues in the Codex, T Huller and ML Maier,
‘Fixing the Codex?: Global Food-Safety Governance under Review’ in Joerges and Petersmann
(n 4) 267, 271 ff (acknowledging that the large majority of observer NGOs belong to the producers
or traders’ community); Livermore (n 4) 783–786.
d) Monitoring
Several actors can be expected to play a monitoring role in connection with
Codex standards, reacting to cases of non-compliance. Consumers are the most
obvious candidates, as they are the direct beneficiaries of standards compliance
and, conversely, the most affected in case of non-compliance. Retailers and
distributors may adopt policies requiring compliance by Codex standards,
hence bearing an interest to monitor the actual respect thereof along the supply
chain. The Codex Commission does not perform directly certification
activities, but encourages Member States to set up a system of certification
run by official bodies or officially recognized bodies.29
e) Enforcing
Non-compliance issues raised through monitoring can be considered and
enforced in different venues. Courts may adjudicate disputes arising from
consumers’ claims alleging the violation of standards (either under tort or
contract law).30 Retailers and distributors can terminate their business relation-
ship with producers and suppliers for non-compliance with the standards.
Third-party certifiers may threaten the withdrawal of, or deny the award of,
certification. State authorities are empowered to regulate (and deny) market
access to food that is produced or processed in violation of standards (that is,
they are not bound to apply the ‘safe haven’ provisions of the international
28
See Henson and Humphrey (n 13) 15. On the ‘mixity’ of the Codex’s original purpose see
Huller and Maier (n 27) 269: ‘If several potentially conflicting goals are built into the mandate of an
individual organization, as in the case of Codex, conceptualizing problem-solving capacity is [a]
daunting task.’ See also Buthe (n 3) 223.
29
See the Principles for Food Import and Export Inspection and Certification Cac/Gl 20–1995,
adopted by the Codex Alimentarius Commission at its 21st Session, 1995, available at < http://
www.fao.org/docrep/009/y6396e/Y6396E01.htm#ch1 > .
30
See A G Chan, ‘Qs-9000 and Its Legal Implications’ (1999) 64 J of Air L and Commerce
1123, 1147, describing plaintiffs’ use of court claims founded on violations of voluntary standards.
2. ISO
a) Agenda-Setting
The impulse triggering a standard-drafting session comes from the industry
sector, which communicates its needs to the respective member(s). After
consideration, and assessment of the potential interests of other industry
sectors and stakeholders, a member submits the proposal to the relevant ISO
organ, to initiate the drafting process.31 Technical Committees and Sub-
Committees examine the proposal, expertise-based Working Groups define
technical specifications, and then a consensus (or at least a two-thirds majority)
is required among members to pass to the next phase.
31
E Shamir-Borer, The Evolution of Administrative-Law Norms and Mechanisms in the
International Organization for Standardization (ISO) (Paper GAL Conference—Viterbo 2006),
see, generally, ISO/IEC Directives (n 20).
32
Industries are encouraged to take part in the decision-making process, see, for instance, HJ
de Vries, ‘Standards for business—How companies benefit from participation in international
standards setting’ in International Standardization as a strategic tool (International Electronical
Commission 2006) 130.
33
See the relevant clauses of the ISO Code of Ethics, (2004) < http://www.iso.org/iso/en/
aboutiso/ethics/ethics.html > , and the ISO document ‘The Consumer and Standards: Guidance and
Principles for Consumer Participation in Standards Development’, available at < http://www.iso.
org/iso/standardsandconsumer.pdf > . For an extensive discussion of participatory issues, see
Shamir-Borer (n 21); H Zúñiga Schroder, ‘Definition of the Concept ‘International Standard’ in the
TBT Agreement’ (2009) 43 J of World Trade 1223, 1233ff; BJ Farquhar, ‘Governance in
the International Organization for standardization (ISO) and the International Electrotechnical
Commission (IEC)’ in K Dawar (ed), Decision Making in the Global Market: Trade, Standards
and the Consumer (Consumers International 2005) 45, 60–62.
c) Implementation
The same caveat made for the Codex applies here.36 However, we adhere to a
traditional approach, and acknowledge that the companies (the industry sector)
are the subjects complying with the standards, and implementing them (after
having bought them from ISO). We also assume that standards are not
incorporated in national regulations, which would make them binding, and
would alter profoundly the following monitoring and enforcement phases.
d) Monitoring
ISO standards have a prominent market-related function. They work as a signal
of quality for consumers and retailers (who are relatively uninterested in
their trade-facilitating function). Certification, like compliance, is a matter of
voluntariness; companies can self-assess ISO performances, or resort to third
party certifiers, to improve their credibility record.37 ISO does not carry out any
conformity assessment activity, nor does it perform certification duties;38
national standardization bodies are responsible for certifying compliance
directly or by accrediting other certification bodies.
34
JK Winn, ‘Globalization and Standards: the Logic of Two-Level Games’ (2009) 5 I/S: J of L
and Policy for the Information Society 185, 210.
35
N Krisch, ‘The Emerging Global Administrative Law’ (2006) 17 European Journal
International Law 265. See also S Baird, ‘The Government at the Standards Bazaar’ (2007) 18
Stanford L and Policy Rev 35, arguing for government’s non-intervention in the setting of
information technology standards.
36
In the case of ISO, where standards are a product on sale, the confusion is further aggravated
by marketing strategies: on the ISO website, standards are claimed to pursue a large number of
purposes, ranging from quality of the production chain to consumers’ health and safety, diffusion of
innovations, harmonization of regulations and trade facilitation; see http://www.iso.org/iso/about/
discover-iso_what-standards-do.htm.
37
For instance, with respect to the environmental standards enshrined in the ISO 14000 series, it
is estimated that self-certification still outnumbers third-party certification, though these standards
were drafted with the purpose of being auditable and certifiable: see DA Wirth, ‘The International
Organization for Standardization: Private Voluntary Standards as Swords and Shields’ (2009) 36
Boston College Environmental Affairs L Rev 79, 85. See also N Roht-Arriaza, ‘Shifting the Point
of Regulation: the International Organization for Standardization and Global Lawmaking on Trade
and the Environment’ (1995) 22 Ecology LQ 479, 499, describing the monitoring process with
respect to the ISO 9000 standards (and how it applies also to the 14000 series), and Chan (n 30)
1132, describing the role of third-party registrars and accreditation bodies in the ISO 9000
compliance assessment procedure.
38
See < www.iso.org/iso/resources/conformity_assessment/mechanisms_for_performing_
conformity_assessment.htm > . ISO, however, adopted some guidelines containing the best
practices for certifiers (ISO/IEC 17021) and accreditation bodies (ISO/IEC 17011).
Notoriously, ISO and Codex standards have obtained direct relevance in the
WTO regime as a consequence of the reference to ‘relevant international
standards’ in the TBT and SPS Agreements. Many authors considered this link
between the WTO and the standards as an element that adds binding force to
the latter, despite their original voluntary nature.40 This view is arguably less
the outcome of a reasoned analysis than of a plausible intuition: the Dispute
Settlement System of the WTO stands out among other international dispute
resolution fora for its high level of effectiveness, both in terms of compulsory
and exclusive jurisdiction and of losers’ compliance with the terms of the
judgment; accordingly, the so-called ‘incorporation’41 of the standards into the
set of applicable law enforced by panels and Appellate Body cannot but add to
the standards’ overall strength.
