China's Growth Miracle: Past, Present, and Future: Li Yang
China's Growth Miracle: Past, Present, and Future: Li Yang
China's Growth Miracle: Past, Present, and Future: Li Yang
Li Yang1
1
Vice President, academic member and professor of the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS).
1
As can be seen in Figure 1, from AD 1 to the middle of 19th century,
China’ share of world GDP remained about 25%, exceeding that of Western
European countries. In particular, around 1820, this share rose to 33%, a
record high level over the past two millenniums. Nevertheless, China’s
economy had long stagnated since then, resulting in a decline of its relative
GDP size vis-à-vis the world and a record low level, 4.6%, in 1950.
Subsequently after three decades of drastic economic fluctuations, around
1980, China started rapid economic growth, resulting in the rise of its GDP
share of the world total, from 5.2% in 1980 to 17.5% in 2008.
Notes: 1. Data come from World Economic Outlook Database, April 2013, IMF.
2. According to the figure, in 2013, the emerging and developing economies’ share of world
GDP will for the first time exceed that of advanced economies.
2
Notes: 1. Data come from World Development Indicators, April 2013, World Bank.
2. Left hand coordinate: GDP growth rate of the “World”, “World excluding China”, and
“China”; right hand coordinate: “China’s contribution” which equals the difference of the GDP growth
rate of the “World” and that of “World excluding China”.
As illustrated in Figure 3, from the 1978, China’s GDP grew faster than
that of the world total, without exception. It means that the contribution of
China to the world GDP growth remains positive, and tends to be
increasingly important since the 1990s. For instance, in 2011, the growth rate
of world economy is 2.73%, of which 0.56% is due to China.
Over the past three decades, China’s growth miracle can be viewed as the
most impressive, lasting, and complex in terms of institutional changes and
constraint conditions in the human history of economic growth, which is
generally praised by both prestigious international organizations and
economists. However, it should be stressed that such miracle is by no means
costless. It is highly needed to reexamine the characteristics of China’s growth
based on the experiences of the last 30 years, and to promote the
transformation of growth mode towards a well balanced and sustainable
development path.
3
1. Main factors determining China’s economic growth
4
according to the market pricing mechanism. From Figures 5,6,7,8, and 9, a
clear trend of market-oriented transformation can be identified.
5
Figure 7: Contribution of state-owned sector to the total urban employment
(%)
6
Figure 9: Contribution of state-owned sector to the total fixed assets
investment (%)
100%
State sector's contribution to FAI
80%
60%
40%
20%
0%
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
(2)Constant opening-up
Another indispensable factor explaining China’s growth miracle is
constant opening-up, which is equally guided by the principle of gradualism.
Regarding the space structure, the markets successively opened up from the
special economic zones, economic and technological development zones,
coastal economic development zones, riparian regions, inland regions, and
finally the whole China; regarding the industrial structure, from the
advantaged manufacturing industry, to the less advantaged agriculture and
service industries. In 2001, China’s entry into the WTO can be regarded as a
milestone: China’s opening up transformed from selective policy measures to
widespread and deep institutional arrangements. Since then, China has
integrated into the labor division of the global market system, under which
China and the rest of the world benefit from each other.
7
Notes: 1. Data come from World Development Indicators, April 2013, World Bank.
2. As the ‘World Factory’, China’s manufactured goods account for over 90 % of
all exported goods of the country. Moreover, the relative share of high-technology goods
was increasing since the 1990s. This trend stopped, however, in recent year, indicating a
less sophisticated export structure.
As shown in Figure 11, since the 1990s, China’s tariff rates gradually
decreased. In particular, after the entry into WTO in 2001, the rates
significantly declined. Nevertheless, compared to other countries, the rates for
manufactured products remain high, and those for primary products appear
low. For instance, in 2010, the rates applied to all the products, manufactured
products, and primary products are 4.0%, 5.6%, and 1.8%, respectively. Those
for the developing countries as a whole, are 4.3%, 5.2%, and 2.7%,
respectively.
8
Figure 12: International comparison: FDI net inflows (% of GDP)
From 1992 onwards, the absolute and relative sizes of the FDI inwards of
China rose significantly. In 1991 China only attracted $4.37 billion of FDI,
accounted for namely 1.15% of GDP, while in the next year, the two indicators
increased to $11.16 and 2.64%, respectively. In 1993, they further jumped to
$27.52 and 6.25%, respectively, enabling China to become the largest recipient
of FDI among developing countries. In some years (such as 2003), China even
overtook the US and became the No.1 recipient among all countries.
9
Figure 13.1: Industrial structure: China (value-added as % of GDP)
11
(OECD)
Developing countries 25.7 28.8 33.3 38.0 43.5 34.2
World 35.1 37.7 40.9 44.5 49.3 41.8
Data source: World Development Indicators, April 2013, World Bank.
12
Source: World Development Indicators, April 2013, World Bank.
14
process of urbanization. Looking ahead, China’s industrialization will follow
a new path relying on green industry, information technique, intelligence,
and servicization. Meanwhile, China’s urbanization will focus on the
coordinated urban-rural development, modernization of agriculture, and
equalization of public services.
Savings and investment. In the future, both the savings and investment
rates seem to remain high compared to other countries. Although the former
will still exceed the latter, the gap tends to be narrowed. On the one hand,
China should make more effort to improve the efficiency of investment. This
concern is of paramount importance given the fact that facing the tendency of
population ageing (see Figure 18), the contribution of ‘population dividend’
to economic growth is disappearing, and consequently the savings tend to be
reduced. On the other hand, China will balance its demand structure by
boosting domestic consumption.
15
Figure 19: Global imbalances (% of world GDP)
After witnessing rapid growth over the last three decades, China’s
economic expansion tends to slow down from 2012. According to the
macroeconomic model of the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS), the
potential growth rate is in the range of 7.8%-8.7% during 2011-2015,
5.7%-6.6% during 2016-2020, 5.4%-6.3% during 2021-2030.
17