However, it is posited that this position is the by-product of a significant
legal and factual simplification, which is ultimately misleading. This section
will first explore the exact design of the TBT and SPS renvois and their actual
construction and application by the Dispute Settlement Body (section A), and
then reflect on the systemic position of this reference in light of the overall
39
See JC Bruno and BD Pynnonen, ‘Legal Implications of ISO 9000 Under the UCC’ (1996)
75 Michigan Bar J 1076, 1077 : ‘. . . if an ISO 9000 adoption statement is made, ISO 9000 could
apply to the sale of the product and may be deemed a part of each supply contract’, as an express
warranty.
40
To list just a few, see DG Victor, ‘The Sanitary and Phytosanitary Agreement of the WTO:
An Assessment After Five Years’ (2000) 32 New York UJ of Intl L and Politics 865, 892;
C Chinkin, ‘Normative Development in the International Legal System’ in D Shelton (ed),
Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Non-Binding Norms in the International Legal System
(OUP 2000) 21, 31–34; D Bevilacqua, ‘Il principio di trasparenza come strumento di accountability
nella Codex Alimentarius Commission’ (2007) 57 Rivista Trimestrale di Diritto Pubblico 651, 657;
S Picciotto, ‘Rights, Responsibilities and Regulation of International Business’ (2003) 42
Columbia J of Trantl L 131, 141.
41
See R Howse, ‘The Sardines Panel and AB Ruling—Some Preliminary Reactions’ (2002) 29
L Issues of Economic Integration 247, 251, noting that since no formal incorporation occurred,
panels and the AB do not enjoy an autonomous interpretive power on Codex standards as if they
were WTO norms.
42
See Preamble and art 2(2) of the TBT. For a commentary on art 2 TBT see L Tamiotti, in
R Wolfrum, PT Stoll and A Seibert-Fohr (eds), Technical Barriers and SPS Measures—
Commentary (Martinus Nijhoff 2007) 210–234. The Preamble also mentions other interests
(product quality, health, environment). For some remarks on the ‘double telos’ of the TBT, a
concept that fits our purpose-shift discourse, see MM Du, ‘Domestic Regulatory Autonomy
under the TBT Agreement: From Non-discrimination to Harmonization’ (2007) 6 Chinese J of Intl
L 269, 272.
43
The full text reads: ‘Where technical regulations are required and relevant international
standards exist or their completion is imminent, Members shall use them, or the relevant parts of
them, as a basis for their technical regulations except when such international standards or relevant
parts would be an ineffective or inappropriate means for the fulfillment of the legitimate objectives
pursued, for instance because of fundamental climatic or geographical factors or fundamental
technological problems.’
44
Reading, in the relevant part: ‘Whenever a technical regulation is prepared, adopted or
applied for one of the legitimate objectives explicitly mentioned in paragraph 2 [national security
requirements; the prevention of deceptive practices; protection of human health or safety, animal or
plant life or health, or the environment] and is in accordance with relevant international standards,
it shall be rebuttably presumed not to create an unnecessary obstacle to international trade.’
45
Annex 1 to the TBT defines a technical regulation as a ‘document which lays down product
characteristics or their related processes and production methods, including the applicable
administrative provisions, with which compliance is mandatory. It may also include or deal
exclusively with terminology, symbols, packaging, marketing or labeling requirements as they
apply to a product, production or processing method.’
46
The illustrative list of art 2(4) TBT does not seem to leave much room for such justifications
of deviation, as it refers to cases where the standards are not efficient ‘because of fundamental
climatic or geographical factors or fundamental technological problems’.
47
See the Preamble to the Agreement: ‘no country should be prevented from taking measures
necessary to ensure the quality of its exports, or for the protection of human, animal or plant life or
health, of the environment . . . at the levels it considers appropriate’.
48
The onus of proof, indeed, rests with the complainant, see European Communities—Trade
Description of Sardines (‘Sardines’), WT/DS231/AB/R, Appellate Body Report adopted
23 October 2002, DSR 2002:VIII, 3359, paras 274–275.
49
Art 2(1) TBT. This requirement is covered by the (rebuttable) presumption of art 2(5) TBT.
50
Art 2(2) TBT. This requirement being outside the scope of art 2(5) TBT, it is in principle
possible to challenge on grounds of discrimination a measure adopted in accordance with a relevant
international standards.
51
The issue is extensively discussed in Howse (n 41, n 4), J Pauwelyn, ‘Human Rights in WTO
Dispute Settlement’ in T Cottier, J Pauwelyn and E Burgi (eds), Human Rights and International
Trade (OUP 2005) 205; Pauwelyn (n 17) and Wolfrum, Stoll and Seibert-Fohr (n 42). The relevant
AB reports are EC Measures Concerning Meat and Meat Products (‘Hormones’), WT/DS26/
AB/R, WT/DS48/AB/R, Appellate Body Report adopted 13 February 1998, DSR 1998:III, 1033,
see para 163 (stating that it is sufficient that a SPS measure is ‘founded’ or ‘built upon’ or
‘supported by’ the international standard) and Sardines (n 48), see para 245 (requiring that the
international standard is the ‘principal constituent’, ‘determining principle’ or ‘fundamental
principle’ of the TBT measure). At first glance, the ‘very close and very strong relationship’
deemed by Sardines (n 48) to meet the ‘based on’ criterion leaves little space for a more stringent
requirement of ‘in accordance with’ under art 2(5) TBT, somehow conflating the two requirements.
This result was correctly avoided in Hormones, where art 3(1) and art 3(2) SPS were interpreted by
giving careful consideration to the difference between measures ‘based on’ and ‘conforming to’
relevant standards (see AB report, para 163).
52
The full definition contained in annex 1 to the TBT reads: ‘document approved by a
recognized body that provides, for common and repeated use, rules, guidelines or characteristics for
products or related processes and production methods, with which compliance is not mandatory.
It may also include or deal exclusively with terminology, symbols, packaging, marketing or
labeling requirements as they apply to a product, process or production method’.
53
The TBT agreement relies on ISO/IEC Guide 2:2004 for guidance, defining a standardizing
body as a ‘body that has recognized activities in standardization’. However, this definition is too
indeterminate to be of actual help.
54
Decisions and Recommendations Adopted by the Committee since 1 January 1995, WTO
Committee on Technical Barriers to Trade, G/ TBT/1/Rev 8, 23 May 2002.
55
This is somewhat at odds with the very role of standards in the TBT framework, which is
exactly to provide a sound justification for unilateral market distortion practices (a presumption of
legality for domestic policies inconsistent with WTO policies). See R Howse, A New Device for
Creating International Legal Normativity: the WTO Technical Barriers to Trade Agreement and
“International Standards (draft Paper IILJ Global Administrative Law Series 2004 available at
< http://www.iilj.org/GAL/documents/HowsePaper.pdf >) 13.
56
Annex 3 to the TBT: Code of Good Practice for the Preparation, Adoption and Application
of Standards. A similar document is the non-binding Annex 4 of the TBT Committee’s Second
Triennial Review (2000), which also argues for a more inclusive process of decision-making, in
which the largest range of interests should have representation.
57
Other recommendations that similarly aim at building consistence within the standard multi-
layered regimes are the duties to cooperate with international standardizing organizations, to avoid
standard duplication, and to adopt performance-oriented standards: see the Code of Good Practice,
General Provisions G, H and I.
58
Zúñiga Schroder (n 33) 1226–1227, examines other GATT and WTO documents of an
informal nature, including an Annex to the Second TBT Triennial Review, in which other
organizations are listed, such as the World Health Organization, the International Organization of
Legal Metrology and the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. This
suggests that, at least in the TBT framework, the list of relevant bodies is open to expansion.
59
ISO’s position in certain areas can be effectively described by referring to the archetypical
model of the ‘monopolist private regulator’, see Cafaggi (n 17) 41.
60
Considerations of regulatory dominance and credibility were also decisive in the choice of
Codex, OIE and IPPC under the SPS, see Zúñiga Schroder (n 33) 1225, fn 7, referring to the
preparatory works of the SPS text.
61
For a full account of the ‘strategic partnership’ established between the WTO and ISO, see
the ISO/IEC information sheet: ‘WTO, ISO, IEC and World Trade’, available at < http://www.
standardsinfo.net/info/livelink/fetch/2000/148478/6301438/inttrade.html > .
62
As well as with the SPS Committee and the Committee on Trade and Environment (CTE).
63
See provisions C, J and K of annex 3 to the TBT.
64
In the case of the Codex, its definition as ‘recognized body’ under the TBT is not
controversial, since it is expressly recognized in the SPS Agreement: see below. However, the AB
makes clear that not all Codex standards are automatically relevant under art 2(4) TBT, and that a
case by case assessment is necessary.
65
Council Regulation No 2136/89 of 21 June 1989 laying down common marketing standards
for preserved sardines, OJ 1989 L 212.
66
Codex Alimentarius Commission, Codex Standard for Canned Sardines and Sardine-Type
Products (Codex Stan 94–1981), art 2(1). EC regulation allowed the use of the word ‘sardines’ only
for the species Sardina pichardus, whereas the Codex standard permitted other species such as the
Sardina sagax to be called ‘sardines’ as well (subject to the attachment of an origin prefix, such as
‘Pacific sardines’).
67
See Sardines, AB Report (n 48), para 225. See also EC Measures Concerning Meat and
Meat Products (‘Hormones panel’), Panel Report adopted 18 August 1997, WT/DS26/R /USA
1998:III, 699, para 8.69.
68
In only a few disputes TBT matters were litigated, and sometimes the TBT part of the claim
was disregarded by the panel. As of October 2011, only a handful of cases are to be mentioned. A
case similar to Sardines was EC—Scallops. However, the parties settled the dispute, thus the panel
report remained unadopted see European Communities—Trade Description of Scallops—Request
by Canada, WT/DS7/R, 5 August 1996, unadopted, DSR 1996:I, 89; WTO Panel Report,
European Communities—Trade Description of Scallops—Requests by Peru and Chile, WT/DS12/
R, WT/DS14/R, 5 August 1996, unadopted, DSR 1996:I, 93. In EC—Asbestos the panel
considered complaints under GATT and overlooked the TBT claims. See WTO Panel Report,
European Communities—Measures Affecting Asbestos and Asbestos-Containing Products, WT/
DS135/R and Add.1, adopted 5 April 2001, modified by Appellate Body Report, WT/DS135/AB/
R, DSR 2001:VIII, 3305. On 2 September 2011 a panel report was circulated, regarding the dispute
2. SPS
The SPS Agreement, in turn, aims to reconcile the tension arising between free
trade and the proliferating regimes of food safety. In the Preamble to the
Agreement, the members make clear that the purpose of the SPS is both ‘to
improve the human health, animal health and phytosanitary situation in all
Members’ and to establish ‘a multilateral framework of rules and disciplines to
guide the development, adoption and enforcement of sanitary and phytosani-
tary measures in order to minimize their negative effects on trade’. This double
purpose might cause difficulties in the interpretation of the SPS provisions,
insomuch as any attempt to relay on a purposive interpretation would have to
take into account these two aspirations, which are often in a relationship of
tension.
SPS provisions are intended, on the one hand, to facilitate mutual
recognition of good faith standards designed to ensure health protection and,
on the other hand, to expose all those standards that are, in fact, market
restrictions disguised as safety regulations dictated by national policies. Since
the distinction between good-faith and bad-faith regulations is in the mind of
the national regulator and is typically hard to appreciate, the SPS Agreement
introduces what is contended to be the most objective benchmark reasonably
available to assess the appropriateness of domestic food safety regulations—
the ‘scientific foundation’.69 Any SPS measure must satisfy other requirements
besides the scientific justification (accompanied by the relative risk-assessment
criterion) and the non-discrimination mantra;70 it must be the least trade-
restrictive available among those that ensure the same level of protection71
(the one every State is entitled to choose freely)72, and if it reflects a level of
United States—Measures Affecting the Production and Sale of Clove Cigarettes WT/DS406/R.
Although TBT-related claims are central and in particular art 2(5) TBT is discussed at length, the
case did not hinge upon the role of international standards. See para 7.458, and footnote 813: ‘In
response to a question from the Panel, both parties agreed that there is no relevant “international
standard” within the meaning of the second sentence of Article 2.5 of the TBT Agreement.’ It is
possible to monitor the status of TBT-related disputes at < http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/
dispu_e/dispu_ agreements_index_e.htm?id=A22#selected_agreement > .
69
See art 2(2) SPS: ‘Members shall ensure that any sanitary or phytosanitary measure is
applied only to the extent necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health, is based on
scientific principles and is not maintained without sufficient scientific evidence.’ The risk
assessment requirement (art 5(1) SPS) is the main pillar of the scientific basis for a SPS measure.
70 71 72
Art 2(3) SPS. Art 5(4) and 5(6) SPS. Art 3(3) SPS.
73
Art 5(5) SPS. Whereas there is no obligation to ensure internal regulatory consistency (States
are free to regulate similar risks differently), States are encouraged to adopt homogeneous
measures, and are not allowed to use their right to set a higher level of protection in order to
implement unjustified discriminations or disguised restrictions, see Hormones (n 51) para 213.
On these consistency requirements, see also the Appellate Body Report, Australia—Measures
Affecting Importation of Salmon (Australia–Salmon), WT/DS18/AB/R, adopted 6 November 1998,
DSR 1998:VIII, 3327, para 178.
74
See art 3(1), reading in the relevant part: ‘Members shall base their sanitary or phytosanitary
measures on international standards, guidelines or recommendations, where they exist’.
75
See annex A to the SPS Agreement, art 3. The IOE and the IPPC are, respectively, the
reference bodies for animal health and plant protection. Art 3(d) is an open clause, stating that for
matters not covered by the Codex, the IOE and the IPPC, a TBT-like method applies, and States
can rely on standards developed by international organizations whose membership is open to all
WTO members. This explicit reference can be read as an ‘ex post recognition of [the] ‘public
functions’ [of these bodies] which extends the scope of legal effect to third parties,’ see Cafaggi
(n 17) 29. For recent qualification of the Codex Commission as a ‘relevant international
organization’ see United States–Continued Suspension of Obligations in the EC–Hormones
Dispute, WT/DS320/R, Panel Report adopted 31 March 2008, para 7.446.
76
In fact, this presumption is wider, since art 2(5) TBT, as seen above, provides for an
expressly rebuttable presumption, and only with respect to the requirement of no unnecessary trade
restrictiveness.
77
Under which regulations stricter than those based on standards are permitted ‘if there is a
scientific justification, or as a consequence of the level of sanitary or phytosanitary protection a
Member determines to be appropriate’.
78
The Parties added a footnote to art 3(3) SPS to clarify the meaning of scientific justification,
which reads: ‘there is a scientific justification if, on the basis of an examination and evaluation of
available scientific information in conformity with the relevant provisions of this Agreement, a
Member determines that the relevant international standards, guidelines or recommendations are
not sufficient to achieve its appropriate level of sanitary or phytosanitary protection’.
79
This specification has a central role in the allocation of the onus probandi regarding the
violation of trade rules. Whereas the Panel had found that art 3(3) SPS works as an exception
(see Hormones panel (n 67), paras 8.51 to 8.54), in fact, the AB ruled instead that it rests with the
complainant, alleging a violation of art 3(3) SPS, to show at least a prima facie lack of scientific
basis for the challenged measure. In other words, deviation from the standards ‘is not penalized’
with a shift of the burden of proof on the defendant. See the AB report in Hormones (n 51) para 171
and Sardines (n 48). This is consistent with the above remark that deviation from the standards does
not trigger a presumption of illegality, in which case the defendant should have the burden of
rebutting the presumption. On the difference between this doctrine and the one adopted with respect
to the exceptional rules of art XX GATT and the Enabling Clause, see M Matsushita, ‘Human
Health Issues in Major WTO Dispute Cases’ (2009) 4 Asian Journal of WTO and International
Health Law and Policy, 1. See Howse (n 4) 388, as regards the similar provision of art 2(4) TBT.
80
A Guzman, ‘Global Governance and the WTO’ (2004) 45 Harvard Intl LJ 303.
81
JG Ruggie, ‘International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the
Postwar Economic Order’ (1982) 36 Intl Organization 379, 398.
82
M Ming Du, ‘Domestic Regulatory Autonomy under the TBT Agreement: From Non-
discrimination to Harmonization’ (2007) 6 Chinese J of Intl L 269, 272.
83
S Cassese, Shrimps, Turtles and Procedure: Global Standards for National Administrations
(Working Paper 2004/4 IILJ Global Administrative Law Series 2004) : ‘[standards] do not create
direct, legally binding obligations upon the States.’ See also Hormones AB Report (n 51) para 165.
84
A Reich, ‘The WTO as a Law-Harmonizing Institution’ (2004) 25 U of Pennsylvania J of
Intl Economic L 362. For an accurate account of the concept of negative integration and its
application in economic communities, see F Ortino, Basic Legal Instruments for the Liberalisation
of Trade: a Comparative Analysis of EC and WTO Law (Hart Publishing 2004) 18 and
bibliography referred to therein, in particular FW Scharpf, ‘Negative and Positive Integration in the
Political Economy of European Welfare States’ in G Marks, FW Scharpf, PC Schmitter and W
Streeck (eds), Governance in the European Union (SAGE 1996) 15.
85
In other words, the WTO does not try to bring about regulatory convergence. It is
disinterested in national policies, as long as they do not affect international trade, and whenever
they do, it just makes sure that the least restriction to trade is provoked. PC Mavroidis Market
Access in the GATT (Research Paper 7/2008 STALS 2008 available at < http://www.stals.sssup.it/
site/files/stals_Mavroidis.pdf >) 7: ‘national policies are being unilaterally defined and, to the extent
that there is an international spillover, it will be internalized through nondiscrimination. . . . Trade
will not harmonize societal preferences. Trade is not the overarching value in the WTO contract.
Trade comes after respect of regulatory diversity.’ On mutual recognition, harmonization and
regulatory authority, see JP Trachtman, ‘Regulatory Jurisdiction and the WTO’ in WJ Davey and
JH Jackson (eds), The Future of International Economic Law (OUP 2008) 193.
86
This species of harmonization is purported to be the one that negotiators of the SPS had in
mind: see Buthe (n 3) 242: ‘International harmonization would force countries with stringent
standards to justify those standards, providing opportunities for agricultural exporters to expose and
potentially block protectionist measures.’
87
For a definition of the ‘terms of trade’ expression see the Deardoff’s Glossary of International
Economics, available at < http://www-personal.umich.edu/~alandear/glossary > : ‘1. The relative
price, on world markets, of a country’s exports compared to its imports.’
88
An accurate description and distinction of these two trade-policy goals is contained in DH
Regan, ‘What Are Trade Agreements for?—Two Conflicting Stories Told by Economists, with a
Lesson for Lawyers’ (2006) 9 J of Intl Economic L 951.
89
RW Staiger and AO Sykes, International Trade and Domestic Regulation (Working Paper
15541 NBER 2009) 19–22.
90
For instance, governments pursue terms-of-trade purposes when they try to safeguard
exporters’ revenues at the expense of global efficiency.
91
Staiger and Sykes (n 89) 29; Trachtman (n 85) 195; G Marceau and JP Trachtman,
‘Responding to national concerns’ in D Bethlehem and others (eds), Oxford Handbook of
International Trade Law (OUP 2009) 209, 235.
92
RE Hudec, ‘Science and Post-Discriminatory WTO Law’ (2003) 26 Boston College Intl and
Comparative L Rev 185, 187.
C. No Hardening
1. Reverse Hardening (Standards are used as a Protection Ceiling)
As observed above, several scholars link the quasi-judicial functions of DSB
bodies with the effectiveness of ISO and Codex standards, and consider that the
latter have undergone a process of hardening, as they are enforced in the WTO
system within a framework of compulsory jurisdiction. For example, Pereira
states that: ‘If one considers that the Appellate Body has been interpreting the
93
Note that according to DH Regan (n 88) 980–981, SPS and TBT’s requirements for efficient
standards (and trade agreements in general) are aimed only at preventing protectionism, and are not
designed to exorcise terms-of-trade manipulation, a goal that is rarely used as an actual regulatory
purpose by State authorities. However, this conclusion is in consequence of Regan’s persuasion
(at 986–988) that the SPS and TBT are solely concerned with hidden protectionist measures and
should not be used to strike down merely inefficient or unnecessarily restrictive measures, to the
point of doubting ‘whether the substantive provisions of the SPS and TBT Agreements—about the
use of international standards, and risk assessment, and the avoidance of unnecessarily trade-
restrictive measures—are a good thing.’
94
See PC Mavroidis, ‘Come together?: Producer Welfare, Consumer Welfare and WTO Rules’
in EU Petersmann (ed), Reforming the world trading system: legitimacy, efficiency and democratic
governance (OUP 2005) 277, 285; Buthe (n 3) 246, stressing that resort to standards was a device
through which SPS negotiators intended to simplify the scientific review of national measures,
avoiding costly case by case risk assessment procedures.
95
See US—Hormones suspension, panel report (n 75), para 7.644: ‘standards, guidelines or
recommendations . . . are based on risk assessments that meet the requirements of the SPS
Agreement. This means, therefore, that there was sufficient evidence for [the standard-setting body]
to undertake the appropriate risk assessments’.
96
G Marceau and JP Trachtman, ‘The Technical Barriers to Trade Agreement, the Sanitary and
Phytosanitary Measures Agreement and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade’ (2002) 36
J of World Trade 811, 838; Buthe (n 3).
97
Pereira (n 7) 1704.
98
Allegedly, Japan lowered its domestic pesticide standards which provided greater public
health protection than was required by Codex standards, in order to prevent WTO litigation with
New Zealand or the US, see LM Wallach, ‘Accountable Governance in the Era of Globalization:
The WTO, Nafta, and International Harmonization of Standards’ (2002) 50 U of Kansas L Rev
823, 838; Y Naiki, ‘Accountability and Legitimacy in Global Health and Safety Governance: The
World Trade Organization, the SPS Committee and International Standard setting Organizations’
(2009) 43 J of World Trade 1255, 1276; Victor (n 40) 879. See Hormones AB Report (n 51) para
177.
99
Pauwelyn (n 17) 213 succinctly phrases this interpretation as: ‘the incentive to harmonize is
limited to the safe-haven offered by conforming to the standard.’ Note that the Panel, when
analyzing the structure of art 2 TBT and 3 SPS, excluded the possibility that departure from a
standard could be construed as an exception: ‘the Appellate Body found no general rule-exception
relationship even though the word ‘except’ was used in both Article 3.1 of the SPS Agreement and
Article 2.4 of the TBT Agreement.’ See EC—Tariff Preferences, report of 1 December 2003, WT/
100
DS246/R, fn 452. Namely, art 5(1) and 3(3) SPS.
101
See Hormones (n 51) paras 208–209.
102
See Buthe (n 3) 228: ‘the freedom to adopt more stringent standards is subject to more, not
fewer constraints.’
103
See J Wouters, A Marx and N Hachez, Private Standards, Global Governance and
Transatlantic Cooperation, the Case of Global Food Safety Governance (Working Paper Leuven
Centre for Global Governance Studies 2009) 14–15 : ‘Any food safety regulation which is
more lenient than a Codex Alimentarius Standard does not violate the SPS Agreement.’ See also
D Kalderimis, ‘Problems of WTO Harmonization and the Virtues of Shields Over Swords’ (2004)
13 Minnesota J of Global Trade 305, 337–341 : ‘SPS and TBT Agreements . . . do not prescribe any
essential requirements because they do not promote any non-trade values. The WTO does not
provide minimum standards of health protection, or specify minimum levels of technical
regulations’. See also Wirth (n 37) 95. Contra, arguing that the obligation not to deviate from
standards is enforceable also in case of looser regulations, see Howse (n 4) 395. See also Hormones
(n 51) para 165, noting that it would be excessive to assume that SPS signatories intended to vest
more stringent voluntary international standards with obligatory force and that, under the in dubio
pro mitius general principle of international law, States should be allowed to maintain their ‘less
burdensome’ obligations. The AB refers to ‘sovereign states’ as a whole, failing to grasp the core of
the issue: technical requirements that are burdensome for some States (exporters) might be
beneficial for others (importers). The AB’s remark, thus, should be read in the sense that exporters
could not deliberately give up the voluntary nature of international standards, to their own
detriment.
104
Wouters, Marx and Hachez (n 103) 15 notes that SPS uses the standards as ‘upper limits’.
Likewise, Landwehr in Wolfrum, Soll and Seibert-Fohr (n 42) 414: ‘the [SPS] Agreement has
effectively changed the nature of these standards: while the standards were originally developed as
minimum standards, they are now used in dispute settlement proceedings as ceilings which—in
principle—have to be observed.’ Similarly, Wirth (n 37) 96.
105
Curiously, the ISO itself, on its website, refers to the ‘floor’ concept of common standards,
even precisely in connection with their trade function: ‘International Standards create ‘a level
playing field’ for all competitors on those markets. The existence of divergent national or regional
standards can create technical barriers to trade.’ On Codex standards as minimum quality standards,
see Livermore (n 4) 768, 771.
106
Pauwelyn (n 17) 213ff raises the question whether TBT and SPS could be used to ratchet-up
national policies or solely to use international standards as a ceiling. His accurate reading of the
TBT and SPS provisions seems to leave space for the ‘upward harmonizing’ view: since members
‘shall’ use standards as a basis for regulations (art 2(4) TBT and 3(1) SPS), it would seem that there
is an actual WTO obligation not to pierce the floor of standard protection by adopting looser
regulations. Even though it could be formally true, some normative elements and a factual
consideration virtually make this reading unlikely, or irrelevant. First, as Pauwelyn concedes,
looser domestic regulations would hardly meet the requirements of art 1(1) SPS (the Agreement
applies only to measures that are likely to affect international trade), and the TBT repeatedly links
the function of standards with the risk of trade distortion (implicitly ignoring their supposed
relevance as minimum protection floor), in the preamble and in art 2(1), 2(2), 2(4), 2(5), 2(9).
Moreover, more pragmatically, it is highly unlikely that a member would challenges a domestic
regulation of another member imposing looser standards, as this measure could not (negatively)
affect its interests (as an exporter); as Pauwelyn states: ‘The odd result of this is that the WTO
would then essentially grant a request to restrict trade more (that is, ask the defendant to impose
stricter SPS measures).’ Likewise Victor (n 40) 883–884 acknowledges that in the SPS looser
national regulations may still be challenged, but not so much in that they deviate from standards,
but only under art 5 tests (risk assessment and scientific justification). For instance, low-protection
national regulations may prove burdensome just because they were only adopted in one country,
making it relatively expensive for companies to adapt their activity just to gain access on that
market. In any event, Victor concedes that the hypothesis is unlikely, ‘because demonstrating the
existence of a trade effect from weak SPS measures is difficult and bringing disputes is
107
costly’. VCLT (n 9), art 31(1).
108
See Howse (n 4) 387.
109
See Hormones (n 51) para 171, emphasis added.
110
Reading, in the relevant part: ‘Members shall ensure that technical regulations are not
prepared, adopted or applied with a view to or with the effect of creating unnecessary obstacles to
international trade. For this purpose, technical regulations shall not be more trade-restrictive than
necessary to fulfill a legitimate objective, taking account of the risks non-fulfillment would create.’
111
This burden is additional to the one typically reserved to complainants, that is, proving the
existence of trade impairment subsequent to the adoption of the challenged measure.
112
This hypothesis must nevertheless be taken into account, at least to maintain a distinction
between the two benefits granted by art 3(2) SPS. On one hand, the necessity requirement is
irrefutably satisfied (‘shall be deemed to be necessary’), on the other hand, every other provision of
the SPS and the GATT is simply ‘presumed’ to be complied with.
113
See Howse (n 4) 388–389.
114
To the contrary, if any importance were attached to the dynamics of the burden of proof in
the treatment of standards, it would be clear that the hardest task is assigned to States that want to
‘surpass’ the standards: they have to prove the standards’ inefficiency and inappropriateness.
115
To date, only five disputes hinging upon the application of the SPS have been brought before
the panels and the AB: EC—Measures Concerning Meat and Meat Products, Panel Report WT/
DS26/R/USA adopted 18 August 1997; AB Report WT/DS26/AB/R adopted 16 January 1998.
Australia—Measures Affecting Importation of Salmon, Panel Report WT/DS18/R adopted 12 June
1998; Appellate Body Report WT/DS18/AB/R adopted 20 October 1998. Japan—Measures
Affecting Agricultural Products (Apples), Panel Report WT/DS76/R adopted 27 October 1998;
Appellate Body Report WT/DS76/AB/R adopted 22 February 1999. Japan—Measures Affecting
the Importation of Apples, Panel Report WT/DS245/R adopted 15 July 2003; Appellate Body
Report WT/DS245/AB/R adopted 26 November 2003. For a full description of this case law, see
Matsushita (n 79). Other disputes were filed relating to SPS provisions without triggering the
adoption of a panel report, see WT/DS3 Korea—Measures Concerning the Testing and Inspection
of Agricultural Products; WT/DS144, United States—Certain Measures Affecting the Import of
Cattle, Swine and Grain from Canada and WT/DS100, United States—Measures Affecting Imports
of Poultry Products. The GMO disputes against the EC (WT/DS291, 292 & 293, European
Communities—Measures Affecting the Approval and Marketing of Biotech Products) were not
appealed before the AB. In 2010, SPS norms were discussed by the panel in US—Certain
Measures Affecting Imports of Poultry from China Panel Report WT/DS392/R adopted
29 September 2010, but the dispute did not touch upon relevant international standards.
Similarly, in the New Zealand Apples dispute art 3 SPS was not invoked nor applied (see
Australia—Measures Affecting the Importation of Apples from New Zealand, Panel Report WT/
DS367/R adopted 9 August 2010; Appellate Body Report WT/DS367/AB/R adopted
29 November 2010). As for TBT-cases, see cases above (n 69).
116
See the data provided in Naiki (n 98) 1265–1266. In fact, in the case of TBT, China is also a
frequent target of trade concerns, presumably due to the difficulty of exporters to adapt their
business to new China-specific registration or verification requirements, quite apart from their
stringency. As for SPS trade concerns, see the data available in T Epps, International Trade and
Health Protection (Elgar Northampton 2008) 32–33, and V Zahrnt ‘Transparency of complex
regulation: how should WTO trade policy reviews deal with sanitary and phytosanitary policies?
(2010) World Trade Rev—FirstView 13: ‘What [exporters] target is poor risk assessment, overly
trade-restrictive measures, and levels of protection that are well above the implementing country’s
average level as well as above international standards.’
117
A study of the negotiation process leading to the adoption of the SPS (Buthe (n 3) 239–241)
seems to confirm that the only rationale for the proposals to take into account international
standards was that of ‘minimizing the adverse effects that [safety] regulations and barriers can have
on trade’. Excerpt from WTO, Ministerial Declaration of 20 September 1986, MIN(86(/W/19, 25
ILM 1623, 1626 (1986). See also the dictum of the panel in US Poultry (n 115) para 5.75: ‘it is
clear that an SPS measure can only be introduced provided that it is based on international
standards, guidelines and recommendations where they exist . . . This is to ensure that measures are
not taken arbitrarily and are not used as a tool for manipulating international trade.’ (emphasis
added)
118
See supra, nn (102 to 104 and 106) for a sample of the available studies on this point.
However, these sparse remarks have not been used against the ‘hardening’ narrative, as this article
seeks to do.
119
J Scott, The WTO Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (OUP 2007)
120 121
261–266. ibid 262. ibid 263.
122
See Hormones (n 51) para 165, and the analysis supra (n 103).
123
Scott (n 119) 264.
D. A Counterfactual
Is it possible that lower-than-standard national measures may in fact
be successfully challenged under the TBT and SPS? Albeit residual, this
hypothesis cannot be categorically excluded, and the very limited case-law
available allows for no absolute certainty on this issue.
As seen above, regulations lessening the protection provided by relevant
international standards might be deemed to violate articles 2(4) TBT and 3(1)
SPS. This would hold true assuming that these regulations have some
detrimental effect on trade, both to meet the letter of article 1(1) TBT and, more
generally, to hypothesize a reasonable litigation scenario under the terms of
article XXIII GATT, providing that the launch of a settlement mechanism
follows the alleged nullification or impairment of some trade benefits.
First, it seems that the requirement that regulations ‘be based on’ relevant
standards is more elastic downwards than upwards. As seen above, regulations
‘based on’ standards (articles 3(1) SPS and 2(4) TBT) do not require their
complete incorporation,125 unlike measures ‘conforming to’ or ‘in accordance
with’ them (articles 3(2) SPS and 2(5) TBT). Although the case-law has not yet
clarified the scope and quality of such a divide, it has made clear that when
compliance with the international standard can result in a violation of the
domestic regulation, this latter cannot be deemed to be adopted ‘on the basis’
of the former.126
In the case of looser standards, in fact, it seems that such one-sense
contradiction would not arise.127 Let us rehearse the Sardines example.
124
ibid 265–266. These conclusions are replicated and agreed upon in L Gruszczynski,
Regulating Health and Environmental Risks under WTO Law (OUP 2010) 102–104. On
the flexibility devices of TBT and SPS designed to accommodate developing countries’ needs
see G Mayeda, ‘Developing Disharmony? The SPS and TBT Agreements and the Impact of
Harmonization on Developing Countries’ (2004) 7 J of Intl Economic L 737, 746ff.
125 126
See Hormones (n 51) para 163. See Sardines (n 48) para 248.
127
See S Charnovitz, ‘The Supervision of Health and Biosafety Regulation by World Trade
Rules’ (2000) 13 Tulane Environmental LJ 271, 287, noting that looser regulations would not be
illegal for the very fact that they deviate in peius from standards, since they would still be expected
to meet the other requirements (scientific justification, non-discrimination, least-restrictiveness).
We just note that not only is compliance with such requirements easier to achieve in the case of less
stringent regulations (with the only possible exception of the alignment obligation under art 5(5)
SPS), but—primarily—it seems unlikely that such regulations are ever challenged by foreign
exporting countries, if only in that they could hardly entail any detrimental trade effect.
128
Compliance with the measure, instead, might result in a deviation from the Codex standards,
but their voluntary nature would imply little consequence in case of violation, at least outside the
Codex regime.
129
See, for instance, the table of cases and complaints included in the Fifteenth Annual Review
of the Implementation and Operation of the TBT Agreement, prepared by the TBT Committee and
published on 5 February 2010, document No G/TBT/28, and the detailed ‘trade concerns’ raised at
the June and November 2009 sessions by the Member States (see the respective Minutes of each
session in documents G/TBT/M/48 of 29 September 2009 and G/TBT/M/49 of 22 December
2009). The only concerns which do not squarely deal with the stringency of the standards deal with
their unreasonableness. For instance, the EC expressed some concern on the possibility that Brazil
introduced a verification procedure on imported health products based on requirements other than
those already included in an ISO standard. The EC insists that these procedures be based on the ISO
standards (see the Minutes of the November meeting, para 142) not so much because they are more
lenient (in fact, it does not transpire that they are) but because, by their very divergence from the
standards, they are unreasonably burdensome.
Likewise, in the SPS framework, concerns reflect the awareness that standards are likely to be
used to foster trade more than health concerns. See, for instance, the debate about the possible
adoption of a Codex standard setting the maximum residue of ractopamine in pork and swine feed.
It is significant that those who push for the adoption of the Codex standard are indeed the States
willing to market meat administered with ractopamine, whereas the EC and China, who had
concerns about the harmfulness of this substance, appear reluctant to accelerate the standard-setting
activity. Under a very candid cost-benefit perspective, it transpires that it is preferable for States that
are relatively more concerned with health protection not to have the standard at all, than to have it
used in the SPS system as an anti-regulation device enforceable by the DSB (see Summary of the
Meeting of the SPS Committee of 28–29 October 2009, document G/SPS/R/56 of 28 January
2010, particularly paras 141ff.
In the previous part of this article, it was indicated that the purpose of ISO and
Codex standard-setting systems is conceptually confused, which may serve to
explain the apparent schizophrenia of the standards hypothesized above. With
respect to the Codex, it seems clear that in the WTO regime the prevailing
purpose of the standards is ‘to guide and promote the elaboration and
establishment of definitions and requirements for foods to assist in their
harmonization and in doing so to facilitate international trade’.132 The same
holds true with ISO standards; among the various purposes of the standard-
setting activity, the only relevant one in the WTO appears to be that of granting
to ‘businesses using International Standards’ market access to ‘many more
markets around the world’.133
130
See the Minutes of the June 2009 meeting of the TBT Committee (n 129), particularly para
326. On the issue of private regulation regimes and the WTO, see S Bernstein and E Hannah, ‘Non-
State Global Standard Setting and The WTO: Legitimacy and the Need for Regulatory Space’
(2008) 11 J of Intl Economic L 575; Vogel (n 17) 264–265.
131
These measures would be challengeable under SPS and TBT to the extent that it is relatively
easier for the complainant to show that, whatever the interest they are alleged to protect, less
restrictive alternative measures are available. In this extreme case, however, it would be less a
matter of protection than of mere unreasonableness and inefficiency of the policy adopted.
132
See Codex General Principles, ‘Purpose of the Codex Alimentarius,’ available at < http://
www.fao.org/DOCREP/005/Y2200E/y2200e05.htm#bm05 > . See the statement of WTO Director-
General Pascal Lamy: ‘[the SPS Agreement] was not primarily conceived with consumers in
mind.’ Address at the Assembly of Consumers Associations in Europe Conference (18–19
November 1999), available at < http://ec.europa.eu/dgs/health_consumer/library/speeches/
speech25_en.html > .
133
See < http://www.iso.org/iso/about/discovers-iso_who-standards-benefits.htm > .
134
United Nations General Assembly Resolution A/RES/39/248 of 16 April 1985, mentioned
in Henson and Humphrey (n 13) 23, emphasis added.
135
Wouters, Marx and Hachez (n 103) 14. See the remarks expressed above about the
ambiguity of the SPS Preamble.
136
In the TBT and SPS, national technical regulations are treated as NTB (non-tariff barriers),
and can be reviewed to prevent national practices of ‘regulatory protectionism’. See Buthe (n 3)
222; AO Sykes, ‘Regulatory Protectionism and the Law of International Trade’ (1999) 66 U of
Chicago L Rev 1.
137
The possibility that legal elements are transformed when they are used in a different regime is
a classic example of interplay between legal orders, see for instance how Santi Romano,
L’ordinamento giuridico (Sansoni Firenze 1946) n 96bis described the possible ways in which one
legal order (or part thereof) can be relevant to another legal order: ‘[i]t can disregard or refuse
another order’s existence; it can take another order into consideration, but providing it with a
different nature than the one this latter would attribute to itself. Likewise, a legal order can equate
another legal order to a mere fact, ignoring his legal nature, or acknowledge it as a legal system,
but only to a certain extent and to certain effects, perhaps subject to the conditions that it deems
opportune to impose’ (emphasis added). Note that the use of standards as facts (ie, as static units of
measurement) has little to do with the well known issue of the proof of foreign law (regarding the
difficulties arising when the law of one order has to be proved and applied before a court of another
legal system), which is generally summarized with the maxim that the proof of foreign law is proof
of fact (see, for instance, A Miller, ‘Federal Rule 44.1 and the ‘Fact’ Approach to Determining
Foreign Law: Death Knell for Die-Hard Doctrine’ (1967) 65 Michigan L Rev 613).
a) Implementation
The shift in purpose142 that we have described requires a re-thinking of the
implementation phase. Trade-related and harmonization concerns are satisfied
by national authorities and regulators better than by single firms; indeed, the
monitoring and enforcement phases in the WTO do not generally target firms’
deviation from standards, but rather State failure to ensure a fair market
138
Shamir-Borer (n 31) 23.
139
Pauwelyn (n 51) 226: ‘knowing that standards are no longer voluntary but at least partially
enforceable at the WTO, countries may be wary to issue new standards’. See Victor (n 40) 931: ‘the
agenda and standards in the Codex are determined heavily by the SPS policies in the advanced
industrialized countries’.
140
S Maljean-Dubois and É Etchelar, ‘World Trade and International Normalisations: Codex
Alimentarius’ in K Byttebier and K Van der Borght (eds), WTO Obligations and Opportunities:
Challenges of Implementation (Cameron May London 2007) 121, 141: ‘By making the Codex
adopt its point of view, a state of a group of states is (almost) totally sheltered from being
sanctioned by the WTO’.
141
See Sardines (n 48) 275.
142
As for standards in the TBT, it is significant to note how the Russian-doll-like inextricable
definition of standards betrays to some extent this shift (from common good to trade). Whereas the
Agreement in itself is consistent in referring to standards as an element of trade facilitation,
compare the text of a footnote with the definition of standards contained in the ISO/IEC Guide
2:2004 referred to by annex 1.2 to the TBT, whose definitions are, in turn, recalled by art 1(2) TBT:
‘Standards should be based on the consolidated results of science, technology and experience, and
aimed at the promotion of optimum community benefits’ (emphasis added). In relation to the
implementation of Codex standards, see Henson and Humphrey (n 13) 5, stressing that the
implementation of standards is not compliance by firms, but rather adoption by States: ‘Codex does
not implement or assess conformity with the international standards, guidelines and
recommendations it develops. Rather, implementation is dependent on adoption by Codex
members, in whole or in part and formally or informally, and/or incorporation into the standards of
other bodies, including private standards setters.’
b) Monitoring
Monitoring of member countries’ compliance seems to depend largely on the
possibility of setting up trade disputes.143 Therefore, actors monitoring
compliance with standards are export firms and exporting States, that is to
say trade-affected parties. The SPS Committee has adopted a monitoring
procedure on compliance with international standards, as required by article
12 SPS. However, it is pretty evident that the real object of the monitoring
activity is the potential occurrence of trade effects connected with the
standards.144
c) Enforcement
Enforcement is provided by the Dispute Settlement Mechanism of the WTO,
triggered following the failure of amicable negotiations and the submission of a
claim by a State. In case of violation, the panel or the AB orders the losing State
to bring the challenged measures into compliance; in our case, this means that
the State must amend the regulatory measure challenged, either to make it
consistent with the ISO or Codex standards, or in a way that allows the State to
meet the further conditions of article 3(3) SPS or 2(5) TBT. In cases of
continuous non-compliance, and subject to further judicial authorization and
143
Pereira (n 7) 1703.
144
See the wording of the SPS Committee decision revising the monitoring procedure
established in 1997 (G/SPS/11/Rev.1 of 15 November 2004): ‘5. The international standards,
guidelines or recommendations proposed by a Member to be monitored . . . should be limited to
those which have a major trade impact. The trade impact of an international standard, guideline or
recommendation should be determined primarily on the basis of the extent to which Members use
the standard (apply it to imports) and the frequency or severity of problems experienced in the trade
of the goods covered by the standard’. See Joint FAO/WHO Food Standard Programme Codex
Alimentarius Commission, Thirtieth Session Rome, Italy, 2–7 July 2007, Activities of the SPS
Committee and Other Relevant WTO Activities from 2006 to the Present, Report by the WTO
Secretariat: ‘Monitoring the Use of International Standards 12. The procedure adopted by the SPS
Committee to monitor the use of international standards invites countries to identify specific trade
problems they have experienced due to the use or non-use of relevant international standards,
guidelines or recommendations’ (available at < ftp://ftp.fao.org/codex/CAC/CAC30/if30_05e.
pdf >). See Naiki (n 98) 1274, noting that the procedure is not used substantively, and targets
only standards with a major trade impact.
145
Under DSU art 21(5).
146
See the Arbor Drugs case (Baker v Arbor Drugs, Inc., 544 NW2d 727, 731; (Mich Ct App)
1996) described in Chan (n 30) 1147–1148: ‘[the] defendant voluntarily assumed a duty of care
when it implemented [a ISO 9000 certified software system for the management of drug
prescriptions] and then advertised that this system would detect harmful drug interactions for its
customers’ (emphasis added). This example is particularly significant because it displays how ISO
standards can be interpreted before a non-WTO court, and serve as foundation of a due diligence
defence that has nothing to do with the presumption of WTO-compliance provided in the TBT
Agreement. ibid 1153–1160, see how additional self-failure assessment requirements (Failure
Mode and Effects Analysis) enshrined in the QS 9000 standards for designers and manufacturers
(the US version of ISO 9000) could end by substantiating plaintiffs’ claims for product liability:
‘FMEAs inherently provide all the basic ammunition to a plaintiff to establish a design [or
manufacturing] defect, [or a] a marketing defect or failure to warn.’ See also Bruno and Pynnonen
(n 39) 1080: ‘Even if ISO 9000 adoption statements are not interpreted to give rise to independent
obligations, they may be sufficient under the UCC to render the seller’s warranty disclaimers
unreasonable, and thus ineffective’.
147
For an appraisal of the relationship between standards and liability in the area of product
safety, see Cafaggi (n 17) 10. See for instance Preamble, point no 14, arts 3(2) and 3(3) of the
Product Safety EC Directive 2001/95/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of
3 December 2001, OJ L 11, 15.1.2002, p 4–17, setting forth a presumption of safety for the
products conforming to national standards transposing European safety standards. This is a telling
example of the ‘New Approach’ adopted by the EU, whereby the Commission sets the general
requirements for products and services, leaving it to voluntary standards the task of providing
detailed specifics. In this framework, the main standardization body is the CEN (Comité Européen
de Normalisation), an organization comprised of all EU members national standardization bodies.
See J Morrison and N Roht Arriaza, ‘Private and Quasi-private Standard Setting’ in D Bodansky
and others (eds), Oxford Handbook of International Environmental Law (OUP 2007) 498, 520.
148
Bruno and Pynnonen (n 39) 1076: ‘The ISO 9000 series is a set of standardized procedures
and principles that sellers can adopt to ensure customer satisfaction. . . . Customer satisfaction, both
with the product and with the system developed to create the product, is the ultimate goal’.
149
This is somewhat different from the EC approach to technical standardization. Although
many of the principles underpinning this ‘new approach to technical harmonisation’ (see at < http://
europa.eu/legislation_summaries/internal_market/single_market_for_goods/technical_harmonisation/
l21001a_en.htm >) recall those laid down in the TBT and professed by the TBT Committee, yet
compliance with the standards is not a mere defence against the charge of trade-restrictiveness, but
creates a presumption of good faith in that it creates a link between the technical regulation and the
‘essential requirements’ and public interest it pursues. See Council Resolution of 7 May 1985 on a
new approach to technical harmonization and standards (Council Resolution (85/C 136/01),
Official Journal C 136 of 4 June 1985; referring to the Council Directive 83/189/EEC of 28 March
1983 laying down a procedure for the provision of information in the field of technical standards
and regulations, Official Journal L 109 of 26 April 1983.
150
See SA Shapiro, ‘International Trade Agreements, Regulatory Protection, and Public
Accountability’ (2002) 54 Administrative L Rev 435, 451: ‘when international standard-setting
organizations issue standards that are less stringent than similar regulations in the United States, it
opens the door for other countries to challenge more stringent American regulations.’
151
See JH Mathis, ‘The WTO Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT) Interaction with
international standards and implications for consumers’ in K Dawar (n 33) 105, 124: ‘From a
national consumer perspective, it seems that the substance question turns upon whether a standard
is posing as a floor or as a ceiling.’ To the extent that the ceiling-argument has been proved, above,
it follows that consumers are indeed worse off.
V. CONCLUSION
152
See Henson and Humphrey (n 13), noting that the slow process guided by WTO case law
would be ineffective in any event in influencing the regulatory regime timely.
153
For instance, by including a reference to the standards in government procurement
instructions, see eg Chan (n 30) 1216: ‘the U.S. Federal Acquisition Regulations specify ISO 9000
and QS-9000 as examples of quality standards that may be required for compliance with higher-
154
level contract quality requirements’. Victor (n 40) 920.
155
ibid (2000) 924. Charnovitz (n 127) 284–285; see also WTO Committee on Sanitary and
Phytosanitary Measures, Proposed Guidelines to Further the Practical Implementation of Article
5.5, G/SPS/W/104, para A.4 (20 March 2000).
156
Wirth (n 37) 96: ‘operating through the TBT Agreement, non-binding ISO standards may
acquire international legal significance, may be transformed from minimum standards of
performance into regulatory ceilings from which governments must justify departure in terms of
greater rigor.’
157
Roht-Arriaza (n 37) 510, describing ISO practices: ‘the global standard serves only as a
158
floor.’ Staiger and Sykes (n 89) 40.